Content uploaded by Björn Hacker
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Björn Hacker on Oct 29, 2019
Content may be subject to copyright.
Björn Hacker, Cédric M. Koch
The divided Eurozone
Mapping Confl icting Interests on the Reform
of the Monetary Union
Björn Hacker, Cédric M. Koch
The divided Eurozone
Mapping Confl icting Interests on the Reform
of the Monetary Union
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
Europe needs social democracy!
Why do we really want Europe? Can we demonstrate to European citizens the opportunities offered by
social politics and a strong social democracy in Europe? This is the aim of the new Friedrich-Ebert-Stif-
tung project “Politics for Europe”. It shows that European integration can be done in a democratic,
economic and socially balanced way and with a reliable foreign policy.
The following issues will be particularly important:
– Democratic Europe
– Economic and social policy in Europe
– Foreign and security policy in Europe
The FES will devote itself to these issues in publications and events throughout 2015–2017: we start
from citizens’ concerns, identify new positions with decision-makers and lay out alternative policy
approaches. We want a debate with you about “Politics for Europe”!
Further information on the project can be found here:
www.fes.de/de/politik-fuer-europa-2017plus
Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung
The Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung (FES) is the oldest political foundation in Germany with a rich tradition dating
back to its foundation in 1925. Today, it remains loyal to the legacy of its namesake and campaigns for
the core ideas and values of social democracy: freedom, justice and solidarity. It has a close connection
to social democracy and free trade unions.
FES promotes the advancement of social democracy, in particular by:
– Political educational work to strengthen civil society
– Think tanks
– International cooperation with our international network of offi ces in more than 100 countries
– Support for talented young people
– Maintaining the collective memory of social democracy with archives, libraries and more.
About the authors
Dr. Björn Hacker is Professor of Economic Policy at the Hochschule für Technik und Wirtschaft (HTW) Ber
lin.
Cédric M. Koch is a research assistant in the Faculty of Economics and Law at the Hochschule für
Tec h
nik und Wirtschaft (HTW) Berlin.
Person responsible in the FES for this publication
Dr. Uwe Optenhoegel, Director EU-Offi ce Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung Brussels
Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung Brussels*
* This study was first published by the German Macroeconomic Policy Institute (IMK) within the Hans Böckler Foundation in
November 2016.
A PROJECT OF THE
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
2015 – 2017
ABSTRACT
SUMMARY
1 INTRODUCTION: THE CONFLICT OVER THE FUTURE OF THE ECONOMIC AND
MONETARY UNION
2 THE EMU REFORM DEBATE SINCE THE OUTBREAK OF THE EURO CRISIS
2.1 Reform initiatives 2011–2014
2.2 The preparation process of the 2015 Five Presidents’ Report
3 TWO CONCEPTS FOR THE FUTURE OF THE EUROZONE: STABILITY UNION
VS. FISCAL UNION
3.1 The EMU as a stability union
3.2 The EMU as a fiscal union
3.3 Interim summary: Instruments for two concepts of a Monetary Union
4 STABILITY UNION AND FISCAL UNION IN THE CREATION OF THE FIVE
PRESIDENTS’ REPORT
4.1 The starting point: The Commission’s Analytical Note
4.2 The stability union camp
4.3 Interim summary on the stability union
4.4 The fiscal union camp
4.5 Interim summary on the fiscal union
4.6 The role of the European Parliament
4.7 The final Five Presidents’ Report
5 THE EU IN THE CONFLICT BETWEEN FISCAL UNION AND STABILITY UNION
6 CONCLUSIONS AND OUTLOOK
List of Figures and Tabels
References
References for Sherpa contributions
2
3
5
7
7
8
10
11
14
17
19
20
21
24
25
32
33
34
36
40
44
44
47
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
Björn Hacker, Cédric M. Koch
The divided Eurozone
Mapping Conflicting Interests on the Reform
of the Monetary Union
2
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
The euro crisis showed how incomplete and vulnerable the
architecture of the Monetary Union is. Institutional reforms
are slow or stalling due to divergent development perspec-
tives for the Eurozone. This study analyses the conflicting in-
terests among member states involved in the recent reform
process. Based on economic theory, a disagreement can be
identified between a minority around Finland and Germany,
which advocate a “stability union”, and a majority around
Italy and France striving for a “fiscal union”. But a far-reaching
fiscal and political integration of the Eurozone cannot be
achieved against the defenders of the status quo, as the “fis-
cal union” representatives lack coherence and unity and are
struggling with economic problems. The intergovernmental
preparation process for the Five Presidents’ Report of 2015,
which is examined here, reveals a deeply divided Europe and
a European Commission desperately seeking consensus. As
the recent Commission White Paper on the Future of Europe
aimed to restart the reform debate on the Eurozone, the con-
flicts identified here are likely to be central to reform negoti-
ations and outcomes.
ABSTRACT
3
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
SUMMARY
This study investigates the conflicting interests and power
struggles among the EU member states and the role of the
European institutions in the debates over reforming the Euro-
zone, following seven years of crisis.
Efforts to institute fundamental reforms of the Eurozone
in response to its crisis have been under way since 2011 and
have already led to individual institutional changes, such as
the European Banking Union. But member states have failed
to achieve consensus over further-reaching reforms, such that
the proposals under discussion encompass a wide range of
different objectives and scales. After the failure of the first
reform initiative in 2012, the reform process was to be re-
launched from early 2015 onwards through the Five Presi-
dents’ Report based on contributions from all the EU mem-
ber states. Eventually the European Commission, which leads
the process, published a White Paper on the Future of Europe
in March 2017 and announced the publication of a Reflection
Paper on deepening Monetary Union for May 2017, which is
to be based on the Five Presidents’ Report.
The disagreements over the reforms needed for the
Eurozone are rooted in fundamentally different economic
paradigms, which already shaped the founding phase of to-
day’s Monetary Union. One camp argues for the vision of
the Monetary Union as a stability union, based on principles
of internal and external price stability and prioritising rule-
based self-regulation of the forces of the free market in or-
der to minimise political risks. The opposing camp pursues
the vision of the Monetary Union as a fiscal union, based on
the conviction that the inevitability of market failure means
that transnational economic governance must address more
than mere price stability. The two visions represent diametri-
cally opposed conceptions of a complete and functioning
Monetary Union and consequently diverge widely in their
interpretations of the causes of the crisis and the necessary
reform steps.
The stability union/fiscal union divide is also reflected in
the process analysed here, the creation of the Five Presidents’
Report. While the Commission’s document initiating the new
reform process remains deliberately vague on the two posi-
tions, the member states’ contributions subsequently com-
municated to Brussels can be classified on the basis of their
demands into three camps in relation to the two diverging re-
form perspectives:
– Proponents of a stability union (Finland, Estonia, Lithuania,
Germany, Malta, the Netherlands, Denmark, Romania, Hun-
gary) reject both expansion of economic governance and
deeper fiscal integration.
– Proponents of a fiscal union (Italy, Spain, Portugal, Belgium,
Luxembourg, Slovenia, Latvia, France) argue for an expan-
sion of both economic governance and fiscal integration.
– Proponents of a fiscal union with restrictions (Cyprus, Slova-
kia, Croatia, Poland, Ireland, Austria, Czech Republic) call
in principle for development of the Monetary Union, but
favour movement on only one of the two fronts: either
more economic governance or steps towards fiscal inte-
gration.
The composition of the three camps reveals the proponents
of a fiscal union, led by Italy, to be the largest group in terms
of both population and GDP, holding a narrow majority with-
in the Eurozone even without including the supporters of a
restricted fiscal union. Proponents of a stability union – led
by Finland – represent a minority position, being the smaller
group under both criteria. The camps also tend to reflect the
different economic contexts of the member states, with states
with higher unemployment dominating the fiscal union group
while states with low levels of debt make up the stability un-
ion camp.
The proponents of a stability union are considerably more
consistent in their demands than the fiscal union group, which
exhibits great variation in the details. This is partly a function
of the clearer position of the stability camp, which wants to
strengthen existing instruments but rejects steps going beyond
the status quo of the existing Eurozone architecture. The sup-
porters of a fiscal union, on the other hand, are calling for far-
reaching reforms in a range of different areas, but share only
a small common denominator. As a result of the diversity with-
in the fiscal union camp (in contrast to the unity of the stabil-
ity union group) and the equivocal stances of the European
Parliament and the Commission, the minority position is most
strongly reflected in the final Five Presidents’ Report.
4
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
This study shows how the euro crisis has reopened a funda-
mental conflict over the right mix between rule-based free
market and policy intervention. At its heart is the disagree-
ment between member states over reforming the Eurozone
towards a stability union or a fiscal union. A determined and
economically relatively successful group led by Finland and
Germany wants to permit only tinkering with the status quo
of the Monetary Union, while a disunited group struggling
with economic difficulties, led by Italy and France, is calling
for far-reaching fiscal and political integration. In the ab-
sence of a decision between the two perspectives, the re-
form debate drags on and creates unsustainable compro-
mises, as in the case of the Banking Union. Alongside other
important national elections and leadership changes in Italy
and the Netherlands, as well in Germany later this year, the
often vacillating position of France will be decisive. Presidential
elections there take place only two months after the publica-
tion of the White Paper on the Future of Europe and around
the time of the announced dissemination of the Commission
Reflection Paper on deepening Monetary Union in May 2017
and will be crucial for the future balance of power in the “map
of reform conflict” (see Figure 1).
Figure 1
Divide d Europe. Identified reform camps on the future of the Eurozone, 2015
Note: Stability Union: FIN, EST, LIT, GER, MLT, NED, DEN, ROM, HUN. Fiscal Union: ITA, ESP, POR, BEL, LUX, SVN, LAT, FRA.
Fiscal Union with restrictions: CYP, SVK, CRO, POL, IRE, AUT, CZE. No data available for UK, SWE, GRE, BUL.
Source: authors, Mapchart.net.
towards a stability union
towards a fiscal union
towards a fiscal union with restrictions
These states favour reform of the Eurozone…
5
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
In the shadow of the challenges faced by the EU over migra-
tion, refugees, integration and Brexit, the dominant European
issue of recent years has been rather ignored: the future of
the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). After seven years
of permanent crisis, all-night summits and a permanent state
of emergency culminating in the clashes over Greece’s future
in the Eurozone in July 2015, Europe’s leaders in 2015 – at the
Initiative of the European Commission – wanted to initiate the
process leading to the next set of fundamental reforms of the
Eurozone architecture. At the June summit of the European
Council, the Commission presented the so-called Five Presi-
dents’ Report (Juncker 2015b), which is still awaiting discus-
sion by the heads of states and governments.
READING OPTIONS:
– For a rapid overview of the analysis as a whole, we
recommend reading Chapters 3.3 (p. 17), 4.3 (p. 24),
4.5 (p. 32), 5 (p. 36), and 6 (p. 40).
– For the positions of individual countries and power
relations within the “map of reform conflict”, we rec-
ommend reading Chapters 4 (p. 19) and 5 (p. 36).
– For the theoretical background to the conflicting re-
form interests and a summary of reform initiatives
to date, we recommend reading Chapters 2 (p. 7)
and 3 (p. 10).
The question of how the Eurozone needs to be modified
cannot be postponed indefinitely, however, especially as
there is already a concrete timetable for the next far-reach-
ing initiatives to complete the EMU. In March 2017, Commis-
sion President Juncker presented a White Paper on the Fu-
ture of Europe, including a roadmap for a Reflection Paper
on the deepening of Monetary Union in May 2017, intended
to re-start discussion on the future course ahead of the De-
cember 2017 European Council. Moreover a new round of
acute euro crisis was only narrowly averted in the summer
of 2016, through yet another agreement between Greece
and its creditors. On 24 May 2016 the Eurogroup released
another instalment from the third bailout package. At the
same time, under pressure from the International Monetary
Fund (IWF), debt relief is now being controversially debated
between the country’s creditors in the Eurozone and the IMF,
with an easing of Greece’s debt ratio of almost 180 percent
of GDP under discussion for 2018 (Eurogroup 2016). But with
Euro finance ministers insisting on strict austerity measures to
achieve a primary surplus of 3.5 percent of GDP in the medium
term, many observers expect only a brief lull (Neuerer 2016;
Schieritz 2016). The potentially explosive consequences of half-
hearted decisions on EMU reform became apparent in 2016,
when the bail-in of investors at four troubled Italian regional
banks – under the Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM), which
came into force in January – caused bewilderment among in-
vestors and lenders and undermined the liquidity of Italy’s
third-largest bank, Monte dei Paschi di Siena, threatening its
solvency and stirring discussion on a public bailout. The rea-
son: to date there is neither agreement among the member
states on the planned European deposit guarantee scheme
nor a functioning fund to protect against defaults and finance
wind-downs (Münchau 2016).
The question of the euro will thus inevitably continue to
play a major role, and the Five Presidents’ Report already in-
dicates where the political battles will lie. This study traces
the fundamental debate that has played out since 2015 in
the background of European politics. It divides Europe politi-
cally: on the one side are proponents of a “stability union”
based on rules and control of national policy-making, on the
other the advocates of a “fiscal union” who believe further-
reaching integration steps to be necessary.
The object of this study is to identify the conflicting in-
terests between the relevant member states and institutional
EU actors over the future shape of the Monetary Union. The
classification of the contributions to the latest Eurozone re-
form process – of which this study represents the first thor-
ough review – permits us to reconstruct the reform discourse.
The resulting “map of reform conflict” yields insights into both
the substantive differences and the majorities within the Un-
ion. The study also questions widely held assumptions about
the positions of individual member states and their role in
the negotiations. The “map of reform conflict” identifies the
ideological and power-political possibilities and limits of a
1
INTRODUCTION: THE CONFLICT OVER
THE FUTURE OF THE ECONOMIC AND
MONETARY UNION
6
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
Monetary Union emerging from years of crisis. It explains –
aside from new political conflicts at the European level – the
persistence of the crisis phenomena in the Eurozone and the
slow nature of progress on developing and implementing
an improved institutional architecture for the single currency.
In the following we supply first of all an overview of the
historical origins of the debate over a fundamental reform of
the EMU, from the outbreak of the euro crisis in 2010 through
to the publication of the Commission’s latest reform propos-
al (Chapter 2). Next, we trace the theoretical roots of today’s
division into the two camps, proponents of stability union
and of fiscal union (Chapter 3). The resulting overview of in-
struments and institutions is used in a qualitative analysis of
member states’ contributions submitted to the Commission
in the process of preparing the Five Presidents’ Report, in
order to create a classification of national preferences and
to establish a ranking of the intensity of their demands (Chap-
ter 4). The findings are contextualised with the concrete pro-
posals of the published report and discussed with regards
to
the real power relations in the reform discussion within the
EU, including a quantitative classification (Chapter 5). The
study concludes with a summary and outlook (Chapter 6).
7
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
This section describes the first initiative to fundamentally re-
form the EMU in 2011/12 and outlines the process employed
by the European Commission for preparing the Five Presidents’
Report. This second attempt to achieve comprehensive re-
forms is also the context of member states’ contributions in
2015. These are analysed in chapter 4 as the central focus of
this study.
SUMMARY:
– Efforts to fundamentally reform the Eurozone in re-
sponse to its crisis have been under way since 2011
and have already led to individual institutional chang-
es, such as the European Banking Union.
–
But there is no consensus among the member states
over further-reaching reforms. So the reform propos-
als to date fluctuate widely between different objec-
tives and dimensions.
– The Five Presidents’ Report of early 2015 was de-
signed to relaunch the reform process, with contri-
butions from all EU member states. The next step
was a Commission White Paper on the Future of
Europe in March 2017 which also announced an
upcoming Reflection Paper on deepening the Euro-
zone due in May 2017.
2.1 REFORM INITIATIVES 2011–2014
Along with the acute bailout packages – which have general-
ly been created under great time pressure – and their various
institutional accompaniments (European Stability Mechanism,
Troika etc.), different plans, ideas and suggestions concerning
the long-term institutional arrangements for the Monetary
Union have been circulating within the EU (see Hacker 2013).
In December 2012, the then-President of the European Coun-
cil, Herman van Rompuy, published a report on developing
“a deep and genuine Economic and Monetary Union” pre-
pared together with the presidents of the Eurogroup, the
European Commission and the European Central Bank (ECB)
(the “Four Presidents’” or “Quadriga” report). In the same
year independent proposals for reform timetables also came
from the European Parliament (“Thyssen Report”) and the
Commission (“Blueprint”), and were discussed together with
the Four Presidents’ Report at the December 2012 summit.
Although the Four Presidents’ Report called for relatively
far-reaching integration steps and supplied a clear political
timetable, the political response of the heads of state and
government in the summit conclusions were reserved and
largely restricted to declarations of intent. The only excep-
tion in this respect was the Banking Union, which has in the
meantime been implemented (albeit incompletely in certain
important respects). Otherwise the European Council em-
phasised above all the need for strict budgetary discipline.
Additional fields of activity were also agreed, namely ex-
ante coordination of national economic policies, direct “mutu-
ally agreed contracts” between each member state and the
EU including a “solidarity mechanism” to create stronger in-
centives and controls in the implementation of national re-
form policies, as well as progress on the social dimension of
the EMU (European Council 2012).
However, more notable than these (largely vague) plans
were the aspects that are absent here, even though most of
them were included in the various preparatory reports: there
is no longer any talk of a medium-term fiscal union in the
sense of joint debt management, a fiscal capacity or steps to-
wards a political union with greater democratic powers at
the supranational level. So by the end of 2012 there were al-
ready clear signs of a reinterpretation of these instruments
and aspects according to the vision of a stability union, where
the fiscal integration steps function only as incentives for
implementing coordinated stability and competition policy
(Hacker 2013). The member states failed to achieve a con-
sensus over the newly identified fields of activity during the
following months. Commission communications in 2013 on
the
Convergence and Competitiveness Instrument, on ex-ante-
coordination of economic policies and on the social dimen-
sion of the EMU were stripped of all controversial aspects be-
fore publication and remained irrelevant. The joint Franco-
German declaration of 30 May 2013, in which all reform pro-
posals that have not yet been set in motion are postponed
2
THE EMU REFORM DEBATE SINCE THE
OUTBREAK OF THE EURO CRISIS
8
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
to the distant future in favour of moves to “establish a com-
mon assessment” of indicators and policy areas, is symptomatic
(Bundesregierung 2013: 9). Even this did not occur and impor-
tant election dates for the German Bundestag in autumn 2013
and the European Parliament in spring 2014 ensured – along-
side the lack of unity among the member states – that further
discussion of the reform plans was continually postponed.
In the period since early 2013 debate in the European con-
text has been largely over the exact details of the Banking
Union. Whereas most European states were interested in
rapid implementation, the German government in particular
dragged its feet over the establishment of the Single Super-
visory Mechanism, the Single Resolution Mechanism and the
implementation of a European deposit insurance (Speyer 2012).
Beyond this, the debate over fiscal austerity escalated after
the election of the left-wing government of Alexis Tsipras in
Greece in January 2015, coming to an ignominious conclu-
sion in July 2015 when controls on capital movements had
to be imposed to prevent a collapse of the Greek financial
sector and the Greek government ultimately ignored its own
referendum result to reach an agreement with the creditor
“institutions” (as the troika is now called) that essentially rep-
resents a continuation of previous policies (Legrain 2015).
The Five Presidents’ Report thus represents the first at-
tempt since the new EU-Commission under President Jean-
Claude Juncker took office in 2014 to revitalise the debate
over the need for further reforms of the Monetary Union. But
because the Report has to date been pushed down the politi-
cal agenda of the European Council summits by the acute
challenge of open disagreements between member states
over migration and refugee policy, responses to terrorist at-
tacks and Brexit, a profound discussion and evaluation by the
heads of state and government has yet to occur. Nonetheless,
the Five Presidents’ Report will represent the basis for discus-
sions about the future shape of the Monetary Union. In tan-
dem with the joint Franco-German proposals initially an-
nounced for the end of 2016 but not delivered to date, the
Report represents the precursor for the Commission’s Re-
flection Paper on deepening the Eurozone due in May 2017,
which was announced by Juncker in the White Paper on the
Future of Europe in March 2017 (see Figure 2). In the follow-
ing, the process of creating the report is described and the
context of the Sherpa contributions explained.
2.2 THE PREPARATION PROCESS OF THE
2015 FIVE PRESIDENTS’ REPORT
To revive discussion about the future of the EMU, the Com-
mission circulated an Analytical Note in February 2015 lay-
ing out an analysis of the crisis and formulating a first set of
eleven questions to member states (see Chapter 4.1). Com-
mission President Jean-Claude Juncker invited member
states to launch a discussion process that “could” address
these very fundamental questions (Juncker 2015a: 8), re-
volving around the economic governance of the Eurozone.
The document employs a multi-level categorisation: First it
addresses political governance capacities in the existing
framework, asking how implementation could be improved.
In a second step the document turns to the institutions and
instruments required for sanctioning violations of the exist-
ing agreed governance framework. Thirdly, it asks whether
November 2012:
Thyssen Report
by European
Parliament with
recommendations
on Four-Presidents-
Report
November 2012:
Blueprint by
European
Commission for a
deep and
genuine economic
and monetary
union
December 2012:
Final Four-
Presidents-
Report (Quadriga-
Report)
December 2012:
European Council
curtails reform
plans
Ma y 2013:
Joint Franco-
German decla-
ration postpones
reform plans until
further notice
Ju ne 2015:
Five-Presidents-
Report restarts
the reform
process
March 2017:
European
Commission
White Paper on
the Future of
Europe
Ma y 2017:
Commission
Reflection
Paper on the
deepening of
the Economic
and Monetary
Union
Figure 2
The Five Presidents' Repor t in the context of Eurozone reform plans since 2012
Source: authors.
Announced
9
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
today’s Eurozone is in fact now equipped to face the chal-
lenges observed in the euro crisis since 2010, before in a
final step concretely posing the question of greater trans-
fers of sovereignty, more risk-sharing and increased conver-
gence.
Following a discussion about the first round of written con-
tributions received from the EU capitals and the European
Parliament between the member states’ negotiators (Sherpas)
and the Commission on 11 March 2015, a second document
of 21 April 2015 supplied a summary of the responses to date
and seven sets of more detailed questions (European Com-
mission 2015a; 2015b). These address individual aspects from
the member states’ contributions and explore how par
ticular
demands could be implemented concretely. In response,
fif-
teen member states and the European Parliament submitted
second contributions to the Commission, whereby Germany
and France prepared a joint response. In some cases, the
member states’ governments responded concretely to the
questions posed to them in the second document, in others
they expanded and enlarged on the views communicated in
the first round. In many cases, the second-round contribu-
tions are more comprehensive than the initial responses to
the Analytical Note. This suggests that the Commission has
succeeded in heightening the member states’ interest in feed-
ing their national stances on the future of the EMU into the
process.
So the Juncker Commission was very quickly able to re-
vive a debate over the EMU that had fallen into abeyance in
2013 and 2014 (see Figure 2). At the same time, it succeed-
ed in structuring the process: most of the member states
answered the questions in order. However, certain govern-
ments only commented on particular aspects, while others
delivered comprehensive disputations. The quality varies con-
siderably, ranging between purely subjective assessments
and semi-scientific focus.
In terms of substance, considering the process as a whole,
a fundamental conflict becomes apparent. It runs throughout
the debate and is also mentioned by the Commission in its
documents. The Commission summarises the national contribu-
tions received thus far in a discussion paper of 21 April 2015:
“There is a general recognition of the significant progress
made over the last few years to strengthen economic gov
ern-
ance and the EMU architecture. Some contributions would
consider this progress broadly sufficient and not see the
need
for significant further steps. On the other hand, other con-
tributions consider that, given the experience so far, the
mini-
mum requirements for a stable EMU are still not in place”
(European Commission 2015a: 1). So the opinions of the mem-
ber states span the range from consolidation of the existing
governance framework and fine-tuning of the European Se-
mester on the one side through to the proposal to establish
new joint institutions and mechanisms on the other, as also
reflected in the Draft Outline of 22 May 2015 for the final
Five Presidents’ Report (European Commission 2015c).
These fundamentally diverging perspectives can be ex-
plained in terms of the different visions of a stability union on
the one hand and a fiscal union on the other. In the follow-
ing, this analytical framework is fleshed out to subsequently
serve as the basis for the analysis of the Sherpa contributions.
Febru ary 2015:
Analytical note
by European
Commission
inviting contribu-
tions by member
states
Ma rc h 2015:
Discussion of
analytical note
by Sherpas,
based on
member state
contributions
Ap ril 2015:
Summary of
contributions by
European Com-
mission and
second question-
naire to member
states
May 2015:
Second Sherpa
discussion
based on mem-
ber state contri-
butions and
draft outline by
European
Commission
June 2015:
Final Five
Presidents'
Report
March 2017:
European Com-
mission White
Paper on the
Fut ure of
Europe
May 2017:
Commission
Reflection Paper
on deepening
monetary
union
Figure 3
The preparation process for the 2015 Five Presidents' Report
Source: authors.
Announced
10
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
After the turmoil and crises of recent years everyone agrees
that the Eurozone needs to be reformed. But that is where
the consensus ends and prescriptions for the Monetary Un-
ion diverge enormously. In fact, disagreement over the right
architecture and governance for the Monetary Union is noth-
ing new. The latest crisis re-ignited the heated debate that
academics and politicians were already conducting in the run-
up to the founding of the EMU. Its origins lie above all in the
question of how a Monetary Union should be constructed.
SUMMARY:
– Disagreement over necessary reforms for the Eurozone
is rooted in fundamentally different economic para-
digms, which shaped the founding phase of today’s
Monetary Union.
– One camp argues for the Monetary Union to be a sta-
bility union based on principles of internal and exter-
nal price stability and prioritising rule-based self-
regulation of free-market forces to minimise political
risks.
– The other camp argues for the Monetary Union to
be a fiscal union based on their belief in the need for
transnational economic governance to extend be-
yond the aspect of price stability, in order to address
inevitable market failures.
– The two visions represent diametrically opposed con-
ceptions of a complete and functioning Monetary
Union and arrive at widely diverging interpretations
of the origins of the crisis and the necessary reform
steps.
When, following World War II, it became clear that Europe
would be striving to grow together economically in order to
overcome the shock and destruction of military confronta-
tion, the desired degree of economic integration was an ob-
vious question. Initially only selected strategic sectors like
coal and steel were integrated, and a gradual timetable was
pursued for mutualising other areas of national economies.
Unlike certain other political proposals for creating a Euro-
pean Federation out of the résistance,1 the question of cur-
rency relations within Europe was initially marginal, despite
growing economic exchange. Although the six founding
members of the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC)
and the European Economic Community (EEC) sought inte-
grated trade during the 1950s and 1960s, hopes for mone-
tary cooperation were placed in the global Bretton Woods
system of fixed exchange rates. At the same time, the 1957
Treaties of Rome proposed the establishment of a “Mone-
tary Committee with consultative status” comprising the
European Commission and representatives of the member
states, “[i]n order to promote the co-ordination of the poli-
cies of Member States in monetary matters to the full ex-
tent necessary for the functioning of the Common Market”
(Article 105, EEC Treaty).
Monetary integration did not return to the agenda until
1968, following completion of the Customs Union between
Germany, France, Italy and the Benelux states, which repre-
sented a decisive step towards the Common Market. At the
summit in The Hague in December 1969, the heads of state
and government of the six member states called for the
preparation of a plan for the establishment of an economic
and monetary union. However, the plan to introduce a single
currency within ten years presented the next year by Luxem-
bourg Prime Minister Pierre Werner was overtaken by the
1970s oil shock, the collapse of Bretton Woods and national
concerns for sovereignty. One important milestone came in
1979 with the conversion of the European Monetary Coop-
eration Fund (EMCF; founded in 1973) into the European
Monetary System (EMS) with a shared basket currency and
coordinated central bank interventions to keep rates within
agreed bands. The EMS lasted until the early 1990s, when it
succumbed to diverging economic developments and corre-
spondingly orientated central bank policies of the participat-
ing states following German reunification and speculative
attacks.
1 For example in the Union of European Federalists’s 1942 Draft Consti-
tution of the United States of Europe, which declares currency and bank-
ing to be federal matters and calls for a new European currency (Europa-
Union 1942 in: Lipgens (1986): 101).
3
TWO CONCEPTS FOR THE FUTURE
OF THE EUROZONE: STABILITY UNION
VS. FISCAL UNION
11
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
After the various models of fixed exchange rates, floating
rates, currency “snakes” and intervention-backed fluctuation
bands all failed to satisfactorily resolve the problem of periodic
currency turbulence, the option of adopting a single currency
(and thus completely abolishing exchange rate risks) appeared
with increasing gravity on the agenda. But could a single cur-
rency function? And if so, under what preconditions?
In the following we examine the theoretical foundations
of the two central – and opposing – concepts for the Mone-
tary Union, before spotlighting the central lines of disagree-
ment in the present discussion in the context of the euro cri-
sis and laying out the two visions: a stability union on one
side and a fiscal union on the other.
3.1 THE EMU AS A STABILITY UNION
On one side of the political debate over the question of wheth-
er and how a Monetary Union in Europe could be successful,
we have the advocates of a stability union.
The stability union idea has been especially predominant
in Germany. Its roots in the emerging debate over a possible
common currency lie in the overriding significance of econom-
ic stability (price and monetary stability) as the precondition
for any successful currency. Against the historical backdrop
of two periods of extreme inflation (most recently 1945–48),
price stability attained great significance in post-war Germa-
ny. Accordingly, the Bundesbank was established as an insti-
tution independent of political influence, with the primary
objective of fighting inflation. This, it was hoped, would pre-
vent governments from opportunistically increasing the mon-
ey supply – which had in the past had such disastrous effects
and ultimately twice led to complete devaluation of the cur-
rency. Price stability, it was believed, would also ensure the sta-
bility of the value of the currency and thus function as a strong
and reliable platform for export-driven German industry. This
concern for monetary stability became the bedrock of German
economic policy and formed the foundation of the economic
school of ordoliberalism that remained domi
nant in Germany
– with few exceptions – for most of the
post-war era (Dyson
and Featherstone 1999). The German Bundesbank in particu-
lar has fulfilled its mission extremely successfully, with the
deutschmark standing for consistently low inflation. Indeed,
it was the only European currency never to be devalued.
Deeply committed to the free market, this school of
thought sees as the central task of a strong state an eco-
nomic policy ensuring fair and stable conditions for maxi-
mally-efficient free-market competition (Stark 2015). This
begins with the central public good of a currency that is sta-
ble both internally (inflation) and externally (exchange rate),
but also applies to a strong legal and institutional frame-
work enabling markets to function as efficiently as possible.2
All other aspects of the economic order are secured through
the disciplining efficiency of market mechanisms. In this
model, the state is not an economic actor in the dirigiste or
2 Meaning effective property and insolvency laws, stability-promoting
regulation, competition-promoting institutions such as a monopolies com-
mission, and institutions promoting market entry, such as the German
Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau (KfW).
Keynesian tradition, but a source of risk – especially in fiscal
policy – of political interventionism creating budget deficits,
leading to inflation and devaluation and thus undermining
its central function as provider of the public goods required
for efficient market processes (Brüderle 2010).
Here there are major overlaps with the school of mone-
tarism, which has dominated internationally at least since the
1980s. In the debate over the founding of a Monetary Union,
its proponents also argued positions supporting a stability
union (De Grauwe 2013: 157ff.; Young 2014). In the first place,
as a response to the experience of stagflation in the 1970s,
this economic discourse argued that central banks should re-
strict themselves as far as possible to the goal of fighting in-
flation and not explicitly pursue other policy objectives such
as employment or economic growth. In this line of thought,
achieving low inflation represents the most important contri-
bution to macroeconomic and financial stability. Pursuing oth-
er goals is thought to lead to inflationary tendencies and is
therefore rejected (Barro and Gordon 1983).
If the central bank, following this school of thought, con-
centrates on fighting inflation, there is no need for an expan-
sive fiscal policy as a governance instrument either, because
its stimulating effects would automatically be negated by
the central bank – through rising interest rates – in pursuit of
its inflation target. So in monetarism, like in ordoliberalism,
economic policy is seen above all as a guarantor of stability
in the sense of low inflation, and bears absolutely no wider
responsibility for economic developments because these can
only be influenced at the price of harmful inflation (Alesina
and Barro 2002). This rests on a strongly supply-side perspec-
tive on the economy, in the sense of the Real Business Cycle
Theory, which proposes that fluctuations in economic activity
always have real causes. Because these lie on the supply side,
recessions and unemployment potentially represent efficient
adjustment processes rather than inadequacies of the market
that need to be addressed through active policy intervention
(Kydland and Prescott 1977).
From this perspective, growth and economic dynamism
are achieved above all through productivity-expanding com-
petition in the markets, and certainly not through expansive
fiscal or monetary policy or the “artificial” and competition-
distorting effects of currency devaluation – which makes do-
mestic products cheaper in relative terms on world markets
but in the longer run is always associated with harmful infla-
tion. If growth fails to occur, the reasons are to be found – in
macro-economic terms – in weaknesses on the supply side,
such as inadequate flexibility of product and labour markets
to allow necessary structural change to produce market effi-
ciency or excessive wage, social or energy costs undermining
international competitiveness.
It is also within this theoretical understanding that the
currency policy reality of post-war Europe arose: Germany
had finally succeeded in banishing the demons of inflation
and devaluation, in a painful process driven by a disciplined
Bundesbank and economic policy. But many other countries
where the influence of political actors on the central banks
was (at least periodically) considerably greater, subordinated
economic stability to other shorter-term goals and accepted
the price of higher inflation and regular devaluations. Olaf
Sievert, long-serving member of the German Council of Eco-
12
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
nomic Experts, writing in the Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung
on the occasion of the Maastricht Treaty of 1992, summarises
this perspective well: “The history of money is above all an
eventful history of the abuse of the right to create money.
Over the centuries, the attraction of state sovereignty over
the monetary system has been defined by the acquisition
and exploitation of undeserved possibilities and benefits by
spending money one does not possess, but can create, by al-
lowing the creation of income and wealth for which there is
no real basis, which thus – if at all – can only be gained at
the expense of others and – not least – by devaluing the debts
one has promised to pay in good money. In short, through
lies and deception in the guise of state sovereignty.” (trans-
lated from Sievert 1992, 14).
For a long time, therefore, a Monetary Union was incon-
ceivable for many representatives of this school, because
the culture of stability required for a successful currency did
not exist in all the participating countries. But without a cul-
ture of stability individual countries would be tempted – and
able – to conduct an excessively expansive fiscal policy in
order to substitute the stimuli previously supplied by devalu-
ations. And this would lead to higher inflation, loss of com-
petitiveness and ultimately undermine the stability of the
currency. This renewed loss of the hard-won economic sta-
bility that was regarded as the foundation of the German
economic miracle of the post-war era was inconceivable and
had to be prevented at any cost.
In this understanding, monetary integration is only possi-
ble as the “coronation” of a much broader political integration
process, in which all members’ national policies must meld
into a “stability union” as the real structures of the economies
converge. This affects aspects as far-reaching as the national
wage and collective bargaining systems, the relative strength
of different economic sectors, and financial relations between
businesses, the financial markets and the public sector. In its
pure form, the coronation theory is hard to reconcile with
the perspective of a Monetary Union in the foreseeable fu-
ture, given that the necessary convergence would demand
incisive political interventions and harmonisations that would
for example contradict an understanding of legitimate dif-
ferences in types of capitalism (Hall and Soskice 2001) and
democratic legitimacy (Scharpf 1997). At least a strict nomi-
nal convergence of the participating economies through sta-
bility-orientated economic policy was therefore demanded
as an alternative minimum criterion that would make the
single currency possible. The real and structural discrepan-
cies, it was argued, are not an absolute reason to reject a
monetary union as impossible, as long as all the states pur-
sue the same economic policy, with the objective of internal
and external price stability.
Over time other arguments accumulated, making a single
currency more attractive and ultimately ensuring that the
question was now “how” rather than “whether” a monetary
union would come into being (Dyson and Featherstone 1999).
The most important factors that turned the economic and
political tables specifically in Germany were:
– the problem of imported inflation from neighbouring
countries now increasingly closely interlinked with Ger-
many through trade and investment;
– fear of the costs and responsibilities associated with func-
tioning as an anchor currency, arising out of the experi-
ence of the Bretton Woods system (Helleiner 2005);
– the striving for European integration and reconciliation with
France as the central goal of German post-war foreign
policy (Dyson and Featherstone 1999);
– the ever-growing importance of monetary stability vis-à-
vis European trade partners, generated by increasing eco-
nomic integration (Rose and Van Wincorp 2001);
– the inherent conflict between economic policy goals of
national monetary autonomy, monetary stability and lib-
eralised capital markets (Padoa-Schioppa 1982).
In order to resolve the “problem” of a Monetary Union with
partners that fail to commit properly to a culture of stability,
the ordoliberal tradition required members’ economic poli-
cies to be strictly tied to the required course (Stark 2015),
meaning in the first place that nominal convergence with
clearly defined economic stability criteria had to be achieved
(Sievert 1992). This was reflected in the Maastricht criteria
laid down before the introduction of the euro, under which
all potential members had to achieve low inflation and inter-
est rates, small exchange rate fluctuations, state budget defi-
cits not exceeding 3 percent annually, and state debt capped
at 60 percent of GDP. The vision of stability also implied that
future monetary policy – including the Bundesbank’s – would
be isolated from policies (also) pursuing other goals, and
would be mandated with the absolute priority of price sta-
bility. As the last necessary condition, finally, it had to be en-
sured that even after the introduction of the new currency
no member state would be in a position to undermine the
internal or external stability of the currency through exces-
sively expansive fiscal policy (and in the worst case to en-
danger it existentially by risking insolvency). Logically there-
fore, the Treaty of Maastricht included a no-bailout clause,
and the budgetary convergence criteria were expanded and
formalised as firm fiscal rules with the possibility of sanctions
in the Stability and Growth Pact. This was designed to ensure
that no state could rely on the assistance of the other mem-
bers to pursue a stability-threatening debt policy.
Going one step further, some observers even explicitly
supported such a construction as a means of disciplining
national fiscal and price policies: members of a Monetary
Union with an inflation-fighting independent central bank
would thus (in theory) be committed to a restrictive fiscal
policy because otherwise in the long term rising inflation
and state refinancing costs would make it impossible to
maintain exchange rate parity implied by the common cur-
rency. Some even regarded any kind of coordination of fiscal
policy as problematic, as this could undermine the disciplin-
ing effect (Beetsma and Bovenberg 1998). These arguments
reflect the positions of supporters of the international gold
standard system of fixed exchange rates as a means of low-
ering inflation, which are central for example in the Austrian
School (De Soto 2012) and have been termed the “golden
straitjacket” of globalisation by Thomas Friedman (1999).
In summary, we note that the stability vision of a Mone-
tary Union is based on fundamental concepts about success-
ful economic policy, especially in post-war Germany, and is
heavily represented in the design of the euro. The central el-
13
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
ements of this vision are firstly the overriding importance of
internal (inflation) and external (exchange rate) monetary sta-
bility as the state-guaranteed basis of efficient markets to
generate growth and prosperity. In order to safeguard these,
there must, secondly, be clear limits to fiscal policy in a mon-
etary union, especially if it is unclear whether it is stability-
orientated or has a tendency towards politicisation of eco-
nomic policy with tolerance of inflation and devaluation, and
thus operates in contradiction to monetary stability. Finally,
as the third component of central importance, the incentives
for “poor” national policy must be reduced as effectively as
possible in order to minimise moral hazard (the incentive to
enter into risks created by externalisation of potential costs).
The mechanism is described by the majority of the German
Council of Economic Experts as a principle of the unity of lia-
bility and control: liability for possible consequences must be
located at the same level as decision-making and control,
because harmful incentive structures are otherwise unavoid-
able (Feld et al. 2016). This also explains the explicit rejection
of conceivable models that include (even temporary) trans-
fers or transnational liability without equivalent control of the
policies of the countries for which such mechanisms would
potentially be expected to assume liability (Stark 2015).
This understanding of the functioning of the Monetary
Union carries through into the analysis of the euro crisis. The
proponents of a stability union emphasise the lack of obser-
vance of the rules of the Maastricht Treaty (deficit and debt
limits) and the negligent policies of the crisis states in the
lead-up to the financial crisis, where competitiveness was
lost (measured as unit labour costs), credit-driven consumer
spending and property bubbles were allowed to form, and
structural reforms of the labour market and the long-term
sustainability of state finances (for example through pension
reforms) were neglected. Fundamentally here, poor national
policies within the institutional framework of the Monetary
Union are defined as the cause of the crisis. Violation of sta-
bility rules necessarily leads to economic crisis (which is there-
fore the country’s own fault) (Franz et al. 2010).
Here we can again cite an example from the majority of
members of the German Council of Economic Experts, who
describe the “two fundamental weaknesses of the Eurozone
prior to the crisis” as follows: “Firstly, there was a lack of eco-
nomic and fiscal policy discipline, accompanied by dysfunc-
tional sanctioning mechanisms as well as flawed financial
regulation, leading to the build-up of huge public and pri-
vate debt levels and a loss of competitiveness; [s]econdly,
there was no credible mechanism for crisis response regard-
ing bank and sovereign debt problems that would have
been able to reign in moral hazard problems and establish
market discipline” (Feld et al. 2016).
In its interpretation of the crisis, the stability camp points
to the good economic performance of countries like Germa-
ny, which it attributes to budget restraint, wage restraint and
flexibility-focused structural reforms, while asserting that the
crisis countries had lived beyond their means, permitted ex-
cessive pay increases, and failed to carry out painful but nec-
essary reforms. Former ECB Executive Board member Jürgen
Stark (2015) described this explicitly as deep-seated “cultural
differences”: “The truth is that, in contrast to many eurozone
countries, Germany has reliably pursued a prudent economic
policy. While others were living beyond their means, Ger-
many avoided excess. These are deep cultural differences
and the currency union brings them to light once again.”
Assuming an efficient Monetary Union in free-market
terms, with free movement of capital since the early 1990s
but restricted movement of the production factor labour,
the only remaining option to restore competitiveness is to
reduce national price levels by cutting wages. The indicator
of trade imbalances, which was central in the euro crisis, is
also interpreted in this light: deficit countries that import
more goods than they export have for years neglected their
competitiveness by tolerating higher wages and rising infla-
tion, and were only able to fund their unsustainable, exces-
sive consumption and economic living standard by borrow-
ing abroad.
Proponents of a stability union therefore demand stricter
monitoring of the Maastricht criteria, and their tightening for
example through national debt brakes and the Fiscal Com-
pact, as well as broader and more direct possibilities for the
supranational level to intervene and impose national struc-
tural reforms: “After the experience of recent years the [poor
policies in the crisis states] can only be counteracted by a new
stability pact that enforces iron discipline on debt. We need
modified debt rules, heavy punishments and above all new
procedural rules that make these punishments automatic
and withdraw them from the realm of political influence”
(translated from Sinn 2010). All conceivable mechanisms by
which these adjustments could either be cushioned by nom-
inal price changes (inflation) or eased by temporary transfers
are therefore consistently rejected, as they would once again
introduce moral hazard (Stark 2015): states might rely on the
internalised option of assistance from other members and
therefore neglect to do their national ‘homework’ (Feld et
al. 2016).
If, despite strengthened rules and more direct interven-
tion instruments, individual member states do get into diffi-
culties, the ESM and the troika now supply adequate instru-
ments to prevent insolvency and if necessary force the re-
quired reforms and cuts through credit conditions. As Sinn
puts it, it is time to accept the bitter truth: “The only option
left is to insist on a phase of credit discipline and to end the
phase of loose budgetary restrictions. […] It is time for Europe
to face up to the realities and begin with the painful adjust-
ment processes in the real economy that are necessary to
restore equilibrium to the euro area” (translated from Sinn
2010). Here some proponents go a step further and regard
state insolvency arrangements as a necessity in particular to
restore the credibility of the no-bailout rule and close one of
the central loopholes for moral hazard (Feld et al. 2016).
From this perspective, macroeconomic imbalances can
only be corrected by reducing wages and prices and deregu-
lating product and service markets in the crisis states, in order
to accelerate the implementation of necessary market-driven
adjustment processes. Adjustments on the part of the surplus
countries would not be helpful, as they would ultimately
amount to a voluntary reduction in competitiveness (vis-à-vis
the rest of the world), a punishment of the stability-orientat-
ed states and an easing of the adjustment for deficit countries,
which would create a set of disincentives for competition-
driven economic policy (Bundesbank 2010).
14
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
3.2 THE EMU AS A FISCAL UNION
The second camp in the debate over the ideal design and
governance of the Monetary Union is made up of support-
ers of a fiscal union.
As with the stability union, the origins of the fiscal union
concept for a single currency lie in the analysis of economic
events in the national framework. The starting point is John
Maynard Keynes’s critique of classical economic theory, after
the latter’s failure in the Great Depression following the crash
of 1929. His General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money of 1936 revolutionised ideas about the equilibrium
assumptions of classical economics, which had hitherto domi-
nated the discussion, and established modern macroeconom-
ics. Keynes (2009 [1936]) shows how an economy in crisis
can remain trapped in underemployment and disproves the
classical assumption that lower wages would increase sup-
ply and thus boost demand. On the contrary, he argues, the
market alone is incapable of returning to full-employment
equilibrium following cyclical unemployment; the central
reason for this, he argues, is the rationing of employment
through the shortfall of aggregate demand in the markets
for goods and products. Keynes argues that in the event of
crisis, the markets require a stabilisation of aggregate de-
mand. Consumer spending and investment cannot be re-
generated by economic “laissez-faire”; instead government
must take measures to (re)instate full employment.
The central actors in the demand stabilisation recom-
mended by Keynes are in practice national governments
and central banks. This is how, abandoning the classical par-
adigm of a market economy liberating itself from crisis, fis-
cal and monetary policies ushered in the post-war “golden
age of capitalism” (Marglin/Schor 1992). And in contrast to
the theories of the ordoliberal school (see Chapter 3.1), the
social market economy as actually practiced in Western Europe
until into the 1970s was strongly orientated on balancing
the spheres of state and market (Schulmeister 2013: 121).
Thus if interest- and exchange rate adjustments are required
to stabilise the economy in the event of market failure, there
would be little reason to abandon these instruments in a Mon-
etary Union.
Within the realm of monetary integration theory, Robert
Mundell’s Theory of Optimum Currency Areas (1961) inves-
tigates whether the renunciation of independent national
monetary policy would be a sensible step, by weighing up
the costs and benefits of joining a monetary union. Mundell
analyses the options for fighting asymmetric demand shocks
affecting specific countries, because within a currency un-
ion, monetary policy interventions to stabilise cyclical and
price fluctuations only function against shocks that affect
all members symmetrically. He concludes that the existence
of asym
metric shocks means that successful shock absorp-
tion is only
conceivable in a world divided into currency ar-
eas that permit monetary and exchange rate policies corre-
sponding to regional conditions: “The optimum currency
area is not the world. [...] The optimum currency area is the
region” (ibid.: 659f.).
The loss of monetary independence is compounded af-
ter accession to a monetary union by the renunciation of in-
dependent funding of state deficits. Members of a monetary
union can no longer borrow in their own currency, and in
the event of liquidity crises must rely on the understanding
and patience of the common central bank and/or foreign cred-
itors. Under these circumstances, liquidity crises can quickly
lead to solvency problems, as was seen in the euro crisis. They
are driven by asymmetric shocks, when financial markets –
doubting the affected state’s ability to service its loans – sell
its bonds and thus drive up interest rates for new borrowing.
Higher interest rates in turn cause the state debt to grow and
curtail the affected state’s fiscal leeway (De Grauwe 2016: 8ff.).
The fact that – despite this dangerous renunciation of
national stabilisation policy – a monetary union also became
a plausible project for proponents of the Keynesian world-
view has to do with the supplanting of the “real-side capi-
talist” “navigation map” by the financial capitalist framework
(Schulmeister 2013: 123) since the end of the 1970s. The eco-
nomic worldview now returned to individual economic ration-
ality and flexible markets, and brought about the end of the
Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates and a gradu-
al deregulation of financial markets. However, the resulting
large movements of capital produced major currency crises,
not only in Latin America and Asia, but also in Europe, where
the EMS with its limited flexibility of exchange rates collapsed
at the beginning of the 1990s in part through currency spec-
ulation.
In this situation, the costs of joining a monetary union ap-
peared smaller than initially assumed. This applied in particu-
lar to smaller states that did not actually face the posited
choice between joining a monetary union or maintaining
their monetary autonomy, because their central banks were
at the mercy of international currency markets anyway (Flass-
beck/Lapavitsas 2015: 20f.). Moreover, under the impression
of advancing internal market integration in the EU, the rele-
vance of asymmetric shocks was regarded as increasingly
small. Mundell (1961) concluded – quite in line with the sup-
porters of a stability union – that the costs of loss of the op-
tion of national exchange rate adjustments after an asym-
metric demand shock are smaller the more flexibly the pro-
duction factors of labour and capital are able to move across
the borders of the affected countries. Thus, he argued, ade-
quate wage and price flexibility and the movement of work-
ers from a country in economic recession to an economically
prospering neighbour can make the use of monetary stabili-
sation instruments superfluous. Developments suggesting
that a higher degree of economic openness while a country
retains monetary sovereignty is associated with smaller costs
of accession (McKinnon 1963) and the benefits of a diversi-
fied production structure (Kenen 1969), which ensures that in
the event of shocks only a part of the domestic economy is
affected, caused a monetary union to appear increasingly at-
tractive to the already highly integrated European economies.
But this Keynesian perspective neither assumed the ex-
istence of an optimal currency area in Europe, nor did it share
the positive view of the microeconomic benefits of a mone-
tary union held by the proponents of a stability union (Kösters
et al. 2001: 60ff.). Instead, Keynesians took the macroeconom-
ic costs of monetary integration seriously and weighed them
against the banishment of currency speculation in Europe.
With respect to the incremental implementation of the Euro-
pean Economic and Monetary Union agreed in 1992 in Maas-
15
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
tricht, the proponents of a fiscal union warned against re-
garding the emerging Eurozone of initially twelve states as
an optimal currency area. Too great, they said, was its sus-
ceptibility to asymmetric shocks, and too weak the transna-
tional factor mobility and trade integration within the Single
Market (Eichengreen 1991).
Politically, however, the founding of the EMU in Europe
was, from this perspective, not only a potential instrument
for containing currency market speculation. Instead the ex-
perience of the EMS had also demonstrated that in the mod-
el of floating currencies within agreed exchange rate bands,
the deutschmark as anchor currency had given the German
Bundesbank a dominant position over monetary policy that
many other states wanted to shake off. France especially felt
its sovereignty was impaired, but repeatedly found itself forced
to execute ordoliberal policies in order to keep the French
franc within the agreed band. Especially in France the EMU
therefore appeared to many as an opportunity to clip the
wings of the German currency hegemon. To that end, the
French were also willing to relinquish their monetary sover-
eignty in favour of a collective central bank (Jabko 2015: 73;
Lierse 2011: 161ff.).
But apart from the political criterion of monetary contain-
ment of Germany – which should not be neglected and re-
appeared on the agenda with heightened relevance in the
course of reunification (McNamara 2015) – the identified defi-
cits of the Eurozone as an optimal currency area were used
to justify new instruments for minimising possible risks. The
widely differing paradigmatic positions of the central actors
– as already mentioned in Chapter 3.1 – led the supporters
of a stability union to strike a course designed to develop
the EMU into an optimal currency area using market compe-
tition mechanisms but largely dispensing with monetary and
fiscal instruments. By contrast, the supporters of a fiscal un-
ion saw the European states’ lack of the characteristics of an
optimal currency area as a clear sign of the necessity for fis-
cal instruments to meet the challenge of regional shocks.
They remained sceptical about the beneficial effect of the Sin-
gle Market project for reducing asymmetric shock potential
and resisted the necessity of price and wage flexibility pos-
tulated by the opposing side. Shocks were localised not only
on the supply side, but in the first place on the demand side.
The active role of the state in reviving the economic cycle
against the phenomenon of hoarding described by Keynes
was now seen to be necessary at the transnational level (De
Grauwe 2006: 726f.).
In the founding phase of the EMU, the United States in
particular was often cited as a model demonstrating that
budgetary transfers in the sense of fiscal federalism would be
required in order to successfully address asymmetric shocks
within a monetary union: “The extent of regional problems
within existing currency and customs unions like the United
States underscores the need for regional shock absorbers,
such as fiscal federalism, to accomodate asymmetrical dis-
turbances” (Eichengreen 1991: 24). If independent national
monetary policy can no longer be pursued, the focus turns
to fiscal policy. A system of fiscal transfers from member
states with healthy growth to those affected by a negative
demand shock would contribute to stabilisation. Above and
beyond this, joint and/or coordinated policies in the areas of
taxation, public spending, social and wage policy could pre-
vent individual states pursuing unilateral decisions and thus
reduce the susceptibility of the currency area to asymmetric
shocks (De Grauwe 2006: 721).
The Keynesian option of stabilising policies at the Com-
munity level of a monetary union appeared in the Werner
Plan of 1970, which provided for synchronisation of national
budget procedures, fiscal harmonisation, and coordination
of stabilisation policies through a Community-level decision-
making organ.3 The McDougall Report (European Commis-
sion 1977: 70) went a step further, proposing that a single
currency be given a central budget of at least 5 percent of
the total GDP of the participating states. While in the 1970s
one could still assume a Keynesian consensus, this had
changed considerably by the time an initiative for a Europe-
an Monetary Union was next launched at the end of the
1980s. Although the Report on Economic and Monetary Un-
ion in the European Community published by Commission
President Jacques Delors in 1989 also speaks of the necessi-
ty of a macroeconomic framework and Community policies,
the monetarist/ordoliberal argument of budgetary disciplin-
ing of national fiscal policies also moves to the fore: [...A]n
agreed macroeconomic framework and [...] binding proce-
dures and rules [...] would permit the determination of an
overall policy stance for the Community as a whole, avoid
unsustainable differences between individual member coun-
tries in public-sector borrowing requirements and place bind-
ing constraints on the size and the financing of budget defi-
cits” (Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary
Union 1989: 14).
In the negotiations for the Treaty of Maastricht the stabil-
ity
orientated zeitgeist came out largely on top, which suited
Germany in particular with its interest in price stability and
deficit avoidance. France on the other hand argued for an
economic government of the Monetary Union. Institutional-
ly, this produced the Council’s regular recommendations on
guidelines for economic policy (Article 121, TFEU) and the
Eurogroup as an initially informal organ. Faced with the hard
criteria for accession to the EMU – the deficit rule and its
tightening in 1997 in the Stability and Growth Pact – and
the ECB’s prioritisation of price stability, the French perspec-
tive of an explicit economic coordination pillar of the Euro-
zone was ultimately reflected only in the form of soft poli-
cies (Pisani-Ferry 2006).
This understanding of the functioning of the EMU as an
economic as well as monetary project experienced a renais-
sance among the proponents of a fiscal union during the
euro crisis. Now it became clear that the asymmetric shocks
highlighted by Mundell could test the Eurozone to breaking
point. On account of the heterogeneous economic develop-
ments since the launch of the euro, the ECB had never been
in a position to conduct a monetary policy that made sense
3 The Werner Plan leaves no doubt as to the necessity for monetary co-
operation to be accompanied by political: “In particular the development
of monetary unification mus t be based on suff icient progress in the field
of convergence and then in that of the unification of economic policies.”
Without a progressive development towards political cooperation with the
objective of political union, it argues, a monetary union will not survive (trans-
lated from Werner 1970, quoted from Lipgens 1986: 533).
16
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
for all the participating countries with regard to their differ-
ent business cycle positions. At the same time, the collective
economic policy coordination instruments agreed in Maas-
tricht and thereafter – the Economic Policy Guidelines, the
Macroeconomic Dialogue, the ten-year Lisbon and Europe
2020 Strategies – turned out to be toothless, and the joint
institutions ECOFIN Council and Eurogroup (and even more
so the European Commission and Parliament) to be too weak
or unwilling to be able to do anything effective about the
regularly occurring asymmetries. The only relevant economic
policy coordination of the Eurozone relates to member states’
deficits and debts. But if independent monetary policy can
no longer be conducted and anti-cyclical tools of national
fiscal policy are severely restricted, budgetary surveillance wors-
ens the situation and is useless as an instrument of transna-
tional coordination (Buiter 2006: 698). Adjustment to asym-
metric shocks is thus left to wage policy in the nation states
(Busch 1994); but once inflation differentials have arisen they
can easily expand pro-cyclically through the ECB’s “one-size-
fits-none” interest rate policy (Enderlein 2005) and unregu-
lated international capital flows (Merler 2015).
As far as the fiscal union camp is concerned, the euro crisis
proves their case that the architecture of the EMU is incom-
plete. Accordingly, all proposals originating from this camp as-
sume the necessity for closer harmonisation of economic poli-
cy. The decisive goal here is not the establishment of real con-
vergence between the member states, but to ensure nominal
convergence, for instance of current account balances, infla-
tion rates and unit labour costs (Auf dem Brincke et al. 2015).
The reasons for the euro crisis are sought not only in the mis-
takes of individual states, but in institutional “design failures”
(De Grauwe 2015) of the EMU. The proponents of a fiscal
union therefore respond with incredulity to the asymmetry
of crisis management, which suggests that states with large
budget deficits and public debt and negative current account
balances bear a specific responsibility for the crisis. In the eyes
of the advocates of a fiscal union, a crisis management poli-
cy that prioritises austerity and consciously accepts defla-
tionary developments has failed to learn the lessons of the
Great Depression of the 1930s (Heise 2015). In the view of
the fiscal union camp, the following points represent the
only positive aspects of the crisis response to date, and only
with caveats:
– The de facto abandonment of the no-bailout rule through
the establishment of a permanent ESM, because this an-
chors the principle of shared liability. The strict conditions
placed on assistance from the ESM (precluding cyclical
adjustment programmes) are classed as counterproduc-
tive (Busch et al. 2012).
– The introduction of a regulated Macroeconomic Imbal-
ance Procedure, (MIP), which supplements one-sided con-
trol of budget policies with numerous additional indica-
tors for identifying macroeconomic imbalances between
the states. Criticism is expressed of its asymmetry in treat-
ing current account surpluses as less relevant for economic
instability than current account deficits, and also the to
date weak application of the sanction instruments in case
of state mismanagement and the simultaneous tighten-
ing of budgetary controls (De Grauwe 2012).
– The unorthodox policy of the ECB as de facto “lender of
last resort”, which has over the course of the crisis devel-
oped into the guarantor of the EMU. The ECB’s crisis man-
agement instruments include a zero-interest policy, nega-
tive deposit rates and bond purchases on the secondary
market. Beyond this ECB President Mario Draghi regularly
points to the need for fiscal stimulus to overcome the euro
crisis, but at the same time underlines the necessity for
structural reforms and observance of budgetary rules:
“Fiscal policies should support the economic recovery,
while remaining in compliance with the fiscal rules of
the European Union. Full and consistent implementation
of the Stability and Growth Pact is crucial to maintain
confidence in the fiscal framework. At the same time, all
countries should strive for a more growth-friendly com
po-
sition of fiscal policies” (Draghi 2016).
– The already initiated Banking Union with joint supervision,
resolution and liability instruments for establishing a uni-
form policy towards financial institutions. Criticism is ex-
pressed that the Single Resolution Fund for transnational li-
ability has been developed as a last resort, is too small and
will not be fully operational until 2024 (Lindner et al. 2014).
– The crisis-driven strengthening of the Eurogroup as an in-
dependent formation for decisions affecting the EMU and
integrating EU mechanisms for coordinating employment
and social policy into the enhanced European Semester
since 2010. The subordination under the objectives of bud-
getary surveillance created by the linkage is however criti-
cised (Armstrong 2012).
– The European Fund for Strategic Investments (EFSI) initi-
ated by the Juncker Commission as a central initiative for
economic intervention in the euro area and the associated
reinterpretation of the Stability and Growth Pact with re-
spect to expanded flexibility over state investment spend-
ing in times of crisis. Criticism is expressed of the small
volume of the fund and its primary focus on activating
private investment (Horn et al. 2015: 8ff.).
The fiscal union supporters sharply criticise the “Berlin consen-
sus” (Bofinger 2012: 77) in European crisis management, un-
der which the euro crisis is understood primarily as a public
debt crisis. On the contrary, the concentration on stricter bud-
getary discipline, internal devaluation through spending cuts
and structural reforms, and trust in market discipline are un-
derstood as the recipe for a protracted crisis. The responsible
politicians, it is asserted, are heading wilfully into deflation,
which will exacerbate the crisis and contribute nothing to sta-
bilising the Monetary Union: “Deflation is the surest way to
wreck an economy. [...] Seeking a Monetary Union without
a political union is an illusion” (translated from Herr 2012: 3).
Peter Bofinger speaks of a “policy of muddling through”, whose
consequences have caused considerable economic and politi-
cal harm: “In other words, a fundamental change of course is
required. This change of course must be guided by the insight
that the architecture of the Monetary Union as adopted in
the
Treaty of Maastricht has lost its viability through the convul-
sions of the financial crisis. If the monetary integration imple-
mented through the founding of the ECB and the introduc-
tion of the euro is to have a future, there will be no alternative
to closer fiscal integration” (translated from Bofinger 2012: 111).
17
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
Concrete proposals for faster fiscal integration of the Euro-
zone range from ideas for joint debt management through
Eurobonds (Delpla/von Weizsäcker 2011) or a redemption
fund (Sachverständigenrat 2012) through the establishment
of a joint budget, stabilisation funds and/or fiscal capacity
(De Grauwe/Ji 2016; Pisani-Ferry et al. 2013) to the estab-
lishment of a joint insurance mechanism (Dullien 2014; En-
derlein et al. 2013). The central thought is firstly, to bring to-
gether liability for state debt at the European level, in order
to prevent the financial markets from exploiting differences
in the creditworthiness of the euro states. Secondly, the intro-
duction of an automatic cyclical stabiliser at European level
would compensate the inadequate adjustment to asymmet-
ric shocks caused by inadequate mobility of labour and re-
place internal devaluation through falling wages and prices,
which is regarded as counterproductive. In place of structural
supply-side reforms, demand in regions affected by a nega-
tive demand shock would be stimulated via a fiscal transfer
system using state spending or tax breaks: “The idea of
EMU-level automatic stabilisers is to be able to respond to
asymmetric shocks or endogenous pressures in the mone-
tary union and to uphold aggregate demand in the short
term, before factors of production can be reorganised in
the affected economy and recovery can resume. In other
words, the point is to maintain enough spending during a
downturn, before failed companies are turned around or
replaced by new ones and before workers who lost their
jobs can find new employment” (Andor 2014: 187).
Closer coordination of other policy areas is also sought
to avoid asymmetric shocks, for example in the area of wage
policy (Dufresne 2015; Pusch 2011) and social policies: “The
absence of any other adjustment mechanism is one reason
why the EMU is sometimes criticised for lacking a social di-
mension: unless countries undergoing an asymmetric shock
have low debt/GDP ratios and can thus afford individual fis-
cal expansion (which will most likely not be the case in the
next few decades), the only possible adjustment in the EMU
is through cost-cutting and ever-greater flexibility in the la-
bour market. [...A] social dimension cannot be achieved with-
out a mechanism for collectively monitoring and preventing
employment and social imbalances – and for collectively de-
tecting and tackling them when they arise” (Andor 2013: 2).
The demand for an explicit political union is raised at
least for the medium to long term. Here the single currency
is regarded as a shared public good requiring a parliament-
controlled government for the Eurozone with revenue and
spending rights (Collignon 2014; De Grauwe 2006): “It is well
known that public goods are not efficiently provided by the
markets, because with free access individuals could free-ride
on others who are willing to pay for them. [...] Democracy is
the mechanism that makes sure that the supply of public
goods coincides with the collective demand of the people
concerned. [...] I have called the limited government for Euro-
pean public goods the European Republic. The Euro-crisis
has revealed that the old ways of governing Europe no longer
work. The republican paradigm points in a new direction. It
focuses on public goods, Europe’s res publica, which affects
and concerns all European citizens” (Collignon 2014: 105f.).
In this connection there is frequent reference to a “European
economic government” to be legitimised by a “euro parlia
ment ”.
3.3 INTERIM SUMMARY: INSTRUMENTS FOR
TWO CONCEPTS OF A MONETARY UNION
The historical summary outlined above reveals very clearly
how sharp the theoretical divide is between the supporters
of a stability union and a fiscal union. The roots of today’s
controversies over the future shape of the EMU’s architec-
ture are to be found in diametrically opposed economic par-
adigms. The belief in rule-based self-regulation of free-mar-
ket forces comes up against a conviction of the importance
of economic governance.4 In the founding phase of the EMU,
a debate that had hitherto been conducted at the national
level moved to the transnational. At the time, the conflict was
papered over with a compromise under which strict stability
rules for national budgets and a central bank dedicated pri-
marily to price stability would go hand in hand with a perma-
nent growth pact and economic policy coordination. Since the
advent of the euro crisis, we now know that none of that was
enough to secure lasting socio-economic convergence in the
Eurozone (Dauderstädt 2014). And there has certainly been
no coming together of the perspectives. In the ongoing cri-
sis, the arguments over the future course of the Monetary
Union are the same as during its founding period. Yet a dif-
ferentiated understanding of the reasons for the euro crisis
is a central precondition for demands for additional instru-
ments to crisis-proof the Monetary Union. As such, the causal
analyses of the euro crisis conducted in the scope of two very
different economic paradigms determine to a great extent the
concrete political proposals for reforms of the EMU.
Accordingly, the development of the EMU into a stability
union involves
– a strict regime of binding budgetary rules;
– ideally automatic sanctions in the event of non-fulfilment;
– reinstatement of the no-bailout rule through an insolvency
procedure for states;
– competition-driven structural reforms and internal devalua-
tions, also as a consequence of rule-breaking;
– greater Community-level control over national economic
policy to secure structural reforms and budgetary compli-
ance, through a finance minister for the Eurozone (without
a political mandate).
While the stability union camp believes the development of
the EMU should do no more than strengthen the reach and
strictness of the current Eurozone status quo ante and sharp-
en existing rules, expansion into a fiscal union would demand
significantly broader reforms:
– a Banking Union to bring together the oversight, resolu-
tion and deposit protection at the European level;
– joint debt management for the euro states;
– an automatic stabiliser to enable cyclical financial trans-
fers between member states;
4 In their analysis of reform proposals for the EMU, Katharina Gnath
and Jörg Haas (2015) find a similar dichotomy, and see the fiscal union
perspective as tied to an objective of risk-sharing, while the stability un-
ion perspective would be associated with the objective of sovereignty-
sharing.
18
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
– closer coordination of economic, employment and social
policies above and beyond state deficits and debt levels;
– in the longer term a federal political union with an eco-
nomic government responsible for the Eurozone and hav-
ing parliamentary legitimacy.
In the following, we will examine the place of these afore-
mentioned instruments in the member states’ contributions
to the preparation of the Five Presidents’ Reports and classify
the arguments put forward by the individual governments
into the two central categories of stability union and fiscal
union.
19
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
In order to assess the process leading to the final report and
give an outlook on the upcoming Commission Reflection Pa-
per and the political starting situation for further integration
steps, we present in the following a detailed analysis of the
Sherpa contributions submitted by the EU member states in
the process of preparing the Five Presidents’ Report. Given
that (almost) all the national contributions are publicly ac-
cessible, this represents a special opportunity – outside of
the unanimously agreed summit declarations – to gain in-
sights into national sensitivities, positions and plans for the
future shape of the EMU. As outlined in the following, this
analysis permits deep insights into the power relations of
the Eurozone, but also into the current state of the long-
running conflict between supporters of a stability union on
the one side and the advocates of a fiscal union on the other.
SUMMARY:
– The divide between the stability union and fiscal un-
ion perspectives for the Eurozone is also reflected in
the preparatory process for the Five Presidents’ Report.
– Both positions are included in deliberately vague
form in the Commission document initiating the new
reform process.
– The member states contributions can be classified
into three camps on the basis of their proposals on
the two diverging reform perspectives.
– Supporters of a stability union (Finland, Estonia, Lith-
uania, Germany, Malta, the Netherlands, Denmark,
Romania, Hungary) reject both an expansion of eco-
nomic governance and deeper fiscal integration.
– Supporters of a fiscal union (Italy, Spain, Portugal, Bel-
gium, Luxembourg, Slovenia, Latvia, France) argue for
an expansion of both economic governance and fis-
cal integration.
– Supporters of a fiscal union with restrictions (Cyprus,
Slovakia, Croatia, Poland, Ireland, Austria, Czech Re-
public) argue in principle for further development of
the Monetary Union, seeking either more economic
governance or fiscal integration steps – but not both.
Our classification of the contributions into two central reform
camps – stability union and fiscal union – is based on qualita-
tive examination of the arguments they put forward. This in-
volved more than noting mere mention of the reform instru-
ments described in the previous chapter. It also took into account
the ways analyses of the functionality of the Eurozone differ-
entiated between systemic errors in the architecture of the EMU
and individual mistakes made by member states. The central
distinguishing characteristic is therefore the question whether
the current economic governance framework of the EMU is ad-
equate (given consistent application or tightening) or whether
it is regarded as insufficient to prevent future crises and there-
fore needs to be deepened through adaptation of economic
governance and greater fiscal integration. States belonging to
the stability union camp reject changes in either of these two
areas, whereas the supporters of a fiscal union demand move-
ment in both. There is also a third group of countries that ar-
gues for neither a stability union nor a fiscal union, but can
imagine developments towards a fiscal union in at least one of
the two areas of reform (see Table 1).
The order in which the member states are discussed takes
into account their closeness to the two core theoretical issues
described in chapter 3. The country presented first (in chapters
4.2 and 4.4 respectively) is the one with the furthest-reaching
4
STABILITY UNION AND FISCAL
UNION IN THE CREATION OF THE FIVE
PRESIDENTS’ REPORT
Table 1
Visions for the Eurozone and support/rejection
of central reforms
Source: authors.
Vision
for the future
Eurozone
Expansion
of economic
governance
Expansion
of fiscal inte-
gration
Stability union No No
Fiscal union Yes Ye s
Fiscal union with
restrictions Yes/ No No/ Ye s
20
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
position, with the intensity declining from country to country
in the course of the chapter.
For the sake of completeness, it is important to note that
certain states are not included in the study, either because
they chose not to submit any contribution, because they chose
not to publish it, or because they did not concretely address
the debate over reform of the EMU. This applies to the Greek
(unpublished) and Bulgarian (not submitted) positions and the
contributions of the United Kingdom and Sweden, both of
which chose not to address the debate on the future of the
Eurozone, and restricted themselves to procedural input. In
addition, two contributions from the European Parliament,
which also flowed into the Sherpa process between member
states and Commission, are analysed (see Chapter 4.6).
4.1 THE STARTING POINT: THE COMMIS-
SION’S ANALYTICAL NOTE
Conceived as a technocratic document to initiate a political
debate among the member states, the Analytical Note pub-
lished by the Commission in February 2015 is by design open-
ended and avoids clearly rejecting various political positions
that might potentially be put forward by a member. None-
theless, at certain points we can observe tendencies that can
be classified on the spectrum between fiscal and stability
union.
The Analytical Note begins by presenting the crisis as
having various origins, with different channels contributing
to its outbreak and course. First of all, the outbreak of the
crisis in the financial sector is discussed, emphasising how
it ultimately resurfaced in public budgets: “A feature of par-
ticular relevance to the euro area was the negative feed-
back loop between bank and government sovereign debt.
[…] Thus, in these countries, a crisis of banks quickly became
a crisis of public finances, with a direct impact on the real
economy” (Juncker 2015a: 2).
So as far as the financial and fiscal aspect of the crisis is
concerned, the blame is placed not – as the stability camp
would have it – exclusively at the door of the states that are
highly indebted today. Instead, the Note points to its roots in
the financial crisis and explicitly points out that this then “be-
came a crisis of public finances”. The nation states are by no
means let off the hook, however, as the document goes on
to point very clearly to the missed opportunities for greater
consolidation before the crisis and the way almost all the
member states ignored and deliberately weakened the Sta-
bility and Growth Pact. Nonetheless, it must be noted that on
this point, the document shares its (partially) systemic analy-
sis with the supporters of a fiscal union.
The second point that the Analytical Note addresses in
its causal analysis is that the Eurozone crisis “can also be
said to have been a competitiveness crisis”, where some of
the weaknesses predated its outbreak. In particular, certain
states failed to use the boom phase before the crisis to ad-
dress existing “rigidities in product and labour markets”.
These rigidities, defined in a figure as “average of employ-
ment protection legislation and product market regulator
OECD indicators”, led, it asserts, to inadequately efficient
and flexible allocation of resources before the crisis (ibid.: 4).
Also, it says, unit labour costs rose strongly in certain
coun-
tries up until 2008, leading to declining competitiveness
vis-à-vis other Eurozone states and larger external econom-
ic deficits. Together, these developments are said to have
led to higher unemployment in certain countries when the
crisis broke out.
In the area of real economy developments, the Analyti-
cal Note therefore adopts a stance tending towards the sta-
bility vision: The countries that have been worst affected by
the crisis are, it says, themselves to blame through their fail-
ure to reduce regulation of labour and product markets, as
well as excessive pay increases. Only in a subsequent, caus-
ally vague paragraph does it address the systemic flip side
of these developments (which supporters of a fiscal union
emphasise): “In addition, the relatively favourable financing
conditions in the first years of the euro led to a misalloca-
tion of sources of financing towards less productive forms of
investment, such as real estate” (ibid.). The document also
mentions a so-called “crisis of markets”, where investors treat-
ed all euro countries similarly, with an excessive correction
of this assumption after the outbreak of crisis leaving some
countries forced to shoulder astronomical interest rates for
their borrowing. The common financial market and the origi-
nation of cheap credit in countries like France and Germany
is however not explicitly named as a factor contributing to
an accumulation of real economic imbalances and funding
rising real wages. Thus, here the Commission abides by the
stability perspective, although the systemic component of
the pre-crisis financing conditions in the crisis-affected coun-
tries is at least mentioned. The possibility of financial market
failure and its contribution to state debt is considered, but not
market failure in other problematic areas, which is attributed
to defective pre-crisis state policies.
In its analysis of the crisis, the Analytical Note thus os-
cil
lates between the fiscal and stability positions. The pro-
posed solutions are described in much less detail, which is
understandable in light of the document’s intended purpose.
The only concrete policies that are put forward relate to
strengthened implementation of “structural reforms” for re-
ducing the analysed rigidities in all member states and an
initiative to create a single capital market in Europe, which
would establish corporate bonds and other derivatives as al-
ternative funding sources to bank loans: “Tangible progress
on these two blocks – growth-enhancing structural reforms
and deepening the Single Market – will contribute to the
smooth functioning of Economic and Monetary Union in the
short term” (ibid.: 7). As far as the identified problem of en-
tanglement of state finances with financial crises is concerned,
the document notes that this is addressed through the intro-
duction of the Banking Union in the form of the Single Su-
pervisory Mechanism, Single Resolution Mechanism and the
harmonised national deposit protection schemes.
However, in the longer term – with reference to the re-
form plans of the Commission and the President of the Eu-
ropean Council from 2012 (which are still regarded as valid)
– the Analytical Note also calls for the comprehensive devel-
opment of the EMU not to be neglected. It justifies this on
the grounds that the Eurozone in 2015 remains trapped in
crisis mode, while the United States is in much better shape
economically: “The euro area has not recovered from the
21
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
crisis in the same way as the U.S., which might point to
the
fact that an incomplete monetary union adjusts much
slower than one with a more complete institutional setup
in place” (ibid.).
4.2 THE STABILITY UNION CAMP
In order to identify the stability union camp, we must ana-
lyse the states’ assessments and interpretations of the caus-
es of the crisis and the required reforms, in the two major
fields of economic governance and fiscal cooperation. The
supporters of a stability union reject greater fiscal integra-
tion, on account of the risk of creating a liability union and
delaying reforms. They also oppose changing economic
governance in the Eurozone, instead regarding implement-
ing pro-competitive “structural reforms” in the crisis states
as the central goal.
4.2.1 FINLAND
The positions of the Finnish negotiators clearly represent
this perspective. In relation to fiscal policy, for example, they
argue that the Commission should concentrate on those are-
as with “the most direct link to the stability of EMU”, mean-
ing “primarily the EDP” (excessive debt procedure) (Finland
2015a: 3). Here, they call for strict application of rules by the
EU level, and (where necessary) sanctions against states. This
contrasts to other policy areas prioritised in the systemic per-
spective of the fiscal union camp: The Macroeconomic Imbal-
ance Procedure for example, the Finnish contribution argues,
is a policy area “where the link with EMU stability is more
distant and where competence remains clearly at the nation-
al level” (ibid.). Accordingly, economic policy coordination in
this area should “rely mainly on peer pressure, best practices
and open exchange of views, rather than on sanctions” (ibid.).
From the perspective of a stability union, no further integra-
tion or firmer implementation is called for, because the im-
balances are regarded primarily as the consequence of poor
policies in individual states. Here, in fact, the procedure is
explicitly reinterpreted as another vehicle for structural re-
forms and alienated from its purpose of restricting current
account imbalances: “The MIP should not be about coercion
but primarily about building political support and ownership
for structural reform in Member States” (ibid.). Here again,
the observed imbalances are treated as the result of struc-
tural policy neglect and in no sense as the outcome of in-
complete integration of a currency area with free flows of
capital. In this context, the institutional changes to the ESM
that have already been implemented are regarded as a stop-
gap required after individual national governments ignored
the agreed rules on fiscal policy. The Finnish contribution
clearly demands: “In the medium and longer term, we should
return to the full respect of the no bail-out rule” (Finland
2015 b: 3).
Consistently, absolutely no common fiscal capacity is pro-
posed for the Eurozone. The contribution argues instead that
collective spending would be unnecessary if national fiscal
policy obeyed the rules. Instead, such a fiscal capacity is in-
terpreted as an instrument for transfers and joint liability be-
tween states with inadequate real and nominal convergence
– which the Finns reject: “As long as the Member States are
as heterogeneous as they are today, creation of a possible
fiscal capacity would in effect entail a transfer union and ex-
pand joint liability. Therefore considering a fiscal capacity is
not realistic before a much closer economic convergence
among the Member States has been achieved, including of
debt levels” (ibid.). As a mechanism for cushioning asymmet-
ric shocks, the Finnish contribution argues, a fully-functioning
Banking Union would anyway be “much more effective” (ibid.).
Nor does a fiscal capacity make sense as a mechanism for
incentivising structural reforms, as one does not require com-
pensation for reforms that are “beneficial as such” (ibid.). While
the lack of implementation of recommended structural reforms
by the nation states is recognised as one of the “real prob-
lems”, it is attributed to lack of ownership on the part of the
governments and parliaments and thus potentially address-
able through better involvement of the national parliaments
in the European Semester (Finland 2015a: 2). So here too,
poor national policies – in the guise of inadequate implemen-
tation of painful but necessary austerity measures and struc-
tural reforms – are understood as the cause of the manifes-
tations of crisis.
According to the Finnish contribution, a closer political
union at EMU level is therefore not necessary either; given
that political responsibility for economic policy is sited at the
na
tional level, “political legitimacy and accountability of eco-
nomic policy-making is best secured at national level through
national parliaments” (Finland 2015b: 3). Finland pithily states
the declared goal of the stability union: “The aim should be
an EMU where market pressure works in a predictable man-
ner to support fiscal discipline and structural reform” (ibid.).
4.2.2 ESTONIA
The Estonian contribution is also clearly committed to a sta-
bility union and pursues a similar line of argument. Great
emphasis is placed on implementation and reinforcement of
existing rules, especially in the fiscal realm: “Most importantly
the Commission should use its full powers to assess the budg-
etary plans and to make recommendations proportional to
the imbalances and risks involved. Flexibility must stay firmly
within the agreed framework of the Stability and Growth
Pact” (Estonia 2015: 2). The Estonian contribution also identi-
fies poor national policies as problematic, and is therefore
open to the proposed “contractual agreements”. These repre-
sent binding agreements on structural reforms between the
Commission and individual member states and are intended
to accelerate the pace of implementation of reform recom-
mendations. Estonia argues that such agreements could lead
to greater ownership and better coordination of policy (ibid.).
A fiscal capacity, on the other hand, is regarded consid-
erably more critically – neither to fund reforms nor to address
asymmetric shocks. In both cases the Estonian contribution
warns against “mechanisms of transfer” that involve “moral
hazard” (ibid.). For shock management, Estonia instead pro-
poses a national reserve fund system, through which each
member state could insure itself against crises. Estonia there-
fore consistently rejects any kind of joint debt management:
“Neither the current situation in the Member States nor
22
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
the level of integration provide for a stable environment for
common risk sharing, such as, but not limited to common
bond issuance” (ibid.: 3).
4.2.3 LITHUANIA
Lithuania’s positions also lie clearly within the stability union
camp. Its negotiators emphasise that the existing fiscal frame-
work is “properly designed”; the problem, they say, is “a lack
of political will” for implementation (Lithuania 2015: 2). On
economic policy coordination, the contribution also argues
that agreed reforms to “improve adjustment capacity” need
to be implemented more fully and possibly more closely moni-
tored by the Commission. This perspective is grounded in a
classical stability union analysis of the situation: “The current
situation showed that if Member States are not implement-
ing structural reforms and sound fiscal policy at national level,
monetary policy alone is not sufficient for reviving the [Euro
Area] economy” (ibid.: 3).
As in the contributions already discussed, Lithuania rejects
a common fiscal capacity; one must “take into account that
tax policies belong to national competence” and that the re-
forms “are beneficial for Member States”, making financial
incentives superfluous (ibid.: 4). Here too, a coherent theory
of poor national policies leading to crisis clearly predominates.
If only the respective fiscal and structural policies were cor-
rected, the crisis could be overcome.
Correspondingly, no further reforms (such as establishing
a European deposit guarantee scheme) are proposed for the
Banking Union either. Instead implementation of the existing,
less collective arrangements is emphasised: “Therefore, prima-
ry focus now should be on final implementation of the Bank-
ing Union. Only then it will be possible to make final evalu-
ation of the effectiveness of the reform and its input in re-
ducing the fiscal-financial nexus” (ibid.: 3).
Stronger democratic institutions at supranational level are
not proposed either; instead consultation of and coordina-
tion between national parliaments should be strengthened.
4.2.4 GERMANY
The specific analytical take of the stability camp is also clear-
ly reflected in the German contribution, although rather less
sweepingly. Particular weight is placed on the interpretation
of the crisis as a “‘competitiveness crisis’ because Euro area
Member States hadn’t sufficiently used the ‘boom period’ to
tackle existing structural weaknesses” (Germany 2015: 3). At
a more granular level, the contribution refers specifically to
the “very important” aspect of “‘nominal and real rigidities in
product and labour markets’ predating the crisis and pre-
venting the efficient allocation of resources” (ibid.).
Even if there is otherwise less detailed discussion of the
opposing options, the stability union perspective dominates.
The lack of structural reforms to create “flexibility” in product
and labour markets is regarded as the central cause of crisis
and the most important hurdle on the path to recovery in
the Eurozone.
But as a whole, Berlin takes a restrained approach in its
contribution to the Five Presidents’ Report and in fact tends
to constrain the process by emphasising that the Sherpa
process should not overstep its mandate: Efforts to deal with
the crisis at national and European level “cannot be the prime
concern of this Sherpa process. As for the relevant European
projects they can and should be left to the normal fora and
procedures” (ibid.). The German contribution questions the
Commission’s stated goal for the entire process and calls for
the process to concentrate “on the medium-term perspec-
tive of reinforcing EMU architecture, namely through stronger
economic policy coordination” (ibid.). Here it is conspicuous
that an attempt is being made to steer the discussion away
from exploration of potential new instruments and institu-
tions and instead to centre it on the sphere of reinforcing
implementation and coordination of national policies. This
can again be interpreted as an argument for the stability
un
ion, seeking to minimise supranational governance and
integration and restrict action to stronger control of nation
al
economic policy guided by a (largely implicit) stability par-
a
digm.
In addition to their individual contributions, Germany and
France later also published a joint paper laying out the policy
areas in which progress needs to be achieved. Although the
language here is less definite than in other contributions, it
points the way to a compromise that – like the German con-
tribution – leans more towards the stability camp.
In particular, it is noticeable that it does not call for sig-
nificant institutional shifts towards a fiscal union. It addresses
at length the implementation and prioritisation of the country-
specific recommendations in the European Semester. This is
followed by a listing of possible measures “to promote the
real convergence of the economies and the resilience of the
Eurozone” (translated from Germany/France 2015: 3). But
these
are mostly aspects affecting the Single Market. Apart from
implementing the Banking Union and the Capital Markets
Union, a call for a common tax base in Europe, and the intro-
duction of nationally defined minimum wages, no EMU-wide
initiatives are mentioned. Thus, for example, there is no place
for joint debt management or a fiscal capacity.
Only in the field of democratic legitimation does the doc-
ument call for reforms at the Eurozone level, such as the pos-
sibility of a Eurozone chamber in the European Parliament
or strengthening the role of the President of the Eurogroup.
Nonetheless, the stability union remains the principal point of
reference, and national economic responsibility is writ large:
“At the same time, democratic control, legitimacy and re-
sponsibility must be ensured at the national level” (ibid.: 4).
4.2.5 MALTA
Malta also argues, in line with the stability vision, that the cri-
sis and its resolution do not originate in systemic causes as-
sociated with the incomplete nature of the Monetary Union.
Instead Malta also places the focus on “[s]tructural reforms
which increase the return on investment” (Malta 2015b: 2) in the
interests of improving national competitiveness. Consistently,
the Maltese contribution also concludes that “the positive re-
sults brought about by structural reforms should themselves
act as an incentive” (ibid.: 3), because for example competitive-
ness increases productivity. The Maltese negotiators note that
many reforms have already been initiated, and argue against
further changes in the governance framework, especially with
23
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
respect to convergence: “[W]e do not see the need for the
introduction of new rules on economic and fiscal govern-
ance and certainly not of rules that would be prescriptive
in nature and ignore the inherent differences in Member
States which cannot be converged” (Malta 2015a: 1).
Nor does Malta see any need or treaty basis for further
fiscal integration within the Eurozone: “We are in principle
against any form of additional fiscal capacity for the Euro
Area other than that already provided by the EU budget”
(Malta 2015b: 3). Malta believes that the “existing instruments”
in the form of the ESM, together with the ECB’s motto to “do
whatever it takes”, are sufficient to provide the shock-absorp-
tion that a Monetary Union needs (ibid.). And Malta explicitly
addresses its rejection of any form of reforms requiring joint
institutional solutions to the other camp: “At this juncture Mal-
ta does not subscribe to any proposals that would lead to a
fiscal union” (ibid.: 4).
4.2.6 NETHERLANDS
The Dutch contribution can also be assigned to the stability
camp. It argues very explicitly that the member states should
not wait for initiatives or policies from the European level, but
should instead “take responsibility and do their part now”
(Netherlands 2015a: 2). All the member states, it argues, should
modernise their economies, deepen the Single Market and
reform their administration along the lines of a proposed
“Better Governance Agenda”.
5
The Netherlands sees the main
remedy for overcoming the crisis in “modern economies”
that need to be “strong and flexible” in order to achieve
growth, real convergence and resilience to shocks (ibid.).
The problem, the contribution argues, is currently that: “Struc-
tural reforms are too often shunned and Member States’ track
record of implementing country-specific recommendations
is poor” (ibid.).
New rules and institutions for achieving the desired na-
tional policies are not necessary: “As long as the full capacity
of existing rules is not being used, new rules will not help
us. […] Proper implementation of recommendations and ex-
isting agreements is the solution to many of our problems”
(ibid.). Towards the end, the contribution becomes even clear-
er and clearly rejects any further integration steps for the fore-
seeable future: “Addressing questions in the realm of further
risk sharing, new competences or institutions in the Four
Presidents’ Report is premature” (ibid.: 4).
4.2.7 DENMARK
Among the group of EU countries with their own currency,
the focus on a stability union is especially strong in the Dan-
ish contribution:
“It is the view of Denmark that the current governance
framework, including the new rules – if fully implemented –
is sufficient to address the challenges mentioned in the
5 This “Better Governance Agenda” is described in greater detail in a
second Dutch contribution (Netherlands 2015b). As its content diverges
from the rest of the debate, we restrict the discussion here to the first
contribution.
analytical note. The long run prosperity of the euro area and
the EU depends on Member States’ structural reforms that
are in turn supported by the current governance framework”
(Denmark 2015: 3). Further steps towards a fiscal union are
neither proposed nor felt to be necessary, because Denmark
takes the view that “the EMU will be able to function well
within the framework of the new and improved rules, pro-
vided they are fully implemented and enforced” (ibid.: 5).
The analytical perspective of the stability union is clear
here: “rule compliance” is central to mastering the challenges
of the EMU. New instruments like joint debt management or
a fiscal capacity would not, it is argued, address the problem
of compliance and are therefore superfluous. Moreover, they
are positively undesirable for Denmark on account of moral
hazard in relation to structural reforms (ibid.: 4).
4.2.8 ROMANIA
Romania can also be considered as part of the stability camp,
although less explicitly than the countries discussed above.
The Romanian negotiators emphasise the importance of
implementing and to an extent simplifying the existing rules
and do not mention further institutional reforms. Like others,
the Romanian government underlines the responsibility of all
member states for structural reforms: “Sustained responsibili-
ty from all Member States it vital for ensuring a sound fiscal
and economic position which will lead to an increased level
of trust within EU Member States and to more resilience to
shocks in the EU economy” (Romania 2015: 1). Competitive-
ness, as a central goal of the EU, is defined as the desired
focus of the EMU institutions, without any necessity for fur-
ther institutional changes.
Romania emphasises: “While acknowledging that impor-
tant challenges remain with respect to the shock-resilience
of the Euro area, we deem more efficient, at least on a short
and medium term, to focus on the full implementation, both
at EU and national level of the already consolidated mecha-
nisms within the governance framework” (ibid.: 3). The con-
tribution also notes that the EU as a whole possesses “suffi-
cient instruments” (ibid.).
4.2.9 HUNGARY
Finally Hungary, like Romania, can also be assigned to the
stability camp. The Hungarian government has repeatedly
underlined its commitment to the existing focus on pro-
competitive reforms in the member states: “The most im-
portant objective of structural reforms in my understand-
ing is to enhance competitiveness. The ultimate objective of
the structural reforms is to enhance competitiveness in glob-
al terms and that implies competition also within the EU”
(Hungary 2015b: 2). Budapest itself is “firmly committed to
continue the policy of growth enhancing structural reforms,
investment and fiscal discipline” (Hungary 2015a: 2).
Neither analysis of the crisis nor its attitude towards fur-
ther institutional steps feature in any great depth in the two
submitted Hungarian contributions, but the focus on national
competitiveness and on implementation and enforcement of
existing stability-driven reforms clearly illustrate its leanings
to
wards that camp.
24
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
4.3 INTERIM SUMMARY ON THE STABILITY
UNION
Summarising the contributions presented above, it can be
said that the Eurozone states Finland, Estonia, Lithuania, Ger-
many, Malta and the Netherlands clearly belong to the sta-
bility union camp. They all emphasise that the causes of the
euro crisis lie in what they see as poor policies of individual
states, and correspondingly demand reforms to correct these
errors. From this perspective, further-reaching integration
steps are not necessary (and frequently not desirable), apart
from demands in certain quarters for the Commission to
be given stronger powers to monitor and sanction national
economic decisions.
These six states represent the ideological base of the
stability union, and are united by their conviction that the
uppermost priority is to prevent the introduction of transfers
to poorer or less “reform-oriented” states. The latter applies
especially to Estonia and Lithuania, both of which have ex-
perienced painful austerity programmes under the existing
stability arrangements, and therefore may tend to see other
countries’ problems as resulting from inadequate implemen-
tation of reforms. One interpretation could be that in Finland,
the Netherlands and Germany right-wing populist parties
represent a direct threat to the established political spectrum,
which frequently finds itself accused of failing to pursue na-
tional interests sufficiently in the European context. This has
the effect of increasing the determination of these states to
defend their own domestic tax revenues.
The joint Franco-German paper hints at a compromise,
but is conspicuous for its absence of any further-reaching
steps towards a fiscal union. With its focus on the implemen-
tation of existing measures and the strengthening of struc-
tural reforms directed towards competitiveness, the contri-
bution must therefore also be assigned to the stability union
camp. The paper does play a special role in the debate be-
tween the two camps over the vision for the future of the
EMU, to the extent that the position expressed in Germany’s
own contribution is also the one represented in the joint
document with France: an exclusive focus on implementation
with only minimal changes to existing frameworks, and the
conspicuous absence of further integration steps or comple-
mentary reforms leading towards the systemic perspective
of a fiscal union. As the analysis of France’s own contribution
shows (see chapter 4.4), this represents a compromise in fa-
vour of the German position and omits aspects and propos-
als that France otherwise regards as important and that tend
more clearly towards a fiscal union.
Among the non-euro states, Denmark’s position in par-
ticular can be clearly assigned to the stability camp. Romania
and Hungary adopt less explicit and less detailed positions,
but also lean towards the stability vision. The explanations
for this second group of states are similar to those for the
core
group around Finland, although the non-euro status of Hun-
gary and Romania may mean that the debate is less urgent
there and the positions are less explicit.
Altogether, substantial similarities can be identified among
the nine states in the stability camp. Almost all of them de-
mand implementation of agreed structural reforms be given
priority or even be stepped up. Estonia proposes binding
contractual arrangements for these reforms to intensify im-
plementation and ownership. Beyond this, Finland, Estonia
and Lithuania call for strict application of the EMU’s deficit
and debt rules and demand that the associated sanctions
not be watered down.
It is noteworthy that – as was to be expected – this group
otherwise makes no central demands. The reformed Mone-
tary Union with its present focus on fiscal rules and rule-based,
more strictly controlled national structural policies is largely
welcomed and regarded as adequate to overcome the crisis
and prevent new fragilities. All the states in this group demand
full implementation of and compliance with the adopted re-
forms. If at all, criticism is directed at inadequate implemen-
tation of rules and recommended national reforms. Certain
member states wish to address this problem that through
stronger sanctions and stricter application of the rules.
Aside from these demands, which are largely restricted
to two aspects, this camp’s contributions are characterised
by dismissal of further integration in other areas. Rejection
of fiscal integration and a corresponding capacity at Euro-
pean or Eurozone level is a central point for almost all of them.
Lithuania, Malta, the Netherlands and – more obliquely – also
Denmark and Germany reject this absolutely. Finland regards
it as ineffective and unnecessary and sees a chance of it oc-
curring – if at all – only following significant convergence of
the member states, while Estonia tends to argue for the alter-
native of national fiscal shock absorbers.
This camp also rejects any form of mutualisation of debt
management in the Monetary Union. Finland goes furthest,
demanding reinstatement of the no-bailout rule in the medium
term (which would mean dissolution of the ESM), whereas
Malta and the Netherlands are satisfied with the current
shape of the bailout fund but see absolutely no need to de-
velop or strengthen it. Eurobonds and similar instruments are
not discussed at all in some contributions, and are rejected
by Estonia, the Netherlands and – if only indirectly – by Den-
mark and Germany.
The stability union group also rejects any further transfer
of responsibilities through closer coordination of economic
policies or the inclusion of new areas of potential systemic
relevance. Finland, the Netherlands, Denmark are Germany
are happy with the present arrangements for the European
Semester and resist greater institutionalisation of the Macro-
economic Imbalance Procedure at supranational level (as al-
ready exists for the stability and convergence criteria of the
Stability and Growth Pact).
As far as the Banking Union is concerned, it is only men-
tioned at all in a handful of contributions; its present arrange-
ments are apparently taken as given and regarded as ade-
quate. Lithuania discusses the aspect of a European deposit
guarantee scheme as part of the Banking Union – but rejects
it entirely in line with a stability union vision.
Finally, and in a sense logically on the basis of their limit-
ed demands, almost none of these countries argues for any
form of supranational democratic legitimisation for the Mon-
etary Union. Finland, Lithuania and Germany emphasise the
national parliaments as the proper forums for reforms – which
they regard as national responsibilities. Closer integration of
the national parliaments, for example in the European Semes-
ter, would therefore be welcomed. The German and in par-
25
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
ticular the Franco-German contribution go further in parts,
discussing stronger inclusion of the European Parliament (or
a conceivable Eurozone chamber within it) and an expansion
of the role of the Eurogroup President.
It is also worth mentioning that many aspects and pro-
posals – some of which have been circulating for years – are
not discussed at all by the stability union group. Germany in
particular pursues this strategy and concentrates on procedur-
al aspects and generalities. More widely, for example joint
debt management is similarly only mentioned at all by three
of the countries, the Banking Union and social aspects are
found in only a handful of the contributions, and fields of pos-
sible economic policy coordination, such as wage policy, are
completely omitted. As already mentioned, this is partly a
consequence of the underlying theoretical and ideological
perspective. It remains unclear to what extent this is also em-
ployed as a tactic to prevent certain issues appearing on the
agenda in the first place.
It is notable that – behind this camp’s apparent unity – dis-
tinguishing between long-term and short-term reform options
rather alters the picture. Thus the joint Franco-German con-
tribution explicitly discusses only short-term measures, in as-
sociation with reference to a more comprehensive paper on
longer-term reforms that the two countries intended to pub-
lish at the end of 2016 (but have so far failed to do). So even
if the general thrust and priorities appear set, in the longer
term – depending on the orientation of this as yet unwritten
document and national elections in both countries in 2017 –
there might actually be greater openness to further integra-
tion steps.
4.4 THE FISCAL UNION CAMP
In the following we now move on to present the reform ideas
of the countries seeking a fiscal union. As already outlined,
we
can divide this camp into a main group and a sub-group:
supporters of an unrestricted fiscal union and supporters of
a restricted version. We begin by presenting the countries
with the most ambitious proposals for change, proposing
that both the present system of economic governance and
elements of fiscal integration need to be reformed in order
to overcome the Eurozone’s susceptibility to crisis. While the
countries supporting this position do not deny the validity of
prior reforms of the EMU with their focus on budgetary sur-
veillance and structural reforms, they leave no doubt that a
deepening of integration is now needed: one that also
pro-
vides transnational liability options and understands economic
policy coordination as a systemic responsibility for the pres-
ervation of the currency area, rather than merely using it
to enforce pro-competitive structural reforms in the crisis
states.
Countries in the sub-group, on the other hand, are only
partly committed to the goal of a fiscal union: they either ap-
prove of fiscal integration of the Eurozone but regard the pres-
ent economic governance as adequate or, conversely, are
dissatisfied with economic coordination based on budget rules
and pro-competitive structural reforms (and wish to see
change
there) but reject the fiscal perspective of shared liability op-
tions. In other words, the countries in the sub-group seek
change in just one of the two areas – even if the concrete
instruments and institutions they propose (and the associat-
ed timeframes and preconditions) certainly vary from state
to state.
4.4.1 SUPPORTERS OF A FISCAL UNION
WITHOUT RESTRICTIONS
4.4.1.1 I t a l y
In the Sherpa process Italy was the most determined advo-
cate of comprehensive fiscal union. It regards the steps al-
ready taken towards a Banking Union as inadequate to break
the vicious circle of bank and state debt, and believes it nec-
essary to complete it by establishing a common fiscal back-
stop mechanism and a European deposit protection. Although
Italy sees the Capital Markets Union project already offering
a possibility to distribute adjustment to economic shocks
better across the Eurozone, because an integrated capital
market would better distribute risks (Italy 2015b: 5), its con-
tributions make it clear that this is not regarded as sufficient.
In order to protect the Monetary Union against future crises,
the Italian government believes that much further-reaching
measures are vital: collective borrowing through Eurozone
bonds (Italy 2015a: 3f.) and a fiscal capacity. Gradual imple-
mentation is recommended. In the longer term a separate
Eurozone budget is proposed, to facilitate an anti-cyclical
buffer function. In this connection the question of new own
revenue sources for the EU and/or the EMU would then have
to be discussed. In the shorter term (and according to the
Italian government possible without a treaty revision) a Euro-
pean unemployment insurance scheme is proposed as an
automatic stabiliser to cushion asymmetric shocks affecting
Eurozone countries: “A European unemployment benefit
scheme would serve as a EU automatic stabilizer, help mod-
erate the economic cycle, tackle asymmetric shock, address
distributive issues” (ibid.: 2). In particular because the EMU
seeks (to intensify) an economic convergence process, Italy
would like to see the European unemployment insurance im-
plemented rapidly as the first manifestation of a fiscal capac-
ity for supporting convergence efforts: “It would therefore
not be coherent to postpone risk-sharing at the conclusion
of the convergence process” (Italy 2015b: 4).
The Italian negotiators heavily criticise the asymmetry of
European economic governance and call for the European Se-
mester to be developed into a governance instrument with
an investment function to reduce imbalances: “Persisting wide
imbalances are incompatible with an economic union. The
governance structure should facilitate a cooperative rebalanc-
ing within the economic area, lacking which adjustment will
remain highly asymmetric” (ibid.: 3). The proposal is for the
European Semester to introduce a “policy mix” enabling a
dis-
tinction to be drawn between short-term needs and me
dium-
term shared political challenges. As well as the member
states,
demands for action should also be addressed to the EU itself
(ibid.: 4). In the longer term, the ESM should serve as a Euro-
pean Monetary Fund for funding investment projects.
Preserving the European social model is central to Italy’s
demands for a social dimension in the Monetary Union. Its con-
tributions warn of growing social stress caused by the crisis
26
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
management it criticises. Rome makes no bones that the trans-
formation of European policy from a subjective threat to so-
cial security into a bulwark of protection represents a key
precondition for all further integration steps. It calls for a focus
on the social costs of the Euro crisis and a social component
to Union citizenship. Here, Italy argues, the European unem-
ployment insurance scheme could serve as “concrete proof of
EU solidarity” (Italy 2015a: 2). The European Youth Guarantee
and the Employment Initiative also need to be strengthened,
it believes, in order to prevent the emergence of a “lost gen-
eration”. The member states’ tax systems also need to become
coherent in order to prevent a race to the bottom.
Italy believes that a political union is required in order to
lend democratic legitimacy to the already implemented gov-
ernance framework of the EMU. The call for better integra-
tion of the European Parliament and the national parliaments
in the European Semester is therefore central. The democrat-
ic
responsibility for further-reaching proposals, such as fiscal
capacity and Eurobonds, should also be located at the Euro-
pean level (ibid.: 4). Italy argues for the Community method
to be used for further reforms and as such implicitly rejects
the intergovernmental agreements (outside the EU treaties)
that have sometimes been employed. Because at the same
time many of the proposed policies would not find the agree-
ment or interest of all the EU member states, the Italian gov-
ernment calls for greater use of enhanced cooperation by the
nineteen Euro states, in order to advance coordination of
fis-
cal policies (Italy 2015b: 8).
4.4.1.2 Spain
Spain is also a supporter of fiscal union and presented similar
arguments like Italy in the Sherpa process. It would like to see
the Banking Union rapidly completed with elements of trans-
national liability and the establishment of a limited fiscal ca-
pacity, initially funded through EU own resources. This would
promote the convergence process within the EMU: “[T]he lim-
ited fiscal capacity could be enhanced to create a true Fiscal
Union encompassing the three central elements (1) transfer
of sovereignty on revenue and expenditure policies to the
European level; (2) a common Eurozone budget; (3) common
debt instruments” (Spain 2015b: 8).
Like Italy, Spain is dissatisfied with the scope of the cur-
rent governance framework and its focus on budgetary as-
pects: “The paradox has been that fiscal criteria have been
monitored after the creation of the single currency through
the Stability and Growth Pact, while no similar treatment
has been given to nominal convergence in inflation criteria”
(ibid.: 4). Madrid
complains that identified imbalances are
inadequately ad
dressed and calls for a simplification of the
Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure by concentrating on
current account bal
ances, real effective exchange rates, unit
labour costs and
inflation rates. Budgetary indicators, it says,
are already adequately covered by the Stability and Growth
Pact. In relation to surveillance of member states’ budgets,
Spain calls for the introduction of a golden rule for invest-
ment, to permit temporary deviations from the adjustment
path of the Stability and Growth Pact. The ESM should be
used to finance or guarantee such infrastructure projects
(Spain 2015a: 4). Internal spill
over effects of structural poli-
cies and impacts on the Euro
zone’s external current account
should also be taken into consideration. Spain’s most radical
demand – unique in the submitted reports – is to amend
the statute of the ECB to require
it to take account of differ-
ences in the real inflation rates of
the member states as well
as Eurozone price stability in its monetary policy (ibid.: 3f.).
The Spanish contributions also speak of preventing profit-
shifting and tax avoidance. Furthermore, alongside the afore-
mentioned fiscal aspects, the European level should also be
granted additional powers in labour and employment policy:
“All competences related to labour mobility should be trans-
fered to the European level, including, for example, matters
related to social security, unemployment insurance, or pro-
fessional qualifications” (Spain 2015b: 8).
Spain also calls for better integration of the European Par
lia-
ment in the EU’s governance framework and argues for
deep-
er integration among the nineteen Eurozone members. In the
long term, Spain would like to see the creation of a finance
minister post for the Eurozone, who would be responsible for
a fiscal capacity and appointed jointly by the European Par-
liament and the national parliaments. Ultimately he or she
should receive the power to sanction nation states (ibid.: 7f.).
4.4.1.3 Portugal
Portugal’s contributions also put it clearly in the fiscal union
camp. On both the Banking Union and deeper fiscal integra-
tion, Portugal argues for transnational risk-sharing. Lisbon ar-
gues for the establishment of a fiscal capacity which is fund-
ed through EU own resources and financially neutral for the
member states. Portugal recommends the European Commis-
sion, when considering own resources and the burdens to be
borne by the member states, take into account “the different
degree to which different social/economic groups benefit from
European integration and, particularly, the single currency”
(Portugal 2015b: 7). Portugal clearly rejects the belief that the
deficits of the Eurozone architecture can be eliminated in the
medium term solely through structural reforms and deepen-
ing of the Single Market. Portugal’s contribution airs the idea
of turning the ESM into a European Monetary Fund (Portugal
2015a: 2f.), which could be expanded into a European “Mon-
etary and Fiscal Fund” by introducing a European unemploy-
ment insurance scheme (Portugal 2015b: 6). While critical of
the inadequate capacity of the EMU to absorb asymmetric
shocks, Portugal does not see a fiscal insurance mechanism
as the path to greater convergence, but conversely calls for
“a greater degree of harmonization between economic poli-
cies and institutions of the participating Member States” as
its precondition (ibid.).
Here Portugal departs from Italy’s and Spain’s ideas of
rapid implementation of a fiscal capacity. But in relation to
their criticisms of economic policy coordination and ideas for
reforming it, Lisbon remain on the side of Rome and Madrid.
Portugal also believes that coordination of economic policies
must not stop at fixed rules for national budgets, but must
have as its objective an aggregated and proactive fiscal poli-
cy for the euro area: “[...S]ince we acknowledge that fiscal co-
ordination is a requirement to avoid negative spillovers from
bad national decisions, we must conclude that fiscal coordi-
nation is also required to explore positive
spillovers” (ibid.: 4).
27
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
Characteristically for a proponent of fiscal union, Portugal
does not fear the prospect of transferring powers to the Euro-
pean level, but sees this as a necessary requirement of grow-
ing European responsibilities. The establishment of a fiscal
capacity is thus justified not exclusively in terms of economic
rationality for a smoother-functioning EMU, but also political-
ly, in order to avoid the kind of ad hoc transfers required in
the most recent crisis because these have always encouraged
intergovernmental negotiations operating outside the Com-
munity method (Portugal 2015a: 3). Like Italy and Spain, the
Portuguese government would like to massively strengthen
the Eurogroup through a European Monetary Fund with
ex-
panded fiscal capacity in order to create a united fiscal
coun-
terpole to the ECB’s monetary policy (Portugal 2015b: 7f.).
4.4.1.4 Belgium
Belgium supports the course of the three proponents of a fis-
cal union already outlined. In its contribution Belgium also
calls for completion of the Banking Union and argues for the
establishment of a fiscal capacity and an only vaguely de-
scribed European “treasury function”. On implementation,
Belgium concurs with Portugal and sees both instruments as
plausible objectives only after a real economic and social con-
vergence process of unstated magnitude: “When all Mem-
ber States are on a proven and determined path towards the
Pact for Stability and Growth’s debt reference value, and the
necessary degree of economic, social and fiscal convergence
has been achieved, a fiscal capacity and a treasury function
for the euro area could be envisaged” (Belgium 2015: 2).
Belgium also calls for sweeping changes in economic
governance, proposing a longer-term policy coordination
mechanism (as already mentioned as ex-ante-coordination in
Article 11 of the Fiscal Compact) (ibid.: 1). Belgium is the only
state in the fiscal union camp to call for the introduction of
the Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB) – in
first place under the keyword “tax convergence” – in order to
fight tax erosion and profit-shifting.
Belgium places high priority on the social dimension of
the EMU and calls for the objective of social convergence to
be promoted specifically by fighting social dumping, through
measures including a “social impact assessment” of the struc-
tural reforms, higher common social standards and the mod-
ernisation of the national labour markets and social security
systems (ibid.: 2).
The Belgian contribution openly admits that the planned
integration steps to create a fully-fledged banking, fiscal and
economic union naturally require parallel steps towards a po-
litical union, which means shared sovereignty (ibid.: 3). One
first step could be to improve the integration of the social
partners in the European Semester, for which concretely a
social
dialogue on the annual growth
survey is
proposed.
Belgium criticises the intergovernmental agreements that have
become common
practice in crisis
management (2015: 3).
ESM, Fiscal Compact and the Single Resolution Fund (SRF), it
argues, need to be quickly integrated into EU law; intergov-
ernmental agreements can only be temporary stopgaps. In-
stead Belgium calls for the powers of the Interparliamentary
Conference under Article 13 of the Fiscal Compact to be ex-
panded beyond the fiscal policy aspects laid out there.
4.4.1.5 Luxembourg
Luxembourg is also clearly among the supporters of a fiscal
union. On the question of the Banking Union it goes even fur-
ther than the demands outlined above and calls for expedit-
ed establishment of the SRF for banks, which is not currently
planned to be fully functional until 2024. Luxembourg is also
the only country to share Italy’s euphoria over the benefits
of the Capital Markets Union, asserting that it is the central
instrument for improving EMU’s capacity to absorb shocks:
“To improve the shock absorption capacity in the euro area
and beyond, the creation of the Capital markets union must
be a priority” (Luxembourg 2015: 7). Nonetheless, in the long
term Luxembourg sees the necessity for a real fiscal capaci-
ty with European own resources, and also for joint debt man-
agement.
Luxembourg largely shares the criticisms of the European
Semester, but focuses its reform proposals less on the Euro-
pean level, calling instead for implementation at national lev-
el. Thus in future the Commission should report regularly on
progress implementing the Country-specific Recommenda-
tions (CSRs). Here Luxembourg borrows from the stability un-
ion camp, reminding them of the contractual arrangements
that Germany introduced into the reform debate in 2012/13:
“To further incentivize structural reforms, the use of contrac-
tual arrangements as discussed in the recent past could be
an option” (ibid.: 8). At the same time, however, unlike the
proponents of the stability union, Luxembourg emphasises
that the Stability and Growth Pact alone cannot form the basis
for reform recommendations. It is as important, it argues, to
make full use of the MIP, whose corrective arm has not to
date
been applied – to the detriment of the credibility of the gov-
ernance architecture.
This perspective is also clearly visible in Luxembourg’s
position on the social dimension as a firm component of EMU
governance: “Member states could eventually be asked to
make adjustments to their national policies to mitigate to
the extent possible negative social consequences without
jeopardizing fiscal consolidation and growth-friendly struc-
tural reforms” (ibid.). Like Belgium, Luxembourg also calls for
stronger integration of the social partners in the European Se-
mester, and also argues for the European Parliament to be
granted a greater say there.
4.4.1.6 Slovenia
Among the Central and Eastern European states, Slovenia is
the most vociferous advocate of fiscal integration for the EMU.
Its contribution argues for the longer-term development of
a transnational risk-sharing mechanism as a central feature
moving towards a fiscal union (Slovenia 2015: 2). It argues
that a fiscal capacity is required to absorb asymmetric shocks,
even if this would open up as yet unclarified questions con-
cerning own resources for the EU and shared debt manage-
ment (ibid.: 4).
That said, the Slovenian position on reforms of the EMU’s
economic governance structure is considerably more moder-
ate than those of the countries already discussed. Slovenia is
happy with the existing European economic governance
frame-
work and believes it to be capable of identifying macroeco-
28
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
nomic imbalances in good time. Progress is more needed in
the field of closer fiscal cooperation, and new incentives for
implementing competitiveness reforms could also be consid-
ered. In this connection the new more flexible application of
the Stability Pact is explicitly mentioned (ibid.: 2, 5).
Slovenia speaks of a transfer of national powers to the
European level not only in connection with a fiscal capacity,
but points to potential spill-over processes in other policy
fields resulting from strengthened budgetary surveillance:
“Similarly, a strengthened coordination of economic policies
and stronger surveillance over national budgets could raise
questions regarding the competences in the areas of em-
ployment, social policy, taxation, education or health system”
(ibid.: 4). With every step associated with transferring sover-
eignty to the European level, Slovenia argues, the role of the
national parliaments should be explicitly strengthened to safe-
guard democratic legitimacy (ibid.: 5).
4.4.1.7 Latvia
Latvia also belongs to the fiscal union camp. It remains cau-
tious over a European deposit guarantee scheme under the
Banking Union, but does not reject it (Latvia 2015b: 3). Pro-
posals for joint debt management in the Commission Blue-
print of 2012 also need to be treated “with extreme caution”
(ibid.: 2).
But in the longer perspective the Latvian government clear-
ly calls for the establishment of a fiscal union with its own
fiscal capacity, as already spelled out in the Four Presidents’
Report of 2012, because the EMU is otherwise powerless in
the face of shocks. But the contribution does emphasise the
requirement for “strong preconditions and conditionalit[ies],
including a closer coordination of the national budgets at EU
level” (Latvia 2015a: 2). For Latvia, the EFSI and the Commis-
sion’s flexible interpretation of the Stability Pact already rep-
resent the first steps on the road to fiscal capacity (Latvia
2015b: 2). Like Portugal and Belgium, Latvia sees closer socio-
economic convergence as a precondition for establishing a
fiscal capacity. As well as a strengthening of the European
and national parliaments, Latvia too would like to see the
social partners integrated more closely into the European
Semester.
4.4.1.8 France
France stands recognisably in the camp of supporters of a fis-
cal union, but not as whole-heartedly as those already de-
scribed. What they share in common is first of all their atten-
tion to macroeconomic imbalances and the inadequacy of
European coordination and governance powers as an initial
cause of the crisis, and the stance that reforms to date repre-
sent only a first and insufficient step: “Nevertheless, while the
emphasis on fiscal consolidation in recent years has restored
confidence, it has also resulted in weaker growth. Similarly,
policy coordination has been strengthened, but remains in-
complete and has not led to sufficient growth or economic
and social ‘reconvergence’ within the euro area” (translated
from France 2015: 2).
With respect to the Banking Union, France points out that
the already adopted Single Resolution Mechanism has yet to
enter into force and lists it under the keyword of transnational
“solidarité” (ibid.: 3). All that the later joint Franco-German con-
tribution has to say on this question is that the Banking Union
should be completed “as planned” (translated from Germany/
France 2015: 2).
Paris states very directly that a EMU orientated on faster
and sustainable growth, dynamic investment and employ-
ment cannot function without a convergence process of the
integrated economies. This rests explicitly on social as well
as fiscal policies and represents for the French an indispen-
sable tool for dealing with asymmetric shocks: “This con-
ver
gence is a prerequisite for better resilience to shocks and
preservation of the European social model” (translated from
France 2015: 3). The joint Franco-German contribution also
understands a “real convergence of the Eurozone economies”
to mean “establishing a convergence framework for the as-
sessment bases, in particular for corporate taxation”, as well
as greater transparency and action to combat tax avoidance
(translated from Germany/France 2015: 2). Unlike Italy and
Spain, the French contribution to the Sherpa process remains
very reserved concerning the details of what it regards as
necessary processes of convergence and transnational soli-
darity and merely notes the necessity of examining possible
instruments (France 2015: 3). The French approach is even
more cautious in its second contribution, submitted jointly
with Germany. Here the longer-term reform perspective of the
EMU is bracketed out entirely. The fundamental choice be-
tween stability union and fiscal union is postponed. Thus the
brief joint contribution ends with a call for closer investiga-
tion of “the future needs of the Eurozone” (translated from
Germany/France 2015: 3): “Such an investigation should ex-
amine in particular the political and institutional framework,
the joint instruments and the legal framework that could be
relevant in the longer term” (ibid.). The two governments
promised another joint contribution by the end of 2016 which
however has not been forthcoming to date.
France positions itself more clearly in relation to the exist-
ing economic governance framework. Here Paris joins Rome,
Madrid and Lisbon in calling for further development of the
European Semester, to lead it away from a one-sided focus on
budgetary and competition policies in the individual states. In
future, it argues, the need for public investment should be
identified and – alongside coordination of national policies –
there should also be a response in aggregated form. In its con-
tribution France makes it clear that this means mobilising Eu-
ropean instruments and funding (France 2015: 2).
Even if the French negotiators underline the necessity of
social convergence, their reference to the “European social
model” is not fleshed out. The goal thus remains very gener-
al, and can be shared by Germany, which commits to it in
their joint contribution. So as the complement to greater
competitiveness, both governments emphasise “strengthen-
ing the social basis of the Economic and Monetary Union”.
But in detail the proposals remain unspectacular: supporting
mobility of labour, promoting the introduction of minimum
wages, and intensifying cooperation in active labour market
policy and in the other social security systems (Germany/France
2015: 2). What does, however, become clear is France’s inter-
est in the institutionalisation of a sectoral Eurogroup forma-
tion of the labour and social ministers (2015: 3). This propos-
29
THE DIVIDED EUROZONE
al is also mentioned as an option in the joint contribution
with the German government (Germany/France 2015: 3).
Like Italy, Spain and Latvia, France also calls for better inte-
gration of the European Parliament and the national parlia-
ments in the governance of the Eurozone; as already men-
tioned by Belgium, Luxembourg and Latvia, the social partners
should also be more closely integrated into the European Se-
mester. Only very cautiously does France (2015: 3) float the
idea of improving the efficiency and outcomes of decision-
making processes by holding regular Eurozone summits and
strengthening
the
chair
and external
representation of
the
Eurogroup. In the joint contribution with Germany, France ar-
gues for the establishment of separate Euro structures in the
European Parliament (Germany/France 2015: 3).
4.4.2 SUPPORTERS OF A FISCAL UNION WITH
RESTRICTIONS
4.4.2.1 Cyprus
Cyprus argues only half-heartedly for a fiscal union, because
its government believes that the current governance frame-
work with ESM, Banking Union and budget rules ensures
that
the Eurozone is able to resist economic shocks. But at
the
same time aspects for the future of the Eurozone were
identified “which were related to the problems of the crisis
that still remain to be addressed” (Cyprus 2015: 2). For the
Cypriot government these include for example closer coordi-
nation of economic policies and the deposit protection in the
Banking Union for deposits under €100,000. The establish-
ment of a fiscal union is seen as a possible chance to give the
member states incentives to improve their fulfilment of eco-
nomic policy goals and at the same time to resolve the moral
hazard problem: “Further risk sharing is not warranted at this
stage. [...A] further risk sharing in the fiscal realm between
member states if examined, should of course be viewed in the
context of an appropriate conditionality to address moral haz-
ard problems“ (ibid.: 3).
Cyprus, like Portugal, Belgium and Latvia, demands great-
er socio-economic convergence as a precondition for estab-
lishing a fiscal capacity, understanding this in the first place
as the fulfilment of the targets laid out in the European Se-
mester. But Cyprus is open to new institutional arrangements
for improving democratic legitimation, for example through
better inclusion of the European Parliament and the national
parliaments in the European Semester.
4.4.2.2 Slovakia
Like Cyprus, Slovakia also argues for the EMU to be expand-
ed into a fiscal union, but without initially altering the exist-
ing policy coordination framework. On the one side, the Slovak
government’s contributions read as an urgent call to action
on fiscal integration: “It is our view that the economic and
monetary union cannot continue to exist in the long term
unless fiscal instruments to address asymmetric and pan-
European Shocks become part of the EMU framework”
(Slovakia
2015a: 2). As a concrete instrument against asym-
metric
shocks, Slovakia – like Italy and Portugal – favours a
European unemployment
insurance
scheme. Shocks
affect-
ing
Europe as
a whole should be addressed through a com-
mon investment mechanism – not described in any greater
detail
– whose orientation bears similarities to proposals from
France, Italy, Spain and Portugal for greater European bundling
of investment support (ibid.: 3).
On the other side the EMU’s current governance frame-
work is regarded as adequate. So any broader transnational
liability in the Banking Union extending beyond the compro-
mise already reached is rejected, and full application of all in-
struments available in the European Semester called for. Like
Latvia and Cyprus, Slovakia believes that fulfilment of the ex-
isting rules in the Eurozone must be a precondition for fiscal
capacity. This is also regarded as an opportunity to create a
clear incentive for obeying the rules: “From the point of view
of Slovakia, fiscal and economic discipline, including equal and
transparent application of SGP and MIP, is a necessary condi-
tion for the further deepening of fiscal integration. Conse-
quently, adherence to existing rules [...] could be a criterion
for entry into a fiscal union” (Slovakia 2015b: 2). Alongside
stronger action on macroeconomic imbalances, Slovakia ar-
gues for better integration of the Europe 2020 strategy in the
European Semester.
True to its line on economic questions, however, the Slovak
government supports no specific social policies for the Euro-
zone, because it regards achieving greater economic conver-
gence, potentially also by means of a shock absorber like the
European unemployment insurance scheme, as the best way
to prevent social hardship. Projects like a common minimum
wage or binding social indicators, on the other hand, it be-
lieves, can undermine economic convergence targets (ibid.).
Clear deviations from the positions of the majority of coun-
tries in the camp of supporters of a fiscal union are found in
connection with ideas on political governance. Slovakia de-
cisively opposes separate Euro formats for strengthening fis-
cal integration and insists that all EU states participate in the
decisions. Slovakia also warns against greater involvement of
the European Parliament at the expense of the Council and
the
national
parliaments:
“We
are
cautious
about
further
strengthening the involvement of the European Parliament
as it could come at the expense of the Council or the national
parliaments” (ibid.: 3).
4.4.2.3 Croatia
As a non-euro state among the restricted fiscal union camp,
Croatia criticises what it sees as the still inadequate functionali-
ty of the Banking Union. It is unclear, Croatia asserts, whether
the new collective rules will be capable of breaking the vicious
circle of financial crisis and fiscal instability. It will depend on
the concrete details of the bail-in rules, Croatia argues, whether
they will make a positive contribution or in fact exacerbate the
problem: “However, the question is whether the system will,
due to some of the new elements, become more prone to
crisis” (Croatia 2015: 2). Croatia criticises the EU’s current bud-
get as insufficient to actively counteract asymmetric shocks. In
an ideal world the member states would have to completely
communitise their economic policies, in order to complete the
EMU (ibid.). On the other hand, economic policy coordination
supports the existing strict regulatory approach, but must not be
allowed to ignore national needs for specific flexibilities. Like
30
FRIEDRICH-EBERT-STIFTUNG
many in the stability union camp, however, the Croatian gov-
ernment emphasises the importance of national politics re-
specting the current governance frameworks. Here strength-
ened national “ownership” is required, along with “continuous
rigorous surveillance through the European semester” (ibid.).
4.4.2.4 Poland
Overall, Poland can also be placed in the fiscal union camp,
even though it rejects further integration steps at this junc-
ture: “In Poland’s view it is not necessary to further Europe-
anise fiscal policy ahead of 2019” (Poland 2015a: 6). Instead
Poland argues in the short and medium term for steps that
would generally be associated with the stability union side,
and proposes explicitly voluntary but binding agreements to
implement priority structural reforms between member states
and Commission, of the kind already discussed in 2013 as the
Convergence and Competitiveness Instrument (CCI): “In the
short term in order to strengthen the EU economic govern-
ance, Poland proposes to improve the functioning of the Eu-
ropean Semester and supplement it with a capacity to enter
into the voluntary contracts on the structural reforms be-
tween the Member States and the European Commission”
(ibid.: 3.; the proposals for modifications to the European Se-
mester are discussed in detail in Poland 2015b). As an incen-
tive mechanism, Poland proposes a “a possibility to fully deduct
direct and indirect costs [...] of the agreed reforms when calcu-
lating the deficit” under the Stability and Growth Pact (2015b: 4).
But in contradiction to those stances, Poland proposes
rapid completion of the Banking Union, including “measures
to strengthen fiscal backstop“ (2015a: 5). Thus in contrast to
the stability union camp, Poland does not reject such a fiscal
safety net per se as a transfer and liability union, but regards
it as a necessary component of the Banking Union.
It is also conspicuous that Poland – despite its blunt re-
jection of imminent acute integration leaps – is not only open
to a long-term fiscal integration and regards it as desirable,
but also sees it preceded by a deeper political integration:
“In the long run such an action [Europeanising fiscal policy]
would be desirable provided that […] the level of political in-
tegration is increased and some competences in the area of
economic and fiscal policy are transferred to the European
level” (ibid.: 6). The function of fiscal integration as a shock
absorber is also explicitly emphasised, even if the need for
prior political integration is underlined: “In the long term, the
fiscal integration would also increase the effectiveness of ad-
justment mechanisms to asymmetric shocks in the Eurozone.
However it would require an appropriate deepening of politi-
cal integration” (ibid.). In other words, Poland currently sees
no basis for a fiscal union, but would support it in the longer
term as long as it is accompanied by integration in the politi-
cal and economic realms.
Above and beyond these fundamental views, the Polish
contributions also demonstrate a willingness to discuss con-
crete reform options for a fiscal union and in the longer run
propose a fiscal capacity in the form of a “pan-European in-
vestment programme” (ibid.) as a further development of
the European Fund for Strategic Investments. As the Poles
propose, contributions to this would come from the mem-
ber states and not be included in the fiscal limits of the Fiscal
Compact and the Stability and Growth Pact. The new fund
would be explicitly positioned as an instrument against asym-
metric demand shocks and should be subject to conditionality
in the form of structural reforms: “This programme, primar-
ily addressed to the countries with the largest output gap,
would require that its beneficiaries commit themselves to
implementing structural reforms (conditionality)” (ibid.: 3).
Alongside a fiscal capacity, Poland also regards a new cri-
sis management institution as a longer-term necessity:
“More-
over in the medium term Poland suggests initiating a debate
on the need to establish a crisis management mechanism in
the Eurozone – resembling the Single Resolution Mechanism.
This
mechanism could set up an efficient decision-making
process
for adjustment measures to be implemented by the
troubled
Member State. This would prevent uncontrolled
tensions in
financial markets and limit the spill-over effects”
(ibid.: 4). Here the contribution explicitly addresses the system-
ic level of asymmetric crises in the Eurozone and the collec-
tive necessity to minimise this spill-over.
4.4.2.5 Ireland
Despite its less unequivocal positioning, Ireland basically also
argues for deeper fiscal integration of the Eurozone. Its sub-
mitted contributions point out that the EMU is not an optimal
currency area, for which further Community institutions would
be required (Ireland 2015a: 3). Like many other proponents
of a fiscal union, Ireland would also like to see the Banking
Union completed as quickly as possible. And in the long term
it is correspondingly positive towards a fiscal capacity, al
though
this, it argues, would need to be fiscally neutral over the eco-
nomic cycle, organised through an automatic insurance mech-
anism, strictly conditional, and sufficiently generous if it is to
achieve an economic Impact. However, Ireland rejects tying
successful implementation of structural reforms to access to
the means of a reduced version of a fiscal capacity, in the
way
discussed for example with the Convergence and Competitive-
ness Instrument (CCI) in 2012/13 and now reintroduced into
the debate by Estonia, Luxembourg and Poland. A meaning-
ful fiscal capacity will need to be financially generous, Dub-
lin argues. Ireland also rejects calls for far-reaching automa-
tisation of reform rules through intergovernmental agreements
heard from the stability union side and instead proposes in-
dividual and political scrutiny of structural reforms: “Defining
reform objectives, assessing their likely overall impact, and
measuring progress towards them all require considerable
scope for political judgement and case by case assessment”
(Ireland 2015b: 3).
More clearly than any other state, Ireland addresses the
unequal treatment of current account surpluses and deficits:
“The MIP needs to be implemented in a way which recognis-
es that excessive current account surpluses and deficits both
need to be tackled” (Ireland 2015a: 2). As such it positions it-
self in the field of supporters of a fiscal union. Like Belgium,
Ireland calls for the powers of the interparliamentary confer-
ence under Article 13 of the Fiscal Compact to be expanded,
and for the establishment of separate euro structures in the
European Parliament.