PreprintPDF Available

A goal-framing approach to green payments' efficiency when vertical integration is an option

Authors:
Preprints and early-stage research may not have been peer reviewed yet.

Abstract

This article explores farmer's decisions regarding the expansion of organic farming through intensive input use and the degree of in-house organic fertilizer production. Using a theoretical synthesis of two strands of the scholarly literature, namely pro-environmental norms and the goal-framing theory, the contribution of this article to the current literature is: (i) it redefines the concept of the crowding effects, which encompasses both changes in environmental preferences and in normative objectives; (ii) it points that the impact of a green payment on vertical integration depends on both the relative (i.e. the direction) and the absolute (i.e. the magnitude) size of the crowding effect being expected; (iii) it states that a trade-off between input use and vertical integration does always exist once a land subsidy is implemented, but not necessarily if a price premium is offered instead.
AUA Working Paper Series No. 2020 - 1
A goal-framing approach to green
payments’ efficiency when
vertical integration is an option
Giorgos N. Diakoulakis, PhD candidate
Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development,
Agricultural University of Athens, Iera Odo 75, 11852, Athens,
Greece
Email: di_gi@aua.gr
Athanasios Kampas, Associate Professor
Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development,
Agricultural University of Athens, Iera Odo 75, 11852, Athens,
Greece
Email: tkampas@aua.gr
This series contains preliminary manuscripts which are not (yet) published in
professional journals
Agricultural University of Athens
Department of Agricultural Economics
& Rural Development http://www.aoa.aua.gr
1
A goal-framing approach to green payments efficiency when vertical integration is an option
Giorgos N. Diakoulakis1 and Athanasios Kampas1,*
1Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Agricultural University of
Athens, Iera Odos 75, 118 55, Athens, Greece.
Abstract:
This article explores farmer’s decisions regarding the expansion of organic farming through
intensive input use and the degree of in-house organic fertilizer production. Using a theoretical
synthesis of two strands of the scholarly literature, namely pro-environmental norms and the goal-
framing theory, the contribution of this article to the current literature is: (i) it redefines the concept
of the crowding effects, which encompasses both changes in environmental preferences and in
normative objectives; (ii) it points that the impact of a green payment on vertical integration
depends on both the relative (i.e. the direction) and the absolute (i.e. the magnitude) size of the
crowding effect being expected; (iii) it states that a trade-off between input use and vertical
integration does always exist once a land subsidy is implemented, but not necessarily if a price
premium is offered instead.
Keywords: personal and social norms, crowding theory, goal-framing theory, green payments
vertical integration
*Corresponding author (E-mail: tkampas@aua.gr). Giorgos N. Diakoulakis is Ph.D student and
Athanasios Kampas is Associate Professor with the Department of Agricultural Economics and
Rural Development.
JEL: D91, Q18, Q58
2
Introduction
According to a widely known postulate, economic incentives primarily correspond to, and
influence, a self-centered rationality, otherwise known as rational egoistic motive or self-interest
hypothesis (Ostrom 2000). Notwithstanding, it is well known that humans often reveal a variety
of non-selfish motives, such as social approval and reciprocity (Fehr and Fischbacher 2002). Non-
selfish motives are often considered to explore and explain voluntary contributions to a public
good. In such a setting, Andreoni (1988) put forward the “impure altruism model” to explain the
limitations of economic incentives. Brekke, Kverndokk and Nyborg (2003) propose the concept
of “one’s self-image as a socially responsible person” in trying to define social approved motives.
The latter bear close resemblance to what Bénabou and Tirole (2006) refer to it as reputational
motive. However, the inability of (economic) incentives to accommodate motivational
heterogeneity produces complex results and very often, is the main reason behind the ambiguity
in ranking policy measures (Heyes and Kapur 2011).
The article focusses on farmers’ voluntary contribution to a public good, such as
environmental quality. Farmers’ preferences play a crucial role in explaining the motivations
towards environmentally friendly practices. In particular, these preferences encompass the moral
commitments of agents (or as Sachdeva, Iliev and Medin (2009) put it the moral self-worth) and
the social norms (compliance with prosocial behavior). In such a setting, incentives may induce
partial and fragmented or even net crowding out of environmentally friendly attitudes. To our best
knowledge, this paper joins for the first time, elements of different strands of the scholarly
literature such as the Motivational Crowding Theory (MCT) (Frey and Jegen 2001) and the Goal-
3
Framing Theory (GFT) (Lindenberg and Steg 2007) with the well-established postulate of
incentives driven rationality.
In this article, GFT is adopted as the basic framework for explaining farmer’s production
choices. Specifically, the purpose of this study is to examine how green payments, deployed by
government and price premiums offered by consumers, affect farmers’ decisions regarding the
input use and the adaption of waste recycling and composting practices. The rationale of relying
on GFT is that farmers may evaluate not only the outcome of their production choices, but also
how this outcome is obtained (Frey, Benz and Stutzer 2004). Specifically, GFT encompasses goals
as the psychological mechanism and hence, it is able to capture such dynamics in two dimensions:
First, it integrates the concepts of values, norms and self-interest motives in a solid manner.
Second, the concept of goals explains in a more consistent way the behavior of a producer, than
MCT proposes. It is not that an external intervention perceived by a producer as controlling, but
rather that it changes her goal hierarchy and hence, her production choices.
The novelty of our contribution is twofold: First, to our best knowledge, it is the first time
that GFT is applied to production choices. Secondly, it brings new insights on the relative
efficiency of different types of green payments. Frey and Stutzer (2006) propose that government
subsidies have an ambiguous impact on intrinsic motivation. This study tries to shed some light
on the conditions under which green payments undermines farmer’s propensity to engage in waste
recycling and composting practices.
By doing so, this article applies the aforementioned synthesis to the case of organic
farming, a typical example of voluntarily contribution to public goods (i.e. environmental quality),
and derives a set of novel results not previously identified in the relevant literature. In particular,
the impact of a land subsidy on the expansion of organic farming depends jointly on the crowding
4
in (out) possibilities and on the relative strength of the farmer’s objectives1. Previous literature
fails to identify such a result (see Jaime, Coria and Liu (2016)). In addition, a land subsidy always
results in a trade-off between vertical integration (the in-house organic fertilizer production) and
the expansion of organic farming. By stark contrast, such results are not necessarily valid when
price premium is used as a policy instrument to enhance organic farming. It is known that
consumers have a positively signicant valuation associated with certied organic produce
(Connolly and Klaiber 2014). The obtained results from this article may enable policy-makers to
design more efficient policy interventions.
The structure of the paper is as follows. Next section presents the theoretical framework
and examines the role of economic incentives to enhance organic farming and discusses the results.
The final section concludes.
Theoretical Framework
Consider a situation where a single farmer owns a piece of a land and produces an agricultural
product, . For simplicity, land is normalized to one and a single input production process is
assumed. A typical example of such a single input is the amount of nitrate fertilizer, . In particular,
a farmer can use either conventional () or organic () fertilizers. By choosing a specific type of
fertilizer, she primarily selects the type of farming system, and accordingly the per-hectare
agricultural good is labeled as conventional () or organic (). The following properties are
assumed for the production process:

 
5
Conventional and organic farming systems have two notable differences. First, an organic
farmer may produce organic fertilizers by herself and thus, she can vertically integrate her farming
system. There are many possible reasons why a farm chooses to vertically integrate its production.
The most obvious one is to reduce the market dependence concerning the supply of inputs. Waste
recycling and composting epitomize vertical integration choices (Galliou et al. 2018; Goncalves
Da Silva et al. 2010). Beyond that, Hennessy (1996) explains the incidence of vertical integration
as a farm response to informational externalities, an approach also employed by Vetter and
Karantininis (2002a). In such a setting, vertical integration denoted by  reflects the
percentage of own produced organic fertilizer. Consequently, producing units of the good costs
, such that , and  for any . Specifically, means
that a farmer chooses to purchase all the necessary amount of the organic fertilizer from the market,
and thus is the market price (i.e. unit cost) of organic fertilizer. On the contrary,
means that a farmer produces exclusively all the necessary amount of organic fertilizer and thus,
 represents the unit cost of in-house fertilizer production. In addition, the rationale
of is that a decreasing marginal cost of in-house fertilizer production is unrealistic, since
purchasing organic inputs seems to be the dominant strategy (Cobo et al. 2019). By contrast, the
cost of producing a good conventionally is where denotes the unit price of
conventional fertilizer.
Second, in-house production of organic fertilizer is a procedure, which further contributes
to environmental quality since own produced organic inputs are associated with lower ecological
footprint compared to the purchased ones (Goldstein et al. 2017). Thus, by choosing a specific
degree of vertical integration, , the environmental benefits from organic production are denoted
by , such that and . Notwithstanding,  indicates that
6
organic production, per se, has positive effects on the environment, even though the farmer
chooses to purchase the whole amount of organic fertilizer, (van Huylenbroek et al. 2009).
A key element in our analysis is that it draws heavily on social psychology theories. To
begin with, pro-environmental protection is perceived as a norm. Although the very meaning of a
norm refers to a shared belief about what people ought to do, norm may have a variety of meanings
in the jargon of social sciences, comprising both objective and subjective elements (Morris et al.
2015). A typical classification of norms distinguishes between social and personal norms
(Thøgersen 2006). Nyborg et al. (2016) define social norm as “ a predominant pattern of behavior
within a group, supported by a shared understanding of acceptable actions and sustained through
social interactions within that group.” Viscusi, Huber and Bell (2011) emphasizes the first part of
the previous definition where a social norm is seen as a normatively appropriate action, while
(Elster 1989) underlines that a social norm is a rule of behavior that is enforced through social
interactions (rewards and punishments).
By stark contrast, Vandenbergh (2004) perceives personal norm as a kind of obligation that
is enforced through an internalized sense of duty and/or a guilt for failure to act accordingly. Often,
personal norms are experienced as a sense of moral obligations (Steg 2016), so in the scholarly
literature the term “moral norm” is used as a synonym with the personal norm (see Nyborg
(2018)).
As Kalish (2012) argues norms guide social preferences, so it is often assumed that the
strength of pro-environmental preferences depends on the interplay between personal and social
norms (Harring and Jagers 2018). Suffice to say that the term “pro-environmental preferences” is
a sub-category of the term “social preferences” used by Bowles and Polanía-Reyes (2012) which
include, inter alia, altruism, reciprocity and ethical commitments. Formally, farmer's pro-
7
environmental preferences, , are determined according to the following additively separable
linear function:
 
where denotes farmer’s personal norm (i.e. her environmental morality),  denotes
social norm (i.e. social pro-environmental preferences) and  is the locus of causality of
environmental protection (De Charms 2013; Heider 1982). In particular, means that a
farmer feels that protecting the environment is her moral obligation and therefore, her
environmental preferences reflect her environmental morality (i.e. ). On the contrary,
a means that a farmer does not feel any moral obligation to protect the environment. Instead,
any responsibility to act pro-environmentally comes from external pressure (i.e. social demand).
Consequently, her pro-environmental preferences will reflect social norms (i.e. ). A
mixed case is possible as well in which farmer believes that protecting the environment is both her
moral obligation and social demand.
Furthermore, we reject the standard, albeit implicit, separability assumption, under which
the value of is fixed and unaffected by external incentives (Bowles and Polanía-Reyes 2012). In
particular, this article assumes that the locus of causality is determined by the presence of various
situational factors, , often applied as subsidies or price premiums (thereafter,
green payments)2. The stronger these payments are, the smaller is the influence of farmer’s
environmental morality upon her pro-environmental preferences. That is, 
  for any
.
The rationale is that green payments swift the locus of causality from inside (i.e. farmer
herself) to outside (i.e. the payment itself) (De Charms 2013; Deci and Ryan 1985; Deci and Ryan
2008). Specifically, a green payment triggers a cognitive process by which a farmer tends to
8
believe that she cares for environmental protection not because she is morally obliged, but rather
because she is getting paid to do so. The higher a payment is, the stronger that feeling becomes
and consequently, a smaller portion of her environmental morality (personal norm) will be
reflected in her pro-environmental preferences (i.e.  
 ).
However, such a crowding out effect of personal norms on farmer’s pro-environmental
preferences does not necessarily imply that they are decreased as well. On the contrary, green
payments have the potential to foster them, if social norms are strong enough. In particular, a
differentiation of (2) with respect to a green payment yields:
 




and therefore,  
  . In words, the case which social norms dominate
personal norms (i.e. ), emphasize the mighty role that perceptions concerning social
approval and conformity have on shaping pro-environmental preferences. In such a setting, green
payments enhance pro-environmental preferences , as they are perceived as impetus
towards environmentally friendly adjustments. On the contrary, when personal (or moral) norms
prevail over social norms (i.e. ), many people develop pro-environmental preferences,
and analogous motivations, on the basis of moral commitment (Steg 2016). This create a general
predisposition to devalue the role of green payments since they are not an internal part of a position
build around the notion of moral obligation, and hence green payments seem to reduce pro-
environmental preferences (i.e. ).
In turn, according to the Goal-Framing Theory (thereafter GFT) developed by Lindenberg
(Lindenberg 2001a; Lindenberg 2001b; Lindenberg 2006) and Lindenberg and Steg (Lindenberg
and Steg 2007; Lindenberg and Steg 2013), farmer’s production choices will be guided by three
overarching goals: the gain goal (i.e. to improve her financial resources, status, etc.), the hedonic
9
goal (i.e. to feel good, to enjoy herself) and the normative goal (i.e. to act appropriately). In the
article’s set up, for brevity and simplicity, the gain and the hedonic goals are merged into a single
one, namely the non-normative goal.
In line with the prominent hypothesis of the GFT, the behavior of an individual is primarily
influenced by that goal that it is in farmer’s cognitive foreground (i.e. goal-frame) or otherwise
known as focal (or central) (Lindenberg and Steg 2013). The elevation of a goal to a goal-frame
status, depends jointly on farmer’s preferences (i.e. on ) and on situational factors (i.e. on )
(Lindenberg and Steg 2007). In this article, the strength of the normative goal is denoted by
, such that  
 , and the strength of the non-normative goal is denoted by
, such that , for any . The open upper bound of
(resp. the open lower bound of ) means that by her nature a farmer always considers non-
normative goals gain and joy- and consequently, she will never base her decisions on a pure
normative fashion.
The rationale behind the assumption  is that pro-environmental preferences
are expected to frame normative actions, since they often considered to be legitimate social choice
rooted in a feeling of normative obligation (Sabet 2014; Steg et al. 2016). On the contrary, green
payments are expected to frame non-normative actions, and especially gain-related behavior, since
they provide a direct way of improving farmer’s personal wealth. Since there is a trade-off between
normative and non-normative action, green payments push the normative goal into farmer’s
cognitive background (i.e. ).
However, green payments also influence the impact of personal norms on farmer’s pro-
environmental preferences. In other words, green payments have a direct effect by framing non-
normative actions, and an indirect effect through their influence on the degree of personal norm
10
internalization. Therefore, the total impact of a green payment on farmer’s normative goal
preferences is:
 







By defining 



 , a green subsidy induces normative goal preferences if
. In addition, may interpreted as the gap between the personal norms and social
ones when normative objectives are unaffected by green payments (i.e.  
 
).
By using (3) and (4) we are able to redefine the concept of “crowding effects” in terms of
how a green payment jointly affects farmer’s pro-environmental preferences and normative actions
(for details, see Appendix):
Lemma 1: Any green payment, , bring about one of the following crowding effects:
(i) a pure crowding-in effect, where both pro-environmental preferences and normative goal
preferences are enhanced: .
(ii) a pure crowding-out effect, where both pro-environmental preferences and normative
goal preferences are reduced: .
(iii) a quasi-crowding-out effect, where pro-environmental preferences are enhanced, but
normative goal preferences are reduced: 
.
In such a setting, the farmer's problem concerns the choice between input use and the
degree of vertical integration. In what follows, a theoretical framework is proposed in which these
choices are determined, based on farmer’s procedural utility  (Frey et al. 2004).
11
External interventions to foster organic farming - The case of economic incentives
Let us assume a social planner who wishes to facilitate the expansion of organic farming by
providing a land-based subsidy (Andreoni and Bergstrom 1996) Such payment reflects
society's acknowledgment for the provision of environmental benefits and belongs to a family of
transfers known collectively as green payments (Horan and Claassen 2007) or payments for
environmental services (Engel, Pagiola and Wunder 2008).
Beyond the regulatory policies, consumers are willing to pay a price premium, for
organic goods, on the basis that they perceive organic products as being differentiated products
(healthier and more safe products) in comparison to the equivalent conventional produce (Endres
2007). Suffice to say that such a claim is primarily based on subjective perceptions (Apaolaza et
al. 2018), whereas the majority of meta-analyses do not support any causality between food quality
and/or food safety and organic produce (Benbrook 2013; Dangour et al. 2009; Magkos, Arvaniti
and Zampelas 2006). However, beyond the self-centered rationality of consumers, it should be
stressed that green consumerism often encompass ethical considerations (Kotchen and Moore
2008; Mazar and Zhong 2010). Notwithstanding, the latter is beyond the scope of this paper.
The price premium is only paid for goods certified as organic and sold under the analogous
label. An independent third body, upon routinely inspecting farmer's compliance with organic
farming prerequisites, issues such a certification. The fixed cost of such a certification denoted by
is assume to be borne by farmers. In its simplest case, such an eco-certification involve the
identification of some traits in the production process, which are (imperfectly) correlated with the
product’s “environmental friendliness (Mason 2011). The complex issues of random monitoring,
12
uncertainty in signals and probabilistic certification are ignored in our analysis. The reader is
referred to (Hamilton and Zilberman 2006) and (Mason 2013) for a thorough analysis.
Incentives put forward by the Social Planner: the case of land subsidy
In line with Frey et al. (2004), farmer’s procedural utility of conventionally producing is
 
where the optimal input use is given by:
 
On the contrary, the procedural utility of a farmer who produces organically is:
 
Likewise, the optimal input use and the optimal degree of in-house production of organic fertilizer
are defined by:
 
where satisfy the first-order condition:
 


 
Standard comparative statics (for details, see Appendix) reveals that the impact of a land
subsidy on the optimal degree of in-house production organic fertilizer is:







whereas its impact on the optimal input use is:
13






There are a number of worth-noting points in (11) and (12) that provide a number of
implications: First, it is evident that  since and . Therefore, it is
clear that  and  have opposite signs. The rationale behind such a result is that
a land subsidy always triggers a trade-off between the expansion of organic production and the in-
house production of organic fertilizer. Provide that the output is a monotonic and increasing
function of the inputs used, a reduction in inputs produces a reduction in output, and vice versa.
Therefore, a change in output may be attributed to changes in input intensity, known as intensive
margin changes, and or to changes in cropping pattern, known as extensive margin changes (Fang
and Rogerson 2009). However, the current modeling framework does not allow us to separate
these two changes, since we assumed a single input production function. Therefore, in what
follows we collectively refer to these changes as expansion or reduction, respectively, of organic
farming3. In other words, land subsidies cannot simultaneously enhance vertical integration and
the expansion of organic production. An increase of in-house production of organic fertilizer
brings extra satisfaction to the farmer since she produces extra environmental benefits. The value
of these benefits cancels off, at the margin, the product loss due to reduced inputs, and
consequently .
Second, the sign of the term  of the LHS of (11) is specified by value of the ratio between
non-normative and normative goal preferences. Specifically,
 
 


14
where denotes a threshold that shows the ratio between the speed that the environmental
benefits increase as the degree of in-house production of organic fertilizer increases, over the
magnitude of the trade-off between the expansion of organic farming and the degree of in-house
production of organic fertilizer.
The implication of (11) and (13) is that crowding effects cannot solely determine the impact
of a land subsidy on the optimal solution . In order to be able to draw a picture on the
effects of a land subsidy has on both input use and the expansion of organic farming, we must able
to identify both the relative (i.e. the type of the crowding effect) and the absolute (i.e. the value of
the ratio between normative and non-normative actions) size of the crowding effect. Formally (for
details, see Appendix):
Proposition 1: By using lemma 1 and (11), (12) and (13), it is proposed that a land subsidy: (i)
triggers a trade-off between the expansion of organic farming and in-house production of organic
fertilizer; (ii) induces in-house production of organic fertilizer if conditions C1 or C2 holds, where:
C1: {a pure crowding in effect is expected and }
C2: {a pure or a quasi-crowding out effect is expected and }.
Figure 1 illustrates the impact of a land subsidy on in-house organic fertilizer production
for different relative and absolute crowding effect. In particular, let’s assume that before the
introduction of a land subsidy a farmer has a ratio between normative and non-normative actions
that corresponds to the point A. If a crowding-in expect is expected, proposition 1 states that a land
subsidy induces in-house organic fertilizer production if the farmer moves to points C or D. On
the contrary, if the crowding in effect is weak (i.e. movement from A to B), then a land subsidy
15
induces only the expansion of organic farming. Following a similar reasoning, a farmer who was
initially at the point D has an incentive to increase the in-house organic fertilizer production, if the
crowding out or the quasi-crowding out effect is strong, such that to end in points A or B.
To recapitulate, the effect of land subsidy on the expansion of organic farming
simultaneously depends on the crowding in (out) possibilities and on the relative strength of the
farmer’s objectives. From the cases characterized above, it seems that the interplay between social
and personal norms with the hierarchy of individual goals is rather complex.
16
Incentives driven by consumers’ choices: the case of price premium
This section examines how price premium affect farmer’s decisions regarding the input use and
the degree of in-house organic fertilizer production. The impact of a price premium, , on the
optimal solution,  is assessed by differentiating the first-order conditions with respect to
. It turns out that the relationship between price premiums and the optimal degree of in-house
organic fertilizer production is given by (see Appendix for the proof):








whereas the total impact of a price premium on the optimal input use is:





Equation (15) points that a price premium affects input use both directly and indirectly.
Specifically, the term 
, since and , reflects the direct impact,
whereas the term 
 
reflects the indirect one, the sign of which depends
on 
. The purpose of this direct impact is twofold: From one side it enhances any positive
indirect impact and at the same time, it mediates the negative influence of the indirect one. The
implication is that the presence of this direct impact does not necessarily trigger a trade-off
between optimal input use and the optimal degree of own-produced organic fertilizer. Specifically,




where the RHS of it is positive, since both the nominator and the denominator are negative. In
particular, (16) highlights that a price premium induces input use (i.e. 
) in two
17
cases: If it reduces in-house organic fertilizer production (i.e. ) or if it enhances in-
house organic fertilizer production (i.e. ), but such a positive effect is weak.
Furthermore, the RHS of (14) becomes positive if:
 






Note that the sign of depends on the sign of  
. In particular, if a crowding out effect or a
quasi-crowding out effect is expected, then , and consequently (17) holds. On the contrary,
if a crowding in effect is expected, then (17) is satisfied, if the value of is relatively low. Such a
situation arises if the crowding in effect is weak or if the direct impact a price premium on input
use is rather strong. In addition, the term  of the LHS of (14) is positive if  
.
Thus, by using lemma 1 and (14), (16) and (17) it is proposed that:
Proposition 2: The introduction of a price premium triggers the following effects: (i) enhances
both input use and in-house organic fertilizer production, if , but not too high; (ii)
it enhances in-house organic fertilizer production if conditions C3, C4 or C5 holds, where:
C3: {a pure crowding out or a quasi-crowding out effect is expected and },
C4: {a pure crowding in effect is expected,  and },
C5: {a pure crowding in effect is expected,  and }
A comparison between propositions 1 and 2 points that in cases where a pure crowding out
or a quasi-crowding out effect is expected, farmer’s responses towards in-house organic fertilizer
18
production are independent from the type of the payment (land subsidy or price premium) being
offered (condition C2 on land subsidy is exactly the same with C3 on price premium). However,
the situation becomes more complex when crowding in effect are expected instead. For instance,
C5 is stricter than C1, since it also requires that . If it is not true, then a “paradox”
arises in which land subsidies induce in-house of organic fertilizer production, whereas price
premiums undermine it. The policy implication is that the type of a green payment being offered
may matters, once pure crowding in effects are expected. This “paradox” is illustrated in Figure 2.
In particular, figure 2 points the following: Let’s assume again that initially a farmer is at
point A. If a pure crowding in is expected, then any movement to points C or D will induce in-
house organic fertilizer production, as long as a land subsidy is offered. On the contrary, if a price
premium is implemented, then proposition 2 points a farmer has an incentive to increase the degree
of in-house organic fertilizer proposition if the crowding in effect is ether weak (from A to B) or
19
if it is quite strong (from A to D). For an “intermediate” crowding in effect (from A to C), the
“paradox” arises. Importantly, a movement from A to B also increases the input use (see (16)), a
feature of price premiums that it is absent in land subsidies.
Conclusion
This article explores farmer’s decisions regarding the expansion of organic farming through
intensive input use and the degree of in-house organic fertilizer production. Using a theoretical
synthesis of two strands of the scholarly literature, namely pro-environmental norms and the GFT,
the contribution of this paper to the current literature can be summarized in the following: First, it
redefines the concept of the crowding effects, which encompasses both changes in environmental
preferences and in normative preferences. Second, it shows that the impact of a green payment on
in-house organic fertilizer production depends on both the relative (i.e. the direction) and the
absolute (i.e. the magnitude) size of the crowding effect being expected. Third, the model presented
here points that the trade-off between the expansion of organic farming and in-house organic
fertilizer production does always exist once a land subsidy is implemented. However, such a
situation does not necessarily arise in cases where price premiums are offered. Specifically, a price
premium can foster both input use and the degree of in-house organic fertilizer production if its
impact on the latter is not substantial high (proposition 2, (i) or (16)).
However, the novelty of this article lies on the observation that for a given crowding effect,
land subsidies and price premiums do not necessarily have the same influence on farmer’s
behavior. Specifically, the model presented here suggests that when a pure crowding out or a quasi-
crowding out effects is expected, then farmer’s behavior is independent from the type of the green
payment being offered. The sufficient condition for a positive effect on the degree of in-house
20
organic fertilizer production is that the ratio between non-normative and normative actions to be
substantial high (see proposition 1, C2 and proposition 2, C3). On the contrary, the situation is far
more complex when crowding in effects are expected, especially when price premiums are offered.
In this article we illustrated that green payment requires a stricter set of conditions than land
subsidies, making more likely for a “paradoxical” situation to occur. Thus, the policy implication
is that when pure crowding in effects are expected due to the introduction of a green payment, then
the type of that payment matters.
At last, few words about the main limitations of this paper are necessary. First, the present
analysis is static, in terms of both time horizon and agent’s heterogeneity. Usually, environmental
improvements come much later than their associated costs. Thus, time could affect how a farmer
forms her normative and non-normative goal preferences, making in that way an important
determinant of farmer’s decisions. Also, in terms of heterogeneity we implicitly assume that every
farmer has the same response function to green payments, meaning that every farmer form both
her pro-environmental preferences and normative preferences in the same way. In reality however,
each farmer may has a unique response to external interventions and thus, heterogeneity might be
a fruitful area for future research. Finally, this article neglects any interaction between farmers and
also, it neglects the impact of policy menus. Future expansions of the present study can overcome
these limitations.
21
Notes
1 The issue of slippage has been ignored in this paper. See Lichtenberg and Smith-Ramírez (2011)
for a thorough analysis.
2 These situational factors can include other types of interventions, like legislation, taxation,
information-based strategies and other type of incentives. However, in this article we limit our
analysis only on monetary incentives and especially, on subsidies and on price premiums.
3 Technically, such an assumption is equivalent to a zero elasticity of input substitution.
22
References
Andreoni, J. 1988. “Privately provided public goods in a large economy: the limits of altruism.”
Journal of public Economics 35(1):5773.
Andreoni, J., and T. Bergstrom. 1996. “Do government subsidies increase the private supply of
public goods?” Public choice 88(34):295308.
Apaolaza, V., P. Hartmann, C. D’Souza, and C.M. López. 2018. “Eat organic–Feel good? The
relationship between organic food consumption, health concern and subjective wellbeing.”
Food Quality and Preference 63:5162.
Bénabou, R., and J. Tirole. 2006. “Incentives and prosocial behavior.” American economic review
96(5):16521678.
Benbrook, C. 2013. “Are organic foods safer or healthier?” Annals of internal medicine
158(4):296297.
Bowles, S., and S. Polanía-Reyes. 2012. “Economic Incentives and Social Preferences: Substitutes
or Complements?” aeaweb.org 50(2):368425.
Brekke, K.A., S. Kverndokk, and K. Nyborg. 2003. “An economic model of moral motivation.”
Journal of public economics 87(910):19671983.
Cobo, S., J.W. Levis, A. Dominguez-Ramos, and A. Irabien. 2019. “Economics of enhancing
nutrient circularity in an organic waste valorization system.” Environmental science &
technology 53(11):61236132.
Connolly, C., and H.A. Klaiber. 2014. “Does Organic Command a Premium When the Food is
Already Local?” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 96(4):11021116.
Dangour, A.D., S.K. Dodhia, A. Hayter, E. Allen, K. Lock, and R. Uauy. 2009. “Nutritional quality
of organic foods: a systematic review.” The American journal of clinical nutrition
90(3):680685.
De Charms, R. 2013. Personal causation: The internal affective determinants of behavior.
Routledge.
Deci, E.L., and R.M. Ryan. 1985. “Cognitive evaluation theory.” In Intrinsic motivation and self-
determination in human behavior. Springer, pp. 4385.
Deci, E.L., and R.M. Ryan. 2008. “Self-determination theory: A macrotheory of human
motivation, development, and health.” Canadian psychology/Psychologie canadienne
49(3):182.
Elster, J. 1989. “Social Norms and Economic Theory.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3(4):99
117.
23
Endres, A.B. 2007. “An Awkward Adolescence in the Organics Industry: Coming to Terms with
Big Organics and Other Legal Challenges for the Industry’s Next Ten Years.” Drake J.
Agric. L. 12:17.
Engel, S., S. Pagiola, and S. Wunder. 2008. “Designing payments for environmental services in
theory and practice: An overview of the issues.” Ecological Economics 65(4):663674.
Fang, L., and R. Rogerson. 2009. “Policy analysis in a matching model with intensive and
extensive margins.” International Economic Review 50(4):11531168.
Fehr, E., and U. Fischbacher. 2002. “Why Social Preferences Matter – the Impact of non‐Selfish
Motives on Competition, Cooperation and Incentives.” The Economic Journal
112(478):C1C33.
Frey, B.S., M. Benz, and A. Stutzer. 2004. “Introducing procedural utility: Not only what, but also
how matters.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift für die
gesamte Staatswissenschaft:377401.
Frey, B.S., and R. Jegen. 2001. “Motivation crowding theory.” Journal of economic surveys
15(5):589611.
Frey, B.S., and A. Stutzer. 2006. “Environmental morale and motivation.” Available at SSRN
900370.
Galliou, F., N. Markakis, M. Fountoulakis, N. Nikolaidis, and T. Manios. 2018. “Production of
organic fertilizer from olive mill wastewater by combining solar greenhouse drying and
composting.” Waste management 75:305311.
Goldstein, B., M. Birkved, J. Fernandez, and M. Hauschild. 2017. “Surveying the environmental
footprint of urban food consumption.” Journal of Industrial Ecology 21(1):151165.
Goncalves Da Silva, M.A., S.A.T. Roque, A.S. Muniz, M.E. Marchetti, J.D.D.V. Da Matta, and
N. Pelisson. 2010. “Efficiency of organic compost from Agri-Industrial wastes as fertilizer
for corn and wheat.” Communications in soil science and plant analysis 41(21):2517
2531.
Hamilton, S.F., and D. Zilberman. 2006. “Green markets, eco-certification, and equilibrium
fraud.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 52(3):627644.
Harring, N., and S.C. Jagers. 2018. “Why do people accept environmental policies? The prospects
of higher education and changes in norms, beliefs and policy preferences.” Environmental
Education Research 24(6):791806.
Heider, F. 1982. The psychology of interpersonal relations. Psychology Press.
Hennessy, D.A. 1996. “Information asymmetry as a reason for food industry vertical integration.”
American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78(4):10341043.
24
Heyes, A., and S. Kapur. 2011. “Regulating altruistic agents.” Canadian Journal of
Economics/Revue canadienne d’économique 44(1):227246.
Horan, R.D., and R. Claassen. 2007. “Targeting Green Payments under a Budget Constraint.” Land
Economics 83(3):319330.
van Huylenbroek, G., K Mondelaers, J Aertsens, Koen Mondelaers, Joris Aertsens, and G. Van
Huylenbroeck. 2009. “A meta-analysis of the differences in environmental impacts
between organic and conventional farming.” British food journal.
Jaime, M.M., J. Coria, and X. Liu. 2016. “Interactions between CAP Agricultural and Agri-
Environmental Subsidies and Their Effects on the Uptake of Organic Farming.” American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 98(4):11141145.
Kalish, C.W. 2012. “Generalizing norms and preferences within social categories and individuals.”
Developmental Psychology 48(4):11331143.
Kotchen, M.J., and M.R. Moore. 2008. “Conservation: From voluntary restraint to a voluntary
price premium.” Environmental and Resource Economics 40(2):195215.
Lichtenberg, E., and R. Smith-Ramírez. 2011. “Slippage in Conservation Cost Sharing.” American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 93(1):113129.
Lindenberg, S. 2001a. “Intrinsic motivation in a new light.” Kyklos 54(23):317342.
Lindenberg, S. 2006. “Prosocial behavior, solidarity, and framing processes.” In Solidarity and
prosocial behavior. Springer, pp. 2344.
Lindenberg, S. 2001b. “Social rationality versus rational egoism.” In Handbook of sociological
theory. Springer, pp. 635668.
Lindenberg, S., and L. Steg. 2013. “Goal-framing theory and norm-guided environmental
behavior.” Encouraging sustainable behavior:3754.
Lindenberg, S., and L. Steg. 2007. “Normative, gain and hedonic goal frames guiding
environmental behavior.” Journal of Social issues 63(1):117137.
Magkos, F., F. Arvaniti, and A. Zampelas. 2006. “Organic food: buying more safety or just peace
of mind? A critical review of the literature.” Critical reviews in food science and nutrition
46(1):2356.
Mason, C.F. 2011. “Eco-labeling and market equilibria with noisy certification tests.”
Environmental and Resource Economics 48(4):537560.
Mason, C.F. 2013. “The economics of eco-labeling: Theory and empirical implications.”
Mazar, N., and C.-B. Zhong. 2010. “Do green products make us better people?” Psychological
science 21(4):494498.
25
Morris, M.W., Y. Hong, C. Chiu, and Z. Liu. 2015. “Normology: Integrating insights about social
norms to understand cultural dynamics.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision
Processes 129:113.
Nyborg, K. 2018. “Social Norms and the Environment.” Annual Review of Resource Economics
10(1):405423.
Nyborg, K., J.M. Anderies, A. Dannenberg, T. Lindahl, C. Schill, M. Schluter, W.N. Adger, K.J.
Arrow, S. Barrett, S. Carpenter, F.S. Chapin, A.-S. Crepin, G. Daily, P. Ehrlich, C. Folke,
W. Jager, N. Kautsky, S.A. Levin, O.J. Madsen, S. Polasky, M. Scheffer, B. Walker, E.U.
Weber, J. Wilen, A. Xepapadeas, and A. de Zeeuw. 2016. “Social norms as solutions.”
Science 354(6308):4243.
Ostrom, E. 2000. “Collective action and the evolution of social norms.” Journal of economic
perspectives 14(3):137158.
Sabet, M. 2014. “‘MORAL OFFSET’: Competing framings of pro-environmental lifestyle
choices.” Critical Discourse Studies 11(1):95116.
Sachdeva, S., R. Iliev, and D.L. Medin. 2009. “Sinning Saints and Saintly Sinners: The Paradox
of Moral Self-Regulation.” Psychological Science 20(4):523528.
Steg, L. 2016. “Values, norms, and intrinsic motivation to act proenvironmentally.” Annual Review
of Environment and Resources 41:277292.
Steg, L., S. Lindenberg, K. Keizer, and others. 2016. “Intrinsic motivation, norms and
environmental behaviour: the dynamics of overarching goals.” International Review of
Environmental and Resource Economics 9(12):179207.
Thøgersen, J. 2006. “Norms for environmentally responsible behaviour: An extended taxonomy.”
Journal of environmental Psychology 26(4):247261.
Vandenbergh, M.P. 2004. “Order without social norms: How personal norm activation can protect
the environment.” Nw. UL Rev. 99:1101.
Vetter, H., and K. Karantininis. 2002. “Moral hazard, vertical integration, and public monitoring
in credence goods.” European Review of Agricultural Economics 29(2):271279.
Viscusi, W.K., J. Huber, and J. Bell. 2011. “Promoting Recycling: Private Values, Social Norms,
and Economic Incentives.” American Economic Review 101(3):6570.
26
Appendix
Proof of Lemma 1:
Since  
 , (3) states that: (i)  
 ; (ii) 
 
 ;  
 . In addition, given that  
  and
 
 , we define 



 . Hence, (4) states that: (i) 
 
 ; (ii)  
 ; (iii)  
 .
Thus, a green payment: (i) induces both pro-environmental and normative goal preferences
if ; (ii) it reduces both pro-
environmental and normative goal preferences if 
; (iii) it enhances pro-environmental preferences but it reduce normative goal
preferences if .
Deriving the values of  and 
Recall that the optimal solution  satisfies the first-order condition, (9) and (10). A
differentiation of (10) with respect to yields:


 




 






Furthermore, by differentiating (9) with respect to we get that;
27







However, note that:
 




Thus, by (A3), (A2) becomes:
 



Deriving the values of  and 
Following a similar procedure as before, a differentiation of Eq(9) with respect to yields:



 



whereas a differentiation of (10) with respect to yields:






 




By using (9) and (A3), (A6) becomes:
 




Therefore, by substituting (A7) into (A5)
28


 





 







... Among the methods that have a positive impact on the climate and the environment are the so-called "green payments", which account for 30% of the national distribution of funds. Special subsidies are also provided to young farmers up to 40 years of age who started agricultural activity not earlier than 5 years before applying for the support(Feng, 2007;Nelson et al., 2019;Diakoulakis et al., 2020). ...
Article
Because of the acceleration of the development of various types of business in the era of global digitalization, the authors propose to pay attention to the regulation of environmental management and agricultural business, as well as to offer tools for state regulation of this aspect. To do this, the authors analyzed the impact of the digital era on various aspects, studied foreign experience in reducing the negative environmental impact of digital technologies. The authors analyzed the current state of the domestic agricultural business and gave forecasts for its development. All this allowed the authors to develop tools for state management of environmental management and agricultural business in the digital era, namely, the main tools and ways to reduce the negative impact of the agricultural business on environmental management using ICT, as well as the main steps of the state program for the rational use of natural resources in the region.
Article
Full-text available
The understanding, prediction, and encouragement of pro-environmental behaviour (i.e., behaviour that impacts the environment as little as possible) depend to a large extent on understanding the motivational dynamics of pro-environmental behaviour. In this review paper, we discuss the state of the art with regard to these dynamics. We explain the importance of three types of goals underlying behaviour: the hedonic goal to feel good, the gain goal to enhance one's resources, and the normative goal to act appropriately. The strength of these goals differs across situation, which affects which aspects in the situation people attend to, how they evaluate these aspects, and which choices they make. We describe factors affecting the strength of goals, and how the normative goal to act appropriately can be strengthened so as to encourage sustained pro-environmental actions. More specifically, we propose that values affect the chronic strength of goals. Besides, various situational factors can affect the strength of goals in a particular situation. These situational factors explain why people do not have stable preferences and why they do not always act upon the values they prioritise. Finally, we discuss strategies that can be employed to encourage pro-environmental actions. These strategies are either aimed at reducing the conflict between different goals by aligning the hedonic and/or gain goal with the normative goal, or at strengthening the normative goal so that people will act pro-environmentally even though this may reduce the realisation of their hedonic or gain goals.
Article
Full-text available
Assessments of urban metabolism (UM) are well situated to identify the scale, components, and direction of urban and energy flows in cities and have been instrumental in benchmarking and monitoring the key levers of urban environmental pressure, such as transport, space conditioning, and electricity. Hitherto, urban food consumption has garnered scant attention both in UM accounting (typically lumped with “biomass”) and on the urban policy agenda, despite its relevance to local and global environmental pressures. With future growth expected in urban population and wealth, an accounting of the environmental footprint from urban food demand (“foodprint”) is necessary. This article reviews 43 UM assessments including 100 cities, and a total of 132 foodprints in terms of mass, carbon footprint, and ecological footprint and situates it relative to other significant environmental drivers (transport, energy, and so on) The foodprint was typically the third largest source of mass flows (average is 0.8 tonnes per capita per annum) and carbon footprint (average is 1.9 tonnes carbon dioxide equivalents per capita per annum) in the reviewed cities, whereas it was generally the largest driver of urban ecological footprints (average is 1.2 global hectares per capita per annum), with large deviations based on wealth, culture, and urban form. Meat and dairy are the primary drivers of both global warming and ecological footprint impacts, with little relationship between their consumption and city wealth. The foodprint is primarily linear in form, producing significant organic exhaust from the urban system that has a strong, positive correlation to wealth. Though much of the foodprint is embodied within imported foodstuffs, cities can still implement design and policy interventions, such as improved nutrient recycling and food waste avoidance, to redress the foodprint.
Article
Waste managers struggle to comply with the European legislation that regulates the handling of organic waste. A waste management system that aims at recovering nutrients from the municipal organic waste generated in the Spanish region of Cantabria was modeled combining Material Flow Analysis, Life Cycle Assessment and Life Cycle Costing. The model was optimized to find system configurations that minimize the total annual cost (TAC) and the global warming impacts (GW) and maximize the circularity indicators of nitrogen and phosphorus (CIN and CIP). The developed superstructure is composed of waste management unit processes and unit processes related to the land application of the recovered products (compost, digestate, (NH4)2SO4 and NH4MgPO4·6H2O) and industrial fertilizers to grow corn. The results of the optimization indicate that increasing CIN and minimizing GW raises the TAC, because of the investment on new technologies, although high CIP values can be achieved at low TACs. The economic margin that enables the organic fertilizers to compete in the market with industrial fertilizers was estimated. The cooperation between waste managers, the farmers that purchase the recovered products and the policy-makers that set the waste management taxes can minimize the costs that hinder the transition towards a circular economy.
Article
Social norms affect environmental quality. But what exactly is a social norm? Environmental economists studying the topic draw on diverse scholarly traditions and may not have the same phenomenon in mind when using the concept. For example, social norms may refer to common, but not necessarily socially approved, behaviors; to internalized ethical rules; or to one of several equilibria in a coordination game. I first discuss some of the definitions used in the environmental economics literature. Then, I outline a simple framework for analysis of voluntary contributions to public goods. Using this framework, I illustrate differences and similarities between altruism, moral norms, and social norms and discuss implications for environmental policies. In particular, when a social norm represents one of several stable equilibria, policy can potentially invoke abrupt and dramatic behavioral changes. Expected final online publication date for the Annual Review of Resource Economics Volume 10 is October 5, 2018. Please see http://www.annualreviews.org/page/journal/pubdates for revised estimates.
Article
Olive mill wastewater (OMW) is generated during the production of olive oil. Its disposal is still a major environmental problem in Mediterranean countries, despite the fact that a large number of technologies have been proposed up to date. The present work examines for the first time a novel, simple and low-cost technology for OMW treatment combining solar drying and composting. In the first step, OMW was dried in a chamber inside a solar greenhouse using swine manure as a bulking agent. The mean evaporation rate was found to be 5.2 kg H2O/m2/d for a drying period of 6 months (February-August). High phenol (75%) and low nitrogen (15%) and carbon (15%) losses were recorded at the end of the solar drying process. The final product after solar drying was rich in nutrients (N: 27.8 g/kg, P: 7.3 g/kg, K: 81.6 g/kg) but still contained significant quantities of phenols (18.4 g/kg). In order to detoxify the final product, a composting process was applied as a second step with or without the use of grape marc as bulking agent. Results showed that the use of grape marc as a bulking agent at a volume ratio of 1:1 achieved a higher compost temperature profile (60 °C) than 2:1 (solar drying product: grape marc) or no use (solar drying product). The end product after the combination of solar drying and composting had the characteristics of an organic fertilizer (57% organic carbon) rich in nutrients (3.5% N, 1% P, 6.5% K) with quite low phenol content (2.9 g/kg). Finally, the use of this product for the cultivation of pepper plants approved its fertility which was found similar with commercial NPK fertilizers.
Article
Pressing problems of environmental degradation are typically argued to require coordination, primarily through state intervention. Social scientists are struggling to understand how attitudes toward such state interventions are formed, and several drivers have been suggested, including education. People with university degrees are assumed to have certain values as well as the analytical skills to understand complex issues such as climate change. By using a unique panel data-set with students in different university programs (economics, law and political science), this study provides a better understanding of whether and how education affects environmental policy acceptance. One important finding is that university studies generate variation in support and scepticism toward different types of policy measures. For example, economics students tend to develop more positive attitudes toward market-based policy measures. This indicates a potential for education to increase the societal support often hindering the implementation of such policy tools.
Book
I: Background.- 1. An Introduction.- 2. Conceptualizations of Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination.- II: Self-Determination Theory.- 3. Cognitive Evaluation Theory: Perceived Causality and Perceived Competence.- 4. Cognitive Evaluation Theory: Interpersonal Communication and Intrapersonal Regulation.- 5. Toward an Organismic Integration Theory: Motivation and Development.- 6. Causality Orientations Theory: Personality Influences on Motivation.- III: Alternative Approaches.- 7. Operant and Attributional Theories.- 8. Information-Processing Theories.- IV: Applications and Implications.- 9. Education.- 10. Psychotherapy.- 11. Work.- 12. Sports.- References.- Author Index.
Article
Environmental problems can be reduced if people more consistently engage in proenvironmental actions. In this article, I discuss factors that motivate or inhibit individuals to act proenvironmentally. Many people are intrinsically motivated to engage in proenvironmental actions, because protecting the environment makes them feel good about themselves. People are more likely to be intrinsically motivated to act proenvironmentally over and again when they strongly endorse biospheric values. However, people may be less likely to act on their biospheric values when these values are not supported by the context, or when competing values are activated by factors in a choice context. Next, I discuss strategies to encourage proenvironmental actions by strengthening biospheric values, or by empowering and motivating people to act on their biospheric values. Moreover, I discuss factors influencing the acceptability of environmental policies that aim to encourage proenvironmental behavior. Expected final online publication date for the Annual Review of Environment and Resources Volume 41 is October 17, 2016. Please see http://www.annualreviews.org/catalog/pubdates.aspx for revised estimates.
Article
We analyze the effects of the interactions that the two pillars of the European Union Common Agricultural Policy—market support and rural development—have on farmers’ uptake of organic farming practices. Special attention is given to the 2003 reform, which substantially altered the relative importance of the two types of support by decoupling direct agricultural payments from the production of a specific crop. In our empirical analysis we study the case of Sweden, making use of the variation in the timing of farmers’ decisions regarding participation in support programs. We estimate a dynamic non-linear unobserved effects probit model to account for unobserved individual heterogeneity and state dependence. Our results indicate the existence of a negative effect of the market support system in place when organic farming techniques were adopted before the 2003 reform. However, this effect is reversed by the introduction of decoupling. Furthermore, the effects of support differ between certified and non-certified organic production: both pillars have significant effects on non-certified organic farming, whereas certified organic farming is exclusively driven by agro-environmental subsidies.