ArticlePDF Available
The Unprecedented Fall in U.S. Revolving
Credit
Gajendran RaveendranathanGeorgios Stefanidis
May 11, 2020
Abstract
Revolving credit in the U.S. declined drastically in the last decade after several
years of upward trending growth. We show that the Ability to Pay provision of the
Credit CARD Act of 2009, which places restrictions on credit card limits, accounts
for this decline. Extending a model of revolving credit to analyze this policy, we
account for changes in credit statistics by income and age. Although the goal was
consumer protection, the policy has led to welfare losses. Even consumers with
time inconsistent preferences who could benefit from tighter credit constraints are
worse off. An alternative policy considered by policymakers —an interest rate cap
—improves welfare.
Keywords: revolving credit, credit limits, Ability to Pay, Credit CARD Act
JEL classification: E21, E44, E65, G28, G50
We thank Juan Carlos Hatchondo, Kyle Herkenhoff, Kyle Dempsey, Pau Pujolas, Zachary Mahone,
Radek Paluszynski, Hyunju Amy, and participants at the University of Montreal for their comments and
discussion.
McMaster University. E-mail: raveeg1@mcmaster.ca
York University. E-mail: stefa107@yorku.ca
1
1 Introduction
The decade succeeding the Credit CARD Act of 2009 and the Great Recession saw an
unprecedented decline in revolving credit (mainly credit card debt). By 2019, revolving
credit to disposable income declined to 70 percent of its 2008 level. The background
to this decline was three decades of consistent growth and a stabilization in the 2000s.
We argue that the Ability to Pay provision of the Credit CARD Act of 2009, which
imposes restrictions on credit card limits, accounts for this decline. We extend a model
of revolving credit lines with a search friction in the credit card market to analyze this
policy. We show that the policy change accounts for changes in credit statistics by
income and age and changes in aggregate credit statistics. The stated intention of the
provision was consumer protection. Through the lens of our model, we show that the
policy has resulted in ubiquitous welfare losses. We further investigate these welfare losses
by considering agents with time inconsistent preferences who stand to benefit from credit
limit restrictions. The provision does not even benefit such agents. Finally, we consider
an alternative policy debated by policy makers —an interest rate cap. We show that such
a policy improves consumer welfare.
We begin our analysis by documenting empirical patterns concurrent with the fall in
credit. Using triennial survey data from the Survey of Consumer Finances, we first show
that credit limits followed a very similar pattern to revolving credit. In particular, the
(cross-sectional) average credit card limit increased from less than 35 percent to more
than 55 percent of disposable income per capita between 1989 and 2007.1By 2016, it
decreased to 38 percent of disposable income per capita. We also find that the decrease
in credit and limits were ubiquitous across all income levels and ages. Furthermore,
the decrease was largest for the middle-high income consumers and young-middle age
consumers.
Our paper attributes these patterns to the Ability to Pay provision. This is a provision
of the Credit CARD Act of 2009 that requires credit card issuers to evaluate consumers’
ability to make minimum payments assuming full utilization of the credit line. To comply,
issuers modified their approval procedures known as underwriting tests. The Consumer
Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB), which surveys issuers to prepare The Consumer
Credit Card Market Report for Congress, found that issuers incorporated thresholds for
debt obligations to income and/or thresholds for residual income in their underwriting
tests. As a result, 4.7 percent of applications failed the Ability to Pay underwriting test
and were denied credit cards in 2013-14. Furthermore, the same report finds that the
number of denied credit line increases due to Ability to Pay were more than the actual
number of credit line increases in the same period. Although there is evidence for the
1The average credit card limit refers to the cross-sectional average of total borrowing limits on credit
cards reported by households.
1
provision’s impact, the CFPB in its 2019 Consumer Credit Card Market Report states
that Ability to Pay has not been studied like the other Credit CARD Act provisions. The
main contribution of our paper is to extend a model of revolving credit lines to study
this provision, evaluate its impact on the credit card market, and quantify implications
for consumer welfare.
Our model of revolving credit lines with a search friction in the credit card market
builds on Mateos-Planas and R´ıos-Rull (2013) and Raveendranathan (2020). In these
papers, credit card contracts are long-term defaultable credit lines specified by a credit
limit and interest rate. To analyze the policy, we incorporate credit limit increases and
on-the-credit-search into our model. These features are important to analyze the Ability
to Pay provision because it applies to credit limit increases and credit card issuances.
Furthermore, we consider agents with time inconsistent preferences in the form of quasi-
hyperbolic discounting as in Nakajima (2012,2017). Such preferences give rise to a
motive for credit limit restrictions. In particular, agents with time inconsistent preferences
may benefit from limit restrictions since they constrain their “future selves” from over
borrowing.
For our benchmark economy, we assume consumers without hyperbolic discounting.
This is our preferred setup because it best accounts for credit data by income. However,
when analyzing welfare, we also consider the implications for consumers with hyperbolic
discounting. We calibrate our pre-policy model to the 2004 U.S. economy and show
that it accounts for non-targeted credit statistics by income and age. Subsequently, we
introduce the Ability to Pay provision into our model. We model Ability to Pay as
a constraint on the lender’s problem. In particular, the credit card limit to expected
earnings has to be below a threshold when the lender issues a credit card or increases
the credit limit. This constraint captures the modifications made to underwriting tests
by issuers for compliance. We refer to the threshold as the Ability to Pay threshold. We
calibrate this threshold to target the observed decline in average credit card limits. The
calibrated model accounts for non-targeted changes in credit statistics by income and
age, discussed above. The model also accounts for changes in aggregate credit statistics
associated with default risk and credit access.
Having shown that our model accounts for a multitude of empirical patterns, we
analyze welfare implications of the policy taking transition dynamics into account. The
provision leads to welfare losses in our benchmark model. The impact is felt most by
middle-high income consumers and young-middle age consumers. The losses for middle-
high income consumers are equivalent to a one-time transfer worth 0.3-0.4 percent of
disposable income per capita. The losses for young-middle age groups are equivalent to
a one-time transfer worth 0.7 percent of disposable income per capita. The total welfare
losses of the policy are equivalaent to a one-time transfer worth 0.25 percent of total
disposable income. To put the total losses in context, they are equivalent to 53 percent of
2
losses consumers would face if we were to shutdown the credit card market. As mentioned
above, two novel features of our model are on-the-credit-search and credit limit increases.
If one ignores these features, the welfare losses of the policy are almost zero.
The stated intention of the policy was to protect consumers. Therefore, we also
consider a framework where there is greater scope for consumers to benefit from gov-
ernment protection. In particular, we incorporate consumers with quasi-hyperbolic dis-
counting. As mentioned above, such consumers may benefit from constraints on credit
limits. For this analysis, we consider hyperbolic discount factors in the range used in Laib-
son, Repetto, and Tobacman (2007) and Nakajima (2017). Furthermore, we re-calibrate
the models with quasi-hyperbolic consumers to match the same set of target moments.
Although the magnitudes are smaller, the policy still leads to welfare losses.
After showing that the Ability to Pay provision leads to welfare losses, we turn to an
alternative policy: an interest rate cap. A potential benefit of an interest rate cap is that
it can limit the degree of credit card firms’ market power. In our model, market power
manifests as a result of two ingredients. First, we have introduced search frictions in the
credit card market. Second, credit card firms set the terms of the credit card contract.
A rate cap benefits consumers by lowering interest rates. There are two major costs
associated with a rate cap. First, as a result of a rate cap, credit card firms become less
profitable. Due to this reduction in profitability, credit card firms send fewer offers, which
makes it harder for consumers to acquire a credit card. Second, with lower interest rates,
credit card firms may find it optimal to reduce credit card limits. We find that an interest
rate cap of 7.41 percentage points over the risk-free rate maximizes total welfare. The
average spread in the data is 11.48 percentage points. Hence, this policy would require
the average credit card interest rate to decrease by approximately four percentage points.
Although low income consumers pay higher interest rates, high income consumers benefit
the most from a rate cap. This is because high income consumers have lower credit card
utilization rates (credit/limit). That is, they are less constrained. Therefore, they can
respond by borrowing substantially more compared to low income consumers.
The fall in revolving credit coincides with other regulatory changes and the Great
Recession. Using our model, we rule them out as potential explanations. One of the
provisions of the CARD Act is that credit card issuers cannot increase interest rates on
existing balances, with some exceptions. Comparing a model where the credit card issuers
choose between commitment and no commitment to interest rates (pre-policy) with one
where credit card issuers commit to interest rates (post-policy), we find that commitment
leads to lower levels of credit among low income consumers. This implication is at odds
with the data.
The Great Recession of 2007 led to the largest and most persistent drop in output
in the post World War II U.S. economy. We analyze the transition dynamics of an
unexpected large drop in average earnings. We find that in the initial years, credit and
3
limits (normalized by income) increase, which is at odds with the data. The magnitudes
of the changes after ten years are negligible.
The BAPCPA (2005) has made filing for bankruptcy more stringent. For example, it
prevents households above median income from filing for bankruptcy. A consequence of
this stringency is increased administrative burden, which has led to higher bankruptcy
fees (Albanesi and Nosal ,2020). Analyzing comparative statics with respect to the cost
of default (stigma), we find that an increase in the default cost leads to higher credit and
credit limits, which goes against the data. A lower cost of default increases the charge-off
rate, which also goes against the data. Finally, we rule out substitution to other forms
of consumer credit.
Related literature Our paper contributes to three strands of the literature: the
literature on quantitative models of consumer credit, the literature that analyzes various
provisions of the Credit CARD Act of 2009, and the literature on consumer credit and
behavioral consumers.
The standard models of consumer credit build on the seminal work of Chatterjee
and Eyigungor (2016) and Livshits, MacGee, and Tertilt (2007). In these models,
credit card contracts are bond price schedules issued by perfectly competitive lenders.
A recent strand of the literature has modified these models to incorporate revolving
credit lines, search frictions, and imperfect competition. Examples include, but are not
limited to Drozd and Nosal (2008), Mateos-Planas and R´ıos-Rull (2013), Herkenhoff
and Raveendranathan (2019), Braxton, Herkenhoff, and Phillips (2019), and Raveen-
dranathan (2020). We make a theoretical contribution to this literature by modifying a
model of revolving credit lines with a search friction to study the Ability to Pay provision.
In particular, we analyze a model where lenders increase credit limits in periods after a
match and issue credit cards to all consumers.
Our paper contributes to the literature that studies various provisions of the Credit
CARD Act of 2009. Other provisions of the CARD Act restricted over limit fees and
interest rate hikes on existing balances. Agarwal et al. (2015) analyze regulatory limits
on over limit fees. In particular, they compare consumer credit cards, which were sub-
ject to the CARD Act, with small business credit cards, which were not subject to the
CARD Act. Nelson (2020) and Mateos-Planas and R´ıos-Rull (2013) study the impact
of restricting credit card interest rate hikes. We study the impact of the Ability to Pay
provision.
Our study also contributes to the literature on consumer credit and behavioral con-
sumers. In particular, Nakajima (2012,2017) and Exler, Livshits, MacGee, and Tertilt
(2018) focus on over-borrowing by consumers with temptation and cross-subsidization
of interest rates between rational and over-optimistic consumers. In these studies, con-
sumers with temptation or over optimism are not exploited by credit card issuers. This
is because credit card issuers are assumed to be perfectly competitive. We incorporate
4
lender market power and long-term relationships in our study to allow for such exploita-
tion. With these modifications, we study welfare implications of both Ability to Pay and
an interest rate cap.
We contribute to the various studies that have analyzed trends in U.S. revolving
credit since the 1970s. More specifically, the literature has studied in great detail the
stark increase between the 1970s and the early 2000s. Athreya, Tam, and Young (2012),
Narajabad (2012), and anchez (2018) attribute the rise in revolving credit to improved
information about consumers through adoption of credit scoring by lenders. Drozd and
Nosal (2008) and Herkenhoff (2019) attribute the rise in revolving credit to greater access
to credit cards resulting from the IT revolution. Livshits, MacGee, and Tertilt (2016)
argue that both improved information and increased access to credit cards jointly account
for the rise in revolving credit and associated empirical patterns. Our paper is the first
to study the potential causes of the fall in revolving credit. Furthermore, we focus on an
explanation based on policy rather than technological advances.
2 Data
We use annual aggregate U.S. consumer credit data from the Federal Reserve Board
G19 data set. In particular, we focus on outstanding revolving credit (mainly credit card
debt). The left panel of Figure 1plots the time series for this variable as a percent
of total U.S. disposable income. Three major patterns emerge from the time series.
First, revolving credit to disposable income increased consistently from the 1970s until
the early 2000s (0.5 percent in 1970 to almost 8 percent in the 2000s). As discussed
above, several papers have argued that the observed rise was driven by lower fixed costs
for lenders in accessing different markets and improved information about consumers.
Second, revolving credit to disposable income stabilized in the early-late 2000s. This is
the period in which there was a boom (often termed over-leveraging) in the mortgage
and home equity line of credit markets (refer to Figure 29c in Appendix B.2). However,
we do not observe a similar pattern for revolving credit, which was mostly flat until 2009.
Third, revolving credit to disposable income declined after 2009. By 2019, it decreased
to 5.6 percent of disposable income (70 percent of its 2008 level). Furthermore, there has
been no recovery.2
We document a similar pattern for credit card limits using triennial data from the
Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF). We normalize the (cross-sectional) average credit
card limit in our sample by the disposable income per capita. The right panel of Figure
2Appendix B.2 shows that there has been a decline whether we measure total revolving credit or
total unsecured credit. Unsecured credit is the sum of revolving credit and personal loans, an alternative
measure used by Livshits, MacGee, and Tertilt (2010). It measures total uncollateralized consumer
credit. Appendix B.2 also shows that there has not been any substitution into other forms of consumer
credit.
5
1plots the time series for this variable. It increased from 35 percent to more than 55
percent of disposable income per capita between 1989 and 2007. By 2016, it decreased to
38 percent of disposable income per capita (70 percent of its 2007 level). External sources
corroborate the fall in credit limits. The Consumer Credit Card Market Report (2017)
prepared by the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau shows that the total credit line
on open credit card accounts decreased from 34 to 24 percent of total disposable income
between 2005 and 2017 (Figure 5, page 36). Summarizing, in the last decade, the U.S
saw an unprecedented fall in both revolving credit and credit card limits.
Figure 1: Total revolving credit and average credit card limits
(a) Total outstanding revolving credit (b) (Cross-sectional) average credit card limit
Notes: The left panel plots total revolving credit as a percent of disposable income between 1970 and 2019 (data sources:
Federal Reserve Board G19, Bureau of Economic Analysis, and authors’ calculations). The right panel plots the
(cross-sectional) average credit card limit per debtor as a percent of disposable income per capita between 1989 and 2016
(data sources: Survey of Consumer Finances, Bureau of Economic Analysis, World Bank WDI, and authors’
calculations). The average credit card limit refers to the cross-sectional average of total borrowing limits on credit cards
reported by households in the Survey of Consumer Finances.
The SCF allows us to investigate how different income and age groups experienced
the drastic changes in the revolving credit market. We separate the 2004 and 2016 SCF
cohorts into 5 quintiles by reported household income. The top left panel of Figure 2
is a bar chart of the change in average credit to disposable income per capita in each
quintile between 2004 and 2016. The top right panel is a bar chart of the change in
average credit limits to disposable income per capita in each quintile between 2004 and
2016. We emphasize the following two patterns. First, the declines in credit and limits
were ubiquitous. Second, the declines were largest for the middle-high income quintiles.3
3We also externally corroborate this pattern. The Consumer Credit Card Market 2017 report shows
the decline in credit by credit scores. Figure 17 (page 47) shows that prime and near prime consumers
experienced the largest drop in credit compared to subprime consumers. This is consistent with our
finding that middle-high income quintiles experienced the largest drop in credit since these consumers
are more likely to have higher credit scores.
6
We then separate the 2004 and 2016 SCF cohorts by age. The bottom left panel
of Figure 2plots the change in average credit to disposable income per capita for each
age group between 2004 and 2016. The bottom right panel plots the change in average
credit limits to disposable income per capita for each age group between 2004 and 2016.
We emphasize the following two patterns. First, the declines in credit and limits were
ubiquitous in all ages. Second, the declines in credit were largest for young-middle age
consumers.
Figure 2: Change in revolving credit and credit card limits by income and age (2004-2016)
(a) Credit (b) Credit card limit
(c) Credit (d) Credit card limit
Notes: The top left panel plots the percentage point change in the (cross-sectional) average credit to disposable income
per capita between 1998 and 2016 by income quintile (data sources: Survey of Consumer Finances, Bureau of Economic
Analysis, World Bank WDI, and authors’ calculations). The top right panel plots the percentage point change in the
(cross-sectional) average credit card limit per debtor to disposable income per capita between 1998 and 2016 by income
quintile (data sources: Survey of Consumer Finances, Bureau of Economic Analysis, World Bank WDI, and authors’
calculations). The bottom panels plot the analogous changes by age.
Ability to Pay: The Credit CARD Act of 2009 is a federal statute intended to
limit the scope of predatory behavior by credit card providers. We focus on the Ability
7
to Pay provision.4This provision requires credit card companies to screen consumers
more thoroughly when issuing new credit cards or increasing credit limits on existing
accounts. Credit card companies have to establish that consumers can make minimum
periodic payments. In particular, they must consider consumers’ ability to make minimum
payments assuming full utilization of the credit line.
We draw from The Consumer Credit Market Report (2015 and 2017) to inform our
discussion of Ability to Pay. These are biennial reports prepared by the Consumer Fi-
nancial Protection Bureau (CFPB) for Congress. These reports highlight procedures
implemented by credit card issuers to comply with Ability to Pay. They also provide
data showing that Ability to Pay has led to fewer credit card issuances and fewer credit
limit increases. To comply, credit card issuers modified their approval procedures, known
as underwriting tests. In particular, they included a threshold for debt obligations to
income and/or a threshold for income the consumer will have after paying debt obliga-
tions (pages 144-145, 2015 report). If a borrower fails this underwriting test, they are
not issued a credit card or an increase in their credit limit.
The reports find that 4.7 percent of all credit card applications in 2013 and 2014 were
denied due to Ability to Pay (page 104, 2015 report). The reported denial rate comes
with an important caveat. In particular, it is not known whether denied applicants would
have subsequently failed other underwriting tests. Ideally, one would want to know the
number of applications that would have been successful had it not been for the Ability
to Pay underwriting test. However, this statistic is not available.
To mitigate this concern, the reports compare rejection rates due to Ability to Pay be-
tween super-prime borrowers (FICO scores 720) and deep sub-prime borrowers (FICO
scores 579). Super-prime borrowers are less likely to be rejected for other reasons com-
pared to deep subprime borrowers. That is, deep sub-prime borrowers are more likely to
have failed other underwriting tests. For super-prime borrowers in 2016, more than 15
percent of rejected applications were due to Ability to Pay (Figure 14, page 129, 2017
report). The same statistic for deep sub-prime borrowers was less than 3 percent. We
view these statistics as a better indicator of the extent to which Ability to Pay impacted
denial rates.
Ability to Pay has also led to fewer credit limit increases. There were more credit limit
increases denied due to Ability to Pay than credit limit increases issued in 2013 and 2014
(Figure 28, page 116, 2015 report). Given these facts, we propose a model of revolving
credit where lenders issue credit cards to all consumers and increase credit limits over
time. In this framework, we introduce Ability to Pay as a constraint on the lender’s
problem to capture the modifications to issuers’ underwriting tests. This constraint will
require the credit limit to expected income ratio to not exceed a parameter: the Ability
4The provision in its entirety can be found here https://www.consumerfinance.gov/
policy-compliance/rulemaking/regulations/1026/2018-06-01/51/
8
to Pay threshold.
3 Model
Our model economy extends Mateos-Planas and R´ıos-Rull (2013) and Raveendranathan
(2020) to analyze the policy discussed above. Novel features in our model are on-the-
credit-search and credit limit increases. We analyze a small open economy with overlap-
ping generations of consumers and credit card firms. Furthermore, we assume a search
friction in the credit card market. The consumers face idiosyncratic earnings shocks
and extreme value type 1 shocks over default and repayment. They maximize lifetime
utility by making decisions on consumption, savings/borrowing, and default/repayment.
Credit card firms maximize ex-ante profits by making the discrete decision whether to
send credit offers. We assume a fixed cost of sending offers. Upon matching with a
consumer, the credit card firm maximizes ex-post profits by choosing the terms of the
credit card contract. The main difference from Mateos-Planas and R´ıos-Rull (2013) and
Raveendranathan (2020) is in our modeling of credit card contracts. The lender commits
to the borrowing premium, which captures the interest rate margin on credit cards over
the index rate. However, the lender does not commit to the limit.5After a match, the
lender is allowed to increase the limit or keep it the same, but not decrease it. This as-
sumption is motivated by the strategy followed by credit card firms where they initially
issue accounts with low limits and increase them over time.6
Consumers live up to Jperiods with jdenoting their age. Consumers of age jsur-
vive to j+ 1 with probability ψj. She supplies labor inelastically until retirement. In
retirement, she does not work, but receives Social Security. The idiosyncratic productiv-
ity of a consumer consists of a permanent component θi, a persistent AR(1) component
ηi,j, and a transitory iid component γi,j . Earning states are summarized in = (θ, η, γ).
Working age earnings for this individual are denoted yj,. They are given by (1τ)θηγνj,
where τis the Social Security tax rate and νjis the deterministic life cycle productiv-
ity. Retirement age earnings are given by Social Security SSθ, where the Social Security
is a function of the permanent component θ. The consumer also faces extreme value
type 1 shocks ζRand ζDover repayment and default, respectively. These extreme value
type 1 shocks capture un-modeled defaults resulting from health care bills, divorce, and
5Before the CARD Act of 2009, lenders were not prohibited from increasing interest rates on existing
credit card balances. However, we show that the model with commitment to the interest rate better
accounts for credit by income in the data. We explore this further in Section 7.1.
6Decreases in credit card limits are rare. For example, on average less than 1 percent of accounts
experience a credit line decrease every quarter (Figure 52, page 154, Consumer Credit Market (2017)).
We have analyzed the case where the lender could decrease the limit or decrease it to current debt levels
as in Mateos-Planas and R´ıos-Rull (2013). In these cases, the model generates too few defaults compared
to the data. Later, we analyze the case where the lender commits to limits as in Raveendranathan (2020).
We show that the policy has a significantly muted effect on welfare.
9
lawsuits.7Debt is denoted as b.
Credit standing determines whether consumers have access to revolving credit, that
is, a credit card. The terms of a credit card are summarized by the credit card limit ¯
b
and credit card borrowing premium τq. These terms may differ between consumers.
To summarize, a consumer’s idiosyncratic state with a credit card is age, debt/asset
level, the vector of productivity components, and credit card terms (j, b, ,¯
b, τq). A
consumer without credit access cannot borrow, but may save. Her idiosyncratic state is
age, level of assets, and productivity components (j, b, ).
Consumers with and without credit cards search for new credit cards. Search is
assumed to be targeted. That is, credit card firms tailor credit offers to consumers on the
basis of their idiosyncratic state variables except the transitory component γ.8Consumers
without credit access can search in submarket (j, b, θ, η). They receive a credit offer with
probability pS(j, b, θ, η). This probability is determined by the following equation:
pSj, b, θ, η=
MuSj, b, θ, η, vSj, b, θ, η
uSj, b, θ, η,(1)
where uS(j, b, θ, η) is the mass of consumers in submarket (j, b, θ, η) without credit access,
vS(j, b, θ, η) is the mass of credit card firms making credit offers in submarket (j, b, θ, η),
and M(u, v) is the matching function. That is, M(u, v) determines the mass of successful
matches when the mass of consumers looking for a credit card is uand the mass of credit
card firms making offers is v. Therefore, the right hand side of equation 1represents the
fraction of successful matches in submarket (j, b, θ, η) receiving a credit offer.
Consumers with a credit card have access to submarket (j, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq). Their proba-
bility of credit access pC(j, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq) is computed analogously to that in equation 1:
pCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq=
MuCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, vCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq
uCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq.(2)
This probability, in addition to the idiosyncratic states of equation 1, also depends on
current credit card terms (¯
b, τq).
7Other papers that use extreme value type 1 shocks in models with consumer credit are Auclert and
Mitman (2018), Herkenhoff and Raveendranathan (2019), Chatterjee et al. (2016), and Raveendranathan
(2020). The main benefit of using extreme value type 1 shocks is that it makes default a probability
function rather than a discrete choice function, adding smoothness to the CC issuer’s ex-post profit
function. In Appendix A.4, we show that our results are not sensitive to these shocks.
8The implicit assumption is that the offer is sent before the transitory earnings realization. This
assumption is similar to Mateos-Planas and R´ıos-Rull (2013) where they assume the lender doesn’t
observe the consumer’s default cost and switching cost. This assumption adds smoothness to the lender’s
ex-post profit function.
10
3.1 Credit card firms
The mass of credit card firms sending offers to each submarket is pinned down by
the zero-profit condition for each submarket. That is, cost κof sending a credit offer is
equated to the expected profits to be made in that submarket. As a result, all submarkets
yield zero expected profits to credit card firms. The zero profit condition for new card
holders is:
κ=
MuSj, b, θ, η, vSj, b, θ, η
vSj, b, θ, ηΠSj, b, θ, η,(3)
and for current card holders is:
κ=
MuCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, vCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq
vCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τqΠCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq.(4)
Both expressions feature M/v, the credit card firm’s probability of matching with a
consumer, and Π, the ex-post profits upon a match which we specify next.
Upon match with a new cardholder, the credit card firm chooses the credit card
contract that specifies a credit card limit ¯
band a credit card borrowing premium τq. The
terms are specific to consumers’ idiosyncratic state (j, b, θ, η). The credit card contract
is chosen as follows:
ΠSj, b, θ, η= max
¯
bSS
q(EγΠj, b, ,¯
bS, τ S
q),(5)
subject to
EγWCj, b, ,¯
bS, τ S
qEγWSj, b,
φE0|θ,η yj+1,0¯
bS
where Π without the superscript, characterized below, denotes the profits to a credit
card firm whose customer has idiosyncratic state (j, b, ) and credit card contract (¯
bS, τ S
q).
As discussed above, credit card firms decide on the credit card terms before observing
consumers’ transitory earnings component. The optimal contract for submarket (j, b, θ, η)
is denoted (¯
bS(j, b, θ, η), τS
q(j, b, θ, η)). The first constraint is the participation constraint
of new cardholders. It imposes that they have to benefit by accepting the credit card
firm’s offer. Their payoff WSis determined in section 3.2. The second constraint is the
Ability to Pay constraint and is only active when this policy is in place. It requires that
the limit at issuance must be less than φfraction of expected earnings.
The next problem we consider is that of a credit card firm newly matched with a cur-
rent cardholder. A credit card firm in this position must offer the consumer a credit card
contract preferable to the existing one.9It makes a balance transfer of any outstanding
9The incumbent credit card firm cannot make a competing offer after the consumer is matched with
11
debt bto the incumbent credit card company. The problem it solves is:
ΠCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq= max
¯
bCC
q(EγΠj, b, θ, η, γ, ¯
bC, τ C
q)max{b, 0},(6)
subject to
EγWCj, b, ,¯
bC, τ C
qEγWCj, b, ,¯
bI(j, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq), τq
φE0|θ,η yj+1,0¯
bC
The problem of the credit card firm matched with current cardholders has two differences
to the one matched with new cardholders in equation 5. First, the credit card firm assumes
any consumer debt, max{b, 0}. Second, the new offer has to be an improvement for the
consumer relative to staying with the incumbent, where ¯
bIis the limit chosen by the
incumbent.
Finally, the incumbent credit card firm may only increase the credit limit and has
committed to the premium.10 The value function for this stage is:
ΠIj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq= max
¯
bI¯
b(EγΠj, b, θ, η, γ, ¯
bI, τq)(7)
subject to
φE0|θ,η yj+1,0¯
bIif ¯
bI>¯
b
The incumbent credit card firm can increase the credit limit ¯
bIwhile making sure to
satisfy the Ability to Pay constraint. It can also keep the same credit limit even if it does
not satisfy the Ability to Pay constraint. The constraint requires that if the incumbent
lender is increasing the limit, it must be less than or equal to φfraction of earnings. This
is consistent with policy, which only applies to issuances and limit increases.
Finally, we characterize the credit card firms’ payoff taking credit card terms as given.
In particular, once credit card firms have chosen the limit and borrowing premium, (¯
b, τq),
a new credit card firm. However, at the stage where they set the limit and/or premium, they can tailor
their offer so that it is not lucrative for other credit card firms to poach their client.
10An exception is the retirement period. During the retirement period, we allow incumbent lender
to choose a limit that is weakly greater than the current debt level. This choice best fits the empirical
default by age distribution. Results are not sensitive to this assumption.
12
their profits are determined as follows:
Πj, b, ,¯
b, τq=1d max{b, 0} − max{b0,0}(qj(τq) + τc)+
Πs=1dCψjE0|po0=0ΠIj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τq+po0=1 max{b0,0}
1 + r!
where (8)
po0=0 = 1 pCj+ 1, b0, θ0, η0,¯
b, τq,
po0=1 =pCj+ 1, b0, θ0, η0,¯
b, τq,
b0=b0j, b, ,¯
b, τq,
d=dj, b, ,¯
b, τq,
where consumer’s default dand borrowing b0policy functions are determined in section
3.2. Assuming the consumer repays, which happens with probability 1d, and holds debt,
b > 0, bis the current-period inflow for the credit card firm. If the consumer borrows,
b0>0, then b0(qj(τq) + τc) is the current-period outflow for the credit card firm, where
qj(τq) is the price of borrowing (described below) and τcis the transaction cost. The
last term is the expected continuation value of the match discounted by the conditional
survival probability ψjand the risk-free rate r. The credit card firm’s continuation value
depends crucially on whether the consumer receives a competing offer, po0=1 , or not,
po0=0. A competing offer results in the credit card firm retrieving any debt, max{b0,0},
but losing the customer. In absence of a competing offer, the credit card firm maintains
its contract with the consumer. The payoff to the credit card firm in this case is that of
the incumbent credit card firm, ΠI.
The price of borrowing, denoted qj, depends on the borrowing premium, τqas well as
the age of the agent, j. It is specified as:
qj(τq) = ψj
1 + r+τq
,(9)
where ris the risk free interest rate and τqis the lending/borrowing premium, set to zero
for saving. This takes into account the possibility of consumer death, in which case the
banks keeps the consumer’s assets.
3.2 Consumers
Consumers are assumed to have quasi-hyperbolic preferences. Value functions with-
out a tilde denote the payoff for consumers who discount the future periods with the
hyperbolic discount factor (βδ, βδ2, β δ3, ..., βδJ). These consumers are the ones making
all decisions. In contrast, value functions with a tilde are associated with consumers
13
who discount the future only with the exponential discount factor (δ, δ2, δ3, ..., δJ). These
consumers do not make decisions. However, they are aware that decisions in the future
will be made by a hyperbolic discounter. In this sense, consumers have sophisticated
preferences.
Problem without credit card: A consumer without a credit card can either repay
or default.11 The value function to the hyperbolic consumer (βδ) before the realization
of the extreme value shocks is:
WSj, b, =EζRDmax
dS∈{0,1}dSVDj, +ζD+1dSVSj, b, +ζR.(10)
Once the taste shocks, (ζR, ζD), have realized the consumer chooses between defaulting,
dS= 1, or repaying, dS= 0. In both choices, the Vterm reflects the “modeled payoff,”
specified below, and the ζterm reflects the non-modeled component affecting the default
decision. The expectation is over extreme value shocks (ζR, ζD).12
The value function to the consumer with an exponential discount factor who takes the
default/repayment decisions of the hyperbolic consumer as given before the realization
of the extreme value shocks is:13
˜
WSj, b, =EζRDdS(j, b, ˜
VDj, +ζD+1dS(j, b, ˜
VSj, b, +ζR.
(12)
The “modeled payoff” of repayment without credit access is the payoff of a consumer
choosing consumption and saving to maximize lifetime utility subject to her budget and
11These consumers do not hold debt in equilibrium. Since revolving credit is the only modeled debt,
default at this stage will occur only due to extreme value taste shocks. In this case, default captures
bankruptcy due to expense shocks such as healthcare bills, lawsuits, and divorce.
12 The probability of default default prior to realization of (ζR, ζD) takes the following form, standard
in the discrete choice literature:
dS(j, b, ) =
expξV D(j, )
expξV D(j, )+ expξV S(j, b, ),(11)
where ξis a scaling parameter that determines the variance of the extreme value shocks.
13The closed form solution to this expectations is:
˜
WS=1
ξγE+ log eξV D+eξ V S+1
eξV D+eξV S˜
VDVDeξV D+˜
VSVSeξV S,
where γEis the Euler’s constant. The logarithm term corresponds to the closed form solution of equa-
tion 10. That is, the expected value for the hyperbolic agent. The remaining expressions correct this
expectation to take into account the payoff of the exponential agent.
14
no borrowing constraint. This is given by the following equation:
VSj, b, = max
c0,b00U(c) + βδψjE0|hpo0=0 ˜
WSj+ 1, b0,0+po0=1 ˜
WCj+ 1, b0,0,¯
b0, τ 0
qi
subject to
c+b=yj,+qj(0)b0,(13)
where
¯
b0=¯
bSj+ 1, b0, θ, η0, τ0
q=τS
qj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,
po0=0 = 1 pSj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,
po0=1 =pSj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,
where cis consumption, b0is next period debt/assets, U(c) is the utility function, and
E0|is the expectation operator over next period earnings shocks given current period
earnings shocks. In the subsequent period, with probability po0=0 the consumer does
not receive a credit offer. The continuation value in this case is ˜
WS(j+ 1, b0,0). With
probability po0=1 the consumer receives a credit offer and gains credit access. The payoff
in this case is ˜
WCj+ 1, b0,0,¯
b0, τ 0
q. This payoff, in addition to the usual state variables,
depends on credit terms (¯
b0, τ 0
q). Continuation values anticipate future discount factor
δ, but decisions being taken by the βδ consumer. Hence, they use the value functions
with tilde. Next period’s credit card limit ¯
b0, credit card borrowing premium τ0
q, and
probability of receiving an offer po0=1 depend on the idiosyncratic state of the consumer.
The credit card terms and probability of receiving an offer are determined in the credit
card firm’s problem discussed in Section 3.1.
As described above, the consumer with the exponential discount factor, who takes the
decisions of the hyperbolic consumer (c and b’) as given, has the following payoff:
˜
VSj, b, =U(c) + δψjE0|hpo0=0 ˜
WSj+ 1, b0,0+po0=1 ˜
WCj+ 1, b0,0,¯
b0, τ 0
qi
subject to
c+b=yj,+qj(0)b0,(14)
where
¯
b0=¯
bSj+ 1, b0, θ, η0, τ 0
q=τS
qj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,
po0=0 = 1 pSj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,
po0=1 =pSj+ 1, b0, θ, η0.
The “modeled payoff” of default is given by the following equation for the βδ dis-
15
counting consumer:
VDj, =Uyj,χ+βδψjE0|hpo0=0 ˜
WSj+ 1,0,0+po0=1 ˜
WCj+ 1,0,0,¯
b0, τ 0
qi,
where (15)
¯
b0=¯
bSj+ 1,0, θ, η0, τ 0
q=τS
qj+ 1,0, θ, η0,
po0=0 = 1 pSj+ 1,0, θ, η0,
po0=1 =pSj+ 1,0, θ, η0,
where χrefers to a default cost (stigma of default). The defaulting consumer just con-
sumes the earnings (c=yj,) and is not allowed to save or borrow during the default
period (b0= 0). The default cost χis incurred only during the default period. Next
period’s payoff is identical to that of a consumer without credit access. The equation for
the δdiscounting consumer is exactly the same as above without the β.
Problem with credit card: A consumer with access to revolving credit can either
repay or default. Similarly to the previous section, the payoff when repaying or defaulting
involves a modeled and a non-modeled component. The non-modeled payoff takes the
form of extreme value shocks. The value function to the βδ discounting consumer before
the realization the extreme value shocks is:
WCj, b, ,¯
b, τq=EζRDmax
dC∈{0,1}dCVDj, +ζD+1dCVCj, b, ,¯
b, τq+ζR,
(16)
and for the δdiscounting consumer it is:
˜
WCj, b, ,¯
b, τq=EζRDdC˜
VDj, +ζD+1dC˜
VCj, b, ,¯
b, τq+ζR.
(17)
This leads to a probability of default function that is analogous to equation (11). The
closed form solution of this expectation takes a similar form to the one discussed in the
footnote to equation 12. The value of default is defined in equation (15).
Current credit card holders can borrow up to limit ¯
bat prices determined by the
borrowing premium τqif they choose to repay. The “modeled payoff” of repayment for
16
the βδ discounting consumer is:
VCj, b, ,¯
b, τq= max
c0,b0¯
bnU(c) + βδψjE0|Eo0˜
WCj+ 1, b0,0,¯
b0, τ 0
qo(18)
subject to
c+b=yj,+
qjτqb0if b0>0
qj0b0if b00
,
where
¯
b0=
¯
bIj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τqif o0= 0
¯
bCj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τqif o0= 1,
τ0
q=
τqif o0= 0
τC
qj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τqif o0= 1,
po0=0 = 1 pCj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τq,
po0=1 =pCj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τq.
The payoff for the δdiscounting consumer is:
˜
VCj, b, ,¯
b, τq=U(c) + δψjE0|Eo0˜
WCj+ 1, b0,0,¯
b0, τ 0
q(19)
subject to
c+b=yj,+
qjτqb0if b0>0
qj0b0if b00
,
where
¯
b0=
¯
bIj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τqif o0= 0
¯
bCj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τqif o0= 1,
τ0
q=
τqif o0= 0
τC
qj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τqif o0= 1,
po0=0 = 1 pCj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τq,
po0=1 =pCj+ 1, b0, θ, η0,¯
b, τq.
Subsequent period payoff ˜
WCshows that the consumer maintains access to credit.
Next period’s borrowing terms depend, among other things, on whether the consumer
receives a new offer. If the consumer receives no new offers, o0= 0, the borrowing
premium remains unchanged. In this case the incumbent bank may choose the credit
limit ¯
bI. A new offer, o0= 1, leads to new limit and borrowing premium, ¯
bCand τC
q. All
these variables are specific to the submarket dictated by the consumer’s state variables.
They are determined in the credit card firm’s problem discussed in detail in Section 3.1.
Finally, the consumer incurs premium τqfor borrowing and no premium for saving. Price
qjis specified in equation 9. In Appendix A.9, we define the equilibrium.
17
3.3 Functional forms
We assume a CRRA utility function given by,
U(c) = c1σ
1σ,(20)
where σis the relative risk aversion. I assume a Cobb-Douglas matching function given
by,
M(u, v) = uv
[uζ+vζ]1
where ζis the matching elasticity, uis the mass of consumers, and vis the mass of credit
offers.
Social Security replaces a fraction λof the average earnings from ages 30-64 given
the permanent component θand the unconditional expected values of ηand γ(E(η) and
E(γ)). The Social Security function is given by,
SSθ=λθE(η)E(γ)
45
X
j=11
νj/35.(21)
4 Calibration
We borrow many parameters from the literature and calibrate the remaining parame-
ters by targeting key moments in the U.S. economy. For the pre-policy calibration, we set
Ability to Pay threshold φso that the constraint never binds. With the remaining cali-
bration parameters, we target salient moments in the 2004 U.S. economy. This captures
the period prior to the Credit CARD Act of 2009, the Great Recession, and BAPCPA
(2005). For the post-policy calibration, the Ability to Pay threshold φwill be indirectly
inferred.
Table 1 presents the parameters determined outside of the model equilibrium. The
benchmark model is one with no hyperbolic discounting (β= 1).14 However, when
analyzing welfare, we also consider the impact of the policy for consumers with hyperbolic
discounting. The risk aversion parameter is set to 2, a standard choice in the literature.
A period is assumed to be one year and the risk free rate is set to 0.0344 (Gourinchas
and Parker,2002).
Consumers of age 1 in our model correspond to 20-year-olds in the data. Maximum
life-span, denoted J, is set to 60 years. Retirement age, denoted jr, is set to 46 years.
The maximum life span corresponds to the age of 79 in the data and retirement age
corresponds to 65 in the data. Figure 3 plots the conditional survival probability ψjand
14This choice best fits the empirical credit by income distribution. In Appendix A.1, we discuss this
further.
18
the deterministic life cycle productivity νj, estimated using data from the U.S. census
and Guvenen, Ozkan, and Song (2014), respectively.
Table 1: Parameters determined outside of the model equilibrium
Parameter Description Value
General
βTemptation discount factor Accounts for credit by income 1
σRisk aversion Standard in macro literature 2
rInterest rate Gourinchas and Parker (2002) 0.0344
Earnings and expense process
σ2
θVariance permanent component
Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004)
0.244
σ2
ηVariance persistent component 0.024
σ2
γVariance transitory component 0.063
ρηPersistence 0.977
Age-specific
JMaximum age Life span, 20-79 60
jrRetirement age Retire at 65 46
ψjConditional survival probability U.S. census Figure 3
νjLife cycle productivity Guvenen, Ozkan, and Song (2014)Figure 3
Credit card market
ζMatching elasticity Herkenhoff (2019) 0.370
τcTransaction cost Agarwal et al. (2015) 0.034
The idiosyncratic productivity process includes permanent, persistent, and transitory
components. The idiosyncratic persistent productivity ηis assumed to follow a log AR(1)
process given by log η0=ρηlog η+υ0. The innovations for all three processes are assumed
to be iid normal with mean zero and variances given by σ2
θ,σ2
η, and σ2
γ, respectively. This
process is parameterized using estimates from Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004)
and discretized using Tauchen (1986). We use 3, 13, and 7 grid points for the permanent,
persistent, and transitory components, respectively.
The matching elasticity for the credit card market ζis set to 0.37, following Herkenhoff
(2019) and Braxton, Herkenhoff, and Phillips (2019). The transaction cost τcis set to
0.034, a direct estimate from the data (Agarwal et al.,2015).
The five remaining pre-policy parameters are cost of credit offer κ, exponential dis-
count factor δ, stigma χ, scaling parameter for extreme value shocks ξ, and Social Security
replacement rate λ. They are calibrated jointly to match five targets in the year 2004
presented in Table 2. The cost of a credit offer is calibrated to match the population
with credit cards in 2004 (71.58 percent). The exponential factor is calibrated to match
the population with interest assessed credit card debt in 2004 (30.21 percent).15 Stigma
15The difference between the population with credit cards and the population with credit card debt is
19
Figure 3: Conditional survival probability and life cycle productivity
(a) Conditional survival probability (b) Life cycle productivity
is calibrated to match the annual Chapter 7 bankruptcy rate in 2004 (0.38 percent of
total population). Scaling parameter ξis calibrated so that the fraction of “taste shocks”
defaults matches the fraction of defaults due to health care bills, divorce, and lawsuits
(44.81 percent). “Taste shocks” defaults are ones for which the Bellman value of repay-
ment is greater than the Bellman value of default (false positives). Finally, Social Security
replacement rate is calibrated to match average Social Security to disposable income per
capita (29.57 percent).
Table 2: Parameters determined jointly in equilibrium
Parameter Value Target Data Model
Pre Ability to Pay Year = 2004
κCost of offer 0.002 Population with CC 71.58 71.47
δSelf-control discount factor 0.867 Population with CC debt 30.21 30.44
χStigma 2.786 Default rate 0.38 0.38
ξScaling parameter 5.814 Defaults: healthcare, divorce, lawsuits 44.81 44.93
λSocial Security replacement rate 0.238 Social Security to income pc 29.57 29.56
Post Ability to Pay Year = 2016
φAbility to pay 0.308 Average limit to income pc (2016/2004) 70.71 70.92
The only post-policy parameter is the Ability to Pay threshold φ. We calibrate it
to match the relative decline in the (cross-sectional) average credit card limits between
2004 and 2016. By 2016, the average credit card limit to disposable income per capita
decreased to 70.71 percent of its 2004 level. Targeting this decline, the calibrated value
of φis 0.308. This implies that the credit card limit at issuance or limit increase must
be less 30.8 percent of the individual’s expected earnings in our post-policy model.16
that the latter only includes consumers with a positive outstanding balance on their credit card.
16We calibrate the final steady state to match the decline in credit limits because calibrating the
20
5 Ability to Pay (ATP)
In this section, we first study the benchmark model without the Ability to Pay provi-
sion. Next, we introduce the Ability to Pay provision to the benchmark model. Finally,
we analyze implications of the policy for consumer welfare.
5.1 Pre-ATP model
We begin our analysis of the pre-ATP calibration by presenting policy functions of
some credit card firms. Figure 4plots an example of the solution to the lender’s problem
by persistent and permanent earnings for a consumer with no assets and no credit card.
The left panel of Figure 4shows that consumers with high permanent or persistent
earnings receive higher credit limits. The lender takes into account consumers’ default
risk. Higher income consumers can maintain higher debt levels while keeping the default
probability low. Therefore, the lender offers higher income consumers higher credit limits.
Figure 4: Example solution to lender’s problem pre-ATP
(a) Credit card limit (b) Credit card interest rate (c) Probability of credit card offer
Notes: Figure 4plots an example of the solution to the lender’s problem by persistent and permanent earnings for a
consumer with no assets and no credit card. The left panel plots the credit card limits as a percent of disposable income
per capita. The middle plots credit card interest rates in percent. The right panel plots probabilities of credit access in
percent. The x-axis is persistent earnings where the unit is percentile of persistent earnings. The red lines refer to
consumers with a high permanent component earnings. The blue lines refer to consumers with a low permanent
component of earnings.
The middle panel of Figure 4shows that consumers with low permanent earnings
receive a credit card offer with a higher interest rate. The reasoning behind the higher
interest rate is twofold. First, consumers with low permanent earnings are more likely
to default. Therefore, just to break even lenders must charge a higher interest rate.
Second, as studied in Raveendranathan (2020), lenders charge a higher premium because
model along the transition path is computationally very demanding. In Appendix A.3, we show that the
transition converges quickly. Hence, our estimate for φis not sensitive to calibrating to the final steady
state. When we analyze welfare, we take transition dynamics into account.
21
of market power. Analyzing the implications across persistent earnings, we see that lower
persistent earnings also lead to higher interest rates, except at the very top of the earnings
distribution.
The right panel of Figure 4shows that consumers with low permanent earnings are
less likely to receive a credit offer. This is due to higher default risk and scale effects
caused by lower average levels of borrowing. Consumers with lower persistent earnings
have stronger borrowing incentives; however, they are more likely to default. Hence,
they receive fewer credit offers. Consumers at the very top of the persistent earnings
distribution have low incentives to borrow. Hence, they too receive fewer credit offers.
Figure 5: Credit statistics by income quintile: model (non-targeted) vs data (2004)
(a) Credit (b) Credit card limit
(c) Credit card interest rate (d) Population with credit cards
Notes: Figure 5plots cross-sectional credit statistics by income quintile. The top left panel plots average credit per
consumer normalized by disposable income per capita. The top right panel plots average credit card limit per debtor
normalized by disposable income per capita. The bottom left panel plots average credit card interest rate per debtor in
percent. The bottom right panel plots the population with credit cards in percent.
We next turn to analyzing the stationary equilibrium outcomes. Figure 5shows that
the benchmark model accounts for 2004 credit statistics by income. We divide consumers
22
into income quintiles and plot credit, credit card limits, credit card interest rates, and the
population with credit cards in each quintile. The model captures the fact that consumers
with higher income hold higher levels of outstanding credit, receive higher credit limits,
lower interest rates, and are more likely to hold a credit card. The result that high income
consumers hold more credit hinges in the permanent earnings component. In Appendix
A.2, we show that without the permanent component of earnings, the model fails to
account for credit among high income consumers.17
Figure 6: Credit statistics by age: model (non-targeted) vs data (2004)
(a) Credit (b) Credit card limit
(c) Credit card interest rate (d) Population with credit cards
Notes: Figure 6plots cross-sectional credit statistics by age. The top left panel plots average credit per consumer
normalized by disposable income per capita. The top right panel plots average credit card limit per debtor normalized by
disposable income per capita. The bottom left panel plots average credit card interest rate per debtor in percent. The
bottom right panel plots the population with credit cards in percent.
Figure 6shows that the benchmark model also accounts for 2004 levels of credit
statistics by age. The model captures the hump-shaped profile of credit, increasing credit
limits, flat credit card interest rates, and increasing population with credit cards over the
17The model also accounts for for credit card utilization (credit/limit) by income (Appendix A.5).
23
life cycle. The hump shaped profile of credit is explained by increasing life cycle earnings,
impatience (low δ), and search frictions in borrowing. Furthermore, lenders being able to
increase limits over time is key in accounting for increasing limits in early stages of the
life cycle. Finally, commitment to borrowing premiums explains the flat interest rates
over the life cycle. Overall, the model does well in accounting for non-targeted pre-ATP
credit statistics by income and age.18
5.2 Post-ATP model
In this section, we analyze the benchmark model with the ATP provision. Recall that
we introduce ATP as a constraint on the lenders’ problem to capture modifications issuers
made to their underwriting tests for compliance (discussed in more detail in Section 2).
The constraint in our model requires that credit limit to expected earnings at issuance or
limit increase must be weakly less than the ATP threshold parameter φ. First, we analyze
the solution to the lender’s problem. Second, we show that the model accounts for changes
in credit statistics by income and age and changes in aggregate credit statistics.
Figure 7: Example of incumbent lender’s credit card limits pre and post-ATP
Notes: Figure 7plots an example of the solution to the incumbent lender’s problem pre and post Ability to Pay by
persistent and permanent earnings. The credit card limits are presented as a percent of disposable income per capita.
The x-axis is persistent earnings where the unit is percentile of persistent earnings. The red lines refer to consumers with
a high permanent component earnings. The blue lines refer to consumers with a low permanent component of earnings.
The solid lines refer to the solution before Ability to Pay. The dashed lines refers to the solution after Ability to Pay.
Our model suggests that the ATP provision mostly impacted higher earnings con-
sumers. Figure 7plots the solution to the incumbent lender’s problem pre-ATP and
post-ATP for two permanent earnings values, with persistent earnings values on the x-
axis. It shows that the limits decrease especially for consumers with high permanent
18The model also accounts for life cycle profiles of default rates and debtors (Appendix A.7).The model
falls short only in accounting for the later stages of the life cycle, in particular, credit limits. Given that
credit levels are low later in the life cycle, we don’t view this shortcoming as a major concern.
24
earnings. The economic intuition is as follows. ATP imposes a restriction by requiring
the lender to evaluate consumers’ ability to pay assuming full utilization of the credit
limit. This evaluation is required even if full utilization is less likely, which is the case for
high income consumers. Hence, lenders are forced to issue lower limits for these consumers
than they would have otherwise. In contrast, low earnings consumers regularly borrow
to their credit limit. As a result, lenders were issuing tighter limits to such consumers
even before ATP taking into account the higher likelihood of full utilization.
ATP not only leads to lower limits at issuance, but also fewer limit increases. For
example, the fraction of accounts that experienced a limit increase in the pre-ATP bench-
mark model was 11 percent. After ATP, the fraction decreases to 8 percent. Hence, the
model is consistent with the fact that ATP has led to fewer limit increases (discussed in
Section 2).
In Figure 8, we show that the benchmark model accounts for changes in credit statis-
tics by income. The left panel of Figure 8plots the change in average credit by income
quintile. The model captures the fact that the decrease in credit is concentrated among
middle-high income quintiles. The right panel plots the change in average credit card
limit by income quintile. Our mechanism suggests that higher earning individuals see a
larger limit decline due to the policy. This is also true in the data.
Figure 8: Changes in credit statistics by income quintile: model (non-targeted) vs data
(2004-2016)
(a) Credit (b) Credit card limit
Notes: Figure 8plots changes in cross-sectional credit statistics by income quintile. The left panel plots the percentage
point change in average credit per consumer to disposable income per capita. The right panel plots the percentage point
change in average credit card limit per debtor to disposable income per capita.
In Figure 9, we show that the benchmark model accounts for changes in credit statis-
tics by age. The left panel of Figure 9plots the change in average credit by age. The
right panel plots the change in average credit card limit by age. The model accounts for
25
the decrease concentrated among young-middle age consumers.
Figure 9: Changes in credit statistics by age: model (non-targeted) vs data (2004-2016)
(a) Credit (b) Credit card limit
Notes: Figure 9plots changes in cross-sectional credit statistics by age. The left panel plots the percentage point change
in average credit per consumer to disposable income per capita. The right panel plots the percentage point change in
average credit card limit per debtor to disposable income per capita.
Table 3 compares levels and changes in aggregate statistics for the credit card mar-
ket between the model and data pre-ATP and post-ATP. The model performs well in
accounting for levels and changes in non-targeted credit statistics before and after ATP.
The policy change in the model quantitatively accounts for the decline in credit (2.40
p.p. in model and 2.31 p.p. in data). Annual bankruptcies to population decrease by
0.12 p.p. in the model compared to 0.23 p.p. in the data. Charge-off rate decreases by
0.93 p.p. in the model compared to 2.14 p.p. in the data. Hence, the model accounts for
lower levels of credit and default risk observed in the data.
Although magnitudes are small, the model also accounts for changes in the population
with credit and the population with credit cards. The population with credit decreases
by 3.10 p.p. in the model compared to 1.39 p.p. in the data. The population with credit
cards decreases by 0.64 p.p. in the model compared to 0.22 p.p. in the data. Finally,
the average spread (Average CC interest - Risk free) decreases by 0.19 p.p. in the model
compared to an increase of 0.82 p.p. in the data. Although the spread in the model
moves in the opposite direction of the one in the data, the magnitudes are small relative
to their levels. That is, the average spreads are more than 10 percentage points in the
model and data. To summarize, our benchmark model accounts for levels and changes in
credit statistics by income and age and aggregate credit statistics.
26
Table 3: Ability to Pay: model vs data
Variable Model Data Model Data Model Data
pre-ATP 2004 post-ATP 2016 Change
(unit=percent) (unit=percent) (unit=p.p.)
Revolving credit to disp. inc. 6.36 7.93 3.96 5.62 -2.40 -2.31
Bankruptcies to population 0.38 0.38 0.27 0.15 -0.12 -0.23
Avg. CC limit to disp. inc. pc 40.45 53.84 28.69 38.15 -11.76 -15.70
Average CC interest - Risk free 11.17 11.48 10.97 12.30 -0.19 0.82
Charge-off rate 3.21 5.66 2.28 3.51 -0.93 -2.14
Population with credit 30.44 30.21 27.34 28.81 -3.10 -1.39
Population with credit cards 71.92 71.58 71.28 71.35 -0.64 -0.22
5.3 Welfare implications of ATP
In this section, we quantify the welfare implications of Ability to Pay for consumers
by income and age. We compute welfare implications for the cohort of consumers in
the pre-ATP stationary equilibrium taking transition dynamics into consideration. To
measure welfare, we compute one-time equivalent transfers using the wealth equivalent
variation (WEV). WEV is the minimum one-time transfer a consumer requires in the
economy without ATP to be at least as well off as they would have been in the economy
with ATP. For a consumer with a credit card, WEV is computed as follows:
min
W EV nW E V o
subject to
WC
No ATP(j, b W E V, ,¯
b, τq)WC
ATP(j, b, ,¯
b, τq)
bW EV ¯
b.
where WC
No ATP(j, b W E V, ,¯
b, τq) is the consumer’s payoff in the benchmark economy
without ATP if the transfer is equal to W E V and WC
ATP(j, b, ,¯
b, τq) is the consumer’s
payoff in the economy with ATP. WEV is computed analogously for a consumer without a
credit card. A positive WEV implies that the consumer is better off in the economy with
ATP compared to the economy without ATP. There are two benefits of using this measure
of welfare. First, this measure allows for aggregation across heterogeneous consumers.
Second, it takes into account that consumers re-optimize their decisions given the one-
time transfer. Hence, if total transfers are positive, there exist lump sum transfers such
that every consumer is weakly better off.
In the left panel of Figure 10, we plot the average transfers by income quintile resulting
from ATP in the benchmark model (red bars). The policy leads to ubiquitous welfare
losses. The consumers most hurt by ATP are those in the middle-high income quintile.
Their losses are equivalent to a onetime transfer worth 0.3-0.4 percent of disposable
27
income per capita. This is consistent with implications discussed above where middle-
high income consumers were the most affected by ATP in terms of credit. The right
panel of Figure 10 plots average transfers by age resulting from ATP (red line). It shows
that young-middle age consumers are hurt the most. The losses for some age groups are
almost 0.7 percent of disposable income per capita.
If we aggregate the losses across all consumers, they are equal to 0.25 percent of total
disposable income. To understand the magnitude of these losses, we compute the welfare
losses of shutting down the credit card market.To shutdown the credit card market, we
consider the case where φ= 0. This would imply that there are no new credit card
issuances or limit increases. However, current card holders will be able to keep their
accounts with the given terms until default or death. If we shutdown the credit card
market, the total welfare losses are 0.47 percent of total disposable income. Therefore,
the losses from ATP are equivalent to 53 percent of losses of entirely shutting down the
credit card market.
Figure 10: Welfare implications of Ability to Pay in benchmark model
(a) One time transfers by income quintile (b) One time transfers by age
Notes: Figure 10 plots welfare implications of introducing Ability to Pay by income quintile (left) and age (right). Red
bars/lines refer to the benchmark model. Blue bars/lines refers to the model without limit increases or
on-the-credit-search re-calibrated to match the set of moments presented in Table 1. Positive transfers indicate gains and
negative transfers indicate losses. The one-time equivalent transfers are reported as a percent of disposable income per
capita.
As mentioned above, two novel ingredients are key in accounting for the impact of
the policy on welfare. First, lenders can increase the credit limit over time. Without this
feature, the model does not capture the reduction in frequency of limit increases due to
Ability to Pay. Second, lenders can send offers to consumers who already have a credit
card (on-the-credit search). Without this feature, the model misses the fact that Ability
to Pay impacts the current card holder when poached by a new lender. We quantify the
importance of these two features by re-calibrating the model without them to match the
28
set of moments in Table 2. Without these two features the losses due to the policy change
are almost zero (blue bars in the left panel and blue lines in the right panel of Figure 10).
Having quantified the welfare losses resulting from ATP, we decompose the sources
in Figure 11. In particular, we focus on the level and volatility of consumption and the
probability of default. We first depict the transition dynamics in the ratio of average
consumption in the model with ATP to the same variable in the model without ATP.
The left panel of Figure 11 plots this statistic for cohorts aged 20 and 30 when ATP comes
into effect. The middle panel plots the analogous ratio for the coefficient of variation of
consumption. Finally, the right panel is the analogous plot for the difference in default
rates. The 20-year old cohort is worse off because of lower average consumption and
higher volatility of consumption in the initial years of the transition. A similar pattern
emerges for the the 30-year old cohort. However, in addition to these losses, their default
rate also increases along the transition path, leading to additional losses. Higher default
rates are explained by the fact that they were heavily indebted in anticipation of credit
limit increases. However, due to ATP, these anticipated limit increases never manifested.
Figure 11: Decomposing welfare losses in the benchmark model by age cohorts
(a) Avg. consump. (post/pre) (b) Consump. volatility (post/pre) (c) Default rate (post-pre)
Notes: Figure 11 decomposes sources of welfare losses in the benchmark model for two cohorts of consumers: consumers
who are 20 years old and 30 years old at the time of the policy change (period 0). The left panel plots average
consumption in the model with ATP divided by average consumption for the same cohort of consumers if there were no
ATP. The middle panel plots the analogous ratio for the coefficient of variation of consumption. The right panel plots the
difference between the default rates in the model with ATP and the model without ATP. The x-axes refer to the number
of periods since the time of the policy change.
To summarize Ability to Pay leads to welfare losses in the benchmark model. Borrow-
ing in this model was a result of idiosyncratic earnings risk, increasing life cycle earnings
profile, and impatience due to a low exponential discount factor (δ). In Appendix A.6,
we show that consumers are worse off even if φtakes different values other than the cal-
ibrated one (Figure 27). However, the goal of ATP was consumer protection. Therefore,
we next investigate a framework where ATP may lead to welfare gains by disciplining
consumers’ from over borrowing. In particular, we allow for time inconsistent preferences
29
by introducing quasi-hyperbolic discounting.
For our analysis, we will assume that the consumers are sophisticated. That is, they
are aware that their preferences are time inconsistent. Nakajima (2017), who studies
consumer credit with quasi-hyperbolic discounting, uses a value of 0.7 for βbased on a
paper by Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman (2007). Hence, we consider implications for
values of βbetween 0.7 and 1.
We re-calibrate the benchmark model to match the set of target moments in Table 2
for every β. Figure 12 plots the total welfare implications. Even though the magnitudes
are smaller, Ability to Pay still leads to losses even with a hyperbolic discount factor as
low as β= 0.7.19 In Appendix A.6, we show that the policy leads to welfare losses for
other values of φ. Summarizing the main takeaway, the ATP provision leads to overall
welfare losses with or without time hyperbolic discounting.
Figure 12: Welfare implications of Ability to Pay with quasi-hyperbolic discounting
Notes: Figure 12 plots welfare implications of introducing Ability to Pay. For each β, the model was re-calibrated.
Positive transfers indicate average gains and negative transfers indicate average losses. The one-time equivalent transfers
are reported as a percent of total disposable income.
6 Counterfactual interest rate cap
We have shown that, through the lens of our model, ATP leads to welfare losses.
ATP is a policy that restricts quantities. An alternative, debated by policy makers, was
a restriction on prices through an interest rate cap. In this section, we use our model
to analyze the welfare implications of an interest rate cap. Lenders in our model have
market power. This market power comes from the search friction in the credit card
market and the fact that lenders pick the borrowing premium after a match. As a result,
19Even a discount factor of β= 0.6 leads to welfare losses.
30
an interest rate cap has the potential of increasing consumer welfare by limiting lenders’
market power.
In our analysis, we impose a cap on the borrowing premium. Therefore, the cap places
a restriction on the interest margin over the risk-free rate (the spread). To be consistent
with the policy analysis from the previous section, we require that the cap applies only
for new credit card issuances. That is, current accounts are not affected.
Figure 13: Trade offs of an interest rate cap
(a) Average spread (b) Population with credit cards (c) Average credit card limit
Notes: Figure 13 plots the trade offs of an interest rate cap. The x-axis refers to the maximum spread over the risk free
rate. For example, a cap = 10 implies that the maximum spread over the risk-free rate is 10 percentage points. The top
left panel plots the (cross-sectional) average spread per debtor. The top right panel plots the percent of population with
credit cards. The bottom panel plots the (cross-sectional) average credit card limit per debtor.
We start by illustrating the trade-offs of a cap in our model. We focus on the effect of
the cap on credit card interest rates, credit card limits, and probabilities of credit offers.
Figure 13 illustrates the average values of these variables in our model for different cap
levels. A rate cap of 10 implies that the maximum spread over the risk-free savings interest
rate is 10 percentage points. As we go from right to left, the cap becomes tighter. As the
cap becomes tighter, the left panel of Figure 13 shows that the spread decreases. This is
the main benefit of the cap. The middle panel of Figure 13 shows that the population
with credit cards decreases with a tighter cap. Less profits for the credit card firms lead
to fewer credit offers. Lower credit access is one of the costs of the cap. The right panel
of Figure 13 plots the average limit as a function of the cap. The resulting limit is not
monotone. As the cap becomes tighter, initially the limit increases. As the cap restricts
prices, lenders increase the limit to increase lending. However, as the cap becomes even
tighter, the limit decreases. With a very tight cap, lenders are no longer compensated for
default risk and they respond by tightening the limit. Hence, depending on the tightness
of the cap, the credit limits may increase or decrease.
Figure 14 plots the total welfare gains (losses) for different levels of a rate cap in
the benchmark model. The welfare implications are not monotone. As the cap becomes
31
Figure 14: Total welfare gains (losses) of an interest rate cap in benchmark model
tighter (right to left), consumers benefit. However, when the cap becomes too tight,
consumers are hurt. The interest rate cap over the risk-free rate that maximizes total
welfare is 7.41 percentage points. It leads to gains equivalent to a one-time transfer worth
0.12 percent of total disposable income. Recall that the losses of shutting down the credit
card market were worth 0.47 percent of total disposable income. Hence, the gains from
the optimal rate cap are worth 25 percent of losses consumers would face if we were to
shutdown the credit card market.
Figure 15: Welfare implications of an interest rate cap in benchmark model
(a) One time transfers by income quintile (b) One time transfers by age
Figure 15 plots the welfare implications by income and age at the optimal rate cap.
With respect to income, although low income consumers pay higher interest rates, the
high income consumers benefit the most. This is because high income consumers have
lower credit card utilization rates (refer to Appendix A.5 for utilization rates by income).
Hence, they can respond to lower interest rates by substantially increasing their borrowing
32
compared to low income consumers. With respect to age, young consumers benefit the
most.
Figure 16 plots the optimal rate cap (left panel) and total welfare gains (right panel) in
the re-calibrated models with quasi-hyperbolic discounting. The optimal rate cap hardly
changes for βbetween 0.8 and 1. For higher levels of hyperbolic discounting (β=.7),
the optimal cap is lower. The right panel shows that the total welfare gains are almost
the same across these models. Hence, an interest rate cap delivers welfare gains with and
without hyperbolic discounting consumers.
Figure 16: Total welfare gains of an interest rate cap with quasi-hyperbolic discounting
(a) Optimal cap over risk-free rate (b) Total welfare gains
7 Ruling out alternative explanations
The fall in revolving credit coincided with several regulatory changes and the Great
Recession in the U.S. economy. In this section, we rule out these alternative explanations.
We also justify why we chose the model with lender commitment to borrowing premiums
as the benchmark economy.
7.1 Restrictions on credit card interest rate increases
The CARD Act of 2009 prohibited credit card issuers from increasing interest rates on
existing balances, with some exceptions.20 To analyze the implications of these restric-
tions, we perform the following numerical experiment. We modify the benchmark model
by allowing lenders to choose between offering credit cards with and without commit-
ment to borrowing premiums when matched with a consumer. For the contract without
20Exceptions include increases due to a variable indexed interest rate, end of a promotional rate period,
and late payments.
33
commitment, the incumbent lender chooses both the borrowing premium and the limit
at the beginning of every period. The contract with commitment is the same as in the
benchmark economy. In both cases, we maintain that the incumbent lender could only
weakly increase the limit. We re-calibrate this model to match the set of target moments
from Table 2. In the post-policy economy lenders are forced to choose the contract with
commitment to the interest rate. This restriction mimics the CARD Act of 2009 provision
that limits interest rate hikes.
The left panel of Figure 17 plots average credit by income quintile for the pre-policy
model. In this case, the model does not even qualitatively account for credit by income.
This is the main reason we chose the benchmark model to be the one with commitment
to borrowing premiums.
The right panel of Figure 17 plots the change in average credit by income quintile after
imposing commitment for interest rates. In this case, the model leads to lower credit.
However, the decrease is concentrated among low income consumers, which is at odds
with the data. Therefore, we conclude that the restriction on interest rate increases did
not play a significant role in driving the fall in revolving credit.21
Figure 17: Credit by income quintile (pre-policy level and post-policy change)
(a) Credit level (pre-policy) (b) Credit change (post-policy)
The remainder of this section discusses the economic intuition for the results. The
21This numerical experiment complements related work by Mateos-Planas and R´ıos-Rull (2013), who
compare a model where the lender commits to the interest rate with one where the lender does not
commit to interest rates. In their exercise, the level of credit does not change. There are three key
differences between their model and ours. First we allow the lender to issue both contracts with and
without commitment to borrowing premiums in the pre-policy model. They allow the lender to issue only
contracts without commitment in the pre-policy model. Second we consider a richer earnings process (13
grid points for the persistent component, 7 grid points for the transitory component, and 3 grid points
for the permanent component) whereas they consider an earnings process with two grid points. Third,
in our model, the lender picks the terms of the contract in all periods. In their model, the consumer
picks the term of the contract at issuance and the lender picks the terms of the contract in subsequent
periods.
34
left panel of Figure 18 plots the percent of commitment and no commitment credit card
contracts by income quintile. For consumers with higher income levels, lenders prefer to
offer credit cards with commitment to the interest rate. Furthermore, for most accounts
(more than 80 percent), lenders prefer to commit to the interest rate.
The right panel of Figure 18 illustrates the key mechanism. We plot the interest
rate chosen by the incumbent lender for any given value of current debt for two values
of persistent earnings. The lender charges a higher interest rate for heavily indebted
consumers with high persistent earnings. This is because a consumer with high earnings
is more likely to repay. The potential of an interest rate hike prevents high earning
consumers from borrowing. Hence, for most high income consumers, the lender is better
off committing to the interest rate.
The right panel of Figure 18 also shows that the lender charges heavily indebted low
earnings consumers a lower interest rate. This is because a consumer with low earnings is
more likely to default. Lowering the interest rate allows the lender to reduce default risk.
Hence, for some low income consumers, the lender is better off without commitment.
Consequently, a policy that imposes commitment eliminates contracts without commit-
ment, which are concentrated among low income consumers. This leads to a fall in credit
among low income consumers.
Figure 18: Credit card contracts and interest rates without commitment
(a) Credit card contracts by income (b) Credit card interest rate without commitment
7.2 Persistent effects of the Great Recession
The Great Recession of 2007 led to the largest and most persistent drop in output in
post World War II U.S. economy (de-trended output per working age person decreased by
7.5 percent). In our benchmark model, we analyze a transition with a permanent drop in
average earnings of 7.5 percent. Figure 19 plots the transition path for credit to income
35
and average credit to disposable income per capita. We see that both credit and credit
card limits (normalized by income) increase in the short run. This is because income falls
more than credit. The changes after 10 years are negligible. Hence, the persistent effects
of the Great Recession fail to account for the fall in credit and credit limits in the last
decade.
Figure 19: Great Recession: 7.5 percent permanent drop in earnings
(a) Total outstanding revolving credit (b) (Cross-sectional) average credit card limit
7.3 Changes in the cost of bankruptcy
The BAPCPA (2005) made filing for bankruptcy more stringent. For example, it pre-
vents households above median income from filing for bankruptcy. A consequence of this
stringency is increased administrative burden, which has led to higher bankruptcy fees
(Albanesi and Nosal ,2020). In this section, we show that increased cost of bankruptcy
captured through highesr stigma (χ) fails to account for the fall in revolving credit and
credit limits.
Figure 20 plots comparative statics with respect to stigma for total revolving credit,
average credit limits, and charge-off rate. It shows that a rise in the cost of bankruptcy,
which increases commitment to repay by the consumer, leads to higher revolving credit
and credit limits. Hence, the implications of a rise in the cost of bankruptcy cannot even
qualitatively account for observed empirical patterns in the last decade. Also note that
a decrease in the cost of bankruptcy decreases credit and credit limits as observed in the
data. However, it leads to a higher charge-off rate, which is at odds with the data.
36
Figure 20: Comparative statics with respect to stigma (χ)
(a) Credit (b) Credit card limit (c) Charge-off rate
8 Conclusion
Revolving credit to disposable income declined drastically in the last decade. By 2019
it had decreased to 70 percent of its 2008 level. This drastic decline came on the heels
of decades of growth. In this paper, we argued that the Ability to Pay provision of the
Credit CARD Act of 2009 accounts for this decline. This provision requires lenders to
evaluate consumers’ ability to make minimum payments at the credit limit when issuing
credit cards or increasing credit limits.
We extended a model of revolving credit lines with a search friction in the credit card
market to analyze this policy. Novel features in our model are credit limit increases and
on-the-credit-search. Calibrating the model to target the observed decline in average
credit limits during this time period, we accounted for non-targeted levels and changes
in credit statistics by income and age.
The intention of the provision was to protect consumers. Instead, the model suggests
that it leads to a ubiquitous welfare loss. This is especially true for middle-high income
consumers and young-middle age consumers. Furthermore, we incorporated consumers
with time inconsistent preferences who could benefit from tighter credit constraints. We
found that even such agents cannot benefit from a constraint on credit limits like the one
imposed by the Ability to Pay provision.
Having shown that the Ability to Pay provision has no scope for welfare improvement,
we used our model to study an alternative policy considered by policymakers: an interest
rate cap. We found that such a price restriction improves welfare through its impact on
the market power of credit card issuers.
Finally, we ruled out concurrent events and policy changes that took place in the
late 2000s such as controls on interest rate hikes imposed by the Credit CARD Act, the
37
Great Recession of 2007, and increased cost of bankruptcy due to the BAPCPA (2005)
as potential causes for the decline in revolving credit.
References
Agarwal, S., S. Chomsisengphet, N. Mahoney, and J. Stroebel (2015), ”Regulating con-
sumer financial products: evidence from credit cards,” The Quarterly Journal of Eco-
nomics, 130(1), 111-164.
Albanesi, S. and J. Nosal (2020), ”Insolvency after the 2005 bankruptcy reform,” Working
paper.
Athreya, K. (2001), ”The growth of unsecured credit: Are we better off?” Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 87(3), 11-33.
Athreya, K. (2004), ”Shame as it ever was: Stigma and personal bankruptcy,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 90(2), 1-19.
Athreya, K. (2005), ”Equilibrium models of personal bankruptcy: A survey,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 91(2), 73-98.
Athreya, K., J. M. S´anchez, X. S. Tam, and E. R. Young (2014), ”Labor market upheaval,
default regulations, and consumer debt,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 18(1), 32-52.
Athreya, K., J. M. S´anchez, X. S. Tam, and E. R. Young (2018), ”Bankruptcy and
delinquency in a model of unsecured debt,” International Economic Review, 59(2):
593-623.
Athreya, K., X. S. Tam, and E. R. Young (2012), ”A quantitative theory of information
and unsecured credit,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(3), 153-183.
Auclert, A. and K. Mitman (2018), ”Bankruptcy and aggregate demand,” Working paper.
Ausubel, L. M. (1991), ”The failure of competition in the credit card market,” American
Economic Review, 81(1), 50-81.
Braxton, J. C., K. Herkenhoff, and G. Phillips (2018), ”Can the unemployed borrow?
Implications for public insurance,” Working paper.
Bethune, Z. (2015), ”Consumer credit, unemployment, and aggregate labor market dy-
namics”, Working paper.
Bethune, Z., G. Rocheteau, and P. Rupert (2015), ”Aggregate unemployment and house-
hold unsecured credit”, Review of Economics Dynamics, 18(1), 77-100.
38
Chatterjee, S., D. Corbae, M. Nakajima, and J. R´ıos-Rull (2007), ”A quantitative theory
of unsecured consumer credit with a risk of default,” Econometrica, 75(6), 1525-1589.
Chatterjee, S. and B. Eyigungor (2016), ”Continuous Markov equilibria with quasi-
geometric discounting,” Journal of Economic Theory, 163, 467-494.
Chatterjee, S., D. Corbae, K. P. Dempsey, and J. R´ıos-Rull (2016), ”A theory of credit
scoring and the competitive pricing of default risk,” Working paper.
Cohen-Cole, E., B. Duygan-Bump, and J. Montoriol-Garriga (2009), ”Forgive and for-
get: Who gets credit after bankruptcy and why?,” Journal of Banking and Finance,
forthcoming.
Corbae, D. and A. Glover (2018), ”Employer credit checks: Poverty traps versus matching
efficiency,” Working paper.
Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (2015), ”Consumer credit market report,” Report.
Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (2017), ”Consumer credit market report,” Report.
Drozd, L. A. and M. Kowalik (2019), ”Credit cards and the Great Recession: The collapse
of teasers,” Working paper.
Drozd, L. A. and J. B. Nosal (2008), ”Competing for customers: A search model of the
market for unsecured credit,” Working paper.
Drozd, L. A. and R. Serrano-Padial (2013), ”On prepayment and rollover risk in the U.S.
credit card market,” Working paper.
Drozd, L. A. and R. Serrano-Padial (2017), ”Modeling the revolving revolution: the debt
collection channel,” American Economic Review, 107(3), 897-930.
Dynan, K., K. Johnson, and K. Pence (2003), ”Recent changes to a measure of U.S.
household debt service,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, October, 417-26.
Eaton, J. and M. Gersovitz (1981), ”Debt with potential repudiation: Theoretical and
empirical analysis,” Review of Economic Studies, 48(2), 289-309.
Exler, F., I. Livshits, J. MacGee, and M. Tertilt (2018), ”Consumer credit with over-
optimistic borrowers,” Working paper.
Exler, F. and M. Tertilt (2020), ”Consumer debt and default: A Macroeconomic perspec-
tive,” Discussion paper.
Fay, S., E. Hurst, and M. J. White (2002), ”The household bankruptcy decision,” Amer-
ican Economic Review, 92(3), 706-718.
39
Fisher, J. (2017), ”Who files for personal bankruptcy in the United States?” Working
paper.
Galenianos, M. and J. B. Nosal (2016), ”Segmented markets and unsecured credit,”
Working paper.
Gourinchas, P. and J. A. Parker (2002), ”Consumption over the Life Cycle,” Economet-
rica, 70(1), 47-89.
Grodzicki, D (2019),”The Evolution of Competition in the Credit Card Market,” Working
paper.
Gross, D. B. and N. S. Souleles (2002),”An empirical analysis of personal bankruptcy
and delinquency,” Review of Financial Studies, 15(1), 319-347.
Guvenen, F., S. Ozkan, and J. Song (2014), ”The nature of countercyclical income risk,”
Journal of Political Economy, 122(5), 621-660.
Jagtiani, J. A. and W. Li (2015), ”Credit access and credit performance after consumer
bankruptcy filing: New evidence,” American Bankruptcy Law Journal, 89(2), 327-362.
Hatchondo, J., and L. Martinez (2017), ”Credit risk without commitment,” Working
paper.
Herkenhoff, K. (2019), ”The impact of consumer credit access on unemployment,” Review
of Economic Studies, 86(6), 2605-2642.
Herkenhoff, K., and G. Raveendranathan (2019), ”Who Bears the Welfare Costs of
Monopoly? The Case of the Credit Card Industry,” Working paper.
Krueger, D. and A. Ludwig (2016), ”On the optimal provision of social insurance: Pro-
gressive taxation versus education subsidies in general equilibrium,” Journal of Mone-
tary Economics, 77, 72-98.
Laibson, D., A. Repetto, and J. Tobacman (2007), ”Estimating discount functions with
consumption choices over the life cycle,” NBER working paper.
Livshits, I., J. MacGee, and M. Tertilt (2007), ”Consumer bankruptcy: A fresh Start,”
The American Economic Review, 97(1), 402-418.
Livshits, I., J. MacGee, and M. Tertilt (2010), ”Accounting for the rise in consumer
bankruptcies,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(2), 165-193.
Livshits, I., J. MacGee, and M. Tertilt (2016), ”The democratization of credit and the
rise in consumer bankruptcies,” Review of Economics Studies, 83(4), 1673-1710.
40
Mateos-Planas, X. and G. Seccia (2006), ”Welfare implications of endogenous credit limits
with bankruptcy,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30(11), 2081-2115.
Mateos-Planas, X. (2013), ”A model of credit limits and bankruptcy,” Economics Letters,
121(3), 469-472.
Mateos-Planas, X. and J. R´ıos-Rull (2013), ”Credit lines,” Working paper.
McKinley, V. (1997), ”Ballooning bankruptcies: Issuing blame for the explosive growth,”
Regulation, 20(4), 3340.
Nakajima, M. (2012), ”Rising indebtedness and temptation: A welfare analysis,” Quan-
titative Economics, 3(2), 257-288.
Nakajima, M. (2017), ”Assessing bankruptcy reform in a model with temptation and
equilibrium default,” Journal of Public Economics, 145, 42-64.
Nakajima, M., and J. R´ıos-Rull (2014), ”Credit, Bankruptcy, and Aggregate Fluctua-
tions,” Working paper.
Narajabad, B. N. (2012), ”Information technology and the rise of household bankruptcy,”
Review of Economic Dynamics, 15(4), 526-550.
Nelson, S. (2020), ”Private information and price regulation in the US credit card mar-
ket,” Working paper.
Raveendranathan, G. (2020), ”Revolving credit lines and targeted search,” Working pa-
per.
anchez, J. M. (2018), ”The information technology revolution and the unsecured credit
market,” Economic Inquiry, 56(2), 914-930.
Santucci, L. (2015), ”A tale of two intages: credit limit management before and after the
CARD Act and Great Recession,” Working paper.
Storesletten, K., C. Telmer, and A. Yaron (2004), ”Consumption and risk sharing over
the life cycle,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(3), 609-633.
Tauchen, G. (1986), ”Finite state markov-chain approximations to univariate and vector
autoregressions,” Economics Letters, 20(2), 177-181.
Zinman, J. (2009), ”Where is the missing credit card debt? Clues and implications,” The
Review of Income and Wealth, 55(2), 249-265.
41
A Model Appendix
A.1 Quasi-hyperbolic discounting and credit by income
Figure 21 plots credit by income quintile for different levels of hyperbolic discounting.
For each case, the model was re-calibrated to match the same target moments presented
in Table 1. We see that with more hyperbolic discounting (lower β), credit decreases
at the highest income quintile. Consequently, credit starts to decrease with income for
higher levels of hyperbolic discounting. This pattern is at odds with the data, where
credit is increasing with income. Hence, our benchmark model assumes no hyperbolic
discounting.
Figure 21: Credit by income quintile
(a) β= 1 (benchmark) (b) β= 0.9
(c) β= 0.8 (d) β= 0.7
42
A.2 Credit by income without permanent component
Figure 22 compares average credit to disposable income per capita between pre-policy
benchmark economy and pre-policy benchmark economy without variation in permanent
earnings θ. It shows that variation in permanent earnings is an important feature of the
model to account for credit among high income quintiles.
Figure 22: Credit by income quintile
A.3 Transition dynamics of ATP in benchmark model
Figure 23 plots the transition path for total credit to disposable income and average
credit limits to disposable income per capita in the benchmark model. The transition
converges quickly to the final steady state. This is because in our model, most of the
consumers that take on credit are young-middle age.
Figure 23: Transition dynamics of introducing ATP to benchmark model
(a) Credit (b) Credit limit
43
A.4 Robustness to taste shocks over default
This section shows that results are not sensitive to the calibrated extreme value type
1 shocks over default and repayment in the benchmark model. For this exercise, we
set the scaling parameter ξto 5000, which leads to almost zero non-modeled defaults.
Furthermore, we re-calibrate the model to match the set of target moments in Table 2
except the fraction of defaults due to healthcare bills, lawsuits, and divorce. Figure 24
plots the changes in credit statistics by income. Figure 25 plots the welfare implications
by income and age.
Figure 24: Changes in credit statistics by income quintile: model (non-targeted) vs data
(2004-2016)
(a) Credit (b) Credit card limit
Figure 25: Welfare implications of Ability to Pay in model without extreme value type 1
shocks
(a) One time transfers by income quintile (b) One time transfers by age
44
A.5 Credit card utilization rates by income in benchmark model
Figure 26 plots credit card utilization (credit/limit) by income quintile. The left panel
plots the percent of population that utilizes more than 25 percent of its credit limit. The
right panel plots the percent of population that utilizes more than 75 percent of its credit
limit. The model does well in accounting for utilization across income, especially for the
higher quintiles.
Figure 26: Credit card utilization by income quintile: model (non-targeted) vs data
(2004)
(a) Utilization above 25 percent (b) Utilization above 75 percent
45
A.6 Comparative statics with ATP
Figure 27 plots the welfare implications for different parameters of φ. The red line
refers to the benchmark model with β= 1, the blue line refers to the model re-calibrated
with β= 0.9, the black line refers to the model re-calibrated with β= 0.7. The x-axis is
the value of the threshold parameter φin units of the percent of the calibrated value for
each β. Overall, the policy leads to welfare losses.
Figure 27: Total welfare implications of Ability to Pay
46
A.7 Default rate and population with credit by age in bench-
mark model
Figure 28 plots the life cycle profile of the population with credit card debt and default
rates in the pre-policy benchmark model and 2004 SCF data. The model accounts for
the hump shaped profiles. The spike in default rates in the model is due to retirement.
Figure 28: Debtors and default rate by age: model (non-targeted) vs data (2004)
(a) Population with credit card debt (b) Annual bankruptcy rate
47
A.8 Computation algorithm
Solve consumer’s problem in the last period (age J).
Use policy functions to calculate ex-post profits for age J
Solve incumbent credit card firm’s problem for age J
Solve lender’s problem with new card holder for age J
Solve lender’s problem with current card holder for age J
Calculate probabilities of credit access for age J
Use backward induction from j=J1, .., 1:
Solve consumer’s problem for age j
Use policy functions to calculate ex-post profits for age j
Solve incumbent credit card firm’s problem for age j
Solve lender’s problem with new card holder for age j
Solve lender’s problem with current card holder for age j
Calculate probabilities of credit access for age j
Given policy functions, simulate and solve for equilibrium
48
A.9 Equilibrium
For ease of exposition, we define stationary equilibrium. For the transition, the value
functions, policy functions, and distributions include a time subscript. Given the risk
free rate r, a stationary equilibrium consists of consumer value functions VSj, b, ,
˜
VSj, b, ,WSj, b, ,˜
WSj, b, ,VDj, ,˜
VDj, ,VCj, b, ,¯
b, τq,˜
VCj, b, ,¯
b, τq,
WCj, b, ,¯
b, τq, and ˜
WCj, b, ,¯
b, τq, consumer policy functions without a credit card
dj, b, ,cj, b, , and b0j, b, , consumer policy functions with a credit card dj, b, ,¯
b, τq,
cj, b, ,¯
b, τq, and b0j, b, ,¯
b, τq, credit card firm profit functions ΠSj, b, θ, η, ΠCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq,
ΠIj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, and Πj, b, ,¯
b, τq, credit card firm policy functions ¯
bSj, b, θ, η,
τS
qj, b, θ, η,¯
bC(j, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq,τC
q(j, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, and ¯
bIj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, mass of con-
sumers uSj, b, θ, ηand uCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, mass of credit card firms vSj, b, θ, ηand
vCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, and probabilities pSj, b, θ, ηand pCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τqsuch that:
policy functions ¯
bSj, b, θ, ηand τS
qj, b, θ, η, solve the credit card firms problem
for consumers without a credit card in (5) with resulting profit function ΠSj, b, θ, η
as defined in (5);
policy functions ¯
bC(j, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τqand τC
q(j, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, solve the credit card firm’s
problem for consumers with a credit card in (6) with resulting profit function
ΠCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τqas defined in (6);
policy function ¯
bIj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq, solves the incumbent credit card firm’s problem for
consumers with a credit card in (7) with resulting profit function ΠIj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τq
as defined in (7);
profit function Πj, b, ,¯
b, τqsatisfies equation (8)
the zero-profit conditions hold for credit offers in (3) and (4);
policy functions dj, b, ,cj, b, , and b0j, b, , solve the consumer’s problem
without credit card in (10) and (13) with resulting value functions WSj, b, ,
˜
WSj, b, ,VSj, b, ,˜
VSj, b, , and as defined in (10), (12), (13), and (14)
respectively;
policy functions dj, b, ,¯
b, τq,cj, b, ,¯
b, τq, and b0j, b, ,¯
b, τq, solve the con-
sumer’s problem with credit card in (16) and (18) with resulting value functions
WCj, b, ,¯
b, τq,˜
WCj, b, ,¯
b, τq,VCj, b, ,¯
b, τq, and ˜
VCj, b, ,¯
b, τqas defined
in (16), (17), (18), and (19) respectively;
Value functions VDj, and ˜
VDj, satisfy (15) and (??) respectively
Matching probabilities pSj, b, θ, ηand pCj, b, θ, η, ¯
b, τqsatisfy (1) and (2)
the tax rate balances the social security budget; and
the distribution of consumers are invariant given the policy functions, probability of
credit access function, credit card limit function, credit card interest rate function,
and the earnings process.
49
B Data Appendix
B.1 Sources
For the risk-free interest rate, we use annual returns on the 3-month treasury bill
from the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED). The average credit card interest rate
data are from FRB G.19. Credit card charge-off rate data are from FRED. Revolving
credit data are from FRB G.19. Chapter 7 bankruptcy filings data are from the American
Bankruptcy Institute. Estimates for bankruptcies by age were taken from Fisher (2017).
The Survey of Consumer Finances was used for the following data: population with
credit cards (total, by age, by income), population with interest assessed credit card debt
(total, by age, by income), interest assessed credit card debt by age and income, average
borrowing limit (total, by age, by income), (cross-sectional) average credit card interest
rate by age and income, and percent of interest assessed debt. In the SCF, credit card
debt is under reported (refer to Zinman (2009) and Exler and Tertilt (2020) for a detailed
discussion). Hence, we scale average credit in the SCF such that it matches average credit
from the FRB G19 series.
2001-2004 averages and 2016-2019 averages were used to calculate levels and percent-
age point changes for aggregate credit statistics (if the data was available for the four
year period).
50
B.2 Other forms of consumer credit
In this subsection, we show that the fall in revolving credit has not been substituted
by the rise in other forms of credit. Figure 29 plots revolving credit, personal loans (e.g.
home equity line of credit), non-revolving consumer credit such as motor vehicle loans and
education loans. The rise in revolving credit between 1970 and the 2000s was associated
with substitution away from personal loans. However, the fall in revolving credit in the
last decade has not been substituted by a rise in personal loans. Motor vehicle loans,
which fell during the recession has been recovering back to trend. The rise in education
loans precedes the fall in revolving credit. The magnitudes of changes in other forms of
non-revolving credit are small.
Figure 29: Other forms of consumer credit
(a) Unsecured & personal (b) Non-revolving (c) Mortgages & HELOC
Notes: The left panel plots total outstanding revolving credit, personal credit, and unsecured credit
(revolving+personal) as a percent of disposable income between 1970 and 2018 (data sources: Federal Reserve Board
G19, Bureau of Economic Analysis, and authors’ calculations). Personal loans were constructed following methodology
used in Livshits, MacGee, and Tertilt (2010). The middle panel plots components of non-revolving credit such as
outstanding motor vehicle loans and outstanding education loans as a percent of disposal income (data sources: Federal
Reserve Board G19, Bureau of Economic Analysis, and authors’ calculations). The right panel plots outstanding
mortgages and outstanding home equity line of credit as a percent of disposable income (data sources: FRED, Bureau of
Economic Analysis, and authors’ calculations)
51
... The gains to consumers amount to 73 percent of the value of credit access. * The rate cap analysis in this paper stems from a rate cap experiment performed in a previous version of Raveendranathan and Stefanidis (2022). We thank anonymous referees for suggesting that we drop the experiment in that paper and analyze rate caps more rigorously in a separate paper. ...
... We perform our analysis in a model of revolving credit lines from Raveendranathan and Stefanidis (2022), which builds on prior work by Drozd and Nosal (2008), Mateos-Planas and Ríos-Rull (2013), and Raveendranathan (2020). In our model, lenders matched with consumers have market power. ...
... Our model economy uses the framework of Raveendranathan and Stefanidis (2022), which builds on prior work by Drozd and Nosal (2008), Mateos-Planas and Ríos-Rull (2013), and Raveendranathan (2020). ...
Preprint
Full-text available
We show how a rate cap can be designed to improve both consumer and lender welfare in the credit card market. We analyze transition paths resulting from different rate caps in a model with revolving credit lines, search frictions, and lender market power. Our analysis shows that if a rate cap only applies to new credit card issuance and not existing accounts, it can improve lender welfare. Incumbent lenders benefit because they can retain their customers for a longer time. New issuers are not affected as long as the posting of credit offers is competitive (zero expected profits in equilibrium). Consumers benefit because of lower interest rates. The rate cap that maximizes consumer welfare leads to gains to consumers and lenders that are equivalent to a onetime transfer worth 0.44 percent of disposable income. The gains to consumers amount to 73 percent of the value of credit access. * The rate cap analysis in this paper stems from a rate cap experiment performed in a previous version of Raveendranathan and Stefanidis (2022). We thank anonymous referees for suggesting that we drop the experiment in that paper and analyze rate caps more rigorously in a separate paper. We also thank SSHRC for Insight Development Grant 430-2021-00075. † McMaster University.
Article
Do cognitive biases call for regulation to limit the use of credit? We incorporate over-optimistic and rational borrowers into an incomplete markets model with consumer bankruptcy. Over-optimists face worse income risk but incorrectly believe they are rational. Thus, both types behave identically. Lenders price loans forming beliefs-type scores-about borrower types. This gives rise to a tractable theory of type scoring. As lenders cannot screen types, borrowers are partially pooled. Over-optimists face cross-subsidized interest rates but make financial mistakes: borrowing too much and defaulting too little. In equilibrium, the welfare losses from mistakes are more than compensated by cross-subsidization. We calibrate the model to the US and quantitatively evaluate policies to address these frictions: financial literacy education, reducing default cost, increasing borrowing costs, and debt limits. While some policies lower debt and filings, only reducing default costs and financial literacy education improve welfare. However, financial literacy education benefits only rationals at the expense of over-optimists. Score-dependent borrowing limits can reduce financial mistakes but lower welfare.
Article
I propose a model of revolving credit lines and targeted search to analyze what accounts for the profitability of the U.S. credit card industry. My analyses lead to two main findings. First, the search friction has minimal impact on the level of profitability of the credit card industry. Most of the profitability is a result of the lender choosing the terms of contract. Second, improved information about consumers accounts for the fall in profitability since the 1980s. Consistent with the data, lenders respond to more information by increasing credit card limits and lowering markups.
Preprint
Full-text available
I propose a model of revolving credit lines and targeted search where credit card firms issue long-term contracts specified by a credit limit and interest rate to heterogeneous consumers. The model accounts for income and life cycle profiles of various credit card market variables. Using the model to adjust for default risk, I show that consumers with lower earnings pay higher spreads because they face tighter credit limits (imposes a quantity restriction) and receive credit offers with lower probabilities. I also quantify the role of improvements in information and improved matching on spreads across consumers between 1983 and 2004.
Article
Full-text available
This paper documents and interprets a fact central to the dynamics of informal consumer debt default. We observe that for individuals 60 to 90 days late on payments, (i) 85 percent make payments during the next quarter, and (ii) 40 percent reduce their debt. To understand these facts, we develop a quantitative model of debt delinquency and bankruptcy. Our model reproduces the dynamics of delinquency and suggests an interpretation of the data in which lenders frequently reset loan terms for delinquent borrowers, typically offering partial debt forgiveness, rather than a blanket imposition of the “penalty rates” most unsecured credit contracts specify.
Article
Full-text available
The information technology (IT) revolution coincided with the transformation of the U.S. unsecured credit market. Households' borrowing increased rapidly and there was an even faster increase in bankruptcy filings. A risk of default model with asymmetric information and costly screening is introduced to study this period. When information costs are high, the design of contracts under private information prevents some households from borrowing with a risk of default. As information costs drop, households borrow more and bankruptcy filings increase. Quantitative exercises suggest that the IT revolution may have played an important role in the transformation of the unsecured credit market. (JEL E43, E44, G33)
Article
Unemployed households’ access to unsecured revolving credit more than tripled over the last three decades. This article analyses how both cyclical fluctuations and trend increases in credit access impact the business cycle. The main quantitative result is that credit expansions and contractions have contributed to moderately deeper and more protracted recessions over the last 40 years. As more individuals obtained credit from 1977 to 2010, cyclical credit fluctuations affected a larger share of the population and became more important determinants of employment dynamics. Even though business cycles are more volatile, newborns strictly prefer to live in the economy with growing, but fluctuating, access to credit markets.
Article
I propose a model of revolving credit lines and targeted search to analyze what accounts for the profitability of the U.S. credit card industry. My analyses lead to two main findings. First, the search friction has minimal impact on the level of profitability of the credit card industry. Most of the profitability is a result of the lender choosing the terms of contract. Second, improved information about consumers accounts for the fall in profitability since the 1980s. Consistent with the data, lenders respond to more information by increasing credit card limits and lowering markups.
Article
Who files for bankruptcy in the United States is not well understood. Previous research relied on small samples from surveys or a small number of states from administrative records. Using over 10 million administrative bankruptcy records linked to the 2000 Decennial Census and the 2001‐2009 American Community Surveys, I document who files for bankruptcy. Compared to U.S. population, bankruptcy filers are middle income, more likely to be divorced, more likely to be black, more likely to be veterans, less likely to be immigrants, and more likely to have a high school degree or some college. Filers are more likely to be employed. The bankruptcy population is aging faster than the U.S. population as a whole. Lastly, using pseudo‐panels I study what happens in the years around bankruptcy. Individuals are likely to get divorced in the years before bankruptcy and then re‐marry. Income falls before bankruptcy and rises after bankruptcy. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.