ArticlePublisher preview available

Eugen Schmalenbach, Austrian economics, and German business economics

Authors:
To read the full-text of this research, you can request a copy directly from the authors.

Abstract

Eugen Schmalenbach was one of the founding fathers of business economics theory in the German-speaking world in the first half of the twentieth century. While Mises mentions or discusses Schmalenbach’s work several times and Schmalenbach refers to, for example, Menger and Böhm-Bawerk, his opus and its significance for Austrian theorizing is largely ignored by today’s Austrian scientific community. This fact is astonishing given that Schmalenbach’s work smoothly integrates with and, even more importantly, enhances the reach of Austrian theory into the field of business economics, particularly with regard to the vast field of economic calculation. Based on Austrian insights, Schmalenbach published extensive approaches to both retrospective and anticipatory monetary calculation that serve the entrepreneur in making decisions on the use of scarce resources and in assessing the success of such decisions ex post. Hence, he operationalized Austrian economic calculation to enable the individual entrepreneur to concretely exercise it in his routine course of business. The conceptual ideas of Schmalenbach are cornerstones of Prussian-German business economics (Betriebswirtschaftslehre) which has been taught in universities and business schools in German-speaking countries for more than a century now. This paper, therefore, aims to introduce the Austrian community to Schmalenbach’s work, to emphasize its significance for the advancement of Austrian theorizing, and to illustrate the close relations between Austrian economics and German business economics.
Eugen Schmalenbach, Austrian economics,
and German business economics
Michael Olbrich
1
&David J. Rapp
2,3
&Florian Follert
1
#Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2020
Abstract
Eugen Schmalenbach was one of the founding fathers of business economics
theory in the German-speaking world in the first half of the twentieth century.
While Mises mentions or discusses Schmalenbachs work several times and
Schmalenbach refers to, for example, Menger and Böhm-Bawerk, his opus and
its significance for Austrian theorizing is largely ignored by todays Austrian
scientific community. This fact is astonishing given that Schmalenbachswork
smoothly integrates with and, even more importantly, enhances the reach of
Austrian theory into the field of business economics, particularly with regard to
the vast field of economic calculation. Based on Austrian insights,
Schmalenbach published extensive approaches to both retrospective and antici-
patory monetary calculation that serve the entrepreneur in making decisions on
the use of scarce resources and in assessing the success of such decisions ex
post. Hence, he operationalized Austrian economic calculation to enable the
individual entrepreneur to concretely exercise it in his routine course of busi-
ness. The conceptual ideas of Schmalenbach are cornerstones of Prussian-
German business economics (Betriebswirtschaftslehre) which has been taught
in universities and business schools in German-speaking countries for more
than a century now. This paper, therefore, aims to introduce the Austrian
community to Schmalenbachs work, to emphasize its significance for the
advancement of Austrian theorizing, and to illustrate the close relations between
Austrian economics and German business economics.
Keywords Eugen Schmalenbach .Austrian economics .German business economics .
Economic calculation .Capital accounting .Cost accounting
JEL classification B25 .M21 .M41
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-020-00520-x
*David J. Rapp
david.rapp@imtbs.eu
Extended author information available on the last page of the article
Published online: 6 July 2020
The Review of Austrian Economics (2022) 35:205–233
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
... We do the same for the relationship between prospective calculation and Schumpeter's approach to the entrepreneur in section 4. In this regard, we build on "investment theory," a stream of business economics literature that has several intellectual connections to the work of the Austrian school and has developed particularly in the Germanspeaking world. It deals primarily with the appraisal of investment options under conditions of imperfect markets, uncertainty, and subjective preferences (see Olbrich et al., 2015Olbrich et al., , 2022. In this approach, prospective calculation is shown to support entrepreneurial judgment à la Foss and Klein (2012) in actual business practice (e.g., Rapp & Olbrich, 2023). ...
... There is a related literature that approaches entrepreneurship and economic calculation from a different angle. Olbrich et al. (2015), Herbener and Rapp (2016), Rapp, Haßlinger, and Olbrich (2018), and Olbrich et al. (2022) go into the details of accounting and investment appraisal. However, they do not integrate their insights systematically into the theory of the entrepreneur. ...
Article
Full-text available
We integrate the issue of economic calculation into the theory of the entrepreneur. In doing so, we fill a gap in the literature by demonstrating that retrospective economic calculation, i.e., financial accounting, dovetails with Kirzner's theory of the alert entrepreneur and that prospective calculation, i.e., the appraisal of investment objects, supports innovational activities by entrepreneurs and therefore facilitates creative destruction as emphasized by Schumpeter. Our integrative conceptualization of the calculating entrepreneur can lead to a better understanding of the role of economic calculation in the economy, thereby bringing theoretical economics and business administration closer together.
... Most certainly the 2007-8 crisis was not monocausal, but it was a prototypical recession preceded by an artificial boom which had been induced by expansionary monetary policy in the early 2000s in response to the bursting of the dot-com bubble (Woods 2009). 6 There has been some discussion in the accounting community about the role that FVA may have played in this business cycle-that is, whether it was an original cause or catalyst of the cycle, or whether it simply acted as a messenger that revealed economic reality but did not contribute to the cycle itself (André et al. 2009;Brösel, Toll, and Zimmermann 2012;Laux andLeuz 2009, 2010;Magnan 2009;Olbrich, Rapp, and Follert 2022). ...
... In other words, the lower the interest rates and the easier the access to credit, the greater the demand for assets and the higher their prices, especially in the case of stocks and real estate. Consequently, if a given company holds financial investments and reports them at fair value (level 1), the book value of its investments will increase in line with the rising market prices (e.g., Olbrich, Rapp, and Follert 2022). ...
Article
Full-text available
Fair value accounting is at the heart of arguably the world’s most prominent accounting standards, particularly US GAAP and IFRS. Fair value measurement has been the subject of intense debate. Among other things, it has been analyzed from an ethical perspective. However, this discussion has mainly been limited to the judgment involved in fair value measurement and the ethics of fair value in its ability to provide decision-useful information to interested parties. This study pushes the boundaries by adding a new dimension to the discussion of the ethics of fair value accounting by examining its ethics from a more systemic and societal perspective. Drawing on Austrian business cycle theory, it argues that fair value accounting facilitates certain distributive effects in inflationary monetary environments, thereby contributing to distributive injustice and potentially to social discord. In this respect, fair value accounting—in contrast to historical cost accounting—should not be considered fair or just, but unethical instead.
... This comment aims to uncover the misconceptions inherent in Kruk's argument and to present alternative ways of addressing uncertainty when using the NPV as a tool to support entrepreneurial decision-making. To do so, we build on Prussian-German business economics, especially investment theory, which has been developed in the German-speaking world based on Austrian economics (Schmalenbach 1919, 334;Mises 1933, 9;[1960] 2003Schmidt 1933, 106;Herbener and Rapp 2016, 13;Olbrich, Rapp, and Follert 2020) and which fully adopts the perspective of the acting individual rather than building on the well-known escapist assumptions of neoclassicism. Kruk's (2020, 138) diagnosis is that "wealth maximizing investors are evaluating projects only using risk-free NPV [and that, hence,] they may underestimate the risk associated with their investment decisions." ...
... See, in particular,Rapp (2015);Olbrich, Quill, and Rapp (2015);Herbener and Rapp (2016);Olbrich, Rapp, and Venitz (2016);Rapp, Olbrich, and Venitz (2017);Follert et al. (2018);Rapp, Olbrich, and Venitz (2018);Olbrich, Rapp, and Follert (2020). ...
Article
Full-text available
In her paper "Corporate Risk Evaluation in the Context of Austrian Business Cycle Theory" recently published in this journal, Joanna Kruk aims to investigate how artificially low interest rates resulting from central bank intervention distort individual investment appraisals and ultimately result in both entrepreneurial misjudgment and resource-wasting malinvestment, fueling the business cycle. She identifies entrepreneurs' net present value calculations, supposedly unadjusted for risk, as a major issue and suggests adjusting those calculations for risk via both the duration method and the Capital Asset Pricing Model to mitigate the distorting effects. Her argumentation is, however, trapped in neoclassical reasoning and is adversely affected by several misconceptions of the net present value criterion. This comment seeks to reveal those fallacies and explain how to address uncertainty when using net present value calculations to make those calculations part of the solution rather than part of the problem of entrepreneurial misjudgment. The findings are derived from German investment theory rooted in the Austrian school of thought, meaning that they differ compared to those of neoclassical finance theory.
... The concept of malinvestment is widely discussed in the literature on ABCT (Sechrest 2006;Holcombe 2017;Braun 2020, sect. 5;Olbrich, Rapp, and Follert 2022) and is closely related to the concept of the 'structure of production' (Skousen 2007). For an economy to be sustainable, its numerous production processes must be well co-ordinated. ...
Article
This study builds on Austrian business cycle theory and empirical evidence to explore how macroeconomic conditions, investment decisions, and fair value accounting interact and contribute to economic crises. The German crash of 1873 serves as an early example of irrational exuberance, marking the decline of peak classical liberalism in German-speaking countries. We argue that liberal reforms, especially in corporate law, culminated in the abolition of the government concession or licence system in 1870, leading to a fundamental change in accounting rules and the adoption of fair value accounting. Our empirical analysis suggests that this shift led to an increase in dividend payments, paid out of capital instead of realised income. Following the dramatic expansion of the German money supply due to French reparations after the Franco-Prussian War, low interest rates-combined with the market-oriented accounting regime-fuelled unprecedented speculation, ultimately culminating in the system's collapse in 1873. Our study contributes to the understanding of the interplay of macroeconomics and accounting, offering practical implications for policymakers and standard setters while drawing historical parallels to the 2008 global financial crisis.
... Hier dominiert ein Gleichgewichtsdenken, auf dessen Basis ein hypothetischer Marktwert ermittelt werden soll (Hering, 2021;Matschke & Brösel, 2013). Die Investitionstheorie, welche sich heute in der Funktionalen Schule manifestiert (auch "deutsche Schule" Hering (2004)), fußt hingegen auf der Österreichischen Schule der Nationalökonomie und fundiert ihre Entscheidungsmodelle insbesondere durch die Wiener Grenznutzenschule (Hering, 2004;Olbrich et al., 2015Olbrich et al., , 2022Quill, 2016). Obwohl sich ein wissenschaftlicher Erkenntnisprozess in den seltensten Fällen nach Mehrheiten richtet, kann die auf der Neoklassik basierende marktwertorientierte Bewertung derzeit als sogenannter "mainstream" und die auf der Marginalanalyse fußende investitionstheoretische Bewertung als Mindermeinung eingestuft werden., was sich für das Schrifttum im deutschen Sprachraum auch empirisch zeigt (Follert, 2020b). ...
... Austrians hold that exchange or trade can only take place, and therefore prices can only emerge, when two parties disagree about the value of the goods being exchanged (Menger 2007;Rothbard 2009). In the case of a stock market transaction, the seller must believe that the money price he is receiving in the exchange is of greater value to him than is the stock which he is giving up (e.g., Matschke 1972;Olbrich, Rapp, and Follert 2022), while the buyer must believe the opposite. If this were not true, then the trade could not take place and the market price could not emerge (Follert et al. 2018;Olbrich, Quill, and Rapp 2015;Herbener and Rapp 2016). ...
Article
Full-text available
This article reviews numerous arguments Austrian scholars have made against the efficient market hypothesis and asserts that these arguments are sufficient grounds for dismissal of many of the theoretical justifications which have been advanced in favor of passive investing, and in favor of the traditional value-weighted index fund in particular. In the absence of theoretical justification, empirical test results are the primary evidence to substantiate passive investing’s claim to superiority relative to alternative investment strategies—results which, this article contends, are insufficient grounds for acceptance of the claim. Finally, it is argued that the much-emphasized contradistinction between active and passive investing is lacking in substance. The passive portfolio’s construction is the product of subjective human judgment just as the actively managed portfolio is; passive investing merely involves a different kind of judgment.
... Some other works in this area include books like Spitznagel's The Dao of Capital (Spitznagel, 2013), Austrian School for Investors by Taghizadegan et al. (2016), Calandro Jr.'s Applied Value Investing (Calandro Jr., 2009), and Skousen's A Viennese Waltz Down Wall Street (Skousen, 2013) as well as papers such as Grimm's (2012) "Fundamental Analysis as a Traditional Austrian Approach to Common Stock Selection." Those contributions fundamentally differ from Herbener and Rapp (2016) and related papers (e.g., Follert et al., 2018;Olbrich et al., 2022;Olbrich et al., 2015). To a great degree, they embrace a particular investing heuristic, namely the value investing paradigm, and essentially claim that value investing provides a genuinely Austrian investment framework (Rapp et al., 2017). ...
Article
Full-text available
The persistent myth of the value investing paradigm’s compatibility with Austrian economics has already been debunked due to its fundamental contradictions with the Austrian theory of value and price. Yet, the conceptual foundations of value investing contradict contemporary Austrian theory on still another level, namely by embracing the opportunity-discovery view of entrepreneurship, rather than the judgment-based approach to entrepreneurship. The value investing paradigm posits an approach of systematically discovering and exploiting objectively existent profit opportunities, while the mainline Austrian view holds that such objective profit opportunities do not exist, and that the very essence of entrepreneurship lies in the act of judgmental decision-making under conditions of uncertainty instead. This paper seeks both to explain how the value investing paradigm misrepresents investors as methodical, systematic discoverers and exploiters of objective profit opportunities and, consequently, how this is in contravention of the judgment-based approach to entrepreneurship. Further, recognizing recent developments in the Austrian entrepreneurship literature, we suggest that the Beliefs-Actions-Results framework should replace the value investing framework as the operational investment process in the future development of Austrian investment theory.
... 8 If the entrepreneur would probably not completely meet customer demand, the possible sales have to be ranked in order of a descending margin of coverage per resource unit until the resource is exhausted. It is then appraised with its marginal costs plus its marginal profit, that is, the profit to be gained from its least profitable use (Hering, 2010;Olbrich, Rapp, & Follert, 2020;Schmalenbach, 1947Schmalenbach, , 1949. ...
Article
Full-text available
Research Summary Entrepreneurial judgment remains a concept that resembles a black box. This article attempts to further open that black box by developing a dimensionalization of types of judgment. To achieve this, it joins recent efforts to explicitly link entrepreneurship to Simonian themes by integrating the notion of decision problem structures into the judgment‐based approach (JBA) to entrepreneurship. This article proposes a more comprehensive and nuanced approach to judgment in the face of decision problems we label “real‐structured.” Extending the JBA comes with several important implications: It uncovers additional entrepreneurial knowledge problems, provides new insights for both economic organization and judgment communicability, and informs research on entrepreneurial success and failure. It also sheds new light on the controversy over the relationship between effectuation and judgment. Managerial Summary When taking decisions, entrepreneurs cannot know how the future will pan out. Those decisions are made under conditions of uncertainty and only time will tell whether they prove astute or otherwise. The uncertainty of the future leads entrepreneurs to exercise judgment based on their individual beliefs and to act accordingly. The components of that entrepreneurial judgment remain rather underexplored. The purpose of this article is to dig deeper into, and thereby improve, the understanding of entrepreneurial judgment. The main result of this article is a four‐part dimensionalization of judgment, covering entrepreneurial (sub‐)judgments on the effects incurred by action, the appraisal of action alternatives, the goals underlying action, and resolving the decision problem.
Article
Full-text available
This brief paper explores the divergent conceptual foundations within Austrian capital theory, highlighting significant differences in the treatment of capital. It contrasts three approaches: one emphasizes the critical role of monetary valuation in economic calculation and decision-making and two focus on physical aspects of the production process. Of these physical approaches, one concerns the intertemporal production structure, and the other addresses the coordination of heterogeneous capital goods. The paper concludes with a proposal for a unified terminology to ensure clarity and consistency in Austrian economic discourse, advocating for terminological precision to maintain coherence within the field.
Article
Full-text available
Avusturya İktisat Okulu piyasa ve girişimcilik konusundaki teorileri ile İşletme Ekonomisinin bir bilim dalı olarak doğuşuna sebebiyet vermiştir. Tartışmasız Eugen Schmalenbach işletme ekonomisinin kuruluşuna ve gelişmesine en önemli katkıyı sağlayan kişidir. Dinamik bilanço kavramı Schmalenbach’ın işletme ekonomisi alanına kazandırdığı en önemli kavramlardan biridir. Bu çalışmada Schmalenbach’ın işletme ekonomisine katkıları ve yaratıcısı olduğu dinamik bilanço teorisi, Avusturya İktisat Okulu’nun ilke ve görüşleri çerçevesinde ele alınmıştır.
Book
Full-text available
From the foreword by Guido Hülsmann: Steeped in the tradition of the Austrian School, Dr Eduard Braun delivers a sweeping and original essay on the foundations of finance. Relying on sources in three languages, and delving deeply into the history of capital theory, his work sheds new light on a great variety of topics, in particular, on the history of the subsistence-fund theory, on the relation between monetary theory and capital theory, on economics and business accounting, on price theory and interest theory, on financial markets, on business cycle theory, and on economic history. The author reinterprets the role of money within the theory of finance. He revisits the theory of the purchasing power of money (PPM) and argues that a suitable definition of the PPM relates exclusively to consumer-good prices, not to capital-good prices. Dr Braun argues that the PPM in that sense is the bridge between the theory of money and the classical theory of the subsistence fund. His book shows that this is a fruitful approach and a promising framework for future research in a variety of contemporary fields, such as financial economics, finance, money and banking, and macroeconomics. Eduard Braun invites us to step back and reflect about the meaning of finance. This is time well spent, as readers of the following pages will discover.
Article
Full-text available
In the division of labor, economizing valuations require an appraisement of the structure of market prices of goods beforehand. Yet, investment decisions concerning the purchase of an entire business enterprise, for example, necessitate considerations beyond appraisement. An economizing valuation of businesses must be based upon both appraisement and a genuine investment appraisal which provides the valuing person with the marginal price he can barely accept. However, even though the computation of this marginal price is a necessary step towards an economizing investment decision, it is still not sufficient. In case of a company purchase, the price to be paid is unknown beforehand. Therefore, an economizing valuation of firms not only requires both appraisement and investment appraisal but also a negotiation of the final price to be paid. Because the corresponding negotiation process must be characterized as a terra incognita in Austrian economics, this paper investigates in depth the negotiation between the involved parties as the final step towards their economizing valuations and discusses purposive negotiation tactics.
Article
Full-text available
Contrary to the Austrian community’s former perception, we revealed value investing’s incompatibility with Austrian economics (Rapp, Olbrich, and Venitz, 2017). However, Leithner (2017) disagrees with this conclusion. He primarily argues that an analysis of value concepts should be neglected in favor of a discussion of the methods value investors apply to “measure” value to diagnose whether or not they adhere to Austrian value theory. Moreover, he claims that value investors use terms imprecisely and that intrinsic value is actually meant to be subjective, even conceptually. However, we believe Leithner’s remarks suffer from fundamental misunderstandings and error. He is mistaken on Austrian value theory, subjectivity, and the conceptual foundations of value investing. Therefore, we gladly accept the offer to address his misapprehensions and to sharpen the Austrian understanding on investment decisions in general.
Chapter
The Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Central Banking covers a wide range of central bank topics, including governance, independence, balance-sheet and crisis management, and the challenges in macroeconomic modeling. The book is intended as an up-to-date reference for the current and potential challenges faced by central banks in the conduct of monetary policy and in the search for the maintenance of financial system stability. The approach involves a wide variety of views about the past and present behavior and performance of central banks around the world, with the aim of providing a state-of-the-art perspective on the likely future challenges to be faced by this critical institution. Clearly, one of the motivations for the book is the great financial crisis of 2007–2009. Nevertheless, several of the themes covered and analyzed in the book predate the crisis. The aftermath of the crisis also raised new questions about the scope, influence, and response of central banks to a changing macroeconomic landscape. These developments also figure prominently in the book.
Article
This article discusses the influence of the initiation of the Second Socialist Calculation Debate on my own subsequent research and contributions to that debate, and briefly summarizes that research presented in articles on arguments made by Plato, Karl Marx, Friedrich von Wieser, Friedrich Hayek, Lionel Robbins, Joseph Schumpeter, and Israel Kirzner. It also mentions some of the changes in Austrian economics understanding stimulated by the Second Socialist Calculation Debate, and suggests a direction for future research.