ArticlePDF Available

The Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT) in EUROMOD: a new instrument for comparative research on tax-benefit policies in Europe

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper introduces the Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT), a new extension of EUROMOD, the tax-benefit microsimulation model for the european Union. With HHoT, users can easily create their own hypothetical data, which enables them to better understand how policies work for households with specific characteristics. The tool creates unique possibilities for an enhanced analysis of taxes and social benefits in Europe by integrating results from population-based microsimulations and hypothetical household simulations in a single modelling framework. Furthermore, the flexibility of HHoT facilitates an advanced use of hypothetical household simulations to create new comparative policy indicators in the context of multi-country and longitudinal analyses. In this paper, we highlight the main features of HHoT, its strengths and limitations, and illustrate how it can be used for comparative policy analysis.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 68
RESEARCH ARTICLE
*For correspondence: tim.
goedeme@ spi. ox. ac. uk
Published: 31 December 2019
This article is distributed
under the terms of the Creative
Commons Attribution License,
which permits unrestricted use
and redistribution provided that
the original author and source
are credited.
Author Keywords:
Microsimulation Model,
Hypothetical Household
Simulations, European Union
© 2019, Hufkens et al.;
DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/
ijm. 00208
The Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT)
in EUROMOD: a new instrument for
comparative research on tax- benefit
policies in Europe
Tine Hufkens1,2, Tim Goedemé1,3*, Katrin Gasior4, Chrysa Leventi4,
Kostas Manios4, Olga Rastrigina4,5, Pasquale Recchia4,6, Holly Sutherland4,
Natascha Van Mechelen7,8, Gerlinde Verbist1
1Herman Deleeck Centre for Social Policy, University of Antwerp, Antwerp, Belgium;
2European Commission, Joint Research Centre (JRC), Seville, Spain; 3Department of
Social Policy and Intervention, Institute for New Economic Thinking at the Oxford
Martin School, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK; 4Institute for Social and Economic
Research, University of Essex, Essex, UK; 5Organisation for Economic Co- operation
and Development (OECD), Paris, France; 6Bank of Italy, Rome, Italy; 7Formerly
Herman Deleeck Centre for Social Policy, University of Antwerp, Antwerp, Belgium;
8Federal Public Service Social Security, Brussels, Belgium
Abstract This paper introduces the Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT), a new extension of
EUROMOD, the tax- benefit microsimulation model for the European Union. With HHoT, users can
easily create their own hypothetical data, which enables them to better understand how policies work
for households with specific characteristics. The tool creates unique possibilities for an enhanced
analysis of taxes and social benefits in Europe by integrating results from population- based microsim-
ulations and hypothetical household simulations in a single modelling framework. Furthermore, the
flexibility of HHoT facilitates an advanced use of hypothetical household simulations to create new
comparative policy indicators in the context of multi- country and longitudinal analyses. In this paper,
we highlight the main features of HHoT, its strengths and limitations, and illustrate how it can be used
for comparative policy analysis.
DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208
1. Introduction
In this paper, we introduce the Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT). HHoT is an extension of the
European tax- benefit microsimulation model EUROMOD that allows the user to generate hypothet-
ical households with a wide range of characteristics in a flexible environment. These households can
subsequently be used as an input database for EUROMOD to assess how tax- benefit policies work and
interact with each other. Traditionally, EUROMOD is used for analysing the distributive, labour market
and budgetary impact of tax- benefit policies and policy changes. To do so, detailed and representa-
tive data on persons and households are required. With the HHoT extension, users can create their
own hypothetical data, which allows them to better understand how policies work for households with
specific characteristics, while giving them full control over the characteristics of interest. This creates
unique possibilities for an enhanced analysis of taxes and social benefits in Europe by integrating
results from hypothetical household simulations and population- based microsimulations in a single
modelling framework. The flexibility of HHoT facilitates the simulation of a range of comparative
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 69
indicators such as the marginal effective tax rate, the net replacement rate and unemployment or
inactivity traps for a large set of hypothetical households in a comparative setting.
In what follows, we first briefly elaborate on the differences and synergies between microsimu-
lation based on representative microdata, and hypothetical household simulations in the context of
analysing tax- benefit policies. Subsequently, we introduce the EUROMOD framework and the HHoT
extension. In the third part we illustrate several ways in which HHoT can be used for policy analysis.
This paper accompanies a paper by Gasior and Recchia (2019), which presents baseline results of
HHoT for 2017 policies in the EU.
2. The complementarity of population-based microsimulation
and hypothetical household simulations
With hypothetical household simulations, also known as model- family analysis or standard simulations,
the researcher specifies detailed characteristics of a limited set of households. In the case of tax-
benefit simulation, these households and their specifications are used to compute the households’ tax
liabilities and benefit entitlements as well as detailed information on income components and total
disposable income. In contrast to hypothetical household simulations, population- based microsimula-
tion makes use of representative microdata (eg, collected in a household survey or from tax registers
and social security registers) for which tax liabilities and benefit entitlements are computed, thus
taking into account the full heterogeneity of household characteristics in the population[1].
Hypothetical household simulations have several strengths that make them an attractive tool for
policy analysis. (1) Given that users can fully control the characteristics of hypothetical data, it is possible
to generate indicators of the institutional functioning of tax- benefit systems that are independent of
cross- national or longitudinal variations in population characteristics (eg, regarding work incentives,
benefit generosity, income adequacy, targeting, replacement rates, implicit equivalence scales), thus
allowing for a comparative analysis of the institutional structure of tax- benefit systems that isolates the
effect of tax- benefit policies from the composition of the population. This is particularly relevant when
evaluating policies that can have a non- negligible impact on the characteristics of the population. For
instance, when studying work incentives of tax- benefit policies, the incidence of certain household
types and work patterns themselves are likely to be influenced by the work incentives that flow from
these tax- benefit policies. If this results in a relatively low incidence of household compositions and
work behaviours that are financially discouraged, population- based simulations might not be able to
reveal, or risk to downplay, the discouraging incentives that result from the tax- benefit system, given
the low incidence of these situations in the data. Hypothetical household simulations are particularly
useful for describing tax- benefit systems across countries with different policy designs. Microsimu-
lation analysis using population- based data may put less weight on policies that encourage certain
demographic behaviours (eg, two- earner orientated policies), whereas this becomes more clear when
using similar household types across countries. (2) For the same reason, it is possible to illustrate in
an accessible way for very simple (or rather complex) households how tax- benefit systems operate
and how policies interact with each other. This allows users to grasp more easily how tax- benefit
systems (or potential policy reforms) work and facilitates the validation of tax- benefit calculations. (3)
Given that users generate their own hypothetical households, it is possible to assess the functioning
of tax- benefit policies when adequate representative household data are lacking. For instance, this
applies to studying households that are too rare in household samples for a reliable statistical analysis
(eg, single- parent families with three or more children under the age of 7); and to situations when
very up- to- date simulations are required (representative survey data or register data typically become
available with quite some delay); or when aspects of policies require variables which are unavailable in
the dataset (eg, on health or assets).
By their specific nature, hypothetical household simulations are not fit for distributive analysis
and for drawing conclusions about the population as a whole (see also Immervoll etal. (2004) for
a discussion of some limitations of hypothetical household analysis). In other words, they cannot
1. Both population- based and hypothetical household simulations work with information on households and
individuals and can thus be considered microsimulations. However, in tax- benefit analyses that make use of
hypothetical household simulations, the term ‘microsimulation’ is often reserved for referring exclusively to
population- based microsimulations, in contrast to hypothetical household simulations.
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 70
show the aggregated impact of policies or policy reforms at the population level, eg, in terms of
poverty, inequality, budgetary effects, or overall labour market participation. This can only be done
on the basis of representative household data (either through a sample or population data) and,
when analysing the impact on eg, labour supply, in combination with a behavioural model. Thus,
population- based microsimulation is required whenever researchers want to say something about
the effect on a population, rather than describing the institutional architecture of tax- benefit systems.
It stands out, though, that in many cases hypothetical household simulations and population- based
microsimulations are complementary to each other. For instance, when studying a reform related
to the progressivity of taxation it is useful to see how progressive personal income taxes are in
relation to the population under study and how a change impacts different parts of the population.
However, given that results depend on the composition of the population under consideration, when
comparing countries it is useful to complement such an analysis with an analysis of how different
systems would perform for the same set of (hypothetical) households. Both approaches can also
generate different indicators of closely related phenomena (eg, hypothetical household simulations
of the extent to which social assistance benefits reach the poverty threshold, jointly with a study of
social assistance coverage and non- take- up). So far though, most comparative studies either make
use of one approach or the other, rather than using them jointly in a synergetic way, because models
are either based on population- based or on hypothetical household data. With HHoT integrated in
EUROMOD, the same tax- benefit model can be used for both population- based microsimulation
and hypothetical household simulations, in a single framework, implying that it is much easier to
combine the strengths of both approaches. Furthermore, EUROMOD allows doing this in a compar-
ative context (multiple countries and/or years) as well as analysing the effect of policy reforms rather
than just the status quo.
EUROMOD is the cross- country tax- benefit model for the European Union, used by both academics
and policy analysts. Many countries also have national models (eg, IZAΨMOD for Germany, TAXBEN
for the UK, FASIT for Sweden, etc.) (Li etal., 2014). Population- based microsimulation studies require
the availability of (comparable) representative household microdata with sufficient information to
assess tax liabilities and benefit entitlements. Such data have only been available since the late 1990s
in many EU countries. The advantage of running microsimulation models on representative household
data is the possibility to carry out distributional analyses, and to show the effects of tax- benefit poli-
cies and tax- benefit reforms on the distribution of work incentives and disincentives across the popu-
lation and on government budgets (Li etal., 2014; Sutherland and Figari, 2013and Van Mechelen
and Verbist, 2005).
With regard to hypothetical household simulations, several databases have been created which
contain for a limited set of hypothetical households tax- benefit simulations that span an extended
time period and cover a wider range of countries. Examples include the CSB Minimum Income
Protection Indicators database CSB- MIPI (Van Mechelen etal., 2011) and the Social Assistance and
Minimum Income Protection Interim Dataset SaMIP (Nelson, 2013). The main drawback of these
databases is that they contain information for a limited number of cases, and simulations are hard-
wired: one cannot assess what would happen if the policy rules were changed. Furthermore, updating
is typically done in a more ad- hoc way given that it is rather demanding to generate the data (see,
for instance, Marx and Nelson (2013), for a more detailed description and applications of the use
of these databases). An exception to these two limitations is the OECD Tax- Benefit Calculator, which
is specifically designed to carry out hypothetical household simulations for tax- benefit policies, in a
flexible and user- friendly environment (eg, Immervoll, 2010; OECD, 2014)[2]. Recently the OECD
developed a tax- benefit web calculator that enables users to quickly see and compare the tax liabili-
ties and benefits entitlements in 40 OECD and EU member states. Family types, the income situation
and the percentage of the average wage can be changed easily. Previous versions of EUROMOD
already included a basic tool to simulate tax- benefit rules for hypothetical households. Compared to
the OECD tool, HHoT/EUROMOD has the advantage that it allows for integrating population- based
and hypothetical household simulations in a single modelling framework, and that it is more flexible in
terms of specifying household characteristics and the simulation of policy reforms. At the same time,
2. See https://www.oecd.org/els/soc/tax-benefit-web-calculator/ (last accessed December 2018).
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 71
this flexibility implies that the tool is also less accessible than the OECD online calculator for those not
familiar with EUROMOD.
3. The integration of hypothetical household simulations in
EUROMOD
EUROMOD is both a software platform and the tax- benefit microsimulation model for the EU (Suther-
land and Figari, 2013). From the beginning, the aim of EUROMOD was to develop an accessible model
that facilitates comparative research (Immervoll and O'Donoghue, 2009). As a result, EUROMOD is
characterised by a drive for comparable policy modelling and the use of largely comparable and
detailed microdata (now mostly EU- SILC). The scope of the simulated tax- benefit policies is limited to
parameters for which the household data provide sufficient information. Consequently, policies that
require longitudinal information on contribution records are not simulated (in particular contributory
pensions). The model is built and maintained by a group of researchers from universities, research
institutes and ministries from all EU countries under the coordination of a team of researchers at the
University of Essex[3]. Continuing support from the European Commission ensures regular updates of
the model (policy rules) and the data (Sutherland and Figari, 2013). The cross- country comparability,
the flexibility of the modelling software, the regular updates and the standardised validation of the
model are important features to meet the increasing demand from users of hypothetical household
simulations.
For many years, EUROMOD contained a very basic hypothetical household generator. This tool
was mostly used for the validation of the model, even though it could also be used to understand tax-
benefit systems by separating the effect of tax- benefit rules from the effects of the populations struc-
ture (Berger etal., 2001). However, it was not very flexible: there were strong limits on the extent
to which household characteristics could be manipulated. To enlarge the possibilities of hypothetical
household simulations with EUROMOD, we designed the Hypothetical Household Tool – HHoT. The
tool, based on the experience of experts in both population- based microsimulation and hypothetical
household analysis, was developed as part of the InGRID- project, an infrastructure project funded
by the European Union's seventh Framework Programme (Hufkens etal., 2016). A first version of
EUROMOD incorporating HHoT was released to the user community in December 2017, covering
policies from 2009 up to 2017.
HHoT is a EUROMOD extension for generating hypothetical households. It can be accessed within
the standard EUROMOD user interface under Applications. The user generates a EUROMOD dataset
by specifying households and the characteristics of the household members. Once the households are
generated, the dataset can be used within EUROMOD to simulate tax liabilities and benefit entitle-
ments as well as detailed information on income components and total disposable household income
for the hypothetical households. This EUROMOD output dataset can thereafter be analysed with
software of the user’s choice. By defining the group at risk (eg, employed, unemployed, inactive) in
the tool, HHoT follows a ‘risk- type approach’ for hypothetical household simulations: the user defines
the characteristics of the households on the basis of generic assumptions, subsequently the simula-
tion model 'decides' which policies are applicable (cf. Van Mechelen etal., 2011). When running the
simulation model, the hypothetical households are treated as if they were real households in a micro-
dataset. Thus, the user needs to make sure to specify the personal and household characteristics such
that the hypothetical household is eligible for the taxes and benefits of interest.
The tool allows the user to specify the characteristics of households for all parameters that are
used in the EUROMOD model. To make it more user- friendly, a distinction is made between standard
and advanced variables. In the case of standard variables the user manipulates a limited number
of characteristics and makes use of default values for all other variables. In the case of advanced
variables, users have full control over all characteristics that are used in the simulations. The user
can define in a flexible way the characteristics of the hypothetical households: in contrast to typical
3. The European Commission is in the process of taking over responsibility for carrying out the annual update
and release of EUROMOD. The transfer of responsibility is expected to be complete by the end of 2020 and the
transition is being facilitated by close cooperation between the University of Essex and the Joint Research Centre
(JRC) of the European Commission as well as Eurostat. The EC intends to continue to provide the model and the
software to its users.
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 72
hypothetical household data or simulations, multi- generational households and complex household
compositions can be generated, while also characteristics such as tenure status, region of residence,
sector of employment, etc., can be changed. The possible employment statuses are employee, self-
employed, unemployed, pensioner, student/pupil or preschool. All numeric variables (eg, age, earn-
ings or housing costs) can be specified either as a single value or as a range. When specifying a range,
the same hypothetical household is reproduced for each value within the range while keeping all
other characteristics constant. It is also possible to include a ‘reference table’ to specify quantitative
variables as a percentage of a value in the reference table rather than in absolute terms. For instance,
gross earnings can be specified as a percentage of the country and year specific minimum wage, the
average wage or another reference wage. The tool allows users to include their own reference tables.
Hypothetical households can be given recognisable names and can be saved for later use.
It is easy to run EUROMOD for the same set of hypothetical households simultaneously for multiple
policy years and countries. As is the case for population- based microsimulations, users have full control
over the simulated policies and can decide to ‘switch on’ or ‘switch off’ policies, or simulate the effect
of a policy reform or ‘policy swap’. Furthermore, advanced users can revise the EUROMOD baseline
by introducing new policy parameters and new policies that require data that are not available in
the microdata, but can be taken into account when specifying the characteristics of the hypothetical
households in HHoT. A user manual of HHoT is available online[4].
The flexibility of HHoT allows users to easily create numerous hypothetical households (especially
when specifying a range for more than one numeric variable) for several countries and years. However,
it is essential to always assess whether the assumptions hold equally across countries or policy years.
Users should also be aware that compared to other hypothetical household simulations (eg, CSB-
MIPI), results based on HHoT are not always the same, largely because of differences in the level
of detail with which some policy measures are modelled (see Hufkens etal., 2016; Marchal etal.,
2019). As a user of HHoT, it is therefore important to be aware of the extent to which policies are
simulated in EUROMOD.
4. Potential applications of HHoT
The possibilities of policy relevant uses of HHoT are numerous. In this section we describe briefly four
examples of how HHoT can create an added- value for the analysis of tax- benefit policies. The exam-
ples are drawn from various strands of research and make use of different household specifications to
show the flexibility of HHoT. In the first example we show how hypothetical household simulations can
complement insights from population- based microsimulations in the case of a simple policy reform. In
subsequent illustrations, we only present results based on hypothetical household simulations, even
though there could be complementarities with population- based microsimulations. In the second
example, we identify the gross wage level that is required to reach the level of the poverty line in a
selection of EU- countries. This exercise makes use of the option to vary flexibly the range of gross
income for each household member. Then we calculate implicit equivalence scales of the tax- benefit
system in four EU- countries, showing that with HHoT it is also very easy to change other household
characteristics, such as household composition. In the last exercise we show the marginal effective
tax rates for all EU- countries and explain some of the differences across countries and income levels.
Unless specified otherwise, we assume that the hypothetical households live in the capital region
(insofar regional policies are relevant and simulated in EUROMOD).
4.1. Example 1: Combining population-based microsimulation and
hypothetical household simulations to measure the impact of a policy
change
In Germany, like in many other countries, children in single parent families face a relatively high
poverty risk (Commission, and E, 2014; Eurostat, 2017; Lenze, 2014). Reforming child benefits
(Kindergeld) can reduce the at- risk- of- poverty rate for families with children. We simulate a simple
4. See https://www.euromod.ac.uk/publications/euromod-hypothetical-household-tool-hhot-%E2%80%93-us-
er-manual (last accessed February 2018).
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 73
reform aimed at reducing child poverty in single parent families in Germany to illustrate how hypo-
thetical household simulations and population- based microsimulations can jointly help to design
and understand policies. With the current child benefit system, the level of child benefit depends
on the rank of the child in the family. In 2016, the level of the child benefit was 190 euro per month
for the first and second child, 196 euro per month for the third and 221 euro per month for all
other children. The benefit is paid to one of the parents. Child benefits are non means- tested,
non- taxable benefits. At the same time, child benefits are part of the definition of income that is
used for the income test of Unemployment Benefit II (Arbeitslosengeld II), social assistance related
benefit (Sozialhilfe) and general social assistance. Apart from child benefits, families with children
are entitled to a tax allowance for children. This allowance is only granted to parents if it is more
beneficial to receive the tax allowance than the child benefit and is mostly relevant to higher income
households. A third benefit that aims at improving the financial situation of families with children
is the additional child benefit (Kinderzuschlag). The additional child benefit is, in contrast to the
Kindergeld, means- tested. To be eligible for the additional child benefit, households also need
to be eligible for Kindergeld. (eg, Gallego Granados and Harnisch, 2017). In the reform that we
simulate below, we focus on the design of the child benefits only. The reform scenario is budgetary
neutral compared to the baseline.
In the reform scenario we abolish the current system based on ranks and replace it by a fixed
amount for each child. Children in two- parent households receive 180 euro per month while children
in single parent households are entitled to 248 euro per month. As illustrated in Table1, we simulate
the effect of the reforms for four different households, while varying the labour market status of the
adults. In households with only one child, the child is 8 years old, in households with three children, the
Table 1. Summary of hypothetical households used in example 1
Demographic composition Labour market status adults
Couple (2 earners) with child (8 years)
Employee – full time at minimum
wage Inactive
Single with child (8 years)
Couple (2 earner) with 3 children (5, 8
and 12 years)
Single with 3 children (5, 8 and 12
years)
Table 2. Net disposable income and different income components for four hypothetical households,
minimum wage, 2016
Two adults with 1
child
One adult with 1
child
Two adults with 3
children
One adult with 3
children
Baseline Reform Baseline Reform Baseline Reform Baseline Reform
Total Total Total Total Total Total Total Total
Gross earnings 2,947 2,947 1,473 1,473 2,947 2,947 1,473 1,473
Total taxes 220 220 70 70 220 220 70 70
SIC employee 602 602 301 301 602 602 301 301
Means- tested
benets 0 0 0 0 0 0 410 410
Non- means- tested
Child Benet 190 180 190 248 576 540 576 744
Disposable income 2,315 2,305 1,293 1,351 2,701 2,665 2,089 2,257
Source: own calculations based on EUROMOD H1.0+ and HHoT.
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 74
children are aged 5, 8 and 12. We first present the effect of the reform on the situation of households
in which all adults work full time at the minimum wage, and subsequently on the situation in which all
adult household members are inactive[5].
The table below shows the effect of the policy change for the four hypothetical households in the
case that adult household members are at work. From Table2 it can be seen that the financial situa-
tion of single parent households improves after the reform while disposable income decreases in two
parent households irrespective of the number of children.
Because child benefits are not taxed in Germany and the sociodemographic and labour market
characteristics of the simulated hypothetical households are unchanged, Table 2 shows that the
benefit reform does not interact with any other part of the tax- benefit system. However, this is not the
case for all households. If we change the labour market status of adults in the hypothetical households
from ‘employee’ to ‘inactive’, there is an interaction between the non- means- tested child benefit and
means- tested benefits. For all households illustrated in Table3, the reformed child benefit does not
result in a changed disposable income. The increase or decrease of the child benefit is fully compen-
sated by a lower or higher Unemployment Benefit II[6]. The income test of the Unemployment Benefit
5. Inactive here means that the person does not meet the conditions with regard to contribution or employment
history, but that he or she is available for the labour market, and hence entitled to Unemployment benefit II.
6. Unemployment Benefits II or Arbeitslosengeld II are means- tested benefits for people who are not employed
and who not receive any contributory unemployment benefits (or whose contributory unemployment benefits do
not entirely cover their basic needs) (Gallego Granados and Harnisch, 2017).
Table 3. Net disposable income and different income components for four hypothetical households,
inactive, 2016
Two adults with 1
child
One adult with 1
child
Two adults with 3
children
One adult with 3
children
Baseline Reform Baseline Reform Baseline Reform Baseline Reform
Total Total Total Total Total Total Total Total
Gross earnings 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Total taxes 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
SIC employee 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Means- tested
benets 1,096 1,106 861 803 1,082 1,118 886 718
Non- means- tested
Child benet 190 180 190 248 576 540 576 744
Disposable income 1,111 1,111 876 876 1,658 1,658 1,462 1,462
Source: own calculations based on EUROMOD H1.0+ and HHoT.
Table 4. At- risk- of- poverty rate of persons living in Germany, by family type, 2016
Baseline Reform
Difference
Change Standard error
90% confidence interval
Lower bound Upper bound
Population 15.15 15.19 0.04 0.04 –0.02 0.11
One adult with children 25.04 24.28 –0.75 0.44 –1.48 –0.03
Two adults with children 11.53 11.75 0.21 0.12 0.02 0.41
We use a xed poverty line at 60% of the median equivalised disposable income in the baseline.
Source: own calculations based on EUROMOD H1.0 and EU- SILC 2014, full sample design information is not
available. For estimating the standard errors and condence intervals, we take account of clustering within
households and the covariance between the simulated scenarios (Goedemé, 2013; Goedemé etal., 2013).
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 75
II considers income from employment, pensions and most benefits, including the child benefit (but not
the additional child benefit).
Tables2 and 3 show the income components of some hypothetical households, illustrating the
possible impact of the reform. The hypothetical household simulations make it easier for researchers
and policy- makers to understand how the tax- benefit system operates and how the policies interact
with each other. Besides, they help researchers and policy- makers to grasp the effect on vulnerable
groups that might be underrepresented in the microdata. However, the hypothetical households are
not representative for the population. Using a representative sample of the population we calculate
the first- order poverty effects of this reform. Table 4 shows poverty headcounts for the baseline
and the reform scenario and the difference between the two. Even though the hypothetical house-
hold simulations make clear that for some household types disposable income would be substantially
increased, the overall (first order) effect on poverty in Germany is not significant. In contrast, the
poverty risk of persons living in single parent households decreases significantly at the 90% confi-
dence level, which was the objective of the reform. For persons living in households consisting of two
adults and at least one child there is a small, but significant increase in the poverty risk. Focussing
on the at- risk- of poverty rate we could conclude that this reform improves the income situation of
lone parents with low incomes. HHoT however, allowed us to easily disentangle the effects for active
and inactive households and to see the interaction between the child benefits and the means- tested
benefit that might be hidden in microsimulation results based on population- data.
4.2. Example 2: How much should one earn to have an income above
the at-risk-of-poverty threshold?
In the EU, the at- risk- of- poverty indicator is one of the headline indicators for monitoring poverty
and social exclusion. Given that the threshold is set at 60 percent of the national median equivalent
disposable household income, it may be difficult to grasp the kind of living standard that is feasible in
each member state with an income at the level of the threshold (Goedemé etal., 2019). By using the
flexibility of HHoT, it is relatively easy to identify at which wage level a household can have a dispos-
able income at the level of the poverty threshold. This is helpful for further contextualising the at- risk-
of- poverty indicator, ie, to make clear what the implications are of using a relative poverty threshold
specified in this way. Also, more information on the required gross wage level to reach the at- risk- of-
poverty threshold could help to better understand quantitative analyses of (cross- country variations in)
in- work poverty. As the simulations below show, the required wage does not only depend on the level
of the poverty threshold, but also on the applicable tax liabilities and benefit entitlements. Impor-
tantly, when interpreting the results it should be kept in mind that wage levels vary in non- negligible
ways in the population (eg, by gender and level of education). This implies that it would be worthwhile
to complement the analysis with an alternative set of reference wages.
The approach is very similar to first estimating budget constraints, and subsequently selecting
the gross wage which corresponds with the relevant disposable household income (see Gasior and
Recchia (2019) for HHoT baseline results for budget constraints in the EU). In a first step we calcu-
late the 60% at- risk- of- poverty threshold on the basis of EU- SILC, with net incomes simulated by
EUROMOD[7]. In a second step, we use HHoT and EUROMOD to calculate the disposable income
for hypothetical households earning a predetermined percentage of the average wage, which we
vary between 60% and 200%. Average gross wages per full- year, full- time equivalent employee refer
7. Please note that the computed poverty thresholds differ somewhat from those published by Eurostat, and the
cross- national variation in this deviation depends on the size of simulation error. In this exercise, we preferred to
keep consistency between HHoT outputs and the estimated threshold, both simulated with the use of EURO-
MOD.
Table 5. Summary of hypothetical households used in example 2
Demographic composition Labour market status adults
Single Employee(s), full time, wage varying from 60% to 200% of
average gross wage*[
Couple (2 earners) with 2 children (5 and 8 years)
*Although we show only one outcome, different combinations of the wages of both partners are possible.
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 76
to 2014 and were downloaded from the OECD database (OECD, 2017). In a third step we identify
the gross wage level which corresponds with a disposable income at, or just above, the level of the
poverty threshold. As illustrated in Table5, simulations are carried out for a hypothetical single- person
household consisting of a 35 years old male, working full time. The second hypothetical household is a
married couple, 35 years old, both working full time. They have two children aged 5 and 8 years old.
For the couple- household, we assume both partners are working, and we vary the gross income of
both partners from 60% to 200% of the average gross wage. To do this, we imported a separate table
in HHoT containing the average gross wages that we downloaded from the OECD online database.
Different combinations of the gross wages of both parents are possible; in this exercise we select
the income that results in a total disposable household income closest to, but above the poverty
threshold[8].
Figure1 shows the gross income, presented as a percentage of the average wage (OECD, 2017),
that is required to reach a disposable income at the level of the at- risk- of- poverty threshold in each
country and for the two hypothetical households. In Poland, Estonia, France and Hungary a single
person working full time requires a gross income of around 80% of the average wage or more to reach
the threshold. In contrast, in Portugal, Italy, Ireland and Greece 60% of the gross average wage suffices
to reach an income just above the poverty line. Despite the relative character of the poverty threshold,
this is quite a substantial difference. A similar observation can be made for two- earner couples (both
working full time) with two children, even though countries score differently as compared to single-
person households. While a single person in Hungary should earn about 85% of the average gross
wage to reach the threshold, a couple with two children requires a total level of earnings of about
150% of the average gross wage, although the at- risk- of- poverty threshold of a household with two
children is 2.1 times as high as the threshold for a single- person household. Compared to the other
countries, the (relatively small) difference between the gross wage for a single person and the total
gross wage for a couple with two children is remarkable. This shows how the Hungarian tax- benefit
system favours couples with children compared to singles (see also Example three below). At the other
extreme, in Portugal a couple with two children should earn about 130% of the average gross wage,
while 65% of the average gross wage suffices for a single- person household. In Hungary an important
part of the increase in disposable income is due to an increase in benefits, whereas in Portugal the
8. We assume both hypothetical households are tenants, but, given that we only want to illustrate the approach,
we do not include housing- related expenditures in the simulation (which may affect housing benefits and tax
reductions).
Figure 1. Gross wage needed to reach the at- risk- of- poverty line, as a percentage of the average gross wage per
full- year full- time equivalent employee, for a hypothetical family , 2014.
Source: own calculations using EUROMOD H1.0+ and HHoT; poverty threshold and average wages based on EUROMOD
calculations using EU- SILC. Note: countries sorted from lowest to highest percentage of the gross average wage needed to
reach a disposable income at the level of poverty threshold for a single- person household. The selection of countries is based on
availability in EUROMOD and availability of the average gross wage (for 2014 in the OECD online database at the time of writing).
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 77
impact of benefits is rather small. Also, the effect of the tax system (through joint taxation for couples
such as in France, or tax advantages for families with children such as in Italy) can explain differences
between countries. A recent similar exercise, done by the OECD on 'working hours needed to exit
poverty' (OECD, 2019), leads to a comparable conclusion that the design of tax- benefit policies is
of great importance when comparing low- income families across countries. More specifically, it is the
variation in the implicit equivalence scale of tax- benefit policies which drives the variation in the addi-
tional gross wage required by couples with children as compared to single person households to have
a net income above the poverty line, a topic to which we turn in the next example.
4.3. Example 3: Implicit equivalence scales
Microsimulations based on population data could show how the net incomes of persons living in
different household types compare to each other and how, on average, the level and composition of
incomes vary. However, these comparisons are limited by the fact that hours worked and wage levels
tend to be partially determined by household composition. This implies that it is difficult to judge from
these results alone how tax- benefit systems support different household types. For this reason, it can
be revealing to calculate ‘implicit equivalence scales’ based on hypothetical data. For the purposes of
this exercise, we define the implicit equivalence scale of a tax- benefit system as the extent to which a
tax- benefit system treats multi- person households of different size and composition more favourably
than a single person household with the same level of gross earnings, in terms of taxes to be paid and
eligibility for receiving social benefits. It is typically measured as the ratio of the disposable income
of two households that have the same gross wage and similar other characteristics, except for the
demographic composition of the household. This shows how policies work in their pure form, and
can help to better understand, for instance, the distribution of poverty risks by household type. The
calculations are similar to those done in the previous exercise, but now we compare more directly
incomes between household types with a similar level of gross income. Further breakdowns can show
how not only the level, but also the composition of net incomes differs by household type as a result
of tax- benefit policies such that one can identify the policies that drive the implicit equivalence scales.
We calculate implicit equivalence scales for hypothetical households living in Belgium (Flanders),
Italy (Lombardia), Greece (capital region) and Hungary (capital region), and take account of the rele-
vant regional policies. The household types included in the analysis in terms of demographic compo-
sition and labour market status are displayed in Table 6. For this exercise, the income ranges are
based on the average wages calculated using the EUROMOD microdata files (based on EU- SILC).
When comparing net incomes between two household types, wages are kept constant. In principle
it is desirable to keep also all other characteristics ‘constant’, in spite of the changing composition of
the household. Given the availability and setup of housing- related benefits in some countries, housing
costs are an important issue in this context. In principle, one could opt for keeping housing costs
constant across household types, but this is often not a realistic assumption. Therefore, in this example
we started from the level of housing costs that were estimated in another project. More in particular,
we made use of the housing cost associated with renting an adequate dwelling on the private market
at the 30th percentile of the distribution of housing costs for the relevant household composition, in
the relevant region (Van den Bosch etal., 2016). In the case of a more in- depth analysis, it would be
worthwhile to undertake sensitivity tests with alternative assumptions regarding housing costs, as we
will show below.
Table 6. Summary of hypothetical households used in example 3
Demographic
composition Labour market status adults (one- earner families)
Single
Inactive Employee, 50% of
average EU- SILC wage
Employee, 100% of
average EU- SILC wage
Employee, 200% of
average EU- SILC wage
Couple
Single with child of 10
years old
Couple with child of 10
years old
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 78
In Figure2, we show the net income of three household types as a percentage of the net income
of a single- person household, having the same level of gross earnings. The households are one- earner
households, in the case of couples one partner is assumed to be inactive on the labour market. With
HHoT it is easy to make variations for more complex households, but we limit ourselves in this illustra-
tion to households with one child. Several observations stand out. First, when looking at differences
within countries between different levels of earnings, it is clear that implicit equivalence scales are
generally above one and higher for inactive persons and for households with lower wages [9]. This
probably has a mitigating effect on poverty for multi- person households living on a low income, even
though the size of the effect will vary by the poverty measure used [10]. In contrast, in all four countries
included in Figure2, the implicit equivalence scale at 200% of the average wage is broadly similar
to the implicit equivalence scale for households with earnings at 100% of the average wage. While in
Greece and Hungary equivalence scales are higher for inactive households as compared to working
households earning 50% of the average wage (both for adding a partner or a child), in Belgium the
implicit equivalence scale for adding an inactive partner is lower than the scale for adding a partner
in a working low- income household (without a child). Second, countries vary strongly in the level of
implicit equivalence scales, and the ranking of the four countries differs substantially depending on
the household composition under consideration. It is noteworthy that in Italy adding a partner to a
single- person household does not make a difference for the tax- benefit system, while adding a child
does make a difference. For working families in Belgium and Hungary the implicit equivalence scales
of the tax- benefit system are higher for an additional partner as compared to a child, while in Greece
and Italy it is the other way around. This shows how the tax- benefit systems across the four countries
result in different outcomes in the degree to which they support (or do not support) households with
a different demographic composition. Apart from showing how these tax- benefit systems operate,
9. When the labour status is inactive, EUROMOD\HHoT simulates full take- up of social assistance for hypotheti-
cal households. In Italy (Lombardia) there is no social assistance (Frazer and Marlier, 2015).
10. The total effect on poverty also depends on the impact that implicit equivalence scales have on the level of
the poverty threshold, and behavioural effects that result from implicit equivalence scales (eg, in terms of deci-
sions with regard to living together and having children or regarding labour supply).
Figure 2. Net income for three household types expressed as a percentage of the net income of a single- person
household with the same gross wage, but without children, 2014.
Note: Positive values for taxes and social contributions indicate that a household with a child pays less in taxes or social
contributions, or receive higher tax credits. Source: own calculations using EUROMOD H1.0+ and HHoT; average wage based on
EUROMOD calculations using EU- SILC.
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 79
more insight into implicit equivalence scales can also help to better understand varying patterns of
poverty and inequality.
It is also interesting to see which part of the tax- benefit system contributes to the observed implicit
equivalence scales. Therefore, in Figures3 and 4 we describe the different income components that
increase the income for a family with a child compared to a family without a child (note that given
our focus on child- related tax- benefit generosity, we use the income of a couple without a child in
the denominator in Figure4). More specifically, it shows the difference in the level of each income
Figure 3. Tax- benet package for a child in a single parent household, income components expressed as a
percentage of the net income of a single parent household without children, 2014.
Source: own calculations using EUROMOD H1.0+ and HHoT; average wage based on EUROMOD calculations using EU- SILC.
Figure 4. Tax- benet package for a child in a couple parent household, income components compared to the net
income in a couple household without children, 2014.
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 80
component (when adding a child), expressed as a percentage of the net income of a similar household
without a child, at a similar level of gross earnings. Not surprisingly, child benefits tend to account
for most of the difference, while social contributions are no different for households with a child as
compared to those without a child. Additional advantages for a single- person households with a child
can include both support directed to lone parents specifically, or to households with children more
generally. As an exception, for inactive households in Belgium and households earning 50% of the
average gross wage in Greece the increase of the net income is mostly due to a higher level of social
assistance benefits, especially for single- parent households, compared to single- person households
the difference in social assistance in the tax- benefit package is much smaller for couples. Even though
the contribution of personal income taxes is significant at higher levels of earnings (especially for
couples with a child), it is relatively small, and non- existent in Greece. In Hungary the housing allow-
ance also varies by household composition, resulting in higher benefits for households with a child.
4.4. Example 4: Work incentives
Another area where hypothetical data can be of use is the analysis of work incentives. One way to
look at tax- benefit systems is to analyse to what extent they encourage their workforce to take up a
job (work incentive on the extensive margin) and to what extent they encourage to work/earn more
(work incentive on the intensive margin). In this example, we focus on the marginal effective tax rate
(METR) which measures the (dis)incentive to work/earn more, expressed as the share of an earnings
increase that is taxed away due to higher social insurance contributions, higher taxes, or the loss of
benefit entitlement. We assume a 3% earnings increase in our calculations using the methodological
approach suggested by Jara and Tumino (2013). METRs usually take values between 0 and 100,
indicating respectively high work incentives when individuals keep the full earnings increase and low
incentives when individuals lose the full earnings increase. However, certain aspects of the tax- benefit
Table 7. Summary of hypothetical households used in example 4
Household composition Labour market status
Single
Employee, full time with between 80% and 120% of the EU- SILC average
wage (in 1% steps).
Figure 5. Decomposition of average METRs for a single person household at earnings levels from 80% to 120% of
average earnings by income component, 2017 policy system.
Source: own calculations using EUROMOD H1.0+ (Gasior and Recchia, 2019). Note: SIC = social insurance contributions.
Countries are ranked by the percentage of marginal earnings increase taxed away. Policy system 2017 refers to the status quo on
30th of June 2017. Results are based on the assumption of full tax- compliance and full benefit take- up.
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 81
system might also lead to higher or lower values. We visualise how different elements of the tax-
benefit system react to the 3% earnings increase.
All results are based on a single- person household assuming full- time employment of 40 hours
per week (cf. Table7). Country- specific average monthly gross earnings levels are calculated using
EU- SILC 2015 data and updated to 2017 using country- specific uprating factors (see Supplementary
data for estimated average wages and Gasior and Recchia, 2019 for more detailed information). The
person is assumed to live in rented accommodation with housing costs of 20% of the average earn-
ings. As is the case for previous examples, we assume full take- up of benefits as well as full compliance
in reporting incomes to tax authorities in all countries.
Figure5 shows (unweighted) average METRs for earners with 80% to 120% (in 1% steps) of average
earnings decomposed by taxes, social insurance contributions and benefits. The reason for averaging
over 41 cases either side of the mean instead of using the example of an average earner is based
on the sensitivity of METRs which can differ a lot between an average earner and someone earning
slightly above or below average earnings. This is due to kinks in the tax and benefit schedule, where
an earnings increase of 3% more can lead to a significant increase in taxes/social insurance contribu-
tions (SIC) or the loss of tax credits or benefits in some countries. Thus, using the average METR of a
certain earnings range produces results that are more in line with results based on representative data
(see Supplementary data in Gasior and Recchia, 2019).
Across countries, increases in net earnings are lower than increases in gross earnings due to higher
taxes and social insurance contributions. The incentive to earn more is very high in Cyprus, Bulgaria
and Estonia, where only about 20% of the earnings increase is lost due to higher taxes and social
insurance contributions. Belgium and Ireland are the countries with the highest work disincentives for
earnings between 80% and 120% of average earnings. While taxes explain most of the overall level
of METRs across countries, social insurance contributions play a similarly important role in Bulgaria,
Hungary and Slovenia. Denmark is the only EU country where average earners are still eligible for
means- tested benefits (housing benefit and green check) which are reduced when their earnings
increase.
While this sheds light on how tax- benefit systems differ in their (dis)incentive to increase working
hours/earnings, it is important to keep in mind that incentives can be quite different by earnings levels.
We select three countries – Cyprus, Hungary and Belgium – to discuss such differences (see Figure6).
Cyprus represents the countries with the lowest METRs on average and Belgium the countries with
the highest METRs (see Figure5). Hungary represents a group of countries with flat tax system which
leads to a quite different picture of METRs at different earnings levels.
Results for Cyprus show relatively low METRs across all income levels except for people with very
low earnings. This, however, corresponds to a very specific case in which the baseline earnings repre-
sent roughly the minimum wage and the 3% earnings increase leads to earnings above this level.
While earnings below the minimum wage are disregarded from the income test for the Guaranteed
Figure 6. Decomposition of METRs at different earnings levels in Cyprus, Hungary and Belgium by income
component, 2017 policy system.
Source: own calculations using EUROMOD H1.0+ (Gasior and Recchia, 2019). Note: Policy system 2017 refers to the status quo
on 30th of June 2017. Results are based on the assumption of full tax- compliance and full benefit take- up. Level of gross earnings
refers percentage of average gross earnings.
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 82
Minimum Income (GMI), this is not the case for the earnings increase which leads to a slightly smaller
benefit amount which creates a high disincentive to work more. All other income groups have incomes
above the GMI and hence, are no longer eligible to receive the means- tested benefit. While the
deducted SIC of the earnings increase amount to 7.8% of gross earnings across all income groups,
only average and above earners are liable to income tax (which subsequently leads to higher METRs).
The income tax paid for the earnings increase is progressive, starting at 18% for average earners,
and going up to 28% for those with earnings that are twice as high. Nevertheless with the exception
of earnings above 150% of average earnings, METRs for earnings above the Minimum Wage are
substantially lower than in other countries.
In Belgium on the other hand, incentives to increase wages are relatively low across the earnings
distribution with more than 50% of the earnings increase being taxed away. Disincentives are espe-
cially high for those with 50% of average earnings due to the high level of social insurance contribu-
tions. While the contribution of the income tax increases relatively smoothly up to earnings levels of
125% of average earnings, the contribution of SIC to the METRs is highest for those with 45%–70%
of average earnings. This is due to the work bonus which has two parts. The first part is a reduction
of SIC, the second part is a tax bonus for monthly gross earnings below € 2,510. Higher earnings lead
to a lower work bonus and hence to a slightly higher income tax than before the earnings increase.
In other words, when the work bonus is reduced, this reduction does not only apply to the increase
in earnings, but to total earnings, which is why the METR is particularly high at this level of earnings.
The picture is quite different in Hungary due to the flat tax system. In relative terms, taxes and
SIC deductions are the same across earnings levels (even for those with earnings below the minimum
wage). Only certain household types (eg, households with children) are eligible for tax allowances and
are subject to lower deductions. In contrast to Cyprus and Belgium, low earnings are not exempted
from contributions. This creates the same METR of 35% for all earnings levels. While increases in
earnings are largely taxed away by the income tax system in Belgium and Cyprus, SIC play a relatively
more important role in Hungary.
This example illustrates the usefulness of hypothetical household data for a better understanding
of tax and benefit systems and their implicit work (dis)incentives. The selected country cases demon-
strate different levels of METR and the contribution of different tax and benefit elements. It further-
more highlights the importance of taking different earnings levels into account rather than just
focusing on average earnings. Even with this simple one- person household example, results are quite
different by country and earnings levels. The possibilities to expand such analysis are unlimited by for
example focusing on different household compositions and analysing the role of tax allowances and
means- tested benefits for these households.
5. Conclusion
With HHoT, EUROMOD now includes a new tax- benefit hypothetical household generator that
is freely accessible. The tool is unique in that it is very flexible, yet user- friendly, and – as part of
EUROMOD – allows for comparable population- based microsimulations and hypothetical household
simulations in an integrated framework. Given that EUROMOD covers all EU Member States, for an
increasing number of policy years, the tool has great potential to substantially contribute to (compar-
ative) research in tax- benefit policies. In addition, EUROMOD is supported by a network of experts,
responsible for regular updates and validations of the tax- benefit simulation model, ensuring the
quality and timeliness of the simulations. In this paper, we introduced HHoT and described its poten-
tial for novel research in tax- benefit policies and for producing policy indicators. The uses and the
advantages of the tool are manifold. HHoT can enhance tax- benefit analyses and studies of poverty
and inequality with illustrations of how policies work and interact with each other in practice. It can
also illustrate how proposed policy reforms and reform ideas would work and interact with other poli-
cies. Second, it can help users to create (new) policy indicators that keep the composition of the popu-
lation constant across time and countries, for instance on benefit adequacy and generosity, targeting,
implicit equivalence scales and work incentives (for an example of a new indicator, see Penne etal.
(2020)). Thirdly, HHoT can be used to go beyond the possibilities of the microdata to study the opera-
tion and impact of policy parameters for which variables are lacking in the microdata or in cases where
specific households are underrepresented in the microdata. An additional advantage for EUROMOD
specifically, is that HHoT helps to validate the tax- benefit algorithms in the model in a very detailed
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 83
way and without the constraints of data availability. Finally, it is also a valuable tool for introducing new
users to EUROMOD and helping them setting the first steps in microsimulation modelling.
Undoubtedly, the main strengths of HHoT are the flexibility in defining hypothetical households
and the ease with which comparisons across time and countries can be made. However, users should
be aware that it is always necessary to reflect upon the validity of assumptions and the quality of the
simulations made, especially in the case of comparative research, and not be tempted to jump all too
quickly to (policy) conclusions. With this caveat in mind, we hope that users will quickly embrace the
potential that HHoT offers to generate new insights into the functioning and impact of tax- benefit
policies.
ORCID iDs
Tine Hufkens https:// orcid. org/ 0000- 0003- 0848- 9165
Tim Goedemé https:// orcid. org/ 0000- 0002- 2985- 4320
Katrin Gasior https:// orcid. org/ 0000- 0003- 4342- 1174
Chrysa Leventi https:// orcid. org/ 0000- 0002- 1756- 9207
Pasquale Recchia https:// orcid. org/ 0000- 0001- 9751- 6449
Holly Sutherland https:// orcid. org/ 0000- 0001- 7393- 0717
Gerlinde Verbist https:// orcid. org/ 0000- 0001- 9253- 3477
Acknowledgments
We are grateful to Alari Paulus and two anonymous referees for comments and feedbacks on a
previous draft of this paper. The Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT) has been jointly developed by
the University of Essex and the University of Antwerp as an application of the EUROMOD software.
The project was coordinated by Holly Sutherland (University of Essex) and Tim Goedemé (University
of Antwerp). The authors are grateful to all participants of two InGRID Expert workshops on HHoT
and minimum income protection organised at the University of Antwerp for comments and feedback
during the development process of HHoT. The authors are also grateful to the first users of the HHoT
for comments and feedback, including Sarah Marchal, Tess Penne and Linus Siöland. Financial support
of the FP7- funded InGRID (Inclusive Growth Research Infrastructure Diffusion) project, under Grant
Agreement No 312,691 is gratefully acknowledged. The results presented in this paper are based on
EUROMOD version H1.0+. EUROMOD is maintained, developed, and managed by the Institute for
Social and Economic Research (ISER) at the University of Essex, in collaboration with national teams
from the EU member states. We are indebted to the many people who have contributed to the devel-
opment of EUROMOD. The process of extending and updating EUROMOD is financially supported
by the European Union Programme for Employment and Social Innovation ‘Easi’ (2014–2020). The
results and their interpretation are the authors’ responsibility. The opinions expressed and arguments
employed herein are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the
European Commission or its member states or the OECD or of its member countries.
Data Availability
The EU- SILC data were made available by Eurostat under contract 175/2015- EU- SILC- ECHP- LFS. The
HHoT is now available as an integral part of EUROMOD.
References
Berger F, Borsenberger M, Immervoll H, Lumen J, Scholtus B, De Vos K. 2001. The impact of Tax- Benefit systems
on poverty rates in the Benelux countries. A simulation approach using synthetic datasets. Journal of Applied
Social Science Studies 121:313–352.
Commission,, E. 2014. Investing in Children: Breaking the cycle of disadvantage (Country Report - Germany).
https:// ec. europa. eu/ social/ main. jsp? catId= 89& langId= en& newsId= 2061& moreDocuments= yes& tableName=
news
Eurostat. 2017. Statistics by theme. https:// ec. europa. eu/ eurostat/ data/ database:
Frazer H, Marlier E. 2015. Minimum income schemes in Europe a study of national policies 2015. Brussels:
European Commission. http:// ec. europa. eu/ social/ main. jsp? pubId= 7882& langId= en& catId= 738& furtherPubs=
yes&
Gallego Granados P, Harnisch M. 2017. EUROMOD Country Report Germany(DE) 2013-2017. https://www.
euromod. ac. uk/ sites/ default/ files/ country- reports/ Y9_ CR_ DE_ Final. pdf
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 84
Gasior K, Recchia P. 2019. The use of hypothetical household data for policy learning: comparative TaxBenefit
indicators using EUROMOD HHoT. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 30:1–20.
DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 1080/ 13876988. 2019. 1609784
Goedemé T. 2013. How much confidence can we have in EU- SILC? complex sample designs and the standard
error of the Europe 2020 poverty indicators. Social Indicators Research 110:89–110. DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10.
1007/ s11205- 011- 9918-2
Goedemé T, Penne T, Hufkens T, Karakitsios A, Bernát A, Franziskus A, Storms B. 2019. What Does It Mean To Live
on the Poverty Threshold? Lessons From Reference Budgets. In:Cantillon B, Goedemé T, Hills J (editors).
Decent incomes for all. Improving policies in Europe. New York: Oxford University Press. p. 13–33
Goedemé T, Van den Bosch K, Salanauskaite L, Verbist G. 2013. Testing the statistical significance of
microsimulation results: a plea. International Journal of Microsimulation 6:50–77.
Hufkens T, Leventi C, Rastrigina O, Manios K, Van Mechelen N, Verbist G, Goedemé T. 2016. HHoT: a new flexible
hypothetical household tool for tax- benefit simulations in EUROMOD. https:// inclusivegrowth. be/ downloads/
output/ d22- 2- validation- report- hhot- eind. pdf
Immervoll H, Marianna P, Mira d'Ercole M. 2004. Benefit Coverage Rates and Household Typologies: Scope and
Limitations of Tax- Benefit Indicators.. Paris: OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers.
Immervoll H, O'Donoghue C. 2009. Towards a multi- purpose framework for Tax- Benefit Microsimulation: lessons
from EUROMOD. International Journal of Microsimulation 2:43–54.
Immervoll H. 2010. Minimum Income Benefits in OECD Countries. Paris: OECD Publishing. DOI: https:// doi.
org// 10. 1787/ 1815199X
Jara H. X, Tumino A. 2013. Tax- Benefit systems, income distribution and work incentives in the European Union.
International Journal of Microsimulation 1:27–62.
Lenze A. 2014. Alleinerziehende unter Druck. Rechtliche Rahmenbedingungen, finanzielle Lage und
Reformbedarf. Gütersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung. https://www. bertelsmann- stiftung. de/ fileadmin/ files/ Projekte/
Familie_ und_ Bildung/ Studie_ WB_ Alleinerziehende_ Aktualisierung_ 2016. pdf
Li J, O’Donoghue C, Loughrey J, Harding A. 2014. Static Models. In C. O’Donoghue (Ed.), Handbook of
Microsimulation Modelling (Contributions to Economic Analysis). 293. Emerald Group Publishing Limited. p.
47–75
Marchal S, Siöland L, Goedemé T. 2019. Using HHoT to generate institutional minimum income protection
indicators. Euromod Working Paper EM 4/19. Colchester: University of Essex.
Marx I, Nelson K (editors). 2013. Minimum Income Protection in Flux. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.
Nelson K. 2013. Social assistance and EU poverty thresholds 1990-2008. are European welfare systems providing
just and fair protection against low income? European Sociological Review 29:386–401. DOI: https:// doi. org/
10. 1093/ esr/ jcr080
OECD. 2014. OECD tax- benefit models. Paper presented at the InGRID Expert seminar 'Model family
simulations of income policies: taking the next step with EUROMOD. Antwerp, Belgium: University of Antwerp.
OECD. 2017. Average annual wages. https://www. oecd- ilibrary. org/ social- issues- migration- health/ data/
oecd- employment- and- labour- market- statistics/ average- annual- wages_ data- 00571- en
OECD. 2019. Working hours needed to exit poverty (indicator). Paris: OECD. DOI: https:// doi. org// 10. 1787/
ceb8bce8- en
Penne T, Hufkens T, Goedemé T, Storms B. 2020. To what extent do welfare states compensate for the cost of
children? the joint impact of taxes, benefits and public goods and services. Journal of European Social Policy
30:79–94. DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 1177/ 0958928719868458
Sutherland H, Figari F. 2013. EUROMOD: the European Union tax- benefit microsimulation model. International
Journal of Microsimulation 6:4–26.
Van Mechelen N, Marchal S, Goedemé T, Marx I, Cantillon B. 2011. The CSB- Minimum Income Protection
Indicators dataset (CSB- MIPI) (CSB WP 11/05). http://www. cent rumv oors ocia albeleid. be/ sites/ default/ files/
CSB% 20Working% 20Paper% 2011% 2005_ April% 202011. pdf
Van Mechelen N, Verbist G. 2005. Simulatiemodellen: instrumenten voor sociaal- economisch Onderzoek en
beleid. Tijdschrift voor Sociologie 26:137–153.
Van den Bosch K, Goedemé T, Schuerman N, Storms B. 2016. Reference housing costs for adequate dwellings in
ten European capitals. Critical Housing Analysis 3:1–9. DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 13060/ 23362839. 2016. 2. 1. 248
Research article Methodology
Hufkens etal. International Journal of Microsimulation 2019; 12(3); 68–85 DOI: https:// doi. org/ 10. 34196/ ijm. 00208 85
Appendix 1
Supplementary material
Table A.1 Country specific 2017 average monthly
earnings used in Example 4
Country In EUR In national currency
AT 3140.24 –
BE 3500.56 –
BG 601.72 1176.84
CY 1891.30 –
CZ 1024.31 27332.60
DE 3495.43 –
DK 4091.22 30425.57
EE 1363.38 –
EL 1412.15 –
ES 1965.41 –
FI 3167.61 –
FR 2730.09 –
HR 928.85 6913.83
HU 695.74 215012.62
IE 3984.27 –
IT 2251.91 –
LT 893.97 –
LU 4753.80 –
LV 1043.15 –
MT 1881.91 –
NL 3617.86 –
PL 912.65 3891.83
PT 1363.98 –
RO 479.33 2176.91
SE 3350.66 32152.29
SI 1539.31 –
SK 928.29
UK 4080.11 3526.11
Source: Own calculation based on EU- SILC 2015 (2014
for UK and DE) data and EM uprating factors and
exchange rates.
... The range of possible characteristics is large, including labor market status, types of income sources, gender, and age, among others. For more information, see Hufkens et al. (2019). 20 The housing costs are assumed to be 20% of the country-specific average monthly gross earnings. ...
Article
Assessing the effectiveness of Minimum Income (MI) schemes in poverty alleviation is challenging. Studies based on survey microdata are usually subject to bias because households tend to underreport benefit receipts. Studies based on microsimulation models tend to overestimate these benefits mainly due to high non‐take‐up rates. In this paper, we tackle these challenges by calibrating the simulation of MI schemes in the microsimulation model EUROMOD to match official expenditure results for each European Union (EU) Member State's scheme. We use this calibrated model to evaluate the poverty‐alleviating effects of existing MI schemes and explore the impacts of possible reforms toward eradicating extreme poverty. Our results show that MI support varies widely across EU countries, with most failing to reach half of households in extreme poverty or provide adequate support, particularly for larger families. Reforms aimed at improving coverage and adequacy could eradicate extreme poverty at a relatively low budgetary cost.
... Microsimulations show the effects on the population (e.g. poverty, inequality and budget) while hypothetical households present the effects of the taxbenefit system [11]. ...
Article
Being a pensioner in Croatia carries certain risks of poverty and inequality compared to the rest of the population. Low level of average pension compared to the minimal wage is just one case in point. On the other hand, the labour market shortage is not negligible and there is also a poor track record when it comes to pension system reforms in the last two decades. This paper investigates a possible path of the future pension system reform aimed at increasing household income levels -- focused on the labour market participation of people aged 65+ who are willing and able to solve labour shortages present in the market. The general aim of the paper is to analyze the effects that the establishment of the Pensioners Service Center might have on market income, mean household income by decile groups, poverty and inequality indices. It fills the research gap by conducting the first microsimulation of the pension system reform in Croatia focusing on market income. The hypothetical reform is simulated using the tax--benefit microsimulation model EUROMOD based on EU--SILC 2019 data for Croatia. Results confirm market income as the main cause of income inequality as well as that the second decile is the target group of the proposed intervention. Pensioners have a clear monetary incentive to increase their labour supply, which in return decreases all poverty and inequality indices.
... The OECD Family Support Calculator, for example, allows us to compare leave policy entitlements based on the characteristics of a wide range of individuals and households, taking the heterogeneity of the population into account (OECD, n.d.-d). A similar model-family approach termed the Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT) is now also available in EUROMOD (Hufkens et al., 2019). This is a microsimulation tool that is based on the EU Survey on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC) and allows the calculation and observation of the statutory leave entitlements for a wide array of hypothetical households that can be specified by the user. ...
Article
Full-text available
In order to investigate and compare welfare states or specific welfare programmes, scientists, opinion‐makers and politicians rely on indicators. As many of the concepts or objects studied are somewhat abstract, these indicators can often only be approximations. In comparative welfare‐state research, scholars have suggested several approximating indicators to quantitatively measure and compare the generosity of public welfare provision, with a special focus on cash benefits. These indicators include social spending, social rights and benefit receipt. We present these indicators systematically, and critically discuss how suitable they are for comparing the generosity of parenting leave policies in developed welfare states. Subsequently, we illustrate how the operationalisation of leave generosity by means of different indicators can lead to different rankings, interpretations and qualifications of countries. Hence, indicator choices have to be considered carefully and suitably justified, depending on the actual research interest.
... Marchal et al. 2018). HHoT is a flexible tool that is part of the European tax-benefit microsimulation model EUROMOD (see Hufkens et al, 2019;Sutherland and Figari 2013). It allows the user to specify a large variation of hypothetical households for which the net income, given a pre-specified gross income, can be simulated. ...
Article
In Europe, food insecurity is still a serious concern for individual and public health. Although progress has been made in reducing undernourishment, other types of malnutrition such as obesity and overweight are on the rise. Policies that aim at improving healthy eating and addressing food insecurity tend to focus on food aid, nutritional education and financial incentives. These policies are generally not targeted at the problem of insufficient income as a key barrier to access a healthy diet. In this paper, we present new evidence which shows that insufficient household income and inadequate minimum income policies constitute a remaining concern for accessing a healthy diet. We make use of estimates of the minimum cost of a healthy diet in 24 European countries, in accordance with national food-based dietary guidelines. We use these unique data to (1) estimate the proportion of people living in (sub)urban areas with insufficient income to access a healthy diet, before and after housing costs, based on representative income survey data (EU-SILC), and, (2) compare the cost of a healthy diet with the level of minimum income schemes for specific household types using microsimulation techniques. We find that in 16 out of 24 countries at least 10% of the population in (sub)urban areas risks to be confronted with income-related food insecurity. Our findings show that policies directed at tackling food insecurity should be embedded in broader economic and social policies that promote an adequate income for all, and limit the cost of other essential goods and services.
Article
Full-text available
Op basis van de Europese sociale indicatoren blijkt de adequaatheid van de Belgische sociale zekerheid te zijn afgenomen het afgelopen decennium, in het bijzonder binnen de groep van werkarme gezinnen of 'quasi-jobloze huishoudens' (binnen deze gezinnen is de som van de werkintensiteit van de volwassen gezinsleden minder dan 20% van de totale potentiële werktijd van het huishouden tijdens het inkomensreferentiejaar). Hoe kan dit verklaard worden? Is er sprake van een verminderde toegankelijkheid van de uitkeringen, een verminderde toereikendheid van de uitkeringen, en/of een kwetsbaarder profiel van de quasi-jobloze huishoudens? We vinden dat een samenspel van factoren een rol heeft gespeeld, waarbij zowel de toegankelijkheid als de generositeit van uitkeringen en het profiel van personen in quasi-jobloze huishoudens van belang waren. Ten eerste hebben personen in quasi-jobloze huishoudens in 2018 een kwetsbaarder profiel dan in 2008. Het zijn vaker alleenstaanden en huishoudens met kinderen, migranten, individuen zonder persoonlijk (vervangings)inkomen, individuen met gezondheidsproblemen, en huurders. Ten tweede is de toegankelijkheid van de uitkeringen, voornamelijk in de werkloosheid, afgenomen. Dit zien we vertaald in een lagere dekkingsgraad oftewel in een toename van het aantal werklozen die geen werkloosheidsuitkering ontvangen en duiden we door een aantal verstrengde maatregelen in de toegang tot werkloosheidsuitkeringen. Tot slot speelt ook de toereikendheid van uitkeringen een rol. Vergeleken met de 60%-armoedegrens kenden de meeste uitkeringen een stilstand of kleine achteruitgang in adequaatheid de voorbije tien jaar. Volgens de referentiebudgetten van 2008 en 2018 die berekend zijn voor welbepaalde gezinstypes onder welbepaalde assumpties was er een lichte verbetering in de adequaatheid van sommige sociale uitkeringen, terwijl andere uitkeringen een stagnatie kenden voor een aantal gezinstypes. Zo goed als alle sociale minima bleven echter ontoereikend. De versterkte degressiviteit van de werkloosheidsuitkeringen sedert 2012 drukte op de adequaatheid van de uitkeringen voor langdurige werklozen.
Article
Full-text available
Financial incentives affect the labour supply decisions of households. However, the impact usually varies significantly across household types. Whilst there is a substantial amount of literature on the labour supply effects of tax reforms and in-work benefits, the impact of changes in social assistance benefits has received less attention. This paper analyses labour supply responses to changes in social assistance. We show that labour supply elasticities vary substantially across gender and household type. Women exhibit higher labour supply elasticities, both on the intensive and the extensive margins. Additionally, labour supply elasticities are typically higher for singles and for households with children. Using these results, we analyse the impact of the Austrian reform proposal “Neue Sozialhilfe” (New Social Assistance), which was introduced in 2019 and substantially cut social assistance benefits for migrants and families with children. The overall effects of the reform are especially strong for men and migrants. Migrants and couples with children, that is, the groups hardest hit by the reform’s social assistance reductions, show the strongest labour supply reactions to the New Social Assistance. Furthermore, we show that overall, the reform is expected to have a positive, but small, effect on the intensive margin of labour supply.
Article
Full-text available
In the context of the Finnish welfare state, this article examines the role of occupational welfare in the interplay between public and occupational sickness benefits from 1947 to 2016, to analyse how the two sickness benefits have interacted over time and the role occupational welfare has played in sickness provision. Previous research has noted that occupational benefits may support or compensate for the much-debated declining welfare state. Hence, it is important to acquire greater knowledge about the public-occupational interplay. The study uses in-depth individual-level analysis from a retrospective point of view, which has been rare in previous research, and examines the public-occupational interplay in the Finnish sickness benefit system from the first national collective agreements to 2016. Based on the reforms made to the public system, the article identifies and utilises six different phases of the Finnish sickness allowance system in the main analysis. The institutional development of sickness provision is investigated by analysing the compensation rate and benefit period, using metalworkers as a representative example of blue-collar workers. The results indicate that occupational benefits are strongly institutionalised in the Finnish sickness benefit system. The interplay between statutory and occupational sickness benefits has taken different forms over time, and occupational benefits have been re-negotiated as the statutory system has been reformed. The article provides valuable information on the historical development and relevance of occupational welfare, in terms of not only understanding its significance for individuals but also comprehending the logic of the interplay in the public-private mix of welfare provision.
Article
This article summarises the arguments in favour of an EU initiative on minimum wages and highlights the steps that have been taken so far, focusing, in particular, on the First Stage consultation document prepared by the European Commission. Based on this consultation document and previous proposals, this article assesses some of the issues related to promoting an EU target minimum wage as a percentage of a national reference wage. Focusing on the adequacy of minimum wages for workers and their families, this article highlights first, the impact rather technical issues relating to the definition of the reference wage may have, and second, the importance of considering the interaction of the minimum wage with the broader tax benefit system in ensuring adequate in-work incomes. Whereas an EU initiative on minimum wages certainly has merit, these two caveats illustrate the need for a clear definition of what one wants to achieve by this initiative, and indicate that specific goals will require additional accompanying measures, such as a further monitoring of the net incomes of minimum wage earners
Article
Full-text available
Tax‒benefit microsimulation models are typically used to quantify the effect of specific policy changes on the income distribution based on representative microdata. Such analysis evaluates policies by considering how different tax‒benefit elements interact given personal, household and labour market characteristics. Using hypothetical household data instead helps address broader questions of policy design and systemic (cross-national) differences. This article introduces the Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT) in combination with the microsimulation model EUROMOD to analyse European tax‒benefit policies from a comparative perspective. It presents a series of applications from social welfare analysis illustrating how hypothetical data can benefit comparative academic and policy research.
Technical Report
Full-text available
This paper aims to show how the newly developed Hypothetical Household tool of the EUROMOD microsimulation model can be used to generate institutional minimum income protection indicators. It does so by updating the CSB's Minimum Income Protection Indicators dataset using HHoT and EUROMOD. We discuss the necessary assumptions for this exercise, and describe, present and validate the obtained indicators. In doing so, we provide and discuss both an updated minimum income protection indicator dataset, and give guidance to researchers who want to use the flexibility of HHoT to calculate purpose designed minimum income protection indicators.
Article
Full-text available
It has been suggested that income adequacy is an important condition for a fair work-test to apply. This article provides new evidence about the construction of just social minimums by analysing the relationship between social assistance, benefit adequacy, and labour market activation. Does social assistance provide benefits at levels necessary to escape poverty? To what extent is the development of benefit adequacy related to active labour market policy? The empirical analyses combine macro-level institutional data from the SaMip data set and micro-level income data for 28 European welfare systems in 1990–2008. It is shown that social assistance seldom reaches commonly applied poverty thresholds. The adequacy of social assistance has also declined, along with the increased emphasis on the activation of beneficiaries. It therefore appears difficult to perceive European social assistance programmes as just distributive instruments.
Article
Full-text available
In this paper we study the impact of tax-benefit systems on income inequality and work incentives across the 27 Member States of the European Union (EU). Using EUROMOD, the EU-wide tax-benefit microsimulation model, we disentangle the role of taxes, benefits and social insurance contributions in influencing country specific Gini coefficients and Marginal Effective Tax Rates. The extent to which tax-benefit systems contribute to income redistribution and provide work incentives at the intensive margin is found to vary considerably across the 27 Member States of the EU. Our results further highlight the presence of a trade-off between income redistribution and work incentives across EU-27 countries.
Article
In recent years simulation models are increasingly used in research on socio-economic policy, particularly in studies of taxes and social benefits. In this article we present two types of simulation models: the standard simulation model and the micro simulation model. Both models are micro models, meaning that they assess the structure and impact of social and economic policy measures for an individual decision unit (individuals, households and enterprises). We discuss the particularities of both models, point out that they are fully complementary and illustrate them with analyses of Belgian taxation and social contributions.
Article
In order to alleviate child poverty, contemporary European welfare states have shifted their focus increasingly towards child-centred investment strategies. However, studies examining the generosity of welfare states to families with children focus mainly on cash benefit packages, or on government expenditure, while not taking into account the actual out-of-pocket costs families have to make to fulfil their needs. This article aims at contributing to existing studies by: (1) empirically assessing the needs and costs of children across welfare states by making use of cross-nationally comparable reference budgets, while taking into account publicly provided or subsidised services; (2) simulating the cash benefits and taxes that affect households with children through the tax–benefit system, by making use of the new Hypothetical Household Tool (HHoT) in EUROMOD; and (3) combining both types of information in order to compare the essential out-of-pocket costs for children between 6 and 18 years old with the simulated cash benefit packages. We propose a new indicator that can be used to assess welfare state generosity to families with children: the child cost compensation indicator. The use of the indicator is empirically illustrated by comparing six European welfare states: Belgium, Finland, Greece, Hungary, Italy and Spain. The article shows that, even though with important cross-national variation, cash transfers generally amount to less than 60 percent of the cost of children. Although in five out of six countries support for families is higher at the lower end of the income distribution, for households living on a low gross wage, the income of a family with children is less adequate compared to a similar childless family and is in many cases insufficient to participate adequately in society.
Chapter
This chapter makes use of the first effort to construct cross-country comparable reference budgets in Europe to show what the large cross-national differences in living standards imply in practice for the adequacy of incomes at the level of the at-risk-of-poverty threshold. The budgets show that, in the poorest EU Member States, even adequate food and housing are barely affordable at the level of the threshold, whereas a decent living standard is much more in reach for those living on the threshold in the richer EU Member States. The reference budgets also suggest that the poverty risk of some groups (for instance, children) is underestimated relative to that of other age groups, while the poverty risk of homeowners is probably relatively overestimated.
Article
Providing adequate housing at affordable prices remains a challenge for all welfare states. As part of a pilot project for developing a common methodology for reference budgets in the European Union, reference rents and other housing costs (energy, taxes, maintenance) corresponding to adequate dwellings for four hypothetical households living in nine capital regions of the EU were estimated. In this paper, we discuss the approach that we have taken. Quality criteria for adequate housing were derived from EU indicators of housing deprivation, and the recent UK Housing Standards Review. We used data from the Study of Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC) of 2012. Unsurprisingly, the estimates of reference rents vary strongly across capitals, reflecting cross-national differences in the level of the average rent. By contrast, other housing costs, which mainly reflect energy costs, vary much less. © 2016, Academy of Sciences of the Czech Republic, Institute of Sociology. All rights reserved.