Content uploaded by Gilbert Matthews
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Gilbert Matthews on Mar 31, 2020
Content may be subject to copyright.
Organismo Italiano di Valutazione
3rd Annual International Conference
19 January 2015
SUTTER SECURITIES GIL@SUTTERSF.COM
1 -415-352-6336
1
“Dual class” companies have common shares with
different voting rights
In most cases, low-vote shares either have (a) the same
economic interest as high-vote shares or (b) the same
economic interest plus a dividend preference
In a few companies (primarily Swiss), all shares have one
vote but the “high-vote” shares have lower par value,
e.g.
, 100 shares with SF10 par value have 100 times the
vote of 1 share with SF1000 par value
Notes re terminology:
“low-vote” shares include non-voting shares
“dual class” includes companies with multiple classes
2
Most countries permit some form of dual class shares
Exceptions include Spain, Portugal, Belgium, Japan
3
Some countries ban non-voting shares but permit
shares with multiple votes (usually with a maximum
10 votes),
e.g.
, U.K. and Sweden
Some, such as Italy, permit non-voting shares but
mandate a dividend preference for the non-voting
shares
Some limit the number of low-vote shares that can
be issued,
e.g.
, Germany and Italy, both of which
limit non-voting shares to 50% of equity
4
Some important stock markets, including London,
Hong Kong and Singapore, do not permit dual class
companies to be listed
The NYSE permits listing by companies that had dual
class structures before they went public, but prohibits
listed companies from creating dual class shares
In the U.S., dual class issues have surged – from January
2010 to March 2012, 20 of the 170 IPOs (primarily in the
technology sector) were low-vote shares in dual class
companies
The NYSE has welcomed dual class foreign companies
that could not list at home, such as China’s Ali Baba and
England’s Manchester United
5
Frequency of dual class structures (2001-2):
Sweden 62%
Switzerland 52%
Italy 43%
U.K. 25%
Germany 19%
U.S. 6%
France 3%
These numbers are above current levels, primarily because
of trend toward unification of dual class structures
6
“Loyalty shares” are shares with time-weighted voting rights,
i.e.,
shares within a class are given multiple votes after being
held in registered form by the same shareholder for a given
period of time (usually two years)
oLoyalty shares are not a “class” of shares – they lose their
extra votes upon transfer to a third party
Loyalty shares are widely used in France (usually with 2
votes) but are rare elsewhere
The NYSE will not list companies with loyalty shares, but three
companies are grandfathered
Art. 2437 of the Italian Civil Code now provides that
companies may authorize loyalty shares
o2 votes for listed companies
o3 votes for private companies
7
Several studies have concluded that companies with
dual class structures are valued at lower levels than
comparable companies
However, several other studies dispute this conclusion
8
In Germany, average premiums were about 40% in the early 1990s – a
decade later, average premiums were 10-15%
Norwegian high-vote shares sold at average
discounts
of about 10% in
the early 1990s – a decade later, average premiums were about 15%
Average premiums in Denmark were 35% in the early 1990’s and 5% in
the late 1990s
Brazilian high-vote shares had average premiums of 10% in 1994, 30%
in 1996, minus 10% in 2000, and 5% in 2004
Average premiums in Italy were low in the early 1980’s, rose to about
80% in the late 1980’s, fell to the 60% level in the 1990’s, declined to
the 20% level a decade later, and were about 3% at the end of 2008
9
10
Source: Caprio & Croce (2008)
Several studies have compared market prices of high-
vote and low-vote shares of the limited number of U.S.
companies where both classes are publicly traded
Basic flaw in these studies: the aggregate publicly
traded high-vote shares in the float rarely can impact
control because the control party normally owns a
majority of the vote
If the publicly traded high-vote shares of a company
collectively cannot affect control, how can the market
prices of those shares measure the value of control?
11
Themainsourceofvalueforvotingrightsisthepricea
prospectivebuyerwouldbewillingtopayabovethe
security value of voting shares in order to gain control of
the corporation and reap the ensuing private benefits. ...
The size of this voting premium will be related to both the
probability that voting shares will be demanded by the
buyer, and the amount of private benefits expected.
(Caprio & Croce, 2008)
12
Likelihood (if any) of affecting control
Potential premium (if any) in a unification or acquisition
Liquidity – a function of the size of the float
Dividend expectations
Limitations on transferability (for shares not publicly
traded)
Legal environment – voting premiums tend to be low in
countries with good legal protections for minority shareholder
and high in countries where legal protection is weaker
Institutional environment
t
13
Can the minority high-vote shareholders be
excluded from a premium paid to the controller in
an acquisition?
In many European countries, a party who buys a
certain percentage of shares becomes legally
obligated to bid the same amount for the remaining
shares of the class – in that case, the answer is “no”
In the U.S. and in Canada, the answer is “yes”
14
The Delaware Court of Chancery – the primary venue for U.S.
corporate litigation – decided in its 1988
Resorts
International
decision that minority 100-vote shares were
functionally equivalent to the 1-vote shares when corporate
control was in the hands of a single shareholder
It ruled that minority high-vote shareholders were not entitled
to a premium over the price paid to low-vote shareholders
The controller had received $135 per share and all other
shareholders of both classes received $36
The Delaware Supreme Court upheld the decision, stating that
the non-control high-vote shares had the same value as the
low-vote shares
15
To obtain data that can be useful in determining the relative
value of high-vote and low-vote shares, we look at data
available from corporate events in dual class companies
Numerous U.S. corporations have combined high-vote and
low-vote shares into a single class
These are called usually “recapitalizations” or “reclassifications”
in the U.S. and “unifications” in Europe
The terms of these unifications provide useful data as to
relative value in various countries
In addition, there have been numerous U.S acquisitions of dual
class companies which provide useful data as to relative value
16
Some of the reasons – some country-specific and some
general – why companies unify dual classes,
e.g
.:
to eliminate dividend preference
to comply with change in law
because of changed criteria for inclusion in indexes
othe size of a class affects its inclusion in index funds and ETFs
to improve liquidity by having a single class
to improve pricing of new equity offerings
to eliminate perceived undervaluation
oa recent study (Lauterbach & Pajuste, 2014) concluded that
there is a correlation between media criticism and unifications
17
Studies have reviewed unifications in several
countries throughout the world
U.K. – a study showed that of 49 unifications, 45
paid special dividends to the high-vote shares
(Ang & Megginson, 1989)
Brazil – 25 of 30 reunifications from 2000 to
2008 were 1:1 (Bortolon & Câmara, 2014)
oWe also look at Israel, Germany, Italy, the U.S.,
and Canada
18
A 1989 change in Tel Aviv Exchange’s rules effectively
forced dual-class companies that wanted to issue new
shares to unify
In 84 dual class unifications from 1990 to 2000, 55%
compensated high vote shareholders (Hauser & Lauterbach,
2004)
The mean compensation to high-vote shareholders was
approximately 4%
On average, majority shareholders owned 86% of the
high-vote shares and 63% of the low-vote shares
Almost all the majority shareholders retained control of
their companies
19
AsubstantialmajorityofGermanunificationsappliedno
discounttothenon‐votingshares
Astudyofunificationsfrom1995through2002showed28
unifications(Dittmann &Ulbrich,2008)
4requirednon‐votingshareholderstomakeacashpayment
equaltoaportionofthedifferencebetweenthemarket
pricesofthevotingandnon‐votingshares
5cancelleddividendsthathadaccruedbutwereunpaid
becauseofinadequateearnings
19wereonashare‐for‐sharebasiswithnopayment
20
In 47 unifications in Italy from 1974 through 2008,
non-voting shareholders either paid cash to convert or
had an exchange ratio <1:1 in 13 cases (Bigelli, Mehrorta
and Rau, 2011)
In several cases of 1:1 unifications, control shareholders
bought low-vote shares, issued options to buy low-vote
shares, and sold high-vote shares prior to
announcement (
Id.
)
Within the past year, Exor, RCS Media Group, Indesit,
and UnipolSai have announced 1:1 unifications and
Italcementi used a 0.65:1 ratio
21
In about 85% of unifications and acquisitions of U.S. dual
class companies, both classes received the same
consideration
There are numerous reasons why the high-vote shares
might not be able to receive a premium in an acquisition
or unification
1. A requirement under the by-laws that multiple-vote shares
may not be transferred unless they are converted into one-
vote shares
2. A provision in the by-laws that high-vote shares will
automatically be converted into low-vote shares if
transferred to a party not in the control group
22
3. A commitment by high-vote shareholders prior to an IPO
that all shareholders would receive the same
consideration in an acquisition
4. A provision that consent of the low-vote class was
required for a merger
5. Prior to a change in accounting rules in 2001, the ability
to account for the transaction without booking goodwill
6. Control shareholder owned similar percentage of each
class
7. High vote shares collectively were less than 50% of total
vote
23
Thepremiumpershareforcontrolhigh‐votesharesisafunctionof
thepercentageofthecompany’ssharesrepresentedbythatclass
Itisillogicaltopositthatthevotingpremiumisthesamepercentage
regardlessofthepercentageofsharesthatarehigh‐vote
Ifonesharehad100%ofthevote,woulditcommandahighpremium?
Therelevantfactoristherelationshipbetweentheaggregateamount
ofthepremiumpaidtothehigh‐votesharesasaclassasapercentage
oftheaggregateequityvalueofthecompany(excludingthevalueof
anydividendpreference)
Wedescribetheaggregatepremiumforthehigh‐voteclassdividedby
theequityvalueofthecompanyasthe“premiuminexcessof
economicinterest”
24
A company with 60% high-vote shares and 40% low-vote
shares with no dividend preference unifies its shares on a
1.25:1 basis
The voting shares have a 60% economic interest before the
unification and 66.7% after the unification [1.25 x 60% ÷
(1.25 x 60%) + 40%) = 80% ÷ 120% = 66.7%
Thus, the premium in excess of economic interest is 6.7%
If the non-voting shares have a dividend preference, the
risk-adjusted present value of the preference is a prior
charge and should be excluded from the economic interest
that is shared pro rata by the two classes
25
We have reviewed all U.S. transactions in the past 40 years in
which high-vote shares received greater consideration than
low-vote shares
For each transaction, we calculated the premium in excess
of economic interest
In the 1980’s, extremely high premiums in excess of
economic interest were paid for high-vote shares
Since 1990, these premiums have been about 3%
The median and mean premiums in acquisitions since 1990 are
3.4% and 3.8%
The median and mean premiums in unifications since 1990 are
2.1% and 2.4%
26
27
0%
3%
6%
9%
12%
15%
18%
21%
24%
1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014
Unifications
Acquisitions
Determine the value of low-vote class’s dividend
preference, if any, and apply it to the low-vote class
Determine the going-concern value of the company’s
equity (net of the dividend preference)
Then apply the appropriate “premium in excess of
economic interest” to equity value net of the preference
Premium is currently about 2½% - 3% in U.S.
Probably materially higher in Italy
The premium is added to the high-vote class’s
economic interest
⇒
28
The balance of the equity value is then divided pro
rata between the two classes in proportion to the
number of shares
The value per share of each class is calculated by
dividing the equity value attributed to each class by
the number of shares in each class
Add the per share value of any dividend preference to
the low-vote share value
If appropriate, the resultant values for non-control
shares are adjusted for marketability discounts
29
30
Shared
economic
interest Portion of
company value
shared pro rata
by high-vote and
low-vote shares
Value of control
shareholder[s]
votes
Value of non-control
shareholders votes
Value of dividend
preference
Company has 1 million voting shares and 1 million non-
voting shares with preference valued at € 1 million
Going-concern value of equity is € 61 million
Appropriate premium in excess of economic interest is 10%
Ergo
:
Premium to equity value for control is € 6 million
Balance of equity value is € 54 million
Value of voting class is €6 million + 50% of € 54 million
= $33 million = €33 per share
Value of non-voting class is € 1 million + 50% of € 54
million = $28 million = €28 per share
31
Premiums have been paid for high-vote shares in
several Canadian acquisitions
Most Canadian unifications have given no premium to
the high-vote shares
However, in the unification of Magna International, the
control shareholder received a huge premium –
approximately C$1 billion
The premium in excess of economic interest paid to
Magna’s control shareholder was 10% of the equity
value of Magna
32
Magna’s control shareholder owned 0.6% of the equity
but had 66% of vote
Litigation against the transaction was unsuccessful
The premium in excess of economic interest paid to
Magna’s control shareholder was 10%
Despite the overpayment and negative publicity, Magna
shareholders benefitted from a higher stock price
33
If the low-vote shares are entitled to a dividend
preference, this preference has a positive impact on
their value
The market premium in many studies has been
calculated based on the difference between the market
prices of shares of each class, with no adjustment for
any dividend preference
To calculate the market premium accurately, the price
of the low-vote shares should be appropriately
adjusted for the risk-adjusted present value of any
dividend preference
34
Valuation of high-vote shares depends on their ability to
affect control and/or participate in benefits to controller
1. Highest level –value in hands of controller
2. Major shareholder with partial or shared control
3. Potential swing vote with no single controller
4. No current value to voting right but potential for
participation in future premium
5. Lowest level – no reasonable expectation of receiving
higher price than low-vote shareholders
Purpose of valuation can be relevant –
e.g.,
is the
valuation for tax purposes or for a fairness opinion?
35
Importantly, the extra votes to which loyalty shares are
entitled are not transferable to third parties
The valuation of a control block of loyalty shares is the
same as a valuation of a control position in a company
without loyalty shares, unless there is a possibility that
a third party could accrue enough extra votes to
impact control by building up its holdings
Valuation of shares in a potential contest for control is
a complex and fact-specific issue that depends on the
probability of various factors
36
Loyalty shares owned by shareholders who are not
part of the control group are worth no more than
other minority shares
37
Dual class valuations are country-specific
Dual stock valuations must reflect the legal and social
factors that affect the value of control
To determine how a market values high-vote and low-
vote shares, it would be helpful to study and analyze not
only relevant stock market prices, but also the relative
prices paid in acquisitions and unifications
Most available studies generally do not provide data that
is useful to valuators
Some studies,
e.g.,
Dyck & Zingales (2004), look at
premiums paid for control blocks, which could provide
useful guidelines
38
Valuations of high-vote and low-vote shares are a subset of
valuations applying control premiums, minority discounts
and marketability discounts
Valuators should ask themselves whether their conclusions
as to the value of specific shares are consistent with the
conclusions they would have reached had the company not
had more than one class of shares
Valuators should ask themselves whether their conclusions
reflect prices that are consistent with what a willing buyer
might pay and a willing buyer might accept
39
High-vote and low-vote shares should be valued as a
class before calculating value per share
Appropriate adjustments must be made for dividend
preferences
Minority high-vote shares that cannot influence control
merit little or no premium over low-vote shares
A valuation should be consistent with the underlying
facts and circumstances
Do not use rules of thumb
Data used should be relevant to the transaction
40
I would like to thank
Prof. Bini and the OIV
for inviting me again
to this professional gathering
and for the opportunity
to share ideas with you
Your questions and comments are welcome
41
Amoako-Adu, B., B F. Smith and V. Baulkaran, “Unification of Dual Class Shares in
Canada with Clinical Case on Magna International,” working paper (2011)
Amoako-Adu, B. and B F. Smith, “Dual class firms: capitalization, ownership structure
and recapitalization back into single class,” 25
Journal of Banking and Finance
, 1083
(2001)
Ang, J S. and W.L. Megginson, “Restricted voting shares, ownership structure, and the
market value of dual-class firms”, 12
Journal of Financial Research
301 (1989)
Bechmann, K.L. and J. Raaballe, “The regulation of bids for dual class shares.
Implication: Two shares - one price,” 15
European Journal of Law and Economics
, 17
(2003)
Bennedsen, M. and K.N. Nielsen, “The Principle of Proportional Ownership, Investor
Protection and Firm Value in Western Europe,” ECGI - Finance Working Paper No.
134/2006 (2006)
Bennedsen, M. and K.N. Nielsen, “Incentive and entrenchment effects in European
ownership,” 34
Journal of Banking and Finance
2212 (2010)
Betzer, A., I. van der Bongard and M. Goerrnan, “Index membership vs. Loss of
Control: The Unification of Dual Class Shares,” working paper (2013)
Bigelli, M. and E. Croci. “Dividend privileges and the value of voting rights: Evidence
from Italy,” 24
Journal of Empirical Finance
94 (2013)
42
Bigelli, M., and S. Mengoli, “Self-expropriation versus self-interest in dual-class voting:
the Pirelli case study,”
Financial Management
677 (Fall 2011)
Bigelli, M., V. Mehrotra, and P.R. Rau, “Why are shareholders not paid to give up their
voting privileges? Unique evidence from Italy,” 17
Journal of Corporate Finance
1619
(2011)
Bortolon, M.P., and R.P Câmara, “Dual-class unifications and corporate governance in
Brazil,” 20
Emerging Markets Review
89 (2014)
Caprio, L. and E. Croci, “The determinants of the voting premium in Italy: The evidence
from 1974 to 2003,” 32
Journal of Banking and Finance
2433 (2007)
Carvalhal da Silva, A., and A. Subrahmanyam, “Dual-class premium, corporate
governance, and the mandatory bid rule: evidence from the Brazilian stock market,”
13
Journal of Corporate Finance
1 (2007)
Dyck, A. and L. Zingales, L.) “Private benefits of control: An international comparison,”
59
Journal of Finance
537 (2004
Dimitrov, V. and P.J. Jain, “Recapitalization of one class of common stock into dual-class:
Growth and long-run stock returns,” 12
Journal of Corporate Finance
342 (2006)
Dittmann, I., and N. Ulbricht, “Timing and Wealth Effects of German Dual Class Stock
Unifications,” 14
European Financial Management
163 (2008)
43
Ehrhardt, O., J. Kuklinski, and E. Nowak, “Unifications of Dual-Class Shares in Germany:
Empirical Evidence on the Effects of Related Changes in Ownership Structure, Market
Value and Bid-Ask Spreads,”
Swiss Finance Institute Research Paper Series No06–12
(2005)
Hauser, S. and B. Lauterbach, “The Value of Voting Rights to Majority Shareholders:
Evidence from Dual Class Stock Unifications,” 17
Review of Financial Studies
1167 (2004)
Kruse, T.A., “Owneship, Control and Shareholder Value in Italy: Olivetti’s Hostile Takeover
of Telecom Italia,” ECGI – Finance Working Paper No83/2005 (2005)
Lauterbach, B. and A. Pajuste, “The Media Role in Corporate Governance Improvement:
Lessons from Dual Class Share Unifications,” Working Paper (2014)
MacIntosh, J.G., “Some Reflections on
Magna
and Dual Class Structures, working paper
(2011)
Megginson, W., “Restricted voting stock acquisition premiums, and the market value of
corporate control,”25
The Financial Review
175 (1990)
Ødegaard, B.A., “Price Differences Between Equity Classes. Corporate Control, Foreign
Ownership or Liquidity?” 31
Journal of Banking and Finance
3621 (2007)
Zingales, L. What determines the value of corporate votes? 110
Quarterly Journal of
Economics
1047 (1995).
44