ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

Belarus was among the few post-communist countries to resign from comprehensive market reforms and attempt to improve the efficiency of the economy through administrative means, leaving market mechanisms only an auxiliary role. Since its inception, the ‘Belarusian economic model’ has undergone several revisions of a de-statisation and de-regulation kind, but still the Belarusian economy remains dominated by the state. This paper analyses the characteristic features of the Belarusian economic system – especially those related to the public sector – as well as its evolution over time during the period following its independence. The paper concludes that during the post-Soviet period, the Belarusian economy evolved from a quasi-Soviet system based on state property, state planning, support to inefficient enterprises and the massive redistribution of funds to a more flexible hybrid model where the public sector still remains the core of the economy. The case of Belarus shows that presently there is no appropriate theoretical perspective which, in an unmodified form, could be applied to study this type of economic system. Therefore, a new perspective based on an already existing but updated approach or a multidisciplinary approach that incorporates the duality of the Belarusian economy is required.
Content may be subject to copyright.
The evolution of
Belarusian public sector:
From command economy
to state capitalism?
Aliaksandr Papko
Piotr Kozarzewski
CASE WORKING PAPERS
WARSAW BISHKEK KYIV TBILISI CHISINAU MINSK
No. 12(136)/2020
The opinions expressed in this publicaon are those of the authors and do not necessarily re-
ect the views of CASE.
This publicaon is a connuaon of a “CASE Network Report” series. Previous works in this
series are available on CASE website: www.case-research.eu
This work was supported by the Naonal Science Centre of Poland
under Grant no. 2017/25/B/HS4/01103 ‘The Phenomenon of «The Return of State-Owned
Enterprises» in Contemporary Economy: Idencaon, Characteriscs, and Consequences for
the Economic Theory and for the Theory of Economic Policy.’
Keywords: state-owned enterprises, post-communist transion, state capitalism, instuons,
Belarus.
JEL codes: L53, O17 P21, P31
© CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw, 2020
Graphic Design: Katarzyna Godyń-Skoczylas | grafo-mania
DTP: Campidoglio
ISBN: 978-83-7178-694-5
Publisher:
CASE-Center for Social and Economic Research
al. Jana Pawla II 61, oce 212, 01-031 Warsaw, Poland
tel.: (48 22) 206 29 00, fax: (48 22) 206 29 01
e-mail: case@case-research.eu
hp://www.case-research.eu
3
Contents
Authors............................................................................................................................... 4
Abstract.............................................................................................................................. 5
1. Introducon .................................................................................................................. 6
2. Literature overview and conceptualisaon........................................................... 7
3.1. The ‘Belarusian economic model’: From rise to the crisis
(1991-2006) ........................................................................................................11
3. From command economy to reluctant reforms ..................................................11
3.2. Limited aempts of market reforms (2007-2015) .....................................14
3.3. Towards stability based on market mechanisms (since 2015) ...............16
4.1. How big is the state? The share of the public sector in the
Belarusian economy ..........................................................................................19
4. State sector in Belarus: Data and analysis ........................................................... 19
4.2. Away from the command economy? The evoluon
of the public sector since 2007 ......................................................................22
5.1. Ownership funcon of the state ....................................................................25
5. Wrien and unwrien rules: The state as a main actor
in the Belarusian economy ....................................................................................25
5.2. State planning system .......................................................................................26
5.3. Discriminaon of the private sector: Subsidies, trade
proteconism and formal and informal barriers .........................................28
5.4. Interests in relaonships between the state and enterprises ..................30
6. Conclusions and discussion .................................................................................... 33
References ....................................................................................................................... 35
4
Aliaksandr Papko is a journalist and polical analyst working for Belsat TV (Minsk/Warsaw) and
the Eurasian States in Transion Research Center (Minsk). He holds a PhD in sociology and an
MA in polical science and European interdisciplinary studies. The topics of his research include
polical, social and economic transion in Russia, Ukraine and Belarus; informal economic ins-
tuons in post-Soviet countries; and the European Neighbourhood Policy and Eastern Partner-
ship.
Piotr Kozarzewski is an economist and polical scienst and an Associate Professor in the Fac-
ulty of Economics at the Maria Curie-Skłodowska University in Lublin. He is a member of the
CASE Supervisory Council and a parcipant of many research and advisory programs in Poland,
the former Soviet Union, and Central and Eastern European countries on instuonal reform,
ownership transformaon, and internaonal knowledge transfer. He is the author and co-author
of over 120 publicaons primarily devoted to the post-communist transion.
Authors
5
Abstract
Belarus was among the few post-communist countries to resign from comprehensive market
reforms and aempt to improve the eciency of the economy through administrave means,
leaving market mechanisms only an auxiliary role. Since its incepon, the ‘Belarusian economic
model’ has undergone several revisions of a de-stasaon and de-regulaon kind, but sll the
Belarusian economy remains dominated by the state. This paper analyses the characterisc fea-
tures of the Belarusian economic system – especially those related to the public sector – as well
as its evoluon over me during the period following its independence. The paper concludes
that during the post-Soviet period, the Belarusian economy evolved from a quasi-Soviet system
based on state property, state planning, support to inecient enterprises and the massive re-
distribuon of funds to a more exible hybrid model where the public sector sll remains the
core of the economy. The case of Belarus shows that presently there is no appropriate theore-
cal perspecve which, in an unmodied form, could be applied to study this type of economic
system. Therefore, a new perspecve based on an already exisng but updated approach or
a muldisciplinary approach that incorporates the duality of the Belarusian economy is required.
6
Aer the fall of the communism, Belarusian authories built a very peculiar economic system
which preserved many of the features of the Soviet period (e.g. the dominaon of state prop-
erty and central planning) and combined them with the features of a market economy (e.g. the
existence of private entrepreneurship and free prices in some areas). Unl the global economic
crisis of 2008/2009, the ‘Belarusian economic model’ proved to be quite successful, allowing
the country’s gross domesc product (GDP) to grow by 8%-10% each year. Belarusian enter-
prises, which, like in Soviet mes, remain predominantly state-owned, acvely exported ad-
vanced industrial products such as trucks, tractors, engines and electronic appliances, as well as
fuel processed from Russian crude oil. However, in the last decade, the Belarusian economy has
slowed down signicantly, demonstrang the limits of the economic model chosen in the 1990s.
The task of the paper is twofold. First, we analyse the characterisc features of the Belaru-
sian economy aer 1990 and their evoluon: from the perspecve of both economic policy
and real processes and outcomes. Special aenon is paid to the role of the government in the
economy, especially in the enterprise sector. Second, we try to nd a theorecal perspecve
which would help to analyse the variety of economic models in transion economies, especially
highly stased ones, as in Belarus. In parcular, we check the applicability of the state capital-
ism approach – which has recently gained popularity – in studying post-communist economies,
because it focuses on an above-the-norm state involvement in the economy.
We come to the conclusion that in this period the Belarusian economy has evolved from
a quasi-Soviet system based on state property, state planning, support to inecient enterprises
and the massive redistribuon of funds to a more exible hybrid model where the public sec-
tor sll remains the core of the economy. This system, however, can only parally be explained
from the perspecve of the state capitalism approach (in its present state); therefore, a new
perspecve based on an already exisng but updated approach or a muldisciplinary approach
that incorporates the duality of the Belarusian economy is required.
The structure of the paper is the following: Secon 2 is devoted to the conceptualisaon of
the study. Secon 3 presents a historical overview of the evoluon of the Belarusian economy
and economic policy. Secon 4 discusses the main features of the ‘Belarusian economic model’.
Secon 5 analyses the state-controlled enterprise sector in Belarus. Secon 6 concludes.
1. Introduction
7
In studies on post-communist economies, the ‘Belarusian economic model’ – its genesis, main
features, evoluon and eects – is largely neglected, especially when taking into account pub-
licaons wrien in English, i.e. those present in the world debate. Consequently, the Belarusian
economic model sll lacks a proper conceptualisaon. In the literature from the West, there are
only sporadic aempts to explain the logic of the funconing of the Belarusian economic mod-
el (Nu, 2005; Korosteleva, 2007). Western-based researchers (e.g. Korosteleva, 2013; Ioe,
2014; Dyner and Wańczyk, 2015) have mainly analysed the economic policy of the Belarusian
government, concentrang on the sustainability of the Belarusian economic system without
fully examining its genesis or fundamental principles. In Belarusian literature as well, most pub-
licaons (e.g. Kizima, 2010; Krishtapovich and Lepeshko, 2010; Bibik, 2011; Grechneva, 2014)
have focused on performance (achievements) and not the mechanisms or costs of the economic
system. These studies were largely aempts by ‘mainstream’ experts to jusfy the economic
policy of the government. There have been a few local authors (e.g. Dashkevich, 2005; Akulich,
2013; Yegorov, 2013) that have aempted to dig deeper and try to explain the logic of the
Belarusian economic model, but their aempts are sll only a paral examinaon. In summary,
exisng studies only focus on, at most, the essence of the model, concentrang on its manifes-
taons rather than its structural logic.
Taking into account this knowledge gap, in this secon of the paper we concentrate rst of all
on the literature which presents possible theorecal approaches towards studying the Belaru-
sian economic system rather than the publicaons specically devoted to the country.
Thus far, there is only one (relavely old) publicaon (Korosteleva, 2007) devoted specically
to the conceptualisaon of the Belarusian economic system. The author discusses the possibili-
es for its analysis from the ‘classical’ (Hall and Soskice, 2001; Amable, 2003) perspecve of the
variees of capitalism (VoC) approach. The author concludes that such analysis is impossible
because the Belarusian economy does not t the denions of both a liberal market economy
and a coordinated market economy. This was in line with the general conclusions on the ap-
plicability of the VoC approach to most post-communist economies made in the book in which
Korosteleva’s paper was published (Lane and Myant, 2007). Since then, the VoC approach has
evolved, taking into account the much wider diversity of market economies, and now admits
that there are more basic variants of capitalism than just the two. Farkas (2016) argues that in
the European Union (EU) alone one can disnguish four models of capitalism, with a h model
specic to some non-EU countries. However, despite the expansion of the VoC approach, most
2. Literature overview
and conceptualisation
8
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
former Soviet republics, including stased economies such as Belarus, are sll excluded from
VoC studies.
An opposite approach, which was largely unknown to internaonal academic circles unl re-
cently because the relevant studies were published in Russian only, rejects aempts to study the
economies of many former Soviet republics in the same way that market economies are studied
(Kordonsky, 2016). It stresses the peculiar non-market, resource-based and redistribuve char-
acter of the economic systems which have formed in these countries. Bessonova (2006) writes
about a ‘distribuve economy’ which originated in the Soviet Union and is characterised by sev-
eral basic features, among which are the abuse of property rights by the state, allocaon based
on the discreonal redistribuon of resources by the state and informaon feedback provided
not by market prices and prot but by complaints to state authories. Kordonsky (2008) applies
a similar approach and calls such a system a ‘resource-based state’. Its economy is not based on
a market exchange, but on the centralised accumulaon of resources from the populaon and
its organisaons with their redistribuon according to the government’s polical and economic
priories. The system is also characterised by a lack of rule of law and the omnipotence of infor-
mal instuons. This perspecve was used by Papko (2017a) in his analysis of the ‘state’ part of
the duality of the Belarusian economy.
Another perspecve is economic dualism, which lays somewhere between the two ap-
proaches described above. It draws aenon to the coexistence of several economic systems
within one economy (Boeke, 1953). From this perspecve, some post-communist economies
may be treated as hybrid systems where two sectors coexist: a prot-making private sector and
a subsidised state-controlled sector. Most transion countries – where this dualism existed to
some extent at the beginning of transion, especially in Central and Eastern Europe –gradually
abandoned this model, while Belarus remains ‘one of the paradigmac cases where a sizeable
backward sector of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) sll coexists with a small and viable sector
of compeve and modern companies, some of which are also controlled by the state’ (Bona
and Haiduk, 2014, p. 9). Thus far, this approach has been applied directly to the economy of
Belarus only in this publicaon and in an unpublished thesis by Papko (2017a), where he also
makes use of the distribuon economy perspecve in his analysis of the ‘state’ part of the eco-
nomic system. However, somemes the state-market duality of the Belarusian economic system
is put under queson by researchers. As Bekus (2010, p. 108) argues, it ‘strives toward preserv-
ing state property in its old, prereform condion, slightly diluted by market elements, but in
general it presupposes no real market system as it is’. It should be noted, however, that during
the 14 years following this statement, the Belarusian economy has made several steps towards
the market and there has been some expansion of private property.
The duality (hybridity) of the system may also be studied from the angle of the economic and
polical duality of patrimonial capitalism (Schlumberger, 2008). This approach has been applied
towards non-democrac transion countries by Robinson (2013) as a form of capitalism which
is ‘created as much by external pressure as by the organic development of a country’s economy,
and where there are constraints on economic development because of rapacious elite behav-
9
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
iours’ (p. 144). Despite looking quite promising, no analysis of the Belarusian case has been
performed from this perspecve.
Another possibility – which is explored in this paper – is the use of the state capitalism (SC)
approach. More than a decade ago, it was suggested by Korosteleva (2007) as an alternave to
the VoC perspecve; however, she hasn’t explored this possibility in detail. Furthermore, at that
me, studies on SC typically covered only one post-communist transion country – Russia (e.g.
Lane, 2008). Studies examining China in this context should be also menoned (although China,
while it may be a transion economy, can hardly be called post-communist), beginning with the
seminal work by Bremmer (2010). Since then, we have witnessed a growing body of literature
on SC, which reects a wider use of state intervenonist policies than before, including in devel-
oped market economies where in many cases the state played an acve role in combang the
global nancial crisis of 2008-2009.
Recently, transion countries have enjoyed more aenon in SC studies because, in some of
them, the tendency towards state intervenonism has increased, even to the point of inducing
changes in the their development paradigms. To start with, this applies to Poland and Hungary.
Bałtowski, Kozarzewski and Mickiewicz (2020) aempted not only to study growing state capi-
talism tendencies in these two countries, but also to contribute to the conceptualisaon of the
state capitalism approach, especially when it is applied to transion economies. Previously, the
term ‘state capitalism’ had many dierent interpretaons, and researchers applied it in a number
of dierent perspecves. Furthermore, there were even some authors that applied the term
state capitalism to diering approaches in their own research papers. The exisng denions
may be divided into broad and narrow ones. In the broad approach, SC is regarded as a market
economic system1 where state intervenon in the economy is much higher than in developed
capitalist countries and plays a key role in meeng polical and developmental goals (Bremmer,
2010; Spechler, Ahrens and Hoen, 2017). In the narrow approach, SC is regarded as a set of
policies allowing the government to have a strong and arbitrary impact on the enterprise sector
(Musacchio and Lazzarini, 2012; Kurlantzick, 2016).
Bałtowski et al. (2020) propose to merge these approaches in analysis and put forward
a concept of six basic features of state capitalism. These features each have specic goals, tools
and core groups of beneciaries who are chosen by the government (in market capitalism, the
main beneciaries are set by market mechanisms). The authors believe that their approach may
be used for studies on other Central and Eastern European countries, and probably on other
post-communist transion countries as well. These features are the following:
1) policisaon of SOEs: the government and polical elite use the state-controlled enter-
prise sector as a source of rents;
2) policisaon of SOEs à rebours: the state-controlled enterprise sector (their sta, execu-
ves and aliated trade unions, among others) is the main rent-seeker itself;
3) cronyism: the main beneciaries of SC are private agents from outside the public sector;
1 An enrely dierent approach exists where state capitalism does not assume the existence of the market; rather,
the state dominates the economy, which is essenally a planned socialist system (Mises, 2009; Fabry, 2019).
10
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
4) oligarchy (a consolidated form of cronyism): very powerful private agents have a very sig-
nicant inuence on economic policy;
5) economic populism (clientelism): a patronage system where the polical elite transfers
goods to clients in chosen social groups expecng their polical support in return;
6) economic naonalism: the state exerts an impact on the economy the declared objecve
of which is to enhance, in the long run, the state’s polical capacity, military power or
internaonal importance. The state itself may be treated here as the major beneciary.
The authors also describe the main tools of state capitalism in Poland and Hungary: impact
through enterprises fully or partly belonging to the state, restricng the ownership rights of
private businesses, regulatory tools and persuasion (pressure, threats) measures.
This approach towards studying state capitalism in transion countries seems to be the most
developed thus far. Therefore, we believe that despite all the specicity of Belarus’ economic
system and economic policy, it is worth making an aempt to apply this approach in studies on
this country, if only as a rst step for further conceptualisaon eorts.
11
3.1. The ‘Belarusian economic model’: From rise to the crisis (1991-2006)
The economic structure of contemporary Belarus was formed long before the country gained in-
dependence in 1991 (Zaleski, 2002, p.11). It was built in the 1960s and 1970s as a result of rapid
industrialisaon, iniated by Soviet authories. Belarus was known as an ‘assembly shop’ of the
Soviet Union. Its economy was based on large enterprises in the machine building, electronics,
chemical, petrochemical and agriculture industries desned to supply the enre Soviet Union.
The industrial giants of Soviet Byelorussia crically depended on a supply of raw materials and
spare parts from other Soviet republics (Yanchuk, 2007, p. 51).
Thus, the disintegraon of the Soviet Union severely aected the Belarusian economy. In
1995, the country’s GDP fell by 34.7% as compared to 1990. The income of the populaon
decreased by half and the number of people living below poverty line rose from 5% to 80% (Yan-
chuk, 2007, p. 52). The government tried to support enterprises by money emission. As a result,
the inaon rate in 1994 reached 2200%2.
As several researchers (Havrylyshyn, 2007; Rovdo, 2009; Olechnowicz, 2010) argue, a com-
prehensive process of market transion never started in Belarus. The government never fully
liberalised prices or the exchange rate; privasaon was slow, hesitant and did not include large
enterprises. In 1994, amidst a deep economic recession, the rst presidenal elecons were
won by Alexander Lukashenko – an authoritarian polician with a strong an-market rhetoric.
By November 1996, Lukashenko dismantled the separaon of powers and consolidated con-
trol over the state in his hands. He also managed to restore non-market exchange with Russia
and re-launch producon capacies remaining idle since the dissoluon of the Soviet Union. In
April 1996, April 1997 and December 1999, the Belarusian authories concluded a series of
treaes the goal of which was to establish a common state with Russia. It was never created,
but these agreements guaranteed Belarus generous economic preferences from Russia for many
years ahead. Belarus was given unrestrained access to the Russian market; it was allowed to
buy oil and gas at the same prices as Russian consumers, which were twice below market prices
(Silicki, 2001, p. 64).
Such a policy brought quick results. In 1996-2001, Belarusian GDP grew by an average of
6.1% (World Bank, 2005, p. 5). Aer obtaining large preferences from Russia, Alexander Lukash-
enko openly contested market transion, reversing those few shallow and inconsistent reforms
2 hp://databank.worldbank.org.
3. From command economy to reluctant
reforms
12
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
which had been introduced by his predecessors. The regress started in 1996 (Figure 1) and was
observed in every single domain of economic transformaon assessed by the European Bank for
Reconstrucon and Development (EBRD).
Figure 1. Market transion progress in selected post-communist countries, 1989-2014
1,0
1,5
2,0
2,5
3,0
3,5
4,0
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
EBRD transition score
BELARUS
ESTONIA
LITHUANIA
POLAND
RUSSIAN
FEDERATION
UKRAINE
-20
-10
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
Percent
Inflation (annual %)
Current account balance (% of GDP)
GDP growth (annual %)
The advancement of reforms in each country is measured by the average of six EBRD transion indicators (large scale
privasaon, small scale privasaon, governance and enterprise restructuring, price liberalisaon, trade & forex
system and compeon policy).
Source: Own calculaons based on EBRD, 2015.
In 1996, Belarusian authories took control of the biggest commercial banks and re-intro-
duced ght price controls (Silicki, 2001, p. 60). Privasaon was virtually stopped. In March
1995, Lukashenko by his decree (dekret)3 cancelled the results of the rst voucher aucon.
Since the summer of that year, he made every privasaon deal subject to his personal deci-
sion (Silicki, 2001. p. 47). Addionally, privasaon deals usually kept the controlling stock in
the hands of the government. One of the most an-market decisions was the Presidenal edict
(ukaz)4which came into eect in January 1998 – granng the state a ‘golden share’ right of
any former state-owned enterprise which had been privased (EBRD, 1999, p. 154). Enterprise
restructuring was also frozen. By the end of the decade no single enterprise was declared bank-
rupt under the 1991 Bankruptcy Law (EBRD, 1999, p. 154).
3 In Belarusian law, a Decree (dekret) is a normave act issued by the President in exceponal cases, having the force
of law and aimed to regulate the most important social, polical and economic issues.
4 A Presidenal Edict (ukaz) it is a normave act having the force of law, issued by the President in order to implement
his mandate and seng (changing, cancelling) certain legal provisions.
13
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
A huge blow to the development of the private sector was the adopon of new business
regulaons. In May 1996, the President issued a decree requiring the re-registraon of all pri-
vate enterprises in accordance with recent changes in the naonal legislaon. As a result, the
number of private rms dropped by 30% due to the administrave burden this re-registraon
entailed (EBRD, 1999, p. 155).
State authories nished the process of taking control over the economic system by the end
of 1996, when the main elements of central planning were re-introduced. The government ad-
opted a programme entled ‘Main direcons of social and economic development for the years
1996-2000’. It set targets for economic development including, among others, the GDP growth
rate, the increase in industrial and agricultural output, the inaon rate, the unemployment rate
and the naonal currency exchange rate (Silicki, 2001, p. 50). On the basis of this document,
various targets for each state enterprise were designed. Enterprises were obliged to meet tar-
gets concerning, among others, output growth, exports and wage growth (EBRD, 2008 p. 105).
By the end of 2002, the eects of smulang factors such as privileged access to the Rus-
sian market and export subsidies were exhausted (World Bank, 2005. p. 6). However, a rapid in-
crease in global oil prices as well as a revival in the Russian market re-launched economic growth
in Belarus (World Bank, 2012 p. 4). In 2001-2008, average annual GDP growth was 8.3%, while
in 2003-2008, the Belarusian economy grew by an astonishing 9.4% a year5.
However, Minsk did not manage to use the extremely posive external environment to re-
structure its industry and increase the compeveness of its products on foreign markets. Be-
larus became more dependent on exports of petrochemical products to the West and more
aached to the Russian market in regard to the export of other products. The possibilies to
increase exports were limited; therefore, the Belarusian government found a new source of
economic growth. Since 2005, about two-thirds of GDP growth is generated by the increase in
domesc consumpon (World Bank, 2012, p. 9).
The authories forced SOEs to increase wages, independent of labour producvity. At the
same me, state-controlled commercial banks provided loans to SOEs with interest rates below
the market level or even below the inaon rate (World Bank, 2012. p. 29, 36). The main recipi-
ents of these loans were SOEs in the agricultural sector, industry and construcon. Neverthe-
less, such generous lending did not help SOEs to work more eciently. Economists have proven
that the bulk of loans were provided to inecient enterprises and that this money was simply
lost (Kruk and Bornukova, 2014, p. 4). To compensate for non-payable loans, the state regularly
re-capitalised commercial banks through money emission (World Bank, 2012, p. 36).
By the end of the decade, this economic model formed as a result of President Lukashenko’s
ad hoc acvity had already exhausted its potenal. A new period in the economic development
of Belarus was triggered in 2007 by the signicant reducon of Russian energy subsidies.
5 hp://databank.worldbank.org.
14
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
3.2. Limited attempts of market reforms (2007-2015)
The second stage of the evoluon of the Belarusian economic system was triggered by growing
economic problems caused by its inecient economic model and by the decision of the Russian
government to cut energy subsidies as a response to the policy of the Belarusian government,
which evidently did not want to full its promises on establishing a common state with Russia
(Sokolov, 2007) and which would make the economic situaon even worse. In this situaon, in
order to prevent a crisis, the Belarusian government decided to modify its policy in two areas:
introduce some market elements into the economy in order to increase its eciency and restore
Russian economic preferences.
Within the rst area, the government parally re-launched market reforms. In 2007, it simpli-
ed procedures for the registraon of small and medium enterprises (SMEs) and for real estate
transacons and granted concessions and tax exempons for IT rms. In the area of ownership
policy, in 2008, it abolished the ‘golden share’ rule and announced a privasaon programme
which included selling the state-owned stakes in 147 industrial and agribusiness enterprises
during 2008-2010. Several Belarusian industrial giants, including MTZ, which produced tractors,
and MAZ, a truck factory, were corporased. In 2011, the Belarusian government approved
further plans for the privasaon of 245 SOEs and the corporasaon of 134 SOEs; however,
most of these were medium-sized communal enterprises with low protability.
In 2009, the Belarusian government liberalised all prices except for a limited number of ‘so-
cially important goods’ (e.g. basic food staples, pharmaceucals, medical services and children’s
goods). A progressive personal income tax with the highest rate of 30% was replaced by a at
tax of 12%. Considerable progress was made in the area of deregulaon: wage control was
abolished and in February 2009, the government introduced a policy of one-day registraon for
enterprises and individual entrepreneurs and simplied registraon procedures. As a result of its
deregulaon reforms, Belarus radically improved its posion in the World Bank’s Doing Business
ranking, rising from a ranking of 129 in 2007 to 58 in 20106.
However, most of these reforms were either inconsistent or short-lived, especially privasa-
on, where plans were fullled only marginally. And many policies remained unchanged, such as
the smulaon of internal demand and nancial support to SOEs as well as its xed exchange
rate policy.
In the second area – aempts to bring back Russian energy preferences – Belarus engaged in
new economic integraon projects iniated by Russia, such as the establishment of the Customs
Union of Belarus, Kazakhstan and Russia in 2009 and the Single Economic Space, which came
into force in 2012. This acvity proved to be successful, gradually restoring the preferenal re-
gime in oil and gas trade with Russia, and was Russia’s way of buying Belarus’ support for the its
integraonist policy among ex-Soviet republics. Among others, Russia abolished export dues
on oil exported to Belarus and introduced a generous gas price discount. In 2012, Russia also
provided Belarus with a USD 3 billion stabilisaon loan. However, part of the deal was the full
6 hp://www.doingbusiness.org/.
15
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
transfer of ownership rights of Beltransgaz, the Belarusian naonal gas transporng company,
to Russia’s Gazprom. It should be noted, however, that by the end of the discussed period, the
value of the subsidies started decreasing again.
Despite the substanal success of Belarus’ relaonship with Russia and some progress in
market reforms, the ulmate goal of increasing the growth potenal of the Belarusian economy
was not achieved. Aer Russian energy subsidies were increased in 2011-2012, the Belarusian
government apparently lost its movaon to connue the hesitant and paral reforms it started
four years earlier, especially in the enterprise sector. In May 2012, the government abolished
its previous privasaon plans and declared that new privasaon deals would take place on
ad hoc basis (EBRD, 2012, p. 101). By the end of 2012, however, the privasaon process had
been reversed, with two large enterprises that had been previously privased being taken over
by the state (EBRD, 2013). Belarusian authories boosted the pracce of wide-scale support for
internal demand through the increase of salaries and the massive emission of credits to SOEs.
Unl 2011, the internal demand factor indeed helped the Belarusian economy to grow, but it led
to a rapid increase of imports and, as a consequence, to the increasing current account decit
(up to 15% of GDP in 2010) and inaon, which skyrocketed to 53-59% in 2011-2012 (Figure
2). Together with the xed exchange rate policy, it created the grounds for the series of nancial
crises in 2009-2015, which eventually led to stagnaon and even recession in 2015 – for the
rst me since 1995. An important role was also played by external condions, for example, the
falling prices of major Belarusian export commodies, and the stagnaon of the economy of its
major trade partner: Russia.
The reacon of the authories to these crises was the successive devaluaon of the naonal
currency (by 25% in 2009, 56% in 2011 and 36% in 2015), which was aimed at smulang
exports and avoiding the depleon of internaonal reserves, and was accompanied by some
austerity measures such as the temporary ghtening of scal policy and liming the growth of
salaries. However, between the crises, the government kept returning to its previous pracce of
emission lending and forced wage increases (EBRD, 2009; World Bank, 2012; Naviny.by, 2015).
In 2015, when the Belarusian economy faced a recession, high macroeconomic disbalance,
stagnaon in main export markets, a connuous reducon of Russian energy subsidies and sev-
eral failed aempts to re-launch economic growth, it became obvious to the government that
such pracces were no longer sustainable and that a more substanal revision of its economic
policy towards one that was more market-oriented was imminent.
16
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Figure 2. Inaon, current account balance and GDP growth in Belarus, 2007-2015
1,0
1,5
2,0
2,5
3,0
3,5
4,0
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
EBRD transition score
BELARUS
ESTONIA
LATVIA
LITHUANIA
POLAND
RUSSIAN
FEDERATION
UKRAINE
-20
-10
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
Percent
Inflation (annual %)
Current account balance (% of GDP)
GDP growth (annual %)
Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) Database.
3.3. Towards stability based on market mechanisms (since 2015)
The major change to Belarusian economic policy occurred in 2015 with the government’s re-
fusal to smulate GDP growth at any cost. The government began to priorise macroeconomic
stability over increases in output and wages. The Council of Ministers appointed at the end of
December 2014, as well as their successors appointed in August 2018, included several mod-
erate reformers with liberal views. They immediately ghtened monetary policy in order to re-
duce inaon. The Naonal Bank increased the interest rate well beyond the inaon level. In
2015, for the rst me in the history of independent Belarus, the Naonal Bank liberalised the
exchange rate regime and refrained from intervenons in the market. A exible exchange rate
ended the persistent problem of the depleon of foreign currency reserves, which had previ-
ously resulted in shock devaluaons (Alachnovič, 2015).
Another important decision was reducing credit to the naonal economy (Figure 3). Howev-
er, the structure of the credit supply remained almost unchanged. The government connued to
support mainly SOEs in construcon, industry and services through state-controlled commercial
banks. But the volume of this lending decreased by one-third. Aer 2014, the government con-
17
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
nued to reduce its support to state-owned farms, as the loans to the agricultural sector proved
to be the most inecient (World Bank, 2018, p. 23).
Figure 3. Credit supply to the economy: growth and sectorial composion, 2006-2016
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
percent
Agriculture, percent of bank credit
Construction, percent of bank credit
Industry, percent of bank credit
Services, percent of bank credit
Bank credit to economy, percent of GDP
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Real estate
Retail
Other services
Information and communication
Accomodation and catering
Professional and technical services
Administrative services
Finance
Industry
Culture, recreation and sport
Transportation and storage
Construction
Agriculture, fishery and forestry
Water supply and waste management
Healthcare and social services
Education
Mining
Electricity and gas supply
Governance
Public
Domestic private
Foreign
Source: World Bank, 2018.
These measures allowed for the stabilisaon of the naonal currency and the reducon of
inaon from 18.1% in 2014 to 4.3% in 2018. However, the decrease in inaon was coupled
with stagnaon in real wages and quite anaemic economic growth. The external debt accu-
mulated in previous years reached 73.4% of GDP in 2017 and generates a constant need to
renance it (EBRD, 2018)
In order to stabilise public nances, Belarusian authories undertook several unpopular mea-
sures. In 2016, the authories increased household taris for the supply of water, electricity and
heang considerably and made a commitment to phase out all subsidies to communal services
for households by 2019. Another unpopular measure aimed at balancing public nances was the
increase of the rerement age for men from 60 to 63 and for women from 55 to 58 by 2023.
Austerity measures were combined with some liberalisaon steps. In January 2016, the gov-
ernment abolished price controls on socially important goods and eliminated volume output tar-
gets for SOEs (EBRD, 2016). In 2017, a favourable taxaon and regulaon regime was created
for IT rms and supporng services (EBRD, 2018).
18
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Decreasing state support of SOEs negavely aected their funconing and caused their em-
ployees to search for beer salaries in the private sector, mainly private SMEs. This inclined the
government to start perceiving SMEs as the main absorber of the released labour force and to
liberalise the regulatory environment for them (Sekhovich, 2018, p. 262). In 2017, the authori-
es radically reduced the formalies needed to open a business in 18 industries (e.g. retail, hotel
and tourist businesses and catering). However, in the opinion of business, the credibility of the
liberalisaon iniaves was undermined by the iniaon of criminal cases against several well-
known businessmen accused of corrupon and tax avoidance (Sekhovich, 2018, p. 263).
At the same me, the Belarusian authories demonstrated no interest in decreasing the
share of the state sector and reducing the role of big enterprises. Unlike in 2011, no plans of
privasaon were declared. The polical elites are sll trying to keep the economy under their
‘manual control’.
As before, economic policy measures were accompanied by aempts to gain as many Rus-
sian energy preferences as possible. The Belarusian government engaged in intensied disputes
with Russia over the price of gas and crude oil with rather unsasfactory results (Zajac, 2016;
World Bank, 2017; Stepanova, 2018). Eventually, Belarus managed to preserve a certain level
of preferenal treatment, but it became obvious that this resource for the Belarusian economy
had lost its importance: rst, because of the diminishing polical will of Russia to subsidise their
neighbour’s economy and second, because the economic base for such treatment has been
shrinking since 2015, as Russia has gradually increased oil prices in the domesc market in an
aempt to make oil trade more transparent and increase tax revenues. The President of Belarus
declared this policy will incur the economy of Belarus losses equal to USD 10.6 billion (Belta,
2019a).
There are also other factors which decrease the aracveness of Russia for the Belarusian
authories. First, due to stagnaon in the Russian market, it cannot absorb as many Belarusian
goods as before. Furthermore, Russia is becoming more and more insistent about full integraon
between the two states, which in fact would mean the incorporaon of Belarus by Russia – and
President Lukashenko strongly opposes this perspecve (Belta, 2019b). In this situaon, the
condions for obtaining Russian support become polically inacceptable.
It may be argued that this reversal of the role of Russia from a source of hope to a source
of threat is addional movaon for the Belarusian government to move towards cauous but
pro-market reforms.
19
4.1. How big is the state? The share of the public sector in the Belarusian
economy
A real assessment of the private sector’s role in the Belarusian economy is extremely dicult.
Ocial stascs do not allow for drawing clear boundaries between the private and the state-
owned sectors. According to the Naonal Stascal Oce (Belstat), only communal or state
unitary enterprises (unitarnoye predpriyae)7 belong to the public sector. At the same me, Bel-
stat classies all joint stock companies as private, even those where the state remains the only
shareholder. State-controlled joint stock companies are very common in Belarus, with truck fac-
tory MAZ or MTZ tractor plant being the most prominent examples.
This leads to signicant discrepancies in esmaons of the size of the Belarusian state sec-
tor. According to the EBRD (2015), it remains one of the largest among all post-communist
countries: about 70% of Belarusian GDP. At the same me, Belstat argues that the Belarusian
economy is mostly private8: in 2017, only 27.5% of the naonal value added was generated by
communal and state unitary enterprises, whereas an addional 18.5% was produced by the cor-
poraons where the state controlled over 50% of the shares.
The real role of the state in the enterprise sector may be even bigger than the EBRD esma-
ons. First, there are many opportunies for state authories to intervene in or assume control
of enterprises. Second, there are strong doubts about the independence of many formally purely
private companies subordinated to Belarusian state instuons which signicantly restrict the
property rights of the owners. Within the bundle of rights (Alchian and Demsetz, 1973), the
authority to use property is most commonly violated. Good examples of such enterprises are
Amkodor JSC, a large producer of road building, municipal and forestry equipment and Milavitsa
JSC, the biggest Belarusian lingerie producer. Both of these companies are privately owned.
However, they have to report to the state authories the results of their business acvity and
follow government guidelines to meet the goals set by the state authories. Amkodor JSC is
directly subordinated to the Ministry of Industry, whereas Milavitsa JSC, alongside 85 other
private and state-owned enterprises, belongs to the Bellegprom state consorum. In pracce, it
7 According to Art. 113 of the Belarusian Civil Code, a unitary enterprise is a business enty which has no ownership
rights to the assets it uses in operaons. It is a very common form of enterprise which operates state or municipal
property.
8 Data provided on the authors’ request.
4. State sector in Belarus:
Data and analysis
20
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
means that the government may impose on these companies output volume, prices, salary levels
and other indicators.
In our study, the noon of state-owned enterprise, state-controlled enterprise or simply
state enterprise refers to an enterprise of any legal form where the signicant share of assets
remains in the hands of the state or municipality and where the managers are heavily controlled
by public authories. One needs to keep in mind that Belarusian authories exercise a dispro-
poronally strong power over the enterprises where they have only minority stakes, which is
leveraged mainly by the reporng requirements towards the relevant branch ministry and the
right of the state shareholder to interfere in the business decisions of the companies. Therefore,
in Figure 4, all enterprises having public authories among their shareholders are considered as
state controlled.
Figure 4. Share of gross value added produced by the public sector in various economic acvies, 2017
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
percent
Agriculture, percent of bank credit
Construction, percent of bank credit
Industry, percent of bank credit
Services, percent of bank credit
Bank credit to economy, percent of GDP
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Real estate
Retail
Other services
Information and communication
Accomodation and catering
Professional and technical services
Administrative services
Finance
Industry
Culture, recreation and sport
Transportation and storage
Construction
Agriculture, fishery and forestry
Water supply and waste management
Healthcare and social services
Education
Mining
Electricity and gas supply
Governance
Public
Domestic private
Foreign
Source: Belstat, own calculaons.
21
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Based on Belstat data, one may conclude that the state sector in Belarus produces over 48%
of the gross value added and employs over 57% of the labour force, which seems to be a quite
conservave esmaon because according to another study (Akulova, 2015), the state sector
may produce 74-75% of the total producon volume and employ up to 69-82% of the work-
force. SOEs dominate in industry, mining, construcon, transportaon and agriculture. They
form vercally integrated corporaons composed of a big enterprise assembling nal products
and a multude of smaller units producing intermediate goods. This type of structure allows
loss-making enterprises to avoid bankruptcy by aaching them to more ecient producers
(World Bank, 2012, p. 43-44). Among SOEs, big rms prevail. For instance, an average industrial
SOE in Belarus employs 525 workers, while a private enterprise in industry – only 28 (Belstat,
2018b, p. 37).
In a developed market economy, an SOE usually has objecves other than just prot gen-
eraon for its owner and it pursues a general goal of maximising value for society through an
ecient allocaon of resources (OECD, 2015). In Belarus, the funcons of SOEs are set even
wider and include the direct provision of social services regardless their main area of operaon.
Like in Soviet mes, SOEs maintain hospitals, childcare and sport facilies, and even restaurants
and museums (Ehrke, Shymanovich and Kirchner, 2014, p. 11).
Therefore, the Belarusian economy is no longer just a simple copy of the Soviet economic
system. The private sector produces a substanal part of Belarusian GDP, although its distri-
buon across sectors of the economy is highly uneven. Such an ownership structure of the
economy is a clear result of delayed privasaon and the discriminave policies applied to the
private sector. Belarusian authories have managed to keep control over the overwhelming
majority of ‘old’ enterprises inherited from the Soviet period. This dominaon of state owner-
ship in industry, construcon and transport, combined with hundreds of thousands of people
employed in public administraon, state-owned educaon and the healthcare system, allowed
the government to keep direct economic and polical control over the majority of populaon.
Private enterprises, in their turn, had to develop in new niches, which emerged aer the fall of
communism and were not occupied by Soviet industrial giants. Private business has also taken
control of the few spheres from which the state has withdrawn, most probably, due to high
control and maintenance costs (e.g. road transport and retail). Private rms, which are predomi-
nantly domesc, are mainly concentrated in services and the informaon industry – e.g. in retail,
public catering, consulng, adversing and computer programming (Pelipas et al., 2014, p. 49).
Foreign direct investments (FDI) form just a ny part of the Belarusian economy: foreign-
owned companies contribute merely 3.5% of the gross value added. According to Naonal Bank
of Belarus data9, by the end of 2018, the total amount of FDI was only USD 13.1 billon. The
biggest foreign investor in Belarus is Russia (USD 4.0 billion, 30.1% of total FDI) and the second
biggest investor is Cyprus (USD 2.3 billion, 17.6%). Taking into account that Cyprus is widely
used as an o-shore investment plaorm for Russia (Repousis, Lois, and Kougioumtsidis, 2019)
and other former Soviet republics including Belarus (Sidoruk, 2017), Cyprian investments may
9 hp://www.nbrb.by/stascs/foreigndirecnvestments.
22
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
largely be of Russian descent with many of them simply domesc investments that have taken
a round trip for tax avoidance purposes. The highest shares of foreign-owned companies (Figure
4) are found in IT and communicaon (Belarus became popular for outsourcing IT services for
European countries) and retail, with big chain stores entering the Belarusian market, whereas
the highest volume of FDI was directed to industry (40.1% of the whole FDI inow) (Mukha,
2019).
4.2. Away from the command economy? The evolution of the public
sector since 2007
SOEs sll dominate in the Belarusian economy; however, since the beginning of the 1990s, their
share in the economy has slowly but constantly declined. In the last decade, this process has
taken a new dynamic. According to ocial data, the contribuons of SOEs to the value added
declined from 61.4% in 2007 to 48.1% in 2017 while employment in the public sector fell from
68.3% to 57.7% during the same period. The most signicant ‘losses’ occurred in construcon
– one of the sectors with the highest presence of the state. The contribuon of state-owned
construcon enterprises to GDP contracted almost by half (both in relave and absolute terms),
while the number of employed decreased by one-third. It is important to note that the output of
state-owned construcon rms has shrunk much more than the output of private enterprises.
This faster decline of SOEs has allowed private business to increase its share from 35% to more
than 47% (Belstat, 2015, p. 332; Belstat, 2018a p. 323).
Very similar changes occurred in some branches of industry. The share of SOEs in the output
of the whole industrial sector has decreased only slightly: from 73.9% in 2011 to 70.4% in 2017.
At the same me, in the producon of vehicles and machine tools and in the woodwork industry,
the share of private rms has increased by more than 10 percentage points. It may signify that
private rms demonstrated higher eciency and resilience to the crisis caused by the decrease
of state support and stagnaon in the Russian market, which was the main desnaon for Be-
larusian exports (Belstat, 2016; Belstat, 2018b).
While the contribuon of state enes to the Belarusian economy since 2007 has evidently
shrunk, the contribuon of economic sectors dominated by private rms (retail, business ser-
vices and scienc acvies) has remained at least stable (see Figure 5). The IT sector even
managed to double its contribuon to GDP both in relave and absolute gures (although its
share is sll modest – about 5%).
23
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Figure 5. Employed by spheres of economic acvity (% of total)
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
Industry
Information and communication
Construction
Professional, scientific and technical activity
Retail
Source: Belstat.
Very interesng changes occurred in the biggest sector of the Belarusian economy controlled
by private rms, namely in retail. Since 2010, big enterprises have increased their share from
40% to 56% of the total turnover.
On the one hand, one may see a natural process of concentraon in retail. The big chain
stores are winning the compeon with smaller and less ecient shops. On the other hand,
such concentraon corresponds to the interests of the Belarusian authories. They do not see
SMEs as the backbone of the naonal economy and thus try to establish good relaons with
big private rms. The government already makes such aempts, giving more space to the larger
private domesc and foreign investors in food producon, machine building, transportaon,
retail and IT (Belarus.by, 2019).
For instance, the largest employer in Belarus is no longer a Soviet industrial giant, but the
private retail company Eurotorg LLC, which is registered in Cyprus. In 2015, it employed more
than 30 thousand people, while the biggest state-owned enterprise, Minsk truck factory MAZ,
employed 18.6 thousand (Probusiness.by, 2015). Other examples of private investors who man-
aged to ‘build into’ the centralised and state-regulated economy of Belarus are Stadler Rail AG
– a large Swiss manufacturer of trains which opened its factory near Minsk in 2014 (Yaroshev-
ich, 2016), and VMG Group – a Lithuanian woodwork company producing furniture for IKEA,
which opened its factory in Mogilev in 2013 (Melekhovets, 2018). Since the beginning of the
24
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
2010s, the Belarusian government has made substanal eorts to aract Chinese investors to
the construcon, chemical, automove, energy, electronics and agriculture industries. However,
the results are yet to come (Manionok, 2018).
If the ocial gures are correct, the share of the private sector in Belarus in the last decade
is growing mainly due to the expansion of big domesc and foreign companies. One can draw
such a conclusion from the fact that the share of (predominantly private) SMEs in employment
remains unchanged since 2009, while the share of the public sector in employment is declining.
In 2011, almost 63% of all employed were working in the public sector, whereas in 2017, this
share decreased to 57.7% (Belstat, 2018a). A simple economic structure based on large private
enterprises may be considered by state authories as the ideal soluon, allowing for the reduc-
on of subsidies to whole sectors and keeping businesses under polical control. For the gov-
ernment, it is much easier to deal with several big players, even those of foreign descent, than
with a large number of small private businesses.
As it has already been menoned, the inuence of the state authories over the Belarusian
economy is not related to the share of the state sector alone. It is also related to the wrien and
unwrien rules of the game imposed by the state, which restrict the private sector and give the
advantage to SOEs. How Belarusian authories manage SOEs and ensure their dominaon in
the naonal economy will be described in the next secon.
25
5.1. Ownership function of the state
According to Belstat (2019) data, Belarusian authories exercise ownership of over 14.3 thou-
sand enterprises (p. 34). As it has already been menoned, the legal form of SOEs in Belarus is
either a unitary enterprise, which operates the assets belonging to local or central authories, or
a joint stock company, which has public authories among its shareholders. The State exercises
its ownership funcon according to a decentralised model (Vagliasindi, 2008). This means that
SOEs in Belarus are not placed under the responsibility of one body but rather under several
enes: relevant sectoral ministries, government commiees and local authories. Their own-
ership funcons are not separated from management funcons and are mixed with regulatory
funcons. The government and local execuves perform ownership funcons, inuence pro-
ducon process and have the power to modify the regulatory environment where SOEs operate
(Avtushko-Sikorskii, Burak, and Miroshnichenko, 2016, p. 29).
De jure, the main owner of state assets in Belarus is the governmental State Property Com-
miee (SPC). In pracce, ownership funcons are given to nine ministries (e.g. the Ministry of
Transportaon, Ministry of Healthcare, Ministry of Transport and Ministry of Communicaon,
among others.) as well as to regional and local execuves (Avtushko-Sikorskii et. al., 2016, p. 21).
Other managers of state assets are ve state consorums the origins of which can be traced
back to the ‘branch ministries’ of Soviet mes (Lavnikevich, 2015). Each consorum unites sev-
eral dozen large enterprises from ve dierent industries: petrochemicals, light industry, food,
mber and woodworking, as well as wholesale trade. State consorums do not have the status
of ministries but perform very similar funcons. They have an impact on economic policy, issue
legal acts and help to achieve the economic targets established by the government. The mem-
bership of private enterprises in state consorums is not obligatory, but state authories oen
force private companies to join (Avtushko-Sikorskii et al., 2016, p. 20).
In the last decade, the Belarusian government has established a second, lower level of this
ownership hierarchy. Since 2010, it has gathered about 800 SOEs into 102 state holdings (Min-
istry of Economy of the Republic of Belarus, 2016). The goal was to decrease the number of
enes under the direct supervision of the government (the SPC) and facilitate the process of
property management. The authories also wanted to improve the nancial condions of the
loss-making enterprises by aaching them to more protable enes. Avtushko-Sikorskii et al.
(2016, p.33) point out that by concentrang SOEs in state holdings, the authories expanded
5. Written and unwritten rules:
The state as a main actor in the
Belarusian economy
26
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
the management pracces previously used in state consorums onto the broader range of en-
terprises.
The managers of unitary enterprises are appointed directly by government bodies or local
authories. The system of appointment in the biggest state-controlled joint stock companies
is not very dierent. The funcons of the board of directors in the majority of such companies
have been signicantly constrained by the regulaons issued by the ministries and state con-
sorums. They do not act as independent supervisory and managing bodies, but as a channel to
receive government instrucons. Therefore, the boards of the majority of the state-controlled
joint stock companies have been abolished and supervision over these enterprises has been
transferred directly to government bodies (Avtushko-Sikorskii et al., 2016, p. 37).
5.2. State planning system
One of the fundamental features of the Belarusian economic model is the planning of economic
acvity by state authories. Every ve years, the Council of Ministers adopt long-term (15-
year) and mid-term (5-year) plans for the social and economic development of the country. All
economic development plan are prepared by the Ministry of Economy in cooperaon with the
Ministry of Finance, the Naonal Bank, other ministries and state consorums.
The Naonal Strategies designed for 15 years establish general priories in economic and
social development. Despite their long-term character, these documents provide detailed in-
formaon about the goals which the government expects to achieve in social, economic, eco-
logical and regional policies. For instance, the Naonal Strategy for the years 2015-2030 in its
chapter on the economy describes the industries the state will promote (such as IT, high-tech
and export-oriented industries). It provides targets for each industry (such as output growth,
producvity of labour and export growth, among others) and describes the way in which these
targets will be achieved. More precisely, the strategy species the investment projects, produc-
on pracces and policy reforms which are expected to bring success (Ministry of Economy of
the Republic of Belarus, 2014. p. 45-69).
The ve-year plan for social and economic development is very similar to the long-term plan.
It sets economic targets (GDP growth, export growth, increases in the producvity of labour,
xed capital investments and populaon income, among others) and species the policy reforms
and projects to be implemented on a mid-term perspecve (President of the Republic of Belarus,
2016). On the basis of this document, the Council of Ministers dras an Acon Plan which con-
tains a long list of precise measures to be implemented in each aspect of social and economic
policy. This Acon Plan includes dozens of quantave indicators the government expects to
achieve (Council of Ministers of the Republic of Belarus, 2017).
Finally, each year, the President of Belarus by his decree approves a Prognosis of Social and
Economic Development containing several growth targets (in such areas as GDP and exports,
populaon income, inaon and FDI, among others). Basing on these indicators, the govern-
ment composes ‘a comprehensive list of targets in nancial and export acvies’ (President
27
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
of the Republic of Belarus, 2018). It is important to note that in recent years this list has been
reduced from 19 to 7 goals. Meeng these targets is obligatory for all SOEs, rms parcipang
in state consorums and especially for the group of ‘GDP-forming enterprises’. The laer group
includes approximately 100 of the largest state-owned Belarusian rms. They are named on
the list of enterprises where the implementaon of state plans is ‘a subject of the government’s
special control’ (Council of Ministers of the Republic of Belarus, 2005). Such parcular aen-
on to these enterprises results from the fact that they produce more than half of the country’s
industrial output (Zayats, 2010). In fact, these ‘naonal champions’ are the key element of the
economic planning system. They are the main agents implemenng the government’s plans and
the achievement of the targets specied in these plans is impossible without them.
On the basis of the prognoses adopted by the government, all SOEs are obliged to dra
their own development plans for both ve- and one-year perspecves. The plans of the ‘GDP-
forming enterprises’ must pass through a long line of approvals. They are consulted and adopted
by the heads of regional (oblast) administraons, state consorums’ boards of directors and
ministries (Council of Ministers of the Republic of Belarus, 2005). The implementaon of these
plans is supervised by the Ministry of Economy and the heads of the state consorums (Council
of Ministers of the Republic of Belarus, 2004).
The performance of other non-‘GDP-forming’ state enterprises is supervised by lower level
authories. However, this does not mean that they have more freedom in their economic ac-
vity. Economic development plans draed by ‘ordinary’ companies with state parcipaon
(though not necessarily with majority state stock) are consulted and adopted by the execuves
of rayons (districts) – administrave units of the lowest level (Vitebsk District Execuve Com-
miee, 2007). The implementaon of these plans is supervised by the vice-heads of the oblast
(region) administraon who are responsible for economic maers and by their analogues on
a district level (Vitebsk Regional Execuve Commiee, 2005).
Belarusian law clearly states that if a state enterprise fails to achieve its expected targets,
its director should be ‘brought to administrave responsibility’ and the ‘irregularies’ should be
immediately corrected (Council of Ministers of the Republic of Belarus, 2005). Failure in plan
implementaon can have negave consequences for state ocials on all levels. Final responsi-
bility for the realisaon of the Prognosis of Economic Development is the Prime Minister. Every
four months he reports to the President regarding the fullment of indicators provided in the
state plan (Zlotnikov, 2009, p. 72).
Such a rigid planning system makes it harder for these enterprises to adjust to the changing
economic environment, especially in mes of crises. Unl recently, they had to meet output
targets and maintain producon levels even when demand was falling. This resulted in growing
stocks of unsold goods. State plans also require SOEs to increase salaries even when producv-
ity stagnates, waste money on unnecessary equipment to meet investment targets, and retain
excessive labour force because it is forbidden to worsen employment stascs (Zayats, 2010).
However, the recent economic problems have caused the authories to reduce the list of eco-
nomic targets and start looking at ways to make enterprises more exible.
28
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
5.3. Discrimination of the private sector: Subsidies, trade protectionism
and formal and informal barriers
The state in Belarus remains the main source of income for the majority of the populaon. To
start with, it pays salaries to those working for the public sector, which is nearly 60% of total
employment. Addionally, state contracts provide revenues for a large part of private rms, and
the policy of public authories strongly inuences the protability of the rest. It is the state
which denes the rules of the game in the Belarusian economy; the private sector is clearly
subordinated to the state-owned sector. Such dominaon is ensured due to the system of legal
and extra-legal barriers protecng the Belarusian public sector from domesc and foreign com-
petors.
The condions established by the state authories for private business signicantly dier
from the condions for SOEs. The majority of private enterprises work under hard budget con-
straints, i.e. the state does not bail them out or support them in another way if they incur losses.
State enterprises, in contrast, benet from various types of support and do not have to t into
hard budget frameworks (Yegorov, 2013. p. 78; Ehrke et al., 2014, p. 3).
As it has already been menoned, subsidised credits given by state-owned commercial banks
are the main instrument to support loss-making enterprises in Belarus. The adverse eect of the
cheap money given to SOEs is the expensive credit given to the private sector. The banks try to
compensate for the losses produced from supporng state companies by increasing the price of
loans to private rms (Yegorov, 2013, p. 78).
The toolkit for state aid is much larger than simple nancial support. As Valery Yanchuk
(2007) explains, state support may take the form of tax exempons, the sale of raw materials
and energy at reduced prices, the refund or remission of debt, the leasing of equipment at pref-
erenal terms and preferenal treatment during parcipaon in public procurement contracts,
among others (p. 60). Private enterprises are deprived of all these benets.
A very powerful tool helping the state to keep private enterprises out of the market is the rig-
id vercal integraon of SOEs and the non-market exchange among them. For instance, state-
owned farms are obliged to sell almost all their products to food processing SOEs at very low
prices set by the government. As a result, these farms do not receive enough funds for develop-
ment and become enrely dependent on state support (Babitski, 2003, p. 692). On the other
hand, the low prices of the raw materials smulate food-processing enterprises, many of which
sell their products abroad and receive high export revenues (Yegorov, 2013, p. 79). Therefore,
food processing SOEs have no need to buy more expensive products from private farms. As
a result, private farms have very lile space to develop. The situaon of private food-processing
enterprises is not much beer because they can hardly compete with SOEs beneng from
cheap raw materials. This discriminatory pricing policy is widespread in other export sectors, e.g.
in the machine building industry (Yegorov, 2013, p. 79).
However, the state authories do not always reward successful ‘naonal champions’ with
generous state aid. The SOEs the government considers as ‘highly protable’ have to pay an ad-
dional lump sum payment to the Naonal Development Fund. Such a policy discourages SOEs
29
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
from undertaking potenally promising acvies. State giants are afraid to nd themselves in
the category of ‘highly protable’ and bear addional costs instead of making prots (Ehrke et
al., 2014, p. 20).
This policy of prot redistribuon does not only help to ensure the dominance of SOEs, but it
produces a chronic illness of the Belarusian economic system: high shares of loss-making enter-
prises and enterprises with low protability (Pyko, 2007, p. 22). About 50% of all enterprises in
Belarus have negave or low (less than 5%) protability of sales. This gure has remained stable
since the beginning of the 2000s (Yegorov, 2013. p. 79).
The government ensures the dominance of SOEs on the Belarusian market not only through
generous subsidies and prot redistribuon, but also through trade proteconism. The volume
of imports to Belarus is regulated by the decisions of the Council of Ministers and Presidenal
decrees. The President regularly orders domesc enterprises to replace imported goods with
domescally produced ones. Each year, the government approves a long list of ‘import subs-
tung goods’. The Council of Ministers gives tax breaks to the Belarusian enterprises producing
these goods and prevents foreign analogues from coming to the Belarusian market (Daneyko,
2012; Akulich, 2013).
The Belarusian market remains dicult to penetrate even for products from Russia and other
members of the Eurasian Economic Union (EEU). Due to the Customs Union exisng within
the EEU, Belarus cannot set high taris on imports from Russia and other EEU member states.
Therefore, the Belarusian government has to regulate the volume of imported goods by admin-
istrave measures. Among the greatest obstacles on the Belarusian market, the Russian Ministry
of Economic Development (2019) menons the Presidenal edicts and the government’s deci-
sions obliging SOEs to buy only domesc agricultural equipment, trucks and buses. The ‘prod-
uct range lists’ issued by the Council of Ministers of Belarus oblige shops, supermarkets and
restaurants to sell a ‘minimal number’ of domesc brands. These lists include all kind of goods
produced in Belarus – from dairy products to texles and electronics. A similar measure is intro-
duced in the pharmacy branch. Imports of popular consumer goods such as alcohol and tobacco
are reserved to several dozens of rms annually appointed by the President.
It is important to note that some of the powerful tools to apply pressure on the private sector
cannot be found in the ocial laws and regulaons. Recent studies of Belarusian SMEs (Papko,
2017b) have shown that Belarusian authories have developed a broad set of informal ways to
extract resources from private rms and control the expansion of the private sector:
1) scal and criminal repressions;
2) forced corporate responsibility;
3) restricng market access;
4) abuse of property rights.
Regarding scal and criminal repressions, this occurs when local authories and state agencies
rounely use real or alleged violaons of the complex regulaons to blackmail private enter-
prises and extract resources from them. Regular nes imposed on SMEs perform the funcon of
informal taxes (Papko, 2017b, p. 112). Owners of large enterprises oen face criminal prosecu-
on on tax avoidance charges. Belarusian experts point out that the persecuon of big business
30
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
increases in mes of crises. In such a way, state authories punish those who are reluctant to
provide resources to the state. Repressions also help to discipline others and make them more
‘cooperave’ (Smok, 2017). These pracces aimed at entrepreneurs are not hard tasks because
the exaggerated legal requirements make full compliance virtually impossible, which exposes
rms to pressure from law enforcement bodies and inspecons.
Forced corporate responsibility is another extracve pracce, namely, forcing private enter-
prises to nance or directly implement public projects. Afraid of sancons, private enterprises
provide public authories with unpaid goods and services. They must nance the construc-
on of public facilies such as schools, hospitals, stadiums and roads and they are required to
sponsor cultural and sports events or support loss-making enterprises – for example, collecve
farms. As one of the richest Belarusian entrepreneurs has recently confessed, ‘If you want to
develop your business, once asked, you will build an ice hockey arena’ (Marcinovič, 2015). This
forced corporate responsibility results from the insucient amount of resources that local au-
thories have at their disposal as well as from the authoritarian tradions of the post-Soviet
administrave apparatus. If local authories do not have enough resources for the realisaon of
their tasks, they perceive taking these resources from SMEs as fully legimate.
Restricng market access to private companies began with the aempts of public authories
to support local SOEs. The authories may ban ‘outsider’ private enterprises from entering the
local market. Local private rms compeng with SOEs may be removed from the market under
the pretext of non-compliance with technical standards or sanitary requirements. Local authori-
es may informally forbid both private and state-owned shops to buy products from other re-
gions. These monopolisc pracces are especially visible in rural areas where there are much
fewer jobs than in cies (Papko, 2017b, p. 116).
Abuse of property rights also hampers the development of private enterprises. State bodies
may conscate the property of private rms and/or put them under the control of state ocials
(Papko, 2017b, p. 114). Since 2010, the Belarusian media has menoned at least seven cases
where large enterprises were taken over by the state (Loyko and Zayats, 2018). In the majority of
these cases, the government or President issued legal acts under various pretexts that suspend-
ed the managing and supervisory boards of the enterprises. This happened even to companies
where the state had no shares at all. Aer appoinng new managers, the authories iniated
the issue of stock which allowed them to buy the controlling stake. Filing a lawsuit to the court
by the shareholders had lile eect, because the judges were always taking the side of the gov-
ernment (Loyko and Zayats, 2018). The courts cannot ensure the protecon of private property
rights against the state because they are not independent: judges at all levels are appointed and
revoked by the President and their decisions are highly inuenced by the execuve power.
5.4. Interests in relationships between the state and enterprises
Although state ocials in Belarus have vast power over economic agents, relaons between
them are not permeated by corrupon and rent-seeking, as can be seen in many other post-
31
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
communist countries, including those which were regarded as transformaon leaders, e.g. Po-
land and Hungary (Bałtowski et al., 2020). The study performed by Papko (2017a) shows that
the majority of resources extracted from businesses do not go into state ocials’ pockets. This
does not mean that patron-client relaonships do not exist; they are just of a quite unique kind.
From the governmental side, they are largely fuelled not by the private interests (especially -
nancial) of bureaucrats, but by their search for resources for the realisaon of the goals dened
by the state.
This precondions, rst, the selecve approach towards enterprises of dierent resource-
extracng potenals, which makes larger enterprises more aracve as clients of the state au-
thories. Second, the relaonships of dierent levels of the state apparatus with enterprises are
dierent. Two paerns can be idened here.
The rst paern covers the relaonships between local authories and SMEs. Their re-
source-extracng potenal is limited, so they do not aract the aenon of the central level of
the state administraon. But for the local administraon, SMEs are sll aracve and are used
as a milking cow to obtain resources for implemenng the socioeconomic policy of the govern-
ment. The peculiarity of this paern is that it is seldom based on patron-client relaonships.
Local authories use every pretext to extract resources from SMEs, mainly through repressions
such as nes (or threats to impose nes), giving nothing in return. Local bureaucrats usually re-
frain from breaching the law if they are asked to give favours to entrepreneurs because they are
ghtly controlled and may easily become the subject of a criminal prosecuon. It is very impor-
tant to note that in Belarus, contacts with state ocials are a necessary but not sucient condi-
on for business success. Indeed, the entrepreneurs who want to expand their business have to
enter into cooperaon with local authories and provide them with the resources they request.
However, local authories almost never give them a monopolisc posion on the market. Even
in exchange for regular extracon, these ‘cooperave’ SMEs do not receive enough protecon.
Moreover, local authories are just not able to guarantee protecon in case of serious problems
with law enforcement.
The second paern describes the relaonships of bureaucrats with large rms. This is the
domain of the central authories that are interested in relaonships with big business only, but
there are also many more possibilies (and much greater will) to reciprocate than with local bu-
reaucrats. If a rm managed to grow under the condions of regular extracon, it has a chance
to enter into a long-term benecial relaonship with the central government. The government
gives large companies signicant preferences in exchange for regular ‘help’ and the realisaon
of ‘socially important projects’. Pavel Topuzidis, one of the richest entrepreneurs in Belarus, is
the unique representave of big business who openly admits having such kind of relaons with
Belarusian authories (Marcinovič, 2015). The core of his business is the Tabak-Invest company
– one of the two rms producing cigarees in the country and the only private tobacco producer
in Belarus.
But the examples of big private rms beneng from a monopolisc posion and having
special relaons with state authories are much more numerous (Sekhovich, 2019). A private
Swiss company, Stadler, the only train producer in Belarus, was allowed to enter the Belaru-
32
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
sian market under the condion that it would bail out Belkommunmash JSC a state-owned
manufacturer of trolleybuses. President Lukashenko demanded Stadler invest in its modernisa-
on and produce trains in cooperaon with this company (TUT.BY, 2014). Mikhail Gutseriyev
– a Russian businessman who was given the right to build the only private potash mining com-
pany in Belarus, invested about USD 350 million in ‘socially important’ infrastructure projects.
His companies have built a terminal in the Minsk airport, a luxury hotel, a school in the capital,
a church and residenal houses in the Minsk region, and even a residence used by President
Lukashenko (TUT.BY, 2017).
Nevertheless, even proximity to power does not guarantee that benecial relaons will last
forever. A clear example would be the prosecuon of Yury Chyzh – one of the richest entrepre-
neurs in the country and a member of Alexander Lukashenko’s inner circle. Chyzh, who owned
a large construcon company which also helped to realise state projects, was arrested in 2016
under tax avoidance charges. Even aer repaying the damages and being pardoned by Alexan-
der Lukashenko, he never returned to the upper posions of Belarus’ richest people rankings
(Sekhovich, 2019).
All this represents a very interesng case of state-organised informality. It was borne neither
from the iniave of private actors nor from individual state ocials. It originates from the
specicity of the Belarusian economy, based on intervenonism with weak formal enforcement
mechanisms, where in order for the system to funcon, wrien rules must be supplemented
with unwrien ones.
33
During the last decade, the Belarusian economy has evolved from a quasi-Soviet system with
strong state planning, generous support to inecient enterprises and the massive redistribuon
of funds within and across the sectors, to a more exible model where the public sector sll
remains the core of the economy. Several tendencies have become parcularly visible in the last
decade.
The rst one is towards the reducon of subsidies, deregulaon and aempts to make the
state sector more ecient. The second one is the growing role of private enterprises, especially
in the new sectors which expanded aer the fall of communism and were not dominated by
SOEs (services, catering, IT). The share of private rms has also increased in some sectors se-
verely hit by the fall of demand on the domesc and Russian markets (construcon, woodwork
industry). Private enterprises proved to be more adapve to the changing economic condions.
The third tendency is the increasing concentraon of the emerging private sector. This sector
has not developed due to the expansion of SMEs, but due to the development of large private
rms. It seems that the government perceives the aracon of large private domesc capital as
a way to increase the eciency of the Belarusian economic system and preserve its ‘manage-
ability’ at the same me. State authories may give large private enterprises a monopolisc
posion on the market in exchange for prot sharing with the state (going far beyond ordinary
taxaon).
However, the state sector does not seem to lose its dominant posion in the economy in the
foreseeable future. The state has set a wide array of wrien and unwrien rules which secures
this dominaon through the means of a state planning and control system over the enre corpo-
rate sector and formal and informal discriminaon of the private sector. The laer is regarded by
authories not as a foundaon of the country’s economic development, but rather as a milking
cow which provides resources for the central and local governments.
The chances for large-scale market reforms in Belarus remain extremely low because the
Belarusian authoritarian regime does not want to lose control over the economy and populaon.
Privasaon and de-monopolisaon of the economy and the emergence of thousands of small
independent economic actors would extremely complicate the extracon and redistribuon of
resources. SOEs will remain the foundaon of the Belarusian economic system, although some
stabilisaon role may be given to a number of large private enterprises.
Regarding the second task of this paper – an aempt to nd the proper theorecal perspec-
ve to describe the Belarusian economy, at this stage of the research, we conclude that the
concept of state capitalism is only parally applicable to the Belarusian reality. First of all, we
6. Conclusions and discussion
34
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
must answer the queson of whether an economic system where the state dominates both in
the ownership structure and regulaon of economic acvity can be called capitalisc. At rst
glance, it does not, because the most popular denions of SC in the ‘broad sense’ assume that
the economic system is sll market based. In fact, the Belarusian government severely restricts
market mechanisms even in non-monopolised sectors and where private businesses dominate.
Furthermore, the state, being the largest owner, acts not as an entrepreneur, but rather as an
administrator who pursues mostly polical goals.
However, if we look at SC in the ‘narrow sense’ – as a set of features and specic policies
(as dened by Bałtowski et al., 2020), many of its manifestaons can be found in the Belarusian
economy. One can witness the policisaon of SOEs, their role being a source of resources to
be distributed for meeng polical goals. The policisaon of SOEs à rebours is paramount, their
rents originate from their privileged posion set up by the state – although SOEs seem to play
a passive part here (unlike, e.g. in Poland – Kozarzewski and Bałtowski, 2017), being mainly an
object of the state’s economic populism acons. The laer seems to be one of the cornerstones
of Belarusian economic policy, with the authories trying to create the widest possible clien-
telist base. At least at the discourse level, economic naonalism is clearly visible as noons of
a strong and independent economy and a state that supports local producers. Cronyism exists
in the case of the (not numerous) big private companies which enter ‘mutually benecial’ rela-
onships with public authories. One should note however the peculiar character of rents and
rent-seeking in Belarus compared to other countries which manifest elements of state capital-
ism: due to the limited scale of outright corrupon, rents in Belarus are also limited in form and
scope, seldom leading to substanal personal enrichment. Basically, only one feature – oligarchy
– is virtually non-existent in Belarus (but it also does not exist e.g. in Poland which clearly heads
towards state capitalism). Besides, all the tools of state capitalism described by Bałtowski and al.
(2020) are present in Belarus.
It seems that this apparent contradicon between the lack of full-edged capitalism (i.e.
a market economy) in Belarus and the existence of numerous manifestaons of state capitalism
in this country may be resolved through dierent ways. One is further development of the SC
concept, maybe within the wider perspecve of the VoC approach. However, the fruiulness of
this way may depend on whether the Belarusian case is not unique and represents some pat-
tern found in other countries as well – and this requires further invesgaon. Another possible
soluon is to apply a muldisciplinary approach which takes into account the duality of the Be-
larusian economy, where market mechanisms and instuons exist but are not the core of the
system. In this case, the state capitalism perspecve would be used only as one of several tools
of analysis, together with other perspecves which have yet to be chosen, e.g. those dealing
with resource-based and redistribuve economies. Theories of hybrid regimes (Wintrobe, 2018)
may be of help as well.
Another important direcon of further research (which will be facilitated by choosing the
appropriate theorecal perspecve discussed above) is idencaon of the main driving forces
of the Belarusian system, including those that ensure its high sustainability (regardless of all the
obvious aws) – because only paral explanaons exist so far.
35
Transliteraon of names and tles in the Belarusian language sources is based on the ocial
instrucon of the Belarusian government (State Commiee for Land Resources, Geodesy and
Cartography of the Republic of Belarus, 2000). It is the only comprehensive transliteraon sys-
tem of the Belarusian language advised for use in the UN.
Akulich, V. (2013), Prevram belarus’ v Shveytsariyu v Vostochnoy Evrope. Zapisi v bloge v period
2010-2012 gg. [How to transform Belarus into East European Switzerland. Arcles in the blog
from the years 2010-2012] (retrieved on November 9, 2015 from: hp://ekonomika.by/down-
loads/Akulich_papers_2010_2012.pdf).
Akulova, M. (2015), The role of Belarusian private sector, Forum for Research on Eastern Europe
and Emerging Economies (FREE), Stockholm Instute for Transion Economics (retrieved on
October 17, 2015 from: hps://freepolicybriefs.les.wordpress.com/2015/01/freepolicybrief_
jan19.pdf).
Alachnovič, A. (2015), Belarus nally reforms its economy? Belarus Digest, October 1 (retrieved
on February 11, 2019 from: hps://belarusdigest.com/story/belarus-nally-reforms-its-econo-
my/).
Alchian, A., and Demsetz, H. (1973), The property right paradigm, The Journal of Economic His-
tory, 33(1), pp. 16-27.
Amable, B. (2003), The diversity of modern capitalism, London: Oxford University Press.
Avtushko-Sikorskii, A., Burak, E., and Miroshnichenko, A. (2016), Mery, napravlennye na povysh-
enie eekvnos upravleniia gosudarstvennoi sobstvennosu [Measures to improve the eciency
of state property management], Belarusian Instute for Strategic Studies (BISS) (retrieved on
February 11, 2019 from: hp://reforms.solidarityby.eu/upload/182-1519651696.pdf).
Babitski, D. (2003), Sel’skokhozyaystvennye subsidii v Belarusi: analiz eekvnos i otsenka sootvet-
stviya trebovaniyam VTO [Agricultural subsidies in Belarus: eciency analysis and evaluaon of
References
36
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
compliance with the WTO requirements], Minsk: IPM Research Center (retrieved on November
20, 2015 from: hp://www.research.by/webroot/delivery/les/ecowest/2003n4r07.pdf).
Bałtowski, M., Kozarzewski, P., and Mickiewicz, T. (2020), State capitalism with populist char-
acteriscs: Poland and Hungary, in: Wright, M., Wood, G., Cuervo-Cazurra, A., Sun, P. Ilya
Okhmatovskiy, I., and Grosman, A. (eds), Oxford handbook on state capitalism and the rm, Oxford:
Oxford University Press (forthcoming).
Bekus, N. (2010), Struggle over identy: The ocial and the alternave ‘Belarusianness, Budapest-
New York: CEU Press.
Belarus.by (2019). Investsii v Belarusi [Investments in Belarus] (retrieved on February 11, 2019
from: hps://www.belarus.by/ru/business/belarus_investment).
Belstat (2015), Stascheskiy ezhegodnik 2015 [Stascal yearbook 2015], Minsk: Naonal Sta-
scal Oce of the Republic of Belarus.
Belstat (2016), Promyshlennost Respubliki Belarus, 2016 [Industry of the Republic of Belarus,
2018], Minsk: Naonal Stascal Oce of the Republic of Belarus.
Belstat (2018a), Stascheskiy ezhegodnik 2018 [Stascal yearbook 2018], Minsk: Naonal Sta-
scal Oce of the Republic of Belarus.
Belstat (2018b), Promyshlennost Respubliki Belarus, 2018 [Industry of the Republic of Belarus,
2018], Minsk: Naonal Stascal Oce of the Republic of Belarus.
Belstat (2019), Belarus v tsifrakh. Stascheskiy spravochnik [Belarus in Figures. Handbook of
Stascs], Minsk: Naonal Stascal Oce of the Republic of Belarus.
Belta (2019a), Lukashenko poruchil kompensirovat poteri iz-za nalogovogo manevra v sotrudnich-
estve s Rossiei [Lukashenko ordered to cooperate with Russia in order to compensate the losses
incurred by the tax manoeuvre], Belarusian Telegraph Agency (Belta) (retrieved on February 11,
2019 from: hps://www.belta.by/president/view/lukashenko-poruchil-kompensirovat-poteri-
iz-za-nalogovogo-manevra-v-sotrudnichestve-s-rossiej-332166-2019/).
Belta (2019b), Lukashenko: Sovereignty of Belarus, Russia unaected by integraon processes, Be-
larusian Telegraph Agency (Belta) (retrieved on February 12, 2020 from: hps://eng.belta.by/
president/view/lukashenko-sovereignty-of-belarus-russia-unaected-by-integraon-process-
es-126920-2019/).
37
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Bessonova, O. (2006), Razdatochnaya ekonomika Rossii: evolyutsiya cherez transformatsii [Russian
redistribuve economy: Evoluon through transformaons], Moscow: ROSSPEN.
Bibik, T. (2011), Belorusskiy put’ reformirovaniya ekonomiki [Belarusian way of economic re-
forms], Trud. Profsoyuzy. Obshchestvo, 2.
Boeke, J.H. (1953), Economics and economic policy of dual sociees, New York: Instute of Pacic
Relaons.
Bona, L., and Haiduk, K. (2014), Dualism and growth in transion economies: A two-sector
model with ecient and subsidized enterprises, Post-Communist Economies, 26(1), pp. 1-16.
Bremmer, I. (2010), The end of the free market: Who wins the war between states and corporaons?
New York: Penguin.
Council of Ministers of the Republic of Belarus (2004), Resoluon of the Council of Ministers
of the Republic of Belarus No. 109 from January 31, 2004 ‘Ob ustanovlenii osobogo kontrolya
za vypolneniem otdel’nymi organizatsiyami osnovnykh tselevykh pokazateley prognoza sotsial’no-
ekonomicheskogo razviya Respubliki Belarus’ na 2004 god’ [On the establishment of a special
control over the implementaon of the main targets of the Prognosis of Social and Economic
Development of the Republic of Belarus for the year 2004 by several organisaons] (retrieved
on November 19, 2015 from: hp://systemaby.com/docs/bit3m/dk-6v1bdz.html).
Council of Ministers of the Republic of Belarus (2005), Resoluon of the Council of Ministers
of the Republic of Belarus No. 873 from August 8, 2005 O prognozakh, biznes-planakh razviya
kommercheskikh organizatsiy’ [On Forecasts and Business Plans concerning the Development of
Commercial Organisaons] (retrieved on November 19, 2015 from: hp://www.pravo.by/main.
aspx?guid=3871&p0=C20500873).
Council of Ministers of the Republic of Belarus (2017), Decision of the Council of Ministers of
the Republic of Belarus No. 18 from January 12, 2017 Ob utverzhdenii kompleksa mer po real-
izatsii Programmy sotsialno-ekonomicheskogo razviia Respubliki Belarus na 2016 – 2020 gody’ [On
approval of measures needed to be taken to implement the Program of Social and Economic
Development of the Republic of Belarus for the years 2016-2020] (retrieved on February 12,
2019 from: hp://www.government.by/ru/soluons/2772).
Daneyko, E. (2012), Protektsionizm kak ‘svyashchennaya korova’ belorusskoy ekonomiki [Pro-
teconism as a ‘sacred cow’ of Belarusian economy], Deutsche Welle, November 9 (retrieved on
December 3, 2015 from: hp://www.dw.com/ru/a-16367838).
38
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Dashkevich, V. (2005), Belorusskaya ekonomicheskaya model’ [Belarusian economic model],
Nashe Mnienie. July 27 (retrieved on November 9, 2015 from: hp://nmnby.eu/news/analyt-
ics/2433.html).
Dyner, A., and Wańczyk, K. (2015), Never ending crisis – prospects for the Belarusian economy,
The Polish Instute of Internaonal Aairs Policy Paper, 7.
EBRD (1999), Transion report 1999, European Bank for Reconstrucon and Development:
London.
EBRD (2008), Transion report 2008, European Bank for Reconstrucon and Development:
London.
EBRD (2009), Transion report 2009, European Bank for Reconstrucon and Development:
London.
EBRD (2012), Transion report 2012, European Bank for Reconstrucon and Development:
London.
EBRD (2013), Transion report 2013. Country assessments: Belarus, European Bank for Recon-
strucon and Development: London.
EBRD (2015), Forecasts, macro data, transion indicators, European Bank for Reconstrucon
and Development (retrieved on October 17, 2015 from: hp://www.ebrd.com/what-we-do/
economic-research-and-data/data/forecasts-macro-data-transion-indicators.html).
EBRD (2016), Transion report 2016. Country assessments: Belarus, European Bank for Recon-
strucon and Development: London.
EBRD (2018), Transion report 2018. Country assessments: Belarus, European Bank for Recon-
strucon and Development: London.
Ehrke, J., Shymanovich, G., and Kirchner, R. (2014), Improving the Management of State-Owned
Enterprises in Belarus, IPM Research Center Policy Paper Series, PP/023/2014.
Fabry, A. (2019), The polical economy of Hungary: From state capitalism to authoritarian neoliberal-
ism, Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.
Farkas, B. (2016), Models of Capitalism in the European Union. Post-crisis Perspecves, London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
39
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Grechneva, E. (2014), Belorusskaya ekonomicheskaya model’ [Belarusian economic model], Minsk:
Belarusian State University.
Hall, P., and Soskice, D. (eds) (2001), Variees of Capitalism: The Instuonal Foundaons of Com-
parave Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Havrylyshyn, O. (2007), Fieen years of transformaon in the post-communist world. Rapid reform-
ers outperformed gradualists, Washington D.C.: Cato Instute.
Ioe, G. (2014), Reassessing Lukashenka: Belarus in cultural and geopolical context, Basingstoke,
Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan.
Kizima, S. (2010), Aspekty neosporimogo preimushchestva. Belorusskaya model’ razviya v kon-
tekste globalizatsii [Aspects of undeniable advantage. Belarusian economic model in globalisa-
on context], Biełaruskaja Dumka, 11.
Kordonsky, S. (2008), Soslovnaya struktura postsovetskoy Rossii [Estate structure of the post-So-
viet Russia], Moscow: Obshchestvennoe mnenie Foundaon.
Kordonsky, S. (2016), Socio-economic foundaons of the Russian post-soviet regime: The resource-
based economy and estate-based social structure of contemporary Russia, Stugart: Ibidem-Verlag.
Korosteleva, J. (2007), Belarus: Heading towards state capitalism?, in: Lane, D., and Myant, M.
(eds), Variees of capitalism in post-communist countries, New York: Palgrave.
Korosteleva, J. (2013), The global recession and the Belarusian economy: Revealing cracks in the
model, in: Feklyunina, V., and White, S. (eds.), The internaonal economic crisis and the post-soviet
states, New York: Taylor and Francis.
Kozarzewski, P., and Bałtowski, M. (2017), Change in the ownership policy paradigm in Poland:
State control vs. privasaon, Acta Oeconomica, 67(1), pp. 1-20.
Krishtapovich, L., and Lepeshko, B. (2010), Formula sotsial’nogo opmizma. Unikal’nyy opyt
postroeniya gosudarstvennos, ekonomiki i obshchestvennykh otnosheniy. [Formula of social
opmism. A unique experience in state building, development of economy and social relaons],
Biełaruskaja Dumka, 11.
Kruk, D., and Bornukova, K. (2014), Dekompositsiya ekonomicheskogo rosta v Belarusi [Decom-
posion of economic growth in Belarus], Minsk: Belarusian Economic Research and Outreach
Center (retrieved on November 1 , 2015 from: hp://www.beroc.by/webroot/delivery/les/
Policy_Brief_Bornukova&Kruk.pdf).
40
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Kurlantzick, J. (2016), State capitalism: How the return of stasm is transforming the world, New
York: Oxford University Press.
Lane, D. (2008), From chaoc to state-led capitalism, New Polical Economy, 13(2), pp. 177-184.
Lane, D., and Myant, M. (eds) (2007), Variees of capitalism in post-communist countries, Hound-
mills: Palgrave.
Lavnikevich, D. (2015), Kholding i klaster: naydite 10 otlichiy [Holding and cluster: nd 10 dier-
ences], BDG Delovaya Gazeta, November 6.
Loyko, O., and Zayats, A. (2018), ‘Eto dostoianie naroda.Samye gromkie sluchai natsionalizatsii
v Belarusi [‘This is a property of the people.The most prominent cases of naonalisaon in
Belarus], TUT.BY news portal, July 13 (retrieved on February 12, 2019 from: hps://news.tut.by/
economics/600700.html?crnd=72097).
Manionok, T. (2018), Kitaiskie investsii v Belarus: led tronulsia? [Chinese investment in Belarus:
has the ice broken?], Belrynok.by. February 5 (retrieved on February 11, 2019 from: hp://www.
belrynok.by/2018/02/05/kitajskie-investsii-v-belarus-led-tronulsya/).
Marcinovič, J. (2015), Paviel Tapuzidzis: ‘Vydam zahad i prymušu ciabie liubić bielaruskuju movu’
[Paviel Tapuzidzis: ‘I’ll give the order and make you love the Belarusian language’], Nasha Niva,
December 31.
Melekhovets, V. (2018), Ot brevna do gotovoi krova. Kak v Belarusi delaiut mebel IKEA [From
the log to the nished bed. How they make IKEA furniture in Belarus], Onliner news portal, April
23 (retrieved on February 11, 2019 from: hps://realt.onliner.by/2018/04/23/ikea-5).
Ministry of Economic Development of the Russian Federaon (2019), Obzor sushchestvuyush-
chikh ogranicheniy v dostupe rossiyskikh tovarov na zarubezhnye rynki [Review of the barriers im-
posed against Russian products of foreign markets] (retrieved on December 10, 2019 from:
hp://www.ved.gov.ru/rus_export/torg_exp/).
Ministry of Economy of the Republic of Belarus (2014), Natsional’naya strategiya ustoychivogo
sotsial’no-ekonomicheskogo razviya Respubliki Belarus’ na period do 2030 goda [Naonal Strategy
of Sustainable Social and Economic Development of the Republic of Belarus unl 2030], Minsk:
Economic Research Instute.
Ministry of Economy of the Republic of Belarus (2016), Perechen kholdingov Respubliki Belarus
[The list of holdings of the Republic of Belarus] (retrieved on February 12, 2019 from: hp://
economy.gov.by/uploads/les/002552_323144_Perech_xold.pdf).
41
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Mises, L. (2009), Socialism: An economic and sociological analysis, Auburn, AL: The Ludwig von
Mises Instute.
Mukha, A. (2019), Dvizhenie pryamykh inostrannykh investsiy [FDI transfers], Nashe Mneniye
(retrieved on February 14, 2020 from: hps://nmnby.eu/news/analycs/6886.html).
Musacchio, A., and Lazzarini, S. (2012), Leviathan in business: Variees of state capitalism and their
implicaons for economic performance (retrieved on January 10, 2020 from: hps://ssrn.com/
abstract=2070942).
Naviny.by. (2015), Novaya deval’vatsiya belorusskogo rublya. 19.12.2014 – 19.01.2015 [New de-
valuaon of Belarusian ruble. 19.12.2014 – 19.01.2015] (retrieved on November 6, 2015 from:
hp://naviny.by/rubrics/nance/2015/01/20/ic_media_infograc_114_4432/).
Nu, D.M. (2005), The Belarus Economy: Suspended Animaon between State and Markets, in:
White, S., Korosteleva, E., and Löwenhardt, J. (eds), Postcommunist Belarus. Oxford: Rowman and
Lileeld, pp. 97-122.
OECD (2015), OECD Guidelines on Corporate Governance of State-Owned Enterprises, 2015 Edi-
on, Paris: OECD Publishing.
Olechnowicz, A. (2010), Białoruś straciła pokolenie [Belarus has lost a generaon], Analiza FOR,
7 (retrieved on October 17, 2015 from: hp://case-belarus.eu/wp-content/uploads/2011/08/
Analiza_FOR_7_2010_Bialorus_stracila_pokolenie.pdf).
Papko, A. (2017a), Informal barriers to the development of small and medium enterprises in Be-
larus, PhD thesis, Warsaw: GSSR (retrieved on December10, 2019 from: hps://www.academia.
edu/41070896/Informal_Barriers_to_the_Development_of_Small_and_Medium_Enterprises_
in_Belarus).
Papko, A. (2017b), It is beer to remain small and invisible. Informal barriers to the development
of small and medium enterprises in Belarus. Part II, Warsaw Forum of Economic Sociology, Vol. 8
No. 2 (16), pp. 109-135.
Pelipas, I., Skriba, A., Tochitskaya, I., Chubrik, A., and Shimanovich, G. (2014), Belorusskiy biznes
2014: sostoyanie, tendentsii, perspekvy [Belarusian business in 2014: situaon, tendencies, per-
specves], Minsk: IPM Research Center.
President of the Republic of Belarus (2016), Edict of the President of the Republic of Belarus No.
466 from December 15, 2016 ‘Ob utverzhdenii Programmy sotsial’no-ekonomicheskogo razviya
Respubliki Belarus’ na 2016 – 2020 gody’ [On the approval of the Program of Social and Economic
42
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Development of the Republic of Belarus for the years 2016-2020] (retrieved on February 12,
2019 from: hps://www.economy.gov.by/uploads/les/Programma-2020.pdf).
President of the Republic of Belarus (2018), Edict of the President of the Republic of Belarus No.
483 from December 20, 2018 ‘O zadachakh sotsialno-ekonomicheskogo razviia Respubliki Belarus
na 2019 god’. [On the goals of social and economic development of the Republic of Belarus for
the year 2019] (retrieved on February 12, 2019 from: hps://www.economy.gov.by/uploads/
les/macro-prognoz/1617406-7296238-7296247.pdf).
Probusiness.by (2015), 5 vpechatlyayushchikh faktov o ‘Yevrotorge’ [5 impressive facts about the
‘Eurotorg’], July 13 (retrieved on February 13, 2017 from: hps://probusiness.by/markets/1051-
5-lyubopytnykh-faktov-o-evrotorge.html).
Pyko, V. (2007), Belorusskaya ekonomicheskaya model’: proizvodstvennyy aspekt [Belarusian
economic model: producve aspect], Vestnik BGEU, 2.
Repousis, S., Lois, P., and Kougioumtsidis, P. (2019), Foreign direct investments and round trip-
ping between Cyprus and Russia, Journal of Money Laundering Control, 22(3), pp. 442-450.
Robinson, N. (2013), Economic and polical hybridity: Patrimonial capitalism in the post-Soviet
sphere, Journal of Eurasian Studies, 4(2), pp. 136-145.
Rovdo, V. (2009), Sravnitelnaya politologiya, chast’ 3. [Comparave polical science. Vol. 3], Vil-
nius: European Humanies University.
Schlumberger, O. (2008), Structural reform, economic order, and development: Patrimonial capi-
talism, Review of Internaonal Polical Economy, 15(4), pp. 622-649.
Sekhovich, V. (2018), Realnyi sektor: postkrizisnyi podyom [The real sector of the economy:
a post-crisis recovery] in: Pankovsky, A., and Kosugova, V. (eds), Belorusskii Ezhegodnik 2018
[Belarusian Yearbook 2018], Vilnius: Logvino.
Sekhovich, V. (2019), ‘Krasnye direktora,oligarkhi, druzia iz Forbes. Chastnyi biznes i Lukash-
enko v proekte ‘Chetvert’ veka’ [Red directors, oligarchs, friends from Forbes. Private business
and Lukashenko in the Quarter Century project], TUT.BY, June 27 (retrieved on January 10, 2020
from: hps://news.tut.by/economics/643329.html).
Sidoruk, A. (2017), Belorusy v oshornoy zone [Belarusians in the oshore zone], Nashe Mnenie,
(retrieved on March 9, 2020 from: hps://nmnby.eu/news/analycs/6390.html).
43
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Silicki, V. (2001), Ekanamičnaja palityka Lukašenki [Economik policy of Lukashenka], in: Bulhakaŭ,
V. (ed.), Bielaruska-rasijskaja intehracyja. Analityčnyja artykuly [Intergaon between Belarus and
Russia. Analycal arcles], Minsk: Encyklapiedyks.
Smok, V. (2017), Why do the authories connue to arrest Belarus’s top businessmen? Belarus-
Digest, May 15 (retrieved on February 12, 2019 from: hps://belarusdigest.com/story/why-do-
the-authories-connue-to-arrest-belaruss-top-businessmen/).
Sokolov, M. (2007), Peresokhshaya ‘Druzhba’. Krizis v otnosheniyakh Minska i Moskvy obsu-
zhdayut Vladimir Milov, Stanislav Bogdankevich, Sergey Markov. [Druzhba Pipeline dried out.
A crisis in Moscow-Minsk relaons discussed by Vladimir Milov, Stanislav Bogdankevich, Sergey
Markov], Radio Svoboda-RFE/RL, January 9 (retrieved on October 29, 2015 from: hp://www.
svoboda.org/content/transcript/371491.html).
Spechler, M.C., Ahrens, J.H., and Hoen H.W. (2017), State capitalism in Eurasia, Singapore: World
Scienc.
State Commiee for Land Resources, Geodesy and Cartography of the Republic of Belarus
(2000), Resoluon of the State Commiee for Land Resources, Geodesy and Cartography of
the Republic of Belarus No. 15 from November 23, 2000 ‘Instruktsiya po transliteratsii geogra-
cheskikh nazvaniy Respubliki Belarus’ bukvami lanskogo alfavita’ [Instrucon on transliteraon
of Belarusian geographical names with leers of Lan alphabet] (retrieved on January 26, 2020
from: hp://knihi.com/storage/Translitaracyja_hieahracnych_nazvau.html).
Stepanova, A. (2018), Zachem nuzhen nalogovyi manevr v neianoi otrasli [Why do we need
a tax manoeuvre in the oil industry], TASS news agency, July 24 (retrieved on February 11, 2019
from: hps://tass.ru/ekonomika/5315335).
TUT.BY (2014), Lukashenko potreboval ot Stadler prives v poriadok «Belkommunmash» [Lukash-
enko demanded Stadler to put Belkommunmash in order], November 20 (retrieved on January
10, 2020 from: hps://news.tut.by/economics/424480.html).
TUT.BY (2017), ‘Lukashenko emu neukosnitelno doveriaet.’ Kak ‘nadezhnyi’ Gutseriev stal svoim
v Belarusi [‘Lukashenko strictly trusts him’. How ‘reliable’ Gutseriev has become close to pow-
er in Belarus], October 5 (Retrieved on January 10, 2020 from: hps://news.tut.by/econom-
ics/563227.html).
Vagliasindi, M. (2008), Governance arrangements for state owned enterprises, The World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper, 4542.
44
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Vitebsk District Execuve Commiee (2007), Decision of the Vitebsk District Execuve Com-
miee No. 112 from February 1, 2007 ‘O razrabotke prognozov razviya i biznes-planov kom-
mercheskikh organizatsiy, nakhodyashchikhsya v vedenii Vitebskogo rayonnogo ispolnitel’nogo
komiteta’ [On the Development of Forecasts and Business Plans of Commercial Organisaons
under the Jurisdicon of the Vitebsk District Execuve Commiee] (retrieved on November 19,
2015 from: hp://pravo.levonevsky.org/bazaby09/sbor16/text16677.htm).
Vitebsk Regional Execuve Commiee (2005), Decision of the Vitebsk Regional Execuve Com-
miee No. 645 from September 27, 2005 ‘O razrabotke prognozov razviya i biznes-planov kom-
mercheskikh organizatsiy’ [On the development of forecasts and business plans of commercial
organisaons] (retrieved on November 19, 2015 from: hp://spravka-jurist.com/base/part-rx/
tx_csskpa.htm).
Wintrobe, R. (2018), An economic theory of a hybrid (compeve authoritarian or illiberal) re-
gime, Public Choice, 177(3), pp. 217-233.
World Bank (2005), Stranovoy ekonomicheskiy memorandum dlya Respubliki Belarus’. Belarus’’:
okno vozmozhnostey dlya povysheniya konkurentosposobnos i obespecheniya ustoychivykh tem-
pov ekonomicheskogo rosta [Country Economic Memorandum for the Republic of Belarus. Be-
larus: window of opportunity to enhance compeveness and ensure sustainable economic
growth] (retrieved on December 10, 2019 from: hp://documents.vsemirnyjbank.org/curated/
ru/204731468201595653/Main-report).
World Bank (2012), Ekonomicheskaya transformatsiya dlya rosta. Stranovoy ekonomicheskiy memo-
randum dlya Respubliki Belarus’ [Economic transformaon for growth. Country economic memo-
randum for the Republic of Belarus] (retrieved on October 30 , 2015 from: hp://www-wds.
worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2012/07/06/000333038_20
120706010040/Rendered/PDF/666140ESW0P1230Ocial0Use0Only090.pdf).
World Bank (2017), Belarus Economic Update, May 15 (retrieved on February 13, 2017 from:
hp://pubdocs.worldbank.org/en/819391494832531504/Eng-EcUpdate-May14-17.pdf).
World Bank (2018), Belarus – Systemac Country Diagnosc: towards a compeve, inclusive and
dynamic Belarus (retrieved on February 11, 2019 from: hp://documents.worldbank.org/curat-
ed/en/602921520877070059/pdf/Belarus-SCD-03072018.pdf).
Yanchuk, V. (2007), Belorusskaya ekonomicheskaya model’: ot liberal’nogo fundamentalizma k
sotsial’no-ekonomicheskomu upravleniyu [Belarusian economic model: from liberal fundamen-
talism to social and economic management], Vitebsk State University, Uchenye zapiski, 7.
45
CASE Working Papers | No. 12(136)/2020
Yaroshevich, A. (2016), Stadler perenosit v Belarus’ zakazy s zavodov v drugikh stranakh
[Stadler moves orders from its factories in other countries to Belarus], Naviny.by. February 10
(retrieved on February 13, 2017 from: hp://naviny.by/rubrics/economic/2016/02/10/ic_ar-
cles_113_190955).
Yegorov, A. (2013), Sravnitel’’nyy analiz belorusskoy ekonomicheskoy modeli [Comparave
analysis of Belarusian economic model], in: Borzdova, T. (ed.), Innovatsionnoe razvie ekonomiki:
predprinimatel’’stvo, obrazovanie, nauka [Innovave development of economy: business, educa-
on, science], Minsk: Belarusian State University.
Zajac, D. (2016), Ekspart naapraduktaŭ skaraciŭsia na 15% [Exports of oil products decreased
by 15%], BelaPAN, December 7 (retrieved on February 13, 2017 from: hp://by.belapan.by/arch
ive/2016/12/07/878245_123456/).
Zaleski, M. (2002), Farmavańnie bielaruskaj ekanomiki jak častki ahuĺnasavieckaha haspadarčaha
komplieksu [Forming of Belarusian economy as a part of Soviet economic system], in: Bulhakaŭ,
V. (ed.), Bielaruska-rasijskaja intehracyja. Analityčnyja artykuly [Integraon between Belarus and
Russia. Analycal arcles], Minsk: Encyklapiedyks.
Zayats, D. (2010), Na kom derzhitsya Belarus’? [On whom Belarusian economy is held up?],
Naviny.by, September 3 (retrieved on November 19, 2015 from: hp://naviny.by/rubrics/eco-
nomic/2010/09/03/ic_arcles_113_170308/).
Zlotnikov, L. (2009), The Belarusian ‘economic miracle’ – illusions and reality, in: Fischer,
S. (ed.), Back from the cold? The EU and Belarus in 2009, Chaillot Paper 119, pp. 65-78.
... In Belarus, a contingent process of establishing a market economy never started (Havrylyshyn, 2007;Korosteleva, 2007;Rovdo, 2009;Papko and Kozarzewski, 2020). The government never fully liberalized prices or the exchange rate; privatization was slow and very selective, it did not include large enterprises which remained state owned, but some institutional changes did take place in the management of them in terms of corporatization. ...
... With regard to the 1990s, the economic model of Belarus could be labeled as a "rent based state capitalism" (Baltowski et al., 2020;Papko and Kozarzewski, 2020). ...
... However, some new tendencies appeared after the economic crisis in 2015: the successive reduction of subsidies to SOEs and deregulation; the growing role of private enterprises, especially in the new sectors (IT, etc.); the growing concentration of the new private sector, due to the top-down corporatization of SOEs and establishing of large private firms (Papko and Kozarzewski, 2020). But the annual economic growth in the country, after 2015, remains on the level of a bit more than 1 percent. ...
... Belarus enjoys extensive support from Russia, which subsidises the Belarusian economy (and helps Lukashenko's regime retain power) in return for political loyalty. The FDI level is quite low due to the poor investment climate and many FDIs are actually organisations of domestic descent that have taken a round trip for tax avoidance purposes (Papko and Kozarzewski, 2020). ...
... Through delayed privatisation and discriminative policies towards the private sector, Belarusian authorities have managed to retain control over the overwhelming majority of 'old' enterprises inherited from the Soviet period, such as infrastructure, mining, construction, and manufacturing. Private enterprises have developed in niches: new sectors that emerged only after the fall of communism (e.g., IT, business services, catering, advertising) and the few areas from which the state has withdrawn, most probably because of their high costs of control and maintenance, such as road transport and retail (Papko and Kozarzewski, 2020). ...
Chapter
Full-text available
Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) comprises 24 countries that are characterised by diverse models of capitalism. We review the literature on varieties of capitalism in the CEE region, distinguishing between the studies that use existing categories in their taxonomies of capitalism in the region versus those that introduce new ones. We analyse the empirical approaches taken to the varieties of capitalism in the region, highlighting the qualitative versus quantitative and static versus dynamic approaches, and discuss how the relations between business and the state have been conceptualised. This allows us to explain how capitalism in CEE countries differs from capitalism in other regions of the world. We then illustrate how capitalism is manifesting in the region, grouping the countries into FDI-based market economies (e.g., Poland), peripheral market economies (e.g., Bulgaria), peripheral market economies with a high level of aid and remittances (e.g., Albania), oligarchic economies (e.g., Kazakhstan), order economies (Belarus) and remittance-and aid-based economies (Kosovo). Finally, we focus on how states exercise influence over business and propose a categorisation of tools of state involvement: corporate control mechanisms, state-led developmental projects and other arrangements for the state enterprise sector, regulation of private businesses, and extra-legal tools to influence private businesses.
... Only China and Russia used to be an exception, towards which some version of this perspective was applied (e.g., Lane 2008; Bremmer 2010). Recently, two studies on Belarus (Papko and Kozarzewski 2020; Rudy 2020) have been published. But perhaps only in the recent very extensive volume on state capitalism which is treated as the direct influence of the state on the economy and behavior of enterprises (Wright et al. 2021) for the first time the notion of state capitalism was extended on all economies throughout the world. ...
... In this section, some statements, research results and literature references from were used. 2. In this section, some statements, research results and literature references from Papko and Kozarzewski (2020) were used. ...
Chapter
This chapter discusses shaping up, evolution and the present situation in the state corporate control of three other post-communist countries where the role of the state-controlled sector is very significant and/or increasing: Hungary, Russia and Belarus comparing their experience with that of Poland and between each other. Analysis of each country, after discussing the specificity of challenges at the beginning of the transition, in an abridged form repeats the structure of the analysis of the Polish case presented in Chapters 4– 6: shaping up and evolution of the state corporate control, its present state, the portrait of the SOE sector and discussion on the factors that lay behind the identified processes and phenomena.
... As a consequence, the paternalist model of state-society relations lost support, especially as the regime's ability to maintain the social contract with the population deteriorated. This argument is corroborated by several studies diagnosing the increasing exhaustion of the neo-Soviet "Belarusian model," the stagnation of economic development and wages, the regime's eroding capacity to deliver social services, and shifting attitudes among the population (e.g., Grishchenko and Titarenko 2020;Krawatzek and Langbein 2022;Moshes and Nizhnikau 2019;Papko and Kozarzewski 2020). ...
Article
Full-text available
Drawing on three theoretical perspectives—“protest-democracy,” “authoritarian/patronal regime dynamics,” and “contentious politics”—developed in the study of popular protests in post-Soviet electoral autocracies, this article argues, first, that the 2020 postelection mobilization in Belarus was not to be expected for both structural and agency-related reasons. Second, by the summer of 2020, the political opportunity structure had opened up because of contingent choices by individual actors, with Alyaksandr Lukashenka committing several major mistakes, particularly on pandemic (non)control and the administration of the upcoming presidential election, and political newcomers taking on the role of challenging him. After the election, mass mobilization unfolded in two waves triggered by two additional regime mistakes: blatant electoral fraud and excessive repression. These mistakes served as focal points for spontaneous coordination, substituting for the deliberate “engineering” of protest by an organized opposition typical of the post-Soviet color revolutions. Third, Lukashenka survived in office because popular protests did not lead to elite defection. Instead, he was able to secure the loyalty of elites because he avoided gross blunders against both regime insiders and Russia. The case of Belarus indicates that hegemonic-authoritarian regimes are more vulnerable to mistakes by incumbents than to challenges from below and outside the regime.
Chapter
Belarus was among the few post-communist countries to resign from comprehensive market reforms and that tried to improve the efficiency of the economy through administrative means, leaving market mechanisms only an auxiliary role. Since its inception, the so-called Belarusian economic model has undergone several revisions of a de-satisfaction and de-regulation kind, but still the Belarusian economy remains dominated by the state. The following chapter analyzses the characteristic features of the Belarusian economic system and its evolution over time. The tentative conclusion is that during the post-Soviet period, the Belarusian economy evolved from a quasi-Soviet system based on state property, state planning, support to inefficient enterprises, and the massive redistribution of funds to a more flexible hybrid model where the state still holds “commanding heights” in the economy. The economic system of Belarus may be described as a hybrid one, with elements of state capitalism and a Soviet-type command economy.
Article
Full-text available
In this paper, we review the regulations and research on the adoption of international accounting and audit standards in eleven Eastern European countries outside of the European Union. We find many regulatory commonalities among these jurisdictions related to their Communist-bloc heritage. The state remains the most important stakeholder and tax accounting dominates financial reporting. The work of local auditors is considered less reliable than that of their Big 4 counterparts. International organizations and the Big 4 auditors provide stimuli for and assistance with international standards’ adoption. Accounting and audit research is limited. The scarcity of data forces most authors to focus on the qualitative evaluation of accounting and audit reforms. Some opt for surveys. Few papers include empirical analyses. Our review covers jurisdictions, which have received limited attention in prior literature. We inform future empirical work and speak to the generalizability of previous research findings to this set of countries.
Chapter
The chapter assesses of the present state of knowledge on the state corporate control in transition countries, including Poland, within the existing research perspectives, and identifies the existing knowledge gaps and possibilities of using these approaches in further research. Transition research, economic policy research and economic systems research are the research streams which may fit most of the studies on state corporate control in transition economies, but generally, they underestimate or even neglect this subject—with several notable exceptions such as new state capitalism studies or relatively unknown studies on resource and distributive economies. Public choice perspective has a very strong explanatory potential in analyzing the real trajectories and outcomes of the evolution of the state corporate control, although the role of SOEs in the institutional setup of transition economies so far was not fully appreciated.
Article
This article offers an initial analyses the mass protests that began in Belarus following the presidential elections of August 2020. Written ‘in the heat of events’ it has the character of preliminary observations. The authors begin with the background and context of events and the outcomes of the economic and social development of the Republic of Belarus during the 25 years of rule by Lukashenko. A preliminary analysis of the social and class make-up both of the protesters and of those who at the time of writing remained a ‘silent majority’ is situated in the context of the contradictions within the Belarusian ‘power elite’. We attempt to distinguish the main factors behind the developments in Belarus and point to initial lessons of these events for social and humanitarian-oriented networks and organisations.
Article
The 2020 political crisis in Belarus erupted against the backdrop of major confrontation in the Belarus–Russia relations. The article looks into the role of Russia and domestic Belarusian factors in creating prerequisites for this political crisis. Since the 1990s, good relationship with Russia have been the source of not only the “integration rent” for Minsk, keeping the specific Belarusian economic model working, but also of the political support from Moscow provided both directly (for instance, through positive coverage of the Belarusian agenda by those Russian federal media that were popular in Belarus) and in indirect forms, such as through maintaining overall positive image of the bilateral relationship. Russia’s role was important for maintaining the loyalty of each major social group at the core of Lukashenko’s support base. Deterioration of the Belarus–Russia relations in 2004–2006, 2008–2010, and 2018–2020 expectedly led to political and economic crises in Belarus. As, by the start of presidential election campaign in Belarus in 2020, Moscow withdrew its main types of support to Lukashenko’s regime, a political crisis was expectable. However, the exact form and scenario of the crisis was shaped by domestic factors, as well as by the country’s leadership’s response to Russia’s pressure. Those domestic factors included accumulated mistakes, disbalances, and dysfunctions in the actions taken by the Belarusian authorities since the late 2016 through 2020. Errors such as the mismanagement of the COVID-19 pandemic were among the immediate triggers of the 2020 crisis. The 2020 developments thus demonstrated a major breakdown of previously effective Belarusian preventive authoritarianism. The internal drivers and dynamics of this breakdown require a more profound study.
Article
Full-text available
Recently, not only has dictatorship resurfaced, but a new form of government has appeared that is neither democratic nor dictatorial. There are various names for this new form: “competitive—authoritarian”, “illiberal democracy”, or simply “hybrid”. Some obvious examples are Hungary, Poland and Turkey. Some connect the origin of hybrids in modern times to the rise of populism. Populism is connected to the illiberal or hybrid idea in that populists tend to repress minorities as a way of appealing to the majority. Authoritarian populists typically divide the population into “us” versus “them”. This paper develops a model of how a hybrid can arise from democracy. I introduce a “strongman or strongwoman” as a leader who can implement repression and gain power. I develop a simple model of a “hybrid” regime in which repression is less than that under dictatorship but greater than that under liberal democracy. The hybrid regime is a special case of Wintrobe’s general theory of dictatorship, but it goes further than that by endogenizing equilibrium extremism of the regime as well as repression. I show how the hybrid regime reacts to exogenous shocks, and develop optimal policy for other countries and institutions interested in reducing repression (the UN, US or EU) towards hybrids. © 2018 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature
Book
Full-text available
Rejecting the cliché about “weak identity and underdeveloped nationalism,” Bekus argues for the co-existence of two parallel concepts of Belarusianness—the official and the alternative one—which mirrors the current state of the Belarusian people more accurately and allows for a different interpretation of the interconnection between the democratization and nationalization of Belarusian society. The book describes how the ethno-symbolic nation of the Belarusian nationalists, based on the cultural capital of the Golden Age of the Belarusian past (17th century) competes with the “nation” institutionalized and reified by the numerous civic rituals and social practices under the auspices of the actual Belarusian state. Comparing the two concepts not only provides understanding of the logic that dominates Belarusian society’s self-description models, but also enables us to evaluate the chances of alternative Belarusianness to win this unequal struggle over identity.
Article
Full-text available
I am not a co-author. John Marangos.
Article
Purpose This paper aims to look at the linkage of Foreign Direct Investments and Round Tripping in the Cyprus – Russian corridor. Design/methodology/approach The paper is divided into two chapters. The first chapter looks at the relationship between Foreign Direct Investments and Round Tripping in Cyprus and Russia. The second chapter discusses and combines statistical data from different sources about illicit financial flows from Russia and the linkage of Foreign Direct Investments and Round Tripping with Cyprus. Findings Evidence suggests that, despite the obviously numerous and varied legislative provisions and initiatives, the movement of vast amounts of capital to or through the Cypriot financial system is a phenomenon, which has absolutely not been removed. The illegal outflow of money seems to grow rapidly over the years instead of decreasing. What actually happens is that after a dramatic decline in the years 2013-2015 the Foreign Direct Investments of the Russians to and from Cyprus in 2016 returned to pre-crisis levels of 2013 and so far it seems the inflows-outflows system returned to "normal" levels. Cyprus ranks first in Inward Foreign Direct Investment and Outward Foreign Direct Investment with almost 35% of total flows from Russia. An element, that demonstrates the presence of round-tripping, is the sharp and rapid parallel increase of Inward Foreign Direct Investment and Outward Foreign Direct Investment and that the category of total deposits in Cyprus by non-residents, including Special Purpose Entity, recorded significant fluctuations due to the large size of deposits, but also due to the short time remaining in the banking sector. Russia ranked in the second position of largest average illegal capital outflows countries in the years 2004-2013. Movement of capital to exploit the particularly beneficial Cyprus tax system is still a tax backdoor for Europe and worldwide (hence the neologisms like Cyp-Rus), especially after the “de-offshorization” Russian law since January 1, 2015. Research limitations/implications - Practical implications Evidences presented in this paper are important for national and super-national supervisory anti-money laundering bodies and compliance authorities to understand bad practices between Russia and Cyprus financial transactions. Originality/value Evidences presented in this paper are important for national and super-national supervisory anti-money laundering bodies and compliance authorities to understand bad practices between Russia and Cyprus financial transactions.
Book
This book explores the political economy of Hungary from the mid-1970s to the present. Widely considered a ‘poster boy’ of neoliberal transformation in post-communist Eastern Europe until the mid-2000s, Hungary has in recent years developed into a model ‘illiberal’ regime. Constitutional checks-and-balances are non-functioning; the independent media, trade unions, and civil society groups are constantly attacked by the authorities; there is widespread intolerance against minorities and refugees; and the governing FIDESZ party, led by Prime Minister Viktor Orbán, controls all public institutions and increasingly large parts of the country’s economy. To make sense of the politico-economical roller coaster that Hungary has experienced in the last four decades, Fabry employs a Marxian political economy approach, emphasising competitive accumulation, class struggle (both between capital and labour, as well as different ‘fractions of capital’), and uneven and combined development. The author analyses the neoliberal transformation of the Hungarian political economy and argues that the drift to authoritarianism under the Orbán regime cannot be explained as a case of Hungarian exceptionalism, but rather represents an outcome of the inherent contradictions of the variety of neoliberalism that emerged in Hungary after 1989.
Article
The paper presents an analysis of the shift in the ownership policy of the Polish government in office since 2015 towards a more active role of the state and a more reluctant attitude towards privatisation. This shift reflects a general change in the paradigm of the role of the state towards the concept of the state as a strong market player, which includes the strengthening of its ownership functions. Among others, it has led to stalling the privatisation process and concentrating only on its fiscal goals. Possible factors causing this statist shift are divided into two dichotomic groups: the government's good faith vs. the impact of rent-seeking interest groups and endogenous vs. exogenous factors. Our main conclusion is that despite similarities with the trends observed in some other countries, endogenous factors such as increasing capture of the state by rent-seeking groups, and not the exogenous ones, including the global financial crisis, contributed most to the growing statist trends in the Polish state's ownership policy.
Book
The world is split today into two hostile camps, fighting each other with 13 the utmost vehemence, Communists and anti-Communists. The magniloquent rhetoric to which these factions resort in their feud obscures the fact that they both perfectly agree in the ultimate end of their programme for mankind's social and economic organization. They both aim at the abolition of private enterprise and private ownership of the means of production and at the establishment of socialism. They want to substitute totalitarian government control for the market economy. No longer should individuals by their buying or abstention from buying determine what is to be produced and in what quantity and quality. Henceforth the government's unique plan alone should settle all these matters. 'Patemal' care of the 'Welfare State' will reduce all people to the status of bonded workers bound to comply, without asking questions, with the orders issued by the planning authority.
Article
This book uses comparative economic analysis to provide a common conceptual framework for all current European Union member states. Based on empirical investigation, the author identifies the Nordic, North-western, Mediterranean, and Central and Eastern models of capitalism on the threshold of the 2008 global financial and economic crisis. The chapters also examine the resulting institutional responses to the crisis and the methods of crisis management adopted by each member state. The analysis reveals that the crisis has not triggered radical institutional change but, instead, highlighted deep institutional differences not between the old and new member states, but between the Nordic, North-western, Mediterranean, and Central and Eastern European countries. These institutional differences are so significant that they require the rethinking of European integration theory. Models of Capitalism in the European Union serves as a useful handbook for academics, advanced students, policy-makers and advisors who are interested in European economic issues.