ArticlePDF Available

Investigating firm heterogeneity in country-of-origin cluster location choice decisions

Authors:

Abstract

Purpose This paper aims to analyse which firm-level characteristics drive their location decisions when investing in a foreign country. Focusing on origin clusters, the authors will study the potential influence of the home country context and, in particular, the impact of firm-level factors, both investor- and investment-related, underlying heterogeneity in their location choice decisions. Design/methodology/approach The empirical analysis draws on data gathered from mainland Chinese MNEs that have invested in Germany between 2005 and 2013 (269 firms). The authors chose a single host (Germany) and a single home (China) country for their representativeness and for methodological reasons to control for country effects. The authors used a multinomial logit model to assess the effects of the independent variables on the probability that each of the three location possibilities would be selected. Findings The results suggest that investors preferring co-location in origin clusters have distinct structural and strategic characteristics. From a more structural point of view, Chinese foreign direct investment (FDI) undertaken by smaller firms and those without prior experience in the EU prefer an area where there are other Chinese investors. From a more strategic perspective, these FDI flows are more likely to tap into industry agglomerations when the investors’ objective is strategic asset seeking, and they have less knowledge-intensive investments. Practical implications The findings may be of great practical value to practitioners and policymakers. Knowledge of the advantages and disadvantages of the types of agglomeration networks can help managers to balance the rewards and risks in their decision-making and to select a suitable development path for their FDIs. For policymakers, an understanding of the structure and formation of different groups of firms in one location and the characteristics of investors who may enter the location can help them to improve their regulatory work and to develop policies to attract investments, thereby enhancing local economic development and community stability. Originality/value The research shifts the emphasis of the location choice decision beyond just where to locate toward with whom to collocate. It also contributes to the growing research on emerging market multinationals by providing further insight into understanding of FDI location behavior by firms from emerging economies.
Investigating rm heterogeneity in
country-of-origin cluster location
choice decisions
Francisco Puig
Department of Management, University of Valencia, Valencia, Spain
Anoop Madhok
York University, Toronto, Canada and Rey Juan Carlos University, Madrid, Spain, and
Zhi Shen
CIIE, Xian, China
Abstract
Purpose This paper aims to analyse which rm-level characteristics drive their location decisions when
investing in a foreigncountry. Focusing onorigin clusters, theauthors will study the potential inuence of the
home country context and, in particular, the impact of rm-level factors, both investor- and investment-
related, underlying heterogeneity in their location choice decisions.
Design/methodology/approach The empirical analysis draws on data gathered from mainland
Chinese MNEs that have invested in Germany between 2005 and 2013 (269 rms). The authors chose a single
host (Germany) and a single home (China) country for their representativeness and for methodological
reasons to control for country effects. The authors used a multinomial logit model to assess the effects of the
independent variableson the probability that each of the three location possibilities would be selected.
Findings The results suggest that investors preferring co-location in origin clusters have distinct
structural and strategic characteristics. From a more structural point of view, Chinese foreign direct
investment (FDI) undertaken by smaller rms and those without prior experience in the EU prefer an area
where there are other Chinese investors. From a more strategic perspective, these FDI ows are more likely to
tap into industry agglomerations when the investorsobjective is strategic asset seeking, and they have less
knowledge-intensive investments.
Practical implications The ndings may be of great practical value to practitioners and policymakers.
Knowledge of the advantages and disadvantages of the types of agglomeration networks can help managers
to balance the rewards and risks in their decision-making and to select a suitable development path for their
FDIs. For policymakers, an understanding of the structure and formation of different groups of rms in one
location and the characteristics of investors who may enter the location can help them to improve their
regulatory work and to develop policies to attract investments, thereby enhancing local economic
development and communitystability.
Originality/value The research shifts the emphasis of the location choice decision beyond just where to
locate toward with whom to collocate. It also contributes to the growing research on emerging market
multinationals by providing further insight into understanding of FDI location behavior by rms from
emerging economies.
Keywords Multinational rms, Location choice, Clusters, Agglomerations, Emerging economies
Paper type Research paper
Introduction
The choice of location within a foreign country is a critical aspect of multinational rms
outward foreign direct investment (OFDI) strategies, as the decision of where to invest in the
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
Received 19 July2018
Revised 1 March 2019
3 May 2019
22 June 2019
Accepted 9 July 2019
Multinational Business Review
© Emerald Publishing Limited
1525-383X
DOI 10.1108/MBR-07-2018-0051
The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available on Emerald Insight at:
www.emeraldinsight.com/1525-383X.htm
foreign market can directly impact the outcome of the investment as well as direction and
prospects for future growth. A recent line of literature has drawn attention to the
subnational or regional aspects of location (instead of other more established levels of
analysis such as the country or city), emphasizing the economies that arise from the co-
location of rms in specic domains as a result of various externalities and spillovers. The
focus of such research haspredominantly been on clusters and industrial districts, which are
seen to comprise an array of industries related through common technologies, buyers/
suppliers, distribution channels, labor pools, etc. (Porter, 1990;Krugman, 1991).
Although the work on industry clusters (IC) has contributed immensely by explaining
how participation in clusters helps the competitiveness of rms, it by and large neglects
another kind of agglomeration that can be observed in the international business context
where, rather than an industry cluster within a particular host country, a group of foreign
investors originating from the same home country locate in proximity to one other when
investing in a foreign location due to certain underlying commonalities that are embedded in
their home context (Tan and Meyer, 2011;Hernandez, 2014;Stallkamp et al.,2017), thus
forming country-of-origin clusters (COC)[1].
In a recent paper, Beugelsdijk and Mudambi (2013) underlined the potential for advances
to be made by combining international business scholarsknowledge of rm organization to
economic geographersknowledge of place and space. Nevertheless, a signicant limitation
of research emphasizing common parentage at the country level is that it is somewhat
coarse-grained in that it tends to treat all compatriot rms homogenously. In this regard,
researchers (McCann, Arita and Gordon, 2002;Kim and Aguilera, 2016) have called for more
attention toward more ne-grained organization-level and behavioral issues to advance
cluster research further. Along similar lines and in an implicit recognition of this limitation,
Tan and Meyer themselves call for further studies that examine how the co-location choice
may be affected by otherfactors, such as knowledge intensity.
In this paper, we respond to this call and examine rm-level factors that drive
heterogeneity in rmschoices with respect to their location choice decision. Our interest is
in origin clusters, although we also address ICs to draw out the contrast between the two.
Work on origin clusters till date has tended to focus more on investing rms originating
from developed economies. Notably, although FDI from emerging economies has been
increasing rapidly in recent years, there has been relatively little investigation of the country
of origin effects in the case of foreign direct investors from emerging economies. In light of
their increasing visibility, there have been louder calls for more research on emerging
economy rmsoutward investment strategies, especially in advanced economy contexts
where these rms face greater disadvantages when investing overseas compared to their
advanced economy counterparts (Peng et al., 2008;Cuervo-Cazurra, 2012;Madhok and
Keyhani, 2012). A particular distinction between the two with respect to the country of
origin effect is that whereas foreign investors from an economically advanced country of
origin benet from superior attributes such as technology or brands when investing in
emerging economies, this is not the case when rms from an emerging economy invest in an
advanced economy. In the latter case, the emerging economy rm faces a credibility decit
(Madhok and Keyhani, 2012).
Our empirical context is Chinese rms investing in the European Union (EU). China
stands out as an emerging economy whose rms are rapidly expanding their global
footprint, both in advanced and other economies. Due to initial resistance in the US to
Chinese investment, especially through acquisitions, they increasingly began investing in
Europe and in particular in Germany, which is both Europes dominant economy as well as
its locomotive (Clegg and Voss, 2012). Second, unlike some of the other European economies,
MBR
Germany has a number of regions where rms can cluster, e.g. Hamburg, Dusseldorf or
Berlin, rather than having one dominant pole (Hanemann and Huotari, 2015). Third, the
home country institutional context is quite distinct from the host country; this aspect creates
unfamiliarity for the investing rm due to the uncertainty of the host countrys institutional
environment.
Our study builds upon and is yet distinct from some of the extant arguments on COC
agglomerations. For instance, we look at prior compatriot investors rather than immigrant
communities (Hernandez, 2014), even though there might be some overlap between the two.
This also contrasts with Stallkamp et al. (2017), who were more interested in the impact of
initial investment in origin clusters on speed and location choice of subsequent investments
within China. We look into the interorganizational dynamics among rms and the
environment where they operate and the effect of these interactions on rmsbehavior
(DiMaggio and Powell, 1983;Scott, 2008). Our paper, closest to Tan and Meyer (2011),
extends and complements their pioneering work by looking at rms located inside and
outside of clusters.
Our paper contributes in a number of ways. By going down to the rm-level, we are able
to better explain the heterogeneity in investing rmslocation choices with respect to
agglomeration. It is worth noting in this regard that our treatment is more comprehensive
than extant work in that we also include the isolated (i.e. non-cluster) location option, as
rms can and also choose to locate outside of clusters. Given the existence of the two types
of clusters, origin and industry, the question of what characteristics may drive rms to
prefer which type of cluster also becomes relevant. Collectively, the argument shifts the
emphasis of the location choice decision beyond just where to locate toward with whom to co-
locate.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we provide an overview
of the difculties faced by foreign investors, especially from emerging economies, and a
brief review of the agglomeration literature followed by our hypotheses. The subsequent
section discusses the methodology followed by the results. The nal section discusses some
of the contributions and implications of the paper. Here, we draw upon an analogy with the
ocking behavior of birds to illuminate our arguments further.
Literature review and hypotheses
Foreign investors confront a number of location-specic disadvantages compared with
national rms when they enter a new foreign market (Hymer, 1960). Broadly speaking, not
knowing the local environment as well as domestic rms, foreign rms are likely unable to
access and absorb the information and resources available in the host country as easily as
the former, who are much more attuned to the local context (Meyer et al., 2011). First and
foremost is the liability of foreignness (Zaheer, 1995), which is rooted in the psychological,
cultural and institutional distance between home and host countries (Zhou and Guillen,
2016), and as a result of which foreign rms face disadvantages stemming from a lack of
knowledge about the political, legislative, economic, market and culture-related
environments of the host country (Anand and Delios, 2002;Meyer et al.,2009). This results
in frictions and increases the cost of doing business broad, in particular in the early stages as
the rm goes about nding its way about in the local market.
Second, foreign investors additionally suffer from a liability of outsidership (Johanson and
Vahlne, 2009). In this argument, instead of an abstraction, markets are considered networks
of relationships in which rms are linked to each other and through which rms learn and
build commitment. It is important to have a relevant network position in the local market
when entering a foreign country and an insidershipis decisive for the investment to
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
succeed. Compared to national rms, foreign entrants are outsiders and usually lack a
developed local business network, which impedes their access to the resources required for
their business development.
A third important barrier to foreign investors, faced specically by MNEs from emerging
economies investing in advanced economies, is what has been termed the liability of
emergingness (Madhok and Keyhani, 2012). In this argument, the establishment and
maintenance of legitimacy in the host environment is vital for the survival and growth of the
business in the host country (Kostova and Zaheer, 1999). Due to their emerging market
origins as well as limited experience in institutionally more developed as well as distant
countries, MNEs from emerging economies nd it difcult to understand and conform to
local norms and practices (Scott, 2008;Asmussen and Goerzen, 2013). This results in a
relative lack of legitimacy and social acceptance from local constituents (Zhou, 2013)
government, consumers and suppliers which, in turn, leads to them being discriminated
against, at least relative to other foreign investors from more advanced economies (Madhok
and Keyhani, 2012). In the absence of such legitimacy, foreign investors in such a context
may nd it more difcult to develop trust and foster cooperative ties with key local
constituents (Eden and Miller, 2004), which results in more uncertainties for their business
(Zhou, 2013).
Collectively, these three liabilities create considerable uncertainty for foreign rms as
they go about conducting their business abroad. One way to overcome these disadvantages
is the (co)location strategy, whereby rms can gain access to the information or resources
they need by locating close to other related rms, i.e. agglomeration.
Location choice and multi-national enterprises clustering
Ever since Marshalls(1920)pioneering work examining external economies in industrial
districts in England, there has been strong and sustained interest in what has now come to
be denominated as agglomeration economies (Parr, 2002). Although researchers interested
in the topic come from diverse disciplines, such as geography, economics, sociology and
strategy, all share the common interest of better comprehending the geographical context,
how agglomeration economies come about and the type of advantage they confer upon rms
(Mariotti et al., 2010;Lazzeretti et al.,2014)[2].
The crux of the argument is as follows. Firms operate and evolve in an environment
consisting of other rms and organizations. Accordingly, they learn not only from their own
experience but also by interacting with other organizations in their immediate environment
(Chen and Chen, 1998). This can give rise to clusters of rms who choose particular
locations, giving rise to agglomeration economies (Krugman, 1991), such benets of
agglomeration being created through links between independent rms present in
proximity to one another within a dened space(Kim and Aguilera, 2016,p.146).
Some authors (Boschma, 2005) have criticized economic geographers for
overemphasizing physical proximity in their explanation for agglomeration economies and
have called for more attention to other forms of proximity, such as cognitive, social and
institutional proximity, which also impact resource and knowledge ows across rms. In
contrast to economic geographersexplanations of spatial organization and dynamics,
where physical proximity and economic variables have mainly tended to characterize much
of the work on location choice, the latter argument also addresses more organizational and
institutional considerations (Peng et al.,2008). In the international business context, even
though there is a geographic proximity in the host nation, an equally important underlying
factor is the shared home country context, which has a richer dimension than physical
proximity.
MBR
A number of scholars have devoted substantial energy to understanding the location
aspect of MNEsinternational expansion and what underlies their decision to place value-
added activities in particular areas outside the home base (Kang and Jiang, 2012;Kim and
Aguilera, 2016;Mesquita, 2016). Basically, in the international context, rms participate in
and are inuenced by two principal environments besides that of the host context. The rst
is the industry context in which interactions among rms are driven by business ties,
whereby rms exchange resources and interact with other rms suppliers, distributors or
even competitors in similar or related activities but not necessarily from the same country.
The other is the home country context, by which interactions among rms in the host
country are characterized by ethnic, diasporic and other such social ties with other
organizations of similar origin but not necessarily in the same industry. In fact, with the
underlying driver being the shared country of origin, these agglomerations are agnostic to
industry.
In short, the two environments thus provide investors with two potentially different
agglomeration tendencies:
(1) into areas preferred by other investors engaged in the same industry; and
(2) into regions where other investors originating from the same home country have
entered.
Because of the distinctiveness of their constituents, these two environments inuence
investors in different ways and provide them with different stimuli and resources.
With the IC argument being quite well-known, we focus our attention more on the origin
cluster. In a nutshell, with respect to the former, rms are attracted toward ICs due to
business-related opportunities to learn as well as to tap into common economies that can
signicantly reduce their business development costs (McCann and Folta, 2008;Alcacer and
Chung, 2014), with the downside being that relationships can be more competitive in nature
(Folta et al.,2006). In contrast, COCs are driven by a different set of considerations that are
cemented by common country bonds (Tan and Meyer, 2011).
There are a number of benets that rms can enjoy by co-locating with their compatriot
rms. First, knowledge does not just ow freely and evenly among rms in physical
proximity within a cluster but is facilitated by social relations (Giuliani, 2007;Jean et al.,
2011). In this regard, it is easier to build trust among compatriots (Chang and Park, 2005;
Stallkamp et al., 2017). Such a high trust relationship can facilitate the communication and
information transfer process among compatriot rms, thus expediting learning about the
host environment and institutions (Liao and Yu, 2012) as well as lowering the cost of
knowledge transfer. Second, new foreign investors can benet from the legitimacy that their
compatriots have already achieved in that location (Auster and Aldrich, 1984). These
advantages can help foreign investors reduce their liability from being outsiders. In other
words, agglomerations of rms with a common nationality can ease the difculty of doing
business and can reduce perceived local investment risks (Bangara et al., 2012). Third, due to
their commonalities, it is easier to absorb knowledge from others who have a relatively
similar way of doing things and may have been through similar adaptation processes and
experiences (Tan and Meyer, 2011). Supporting this line of argument, studies (Miller et al.,
2008;Belderbos and Zou, 2009) show that co-locating with ethnically similar rms in a
foreign country signicantly increases new entrantschances of survival.
To sum up, an origin cluster in a sense provides a foreign investor with a friendly start-
upenvironment and can reduce its entry costs by helping it learn about the host context as
well as mitigate institutional uncertainty at the country level. Besides, in our particular
context, the different ethnic origin and socio-cultural background, combined with a
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
reputation for relative technological backwardness and thus less to contribute, would render
it more difcult for Chinese investors to gain easy access to the benets of ICs. In other
words, even though the benets of ICs, especially in advanced economies, may be attractive
for emerging multinationals, they may not be so easily accessible to them. Moreover,
participation in such clusters may be perceived as somewhat riskier since relationships are
more rivalries as a result of similar or overlapping business activities (Iammarino and
McCann, 2006;Wang et al.,2014).
At the same time however, as they are not all inuenced equally by the two distinct kinds
of environments, it is unrealistic to expect that all rms from a particular country would act
in a similar manner in their location choices. Put differently, rm-level differences can also
be expected to impact this decision, with both individual investor and investment
characteristics leading to heterogeneity in rmslocation choices. This heterogeneous
behavior of investing rms causes the agglomeration tendency to vary across rms (Shaver
and Flyer, 2000).
Hypotheses
Smaller rms sometimes called micro-multinationals (Dimitratos et al., 2003) differ from
larger rms in their independence from as well as interaction with their environment
(Shuman and Seeger, 1986;Brouthers and Nakos, 2004). For one, resource limitations
constrain small rmsability to build industry networks. As it is, this is usually a costly and
time-consuming process, which is then further exacerbated due to the liabilities of
foreignness, outsidership and emergingness identied earlier. On the other, their small size
limits their credibility further. All this impedes their access to the necessary resources for
their overseas operations, both with respect to business information as well as the necessary
knowledge of the foreign context. Moreover, as the literature has shown, there are costs and
risks associated with working and doing business in clusters due to imitation and
congestion (Krugman, 1991;Iammarino and McCann, 2006). As a result of the above, the net
effect of clustering can be negative.
On the one hand, foreign rms, both large and small, are more likely to decide to co-locate
and interact with other rms in particular areas, forming agglomerations and clusters, to
benet from information and knowledge spillovers as well as gain from local institutional
linkages. On the other, smaller rms have fewer resources and less condence than larger
rms (Dimitratos et al.,2003) to withstand any negative impacts from competitive
retaliation by cluster incumbents or from unintended technological spillovers. As a result, in
spite of potential benets, smaller rms may nd participation in ICs particularly
challenging due to resource constraints and weak legitimacy, at the very least in the early
stages till they nd their initial footing. As smaller rms usually nd it more difcult to
withstand challenges arising from the institutional context (Erramilli and Rao, 1993;
Schwens et al.,2011), this makes them more likely to depend on their home-based resources,
including networks, and be inuenced by others with whom they share a common home
context, members of which aremore willing to share with them their information, experience
and legitimacy in the overseas markets. Moreover, the common heritage facilitates
absorption and lowers learning and adaptation costs to local environments (Tan and Meyer,
2011). In addition, if unsure of the appropriate course of action, one way to mitigate such
uncertainty is to imitate referent others, i.e. mimetic isomorphism (Guillen, 2003).
Consequently, SMEs are more likely to locate with compatriot rms, i.e. interact with other
investors from the same home environment:
MBR
H1. Ceteris paribus, in establishing subsidiaries in host countries, smaller (emerging
market) rms are more likely than larger rms to locate (with compatriots) within
an origin cluster.
State-owned enterprises (SOEs) are a signicant force in worldwide overseas investments,
especially in the case of emerging economies (Yeung and Liu, 2008;Kolstad and Wiig, 2012).
SOEs usually have both political and economic concerns in their ideology and strategies
(Cuervo-Cazurra et al.,2014) and, accordingly, are frequently required to serve the political
aims and mandates of the state as well as align their interests with their home institutions
while pursuing their business objectives (Scott, 2002;Zhang et al., 2011). Thus, SOEs are
more tied to the home context and their behavior is usually inuenced by the considerations
and strategic needs of the home context (Ramasamy et al., 2012). Moreover, the political
afliation of SOEs makes their interests less likely to be consonant with the expectations of
the external institutions in the local context (Globerman and Shapiro, 2009). Indeed, they are
usually perceived by host country institutions as not simply business entities but also as
political actors (He and Lyles, 2008), which exacerbates the legitimacy problem and acts as
an extra entry barrier, even more so when the investment is from an ideologically or
politically distant foreign country (Cui and Jiang,2009, 2012). The strong ties with the home
context and the greater perceived institutional pressure from the host context makes SOEs
more likely to seek refugeamong compatriots:
H2. Ceteris paribus, in establishing subsidiaries in host countries, SOEs are more likely
than privately owned enterprises to locate within an origin cluster.
As explained above, the various liabilities confronting foreign investors constitutes a major
obstacle for them. Unfamiliarity with the political, legislative, economic, market and cultural
environments hinders the development of an investors business network and the
attainment of legitimacy for business operations in the host context. Knowledge of sensitive
cultural or other institutional aspects of the host environment is not easy to attain or
understand (Tung, 1998;Miller et a., 2008). Although such knowledge required for FDI can
be partly acquired through market transactions, this kind of knowledge exchange lacks the
richness and effectiveness of that based more on primary relationships (Hernandez, 2014).
More direct exposure through prior investment in the host environment facilitates
development of such ties.
Moreover, new foreign entrants may nd it difcult to develop trust with local business
partners in a culturally or institutionally distant country (Tsui-Auch and Möllering, 2010).
This raises additional challenges for those lacking prior experience in the host context to
carry out their business operations. Thus, they are more likely to locate next to compatriot
rms to take advantage of the legitimacy that these prior entrants have already generated in
the region. In addition, as mentioned earlier, the interrm relationships between rms of the
same origin is characterized by a relatively high degree of trust, which can help latecomers
reduce investment uncertainty and facilitate development of their business networks[3].
Even though Tan and Meyer (2011) made a similar argument in the context of
institutionally-decient environments, the argument above suggests that it is not so much a
question of just the presence of local institutional voids but rather, and more broadly,
institutional differences between home and host country contexts. In this regard, in spite of
country-level variations, EU member countries have a high level of institutional
convergence since they all need to abide by common EU policies on many signicant issues,
for which reason they can for all practical considerations be considered the same
institutional region for the purpose of global strategy (Rugman and Verbeke, 2004):
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
H3. Ceteris paribus, in establishing subsidiaries in host countries, (emerging market)
rms lacking host environment experience are more likely than those with such
experience to locate within an origin cluster.
Scholars investigating the agglomerating behavior of rms have found that colocation
signicantly reduces investorsperception of risks and increases new entrantschances of
survival (Belderbos and Zou, 2009). Moreover, investors with different aims have quite
different preferences and strategic considerations in FDI (Buckley et al.,2007;Lu et al.,2011).
These motives impact the extent and type of dependence and how they interact with others
in these contexts, which in turn is reected in their location tendencies (Shaver and Flyer,
2000). Investors engaging in upstream FDI with the objective of seeking specic industry-
related assets such as technologies, brands, and specic management know-how are more
likely to interact with other rms engaged in related activities to acquire or create these
assets. In this context, it is less likely that locating among compatriots would enable them to
attain these objectives, and accordingly makes it less likely that they would choose to locate
among compatriot rms in the host context for this purpose.
On the other hand, investors seeking foreign markets have to compete directly with other
rms with similar activities for distribution channels and markets (Fan et al., 2016). In
contrast to those primarily seeking complementary upstream resources, investors with a
market-seeking aim may perceive more rivalry from the host environment. As it is,
expanding into the markets of developed economies such as the USA and the European
Union (EU), where industries or markets are in a more mature stage of development
characterized by a high degree of competition, is particularly challenging. This is even more
so for emerging market rms, as such rms usually lack signicant advantages to compete
in the global market (Luo and Tung, 2007;Deng, 2009). In addition to this, emerging market
rms suffer from a status of outsider and lack of legitimacy resources, which makes it more
difcult for them to build trust and gain acceptance in the market. The lack of legitimacy
and trust poses a daunting obstacle but is an imperative that needs to be overcome. One way
is to learn from and benet from compatriot resources (Kang and Jiang, 2012). Thus,
emerging market investors seeking foreign markets are more likely to locate among
compatriots to gain legitimacy and develop their business networks.
Although the literature has shown that foreign rms need legitimacy in the host country
to increase their chance of survival and their access to resources, these arguments do not
apply as much to rms seeking strategic assets. The latter are less local market-oriented and
for them the imperative is more frequently to learn from other industry participants for
upgrading and catching up, not just to compete locally but also to become more competitive
at home:
H4. Ceteris paribus, in establishing subsidiaries in host countries, (emerging market)
rms seeking overseas markets are more likely than rms seeking strategic assets
to locate within an origin cluster.
A major advantage of co-locating with other rms is access to knowledge or information
spillover. However, as mentioned, geographic proximity increases competition and rivalry
and raises the appropriation hazard. This competitive relationship reduces the propensity to
interact with others in the same industry, especially for weaker rms, as leakage of specic
knowledge, such as technological and management know-how, to potential competitor rms
with similar activities would erode competitive advantages (Iammarino and McCann, 2006).
Moreover, as Chang and Xu (2008) demonstrate, foreign entrants tend to be crowded out by
MBR
local players from the region due to the competitive aspect. Thus, such rms would be
motivated to avoid such risk by locating among compatriots, where such a threat is weaker
since business activities are more diverse.
However, subsidiaries differ in knowledge intensity of their industries and investments.
Firms in high-knowledge industries require higher investment but demand tends to be more
differentiated, thus they enjoy higher prot margins and are more buffered from
competition relative to less knowledge-intensive rms. In contrast, rms in low-intensity
industries and investment are less able to withstand the effect of competition as they lack
such differentiation. Along similar lines, rms from emerging economies have an even
greater legitimacy decit in knowledge-intensive sectors because their technology is
considered inferior and not sufciently up to speed (Madhok and Keyhani, 2012).
Nowadays, investors from emerging economies are increasingly climbing up the
technological ladder and starting to get noticed for some imaginative technology, even
though this may not be leading edge. Thus, rms with higher knowledge-intensity
investments may not suffer a legitimacy decit to the same extent as their more ordinary
low knowledge intensity counterparts. In contrast, the latter are less able to endure some of
the negative effects of the lack of legitimacy in the host environment and thus more drawn
toward gaining legitimacy indirectly through compatriots compared to their high
knowledge intensity counterparts:
H5. Ceteris paribus, in establishing subsidiaries in host countries, (emerging market)
rms with lower knowledge intensity are more likely than those with higher
knowledge intensity to locate within an origin cluster.
Methodology
Data collection and sample
Our empirical analysis draws on data gathered from mainland Chinese MNEs that have
invested in Germany between 2005 and 2013. We chose a single host (Germany) and a single
home (China) country for our study for their representativeness and for methodological
reasons to control for country effects (Klossek et al.,2012). Using the AMADEUS database,
considered to be an important secondary research source with a high degree of reliability
(Brouthers and Brouthers, 2003;Siedschlag et al., 2013), we identied rms in Germany that
have owners from China (owned more than 51 per cent of the shares)[4].
Combining the information of AMADEUS with information extracted from rms
reports[5] and web sites, as well as government publications, we created a database of 269
rms. We then deleted from our sample those rms which did not have complete
information on the focal variables of our analysis. The main sample therefore comprised of
238 rms. These represent the principal Chinese outward FDIs carried out by enterprises in
Germany during the period covered (UNCTAD, 2013) and covers the four types of location
choices: industry clusters, origin clusters, overlapping clusters (i.e. where the two cluster
types overlap) and non-clusters (i.e. locationally isolated investments). Similar information
sources and collection methods have been used in other studies (Dikova and Van
Witteloostuijn, 2007;Siedschlag et al., 2013).
Measurements
The dependent variable in the analysis is the FDI location tendency of Chinese MNEs within
the host country. In our case, this was reected in three types of agglomeration choices:
industry, origin and isolated (i.e. non-cluster). As highlighted in the footnote below, Tan and
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
Meyer (2011) underline the extreme difculty, both conceptually and empirically, in
separating out the independent effects of industry and origin in situations where there is
cluster overlap. We therefore decided to follow their example and exclude these (40 cases)
from our main sample, reducing the sample to 198 rms[6].
There is no agreed method for identifying and mapping clusters, either in terms of the
measurement or the procedures by which the geographical boundaries of the clusters should
be determined (Martin and Sunley, 2003). To address this aspect we followed the
suggestions of Alcácer and Zhao (2016), who establish a three step process:
the denition of the activity to study in our case, the sector (industry) and the
phenomenon (Chinese multinationals);
the delineation of the geographic unit of analysis upon which to carry out said
analysis (in our case German regions at a NUT-2 level)[7]; and
the establishment of the number of agglomerated units (rms) to label
agglomeration as a cluster (contingent upon the size of the region).
Consistent with this process and in line with some previous authors (Cader and Leatherman,
2011;Delgado et al., 2014), we used the location quotient (LQ)[8] as the method to identify
agglomerations. As there are no commonly accepted thresholds for dening an
agglomeration (ODonoghue and Gleave, 2004), and given that the ratio of ratios
representing the location quotient can be interpreted in terms of specialization when greater
than 1, we dene and categorize an agglomeration if the LQ >1.0 and 0 otherwise. This is
similar to Wu et al. (2017). It is important to remark that although we could have dened the
boundaries of agglomerations more broadly (NUT-1) or more narrowly (NUT-3) we use the
NUT-2 level, as the selection of the level of analysis has to be suitable to test the theoretical
relationships and data availability. Specically, for NUT-1 the Germany country is divided
into only seven areas or states, and for NUT-3 in 401 districts, whereas for NUT-2 in 38
regions. Other papers (De Beule et al.,2018) have used a similar criterion:
L:Q:ðorigin agglomerationÞ¼
Number of firms with Chinese shareholderðsÞin a particular region=Number of all firms in the region
Number of all firms with Chinese shareholderðsÞin Germany=Number of all firms in Germany
L:Q:ðindustrial agglomerationÞ¼
Number of firms of a particular sector in a particular region=Number of all firms in the region
Number of all firms of a particularsector in Germany=Number of all firms in Germany
The NACE Rev. 2 (Statistical Classication of Economic Activities in the European
Community) is used for the industry denition. The geographic unit of analysis is the
region at a NUTS-2 level. Our analysis revealed substantial geographical diversity in
our sample: Dusseldorf, Darmstadt, Oberbayern, Koeln, Stuttgart, Unterfranken,
Hamburg and others.
The independent variables in the study were dened in line with the hypotheses, which
focus on ve structural and strategic characteristics of the investors when they entered the
host country. The corresponding variables that we created are investor size,investor
ownership,investor exposure,investment motivation and knowledge intensity.
MBR
Investor size was captured by a rating scale using the log of the operating revenue, total
assets, and number of employees of the investors in the year prior to their FDI entry; this
scale has been widely adopted in IB empirical studies (Aw and Lee, 2008;Demirbag et al.,
2008). It is important to highlight that we followed the classication provided by Bureau
Van Dijk (SME, Large, Very large). In other words, we did not use a single criterion for the
measurement to avoid potential bias in analysis resulting from cases where there are large
operational revenues but few total assets or employees, or the reverse.
Investor ownership was measured based on the ownership structure of the investor. In
hypothesizing the effects of the home institutional dependence in the host context, we
argued that the dependence on their home institution context and perceived institutional
pressures from the host environment would be greater for state-owned enterprises.
Following some prior authors such as Duanmu (2012) and Cui and Jiang (2012),we
calculated the total percentage of the equity owned by the Chinese government and its
agencies in the investing rms. We then created a dummy variable, with private investors
being coded 0and SOEs as 1.
Investor exposure focuses on investorsexposure to the host context through prior FDI.
This was captured by a dummy variable, where the code 1was used when the investing
rm had prior FDI experience in the EU and 0otherwise. Similar measurements related to
MNEsexperience have been employed in research by authors such as Makino et al. (2002).
We had access to information regarding when investors entered a host country in the EU for
the rst time. As explained earlier, adherence to the ever-increasing number of common EU-
level policies and regulations has consistently been prompting greater institutional
convergence among EU members over the years, in spite of country-level variations in
political, legal and business systems. This is particularly so in the economic and business
realm, thus justifying their being considered the same institutional region for the purpose of
global strategy (Rugman and Verbeke, 2004). We accordingly considered it justiable to
operationalize the four countries where the majority of Chinese investments in the EU being
concentrated, i.e. Germany, UK, France and Spain (De Beule et al., 2018), as a common
destination for the rst investment in the EU. A similar kind of argument was made by
Cuervo-Cazurra and Genc (2008) in the context of prior investment in countries with
institutional voids serving as a platform for subsequent investments in similar countries in
the region.
Investment motivation measures the Chinese investorsprimary purpose for undertaking
their investment. Prior studies have shown that investment motivation has a signicant
impact on MNEslocation preference (Chung and Alcácer, 2002;Makino et al.,2002).
Broadly, rms invest internationally to seek access to new markets (market-seeking), to
secure better access to raw materials (resource-seeking), to secure better access to
technologies, brands, distribution channels (asset-seeking and/or to reduce overall
production costs (efciency-seeking) (Dunning, 1988). Although legitimacy issues are
relevant irrespective of the motive, the type of motive impacts the requisite level of
legitimacy due to the differing dependence on their immediate environment.
Clearly, Germany not being a primary goods producer or a location for low-cost
production, it is especially likely that Chinese direct investments in economically developed
countries as Germany are driven by a motivation to acquire technologies and brands (asset-
seeking) or to expand markets. Such investments potentially augment their competitiveness.
Moreover, a sharper competitive edge through asset-seeking or through more successful
participation in more competitive markets like Germany makes them more competitive back
in the home country (a huge market) as well as elsewhere.
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
In line with the above authors, and with the information extracted from rmsreports
and websites, as well as government publications, we classied the investment motivations
into two categories. Given the nature of our variables, we coded them as dummies. Strategic-
asset seeking investment (coded 0) includes activities such as design, research and
development and the acquisition of assets such as technology, patents and some intangible
know-how with the aim of enhancing the home-based capability. Market seeking investment
(coded 1) includes activities related to overseas market expansion, either by wholesaling or
retailing products or services, and other sales-support activities.
Knowledge intensity measures the intensity of technology or knowledge involved in the
investments of the Chinese MNEs. Due to the limitations of the information that we could
access, we followed the Classication of Manufacturing Based on NACE Rev. 2 and
Classication of Services Based on NACE Rev. 2 provided by Eurostat (2014)[9] as proxies,
which indicates the average level of the technology or knowledge intensity in each sector.
Where MNEssubsidiaries in the host country operate in higher technology or knowledge
intensity industries, we coded it as 1and the other cases as 0.
We also included a set of control variables in our analysis. Investment sector was created
to capture the differences between manufacturing investments and service investments.
Some previous FDI studies have suggested that manufacturing sector investors and service
sector investors perceive environmental uncertainties differently (Brouthers and Brouthers,
2003). We also measured investment size as the log of the size of the subsidiary used by the
foreign investors in the host country. A larger investment is considered to be riskier in FDI
and is likely to receive more institutional pressure from the local institutions (Li and Li,
2010). Finally, establishment mode was created to capture whether the investment was made
through a greeneld operation or an acquisition. This is important because acquisition of an
already existing operation would constrain the location choice of the investing rm.
A summary of the measurement of the independent, dependent, and control variables
and their operated values is given in Table I. The descriptive statistics indicate that of the
total sample size of 198 FDIs 29.3 per cent involved isolated location choices, 33.8 per cent
involved location inICs, and the remaining 36.9 percent involved location in COCs.
Method
We used a multinomial logit model to assess the effects of the independent variables on the
probability that each of the three location possibilities IC, COC and non-cluster would be
selected. This is a particularly appropriate and often-used technique when rms are
confronted with a choice among multiple options (Gatignon and Anderson, 1988;Agarwal
and Ramaswami, 1992;Goerzen et al., 2013). In a multinomial logit model, one of the
dependent variable is selected as a case of reference, or base case. In our study, the non-
cluster or isolated option is set as the base case.
Results
Table II presents the means, standard deviations and correlations between variables. The
correlations between the independent and control variables were generally lower than 0.4
except, for understandable reasons, the ones between location choice, investment motivation
and the establishment mode of the subsidiary, i.e. greeneld or acquisition[10]. The VIF
factors (values lower than 2.5) indicate that that there were no serious problems of
multicollinearity (Gujarati, 2003;Hair et al.,2006).
Table III shows the results of the multinomial logistic regression analysis, as estimated
with SPSS-20. To interpret the magnitude of the relationship between an independent
variable and the dependent variable in multinomial regression, the table includes, for each
MBR
independent variable, the estimated coefcient (
b
i), signicance (*), standard error (SE). To
display the results, we dened six models. Establishing different models makes it possible
to compare alternative models by isolating changes in model t and determining the
explanatory power of the variables (Aiken et al.,1991). As mentioned, the isolated location
choice is set as the base case. As such, no empirical statements can be made about which
circumstances favor the base case, as all its coefcients being set to zero, this being the case
from which all deviations (in our case, origin and industrial cluster) are measured, with
(Gatignon and Anderson, 1988).
Table I.
Description of the
variables
Name Description Values (% in sample)
Location mode Agglomeration choice 1 = Isolated (29.3%)
2 = Industry cluster (33.8%)
3 = Origin cluster (36.9%)
Investor size Investor size (group) 1 =SME
a
(13.3%)
2 = Large company (28.1%)
3 = Very large company (58.6%)
Investor ownership Owners of the investor 0 = Private (65.7%)
1 = SOE (34.3%)
Exposure Previous FDIs in the EU 0 = No (68.5%)
1 = Yes (31.5%)
Investment motivation Investment strategic objective in the
host country
1 = Market seeking (48.9%)
2 = Asset seeking (51.1%)
Knowledge intensity Technology and knowledge intensity
of the subsidiary
0 = Low and medium-low (53.9%)
1 = High and medium-high (46.1%)
Investment sector Investment activity in host country 0 =Manufacturing activity (44.0%)
1 = Trading and service activity (56.0%)
Investment size Subsidiary size in host country 1 = SME (66.7%)
2 = Large company (18.7%)
3 = Very large company (14.6%)
Established mode Entry mode 0 = Acquisition (50.5%)
1 = Greeneld (49.5%)
Note:
a
SMEs refer to small- and medium-sized rms
Table II.
Descriptive statistics
and correlation
coefcients
Variables Mean SD 12345678910
1. Isolated 0.28 0.45
2. Industry cluster (IC) 0.34 0.47 0.44
3. Origin cluster (COC) 0.38 0.49 0.49 0.55
4. Investor size 2.45 0.72 0.17 0.15 0.31
5. Investor ownership 0.34 0.48 0.07 0.00 0.06 0.33
6. Exposure 0.31 0.47 0.04 0.29 0.32 0.31 0.02
7. Investment motivation 0.51 0.50 0.05 0.42 0.46 0.35 0.20 0.27
8. Knowledge intensity 0.46 0.50 0.11 0.14 0.24 0.27 0.04 0.24 0.48
9. Investment sector 0.56 0.50 0.00 0.31 0.30 0.18 0.05 0.21 0.38 0.43
10. Investment size 1.48 0.74 0.12 0.20 0.31 0.38 0.23 0.28 0.42 0.25 0.37
11. Established mode 0.49 0.50 0.08 0.43 0.49 0.38 0.10 0.40 0.64 0.32 0.40 0.48
Note: Number of observations: 198
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
COC-Isolated COC-Isolated IC-Isolated IC-Isolated COC-IC COC-IC
Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
Investor size
SME 1.62** (0.78) 0.21 (1.03) 1.41 (0.94)
Large 0.34 (0.55) 1.01*(0.58) 0.67 (0.60)
Ownership
Private 0.42 (0.50) 0.33 (0.48) 0.75 (0.54)
Exposure
Without experience 1.18* (0.64) 0.89* (0.49) 2.08** (0.65)
Investment motivation
Market seeking 0.34 (0.63) 1.63** (0.61) 1.97**(0.66)
Knowledge intensity
Medium and low Know intensity 0.42 (0.59) 1.19** (0.55) 0.77 (0.61)
Investment sector
Manufacturing 0.27 (0.45) 0.43 (0.59) 0.64 (0.41) 0.88* (0.50) 0.92** (0.43) 0.46 (0.60)
Investment size
SME 0.98 (0.75) 0.27 (0.87) 0.73 (0.52) 0.75 (0.61) 0.24 (0.77) 0.48 (0.89)
Large 1.27 (0.85) 0.67 (0.92) 1.41** (0.59) 1.43** (0.66) 0.13 (0.83) 0.76 (0.91)
Established mode
Acquisition 1.60*** (0.47) 1.42** (0.62) 0.95** (0.46) 0.29 (0.24) 2.56*** (0.49) 1.72**(0.49)
Constant 0.01 (0.79) 1.11 (1.05) 1.56** (0.64) 1.08 (0.86) 1.564* (0.84) 0.031**(1.11)
Observation (N) 198 (125) 198 (125) 198 (121) 198 (121) 198 (133) 198 (133)
Log-likelihood ratio 65.251 196.949 65.251 196.949 65.251 196.949
R
2
(Cox and Snell) 0.315 0.451 0.315 0.451 0.451 0.451
R
2
(Nagelkerke) 0.355 0.509 0.355 0.509 0.509 0.509
Chi square 72.399*** 107.978*** 72.399*** 107.978*** 72.399*** 107.978***
Correctly classied (%) 59.7 83.6 59.7 73.4 59.7 66.1
Notes:
*
p<0.10;
**
p<0.05;
***
p<0.01
Table III.
Multinomial
regression
MBR
Models 1 and 2 estimate the coefcients for the choice of origin clusters vis-à-vis the base
case. Model 1 includes only the control variables, whereas Model 2 tests the complete model
by including all the independent variables. In these models, a positive and signicant
coefcient indicates that the corresponding explanatory variable increases the likelihood of
the investor locating in the corresponding type of cluster, in this case COC. Conversely, a
negative and signicant coefcient indicates that the corresponding explanatory variable
decreases the likelihood of the same. Models 3 and 4 do likewise for the choice of ICs. We
additionally also examined the choice of COC treating IC as the base case. This is captured
in Models 5 and 6.
The regression results show that all the models have signicant explanatory power and
model t. As one can see, when adding the independent variables, the chi squares and
correctly classied percentages of these models increases signicantly. In the case of COCs,
whereas model 1 with only the control variables correctly classied just 59.7 per cent of the
location decisions, the correct classication percentage increased to 83.6 per cent for COCs in
the full model. This is a signicant jump in classication accuracy.
In line with our hypotheses, we expected investor size, investor ownership, investor
exposure, investment motivation and knowledge intensity to impact the agglomeration
decision. Analyzing the coefcients of investor size (1.62; p<0.05) and exposure (1.18; p<
0.1) in Model 2, we can afrm that our H1 and H3 are conrmed. That is, smaller size and
lack of experience in the EU increase the likelihood of an investor location in a COC.
Moreover, in the case of IC (Model 4), the coefcients for investor size is 1.01 (p<0.1) and
exposure is 0.89 (p<0.1), the latter suggesting that rms without experience are less
likely to locate in ICs. It is also worth noting that the effect size for these coefcients are
stronger for COCs than ICs. However, only the exposure variable (2.08; p<0.05) in Model 6
(base case IC) is signicant. This reinforces the argument that, besides seeking
agglomeration initially, less experienced rms seem to prefer a COC.
With respect to H2, although the coefcient for ownership is negative as expected,
suggesting that private rms are less likely to locate in origin clusters, it is not signicant. In
other words, the type of ownership (i.e. state or private) does not have any signicant impact
on the location choice decision. It is possible that, as state enterprises increasingly engage
overseas, economic concerns have begun to crowd out political concerns, at least compared
to earlier. In fact, institutional reforms in countries like China may be compelling state-
owned rms to become more competitive and economically-driven, even though the effect
might be greater on non-state-owned rms (Dau, 2012). In such case, and as host countries
become more exposed as well as accustomed to their presence, they become increasingly
accepted and viewed with less suspicion. Both these aspects would mitigate the pressure to
gravitate toward compatriots[11]. Additionally, we did not distinguish between different
types of state-owned rms. In their recent work, Benito et al. (2016) analyzed publicly listed
and non-publicly listed state-owned rms, the former often having some degree of private
ownership, and suggest the arrival of a modernstate-owned rm more in tune with
competitive considerations.
With respect to the investment motive (H4), the corresponding coefcient for market-
seeking investment in Model 2 was not signicant, even though the sign was pointing in the
right direction. However, the coefcient for market seeking (1.63, p<0.05) in Model 4
suggests that rms characterized by market-seeking investments are less likely to locate
within an industry cluster. Moreover, using IC as the base case, the coefcient for market
seeking (1.97, p<0.05) in Model 6 reinforces this argument. Thus, even though H2 is not
directly supported, there is some indirect support for the argument.
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
Finally, we postulated in H5 that rms with lower knowledge intensity investments are
more likely to locate within a COC. In the case of COCs, however, the corresponding
coefcient in Model 2 was not signicant. In contrast, the coefcient for industry cluster
(1.19; p<0.05) in Model 4 suggests that rms with low and medium-intensity investments
prefer ICs. Our argument had more to do with the non-existence of slack in low knowledge-
intensity investments and thus the limited ability to withstand competitive and legitimacy
pressures. However, it is possible that the opportunity to learn and upgrade may offset other
considerations. Also, these rms may be less concerned about competitive spillovers as they
have less to lose.
In conclusion, overall the directionality and signicance of the coefcients are broadly
consistent with our hypotheses, with the empirical results supporting many of our
arguments and others seeking mixed support. Besides the direct results, some further
information can be extracted from Table III. For instance, the fact that the corresponding
coefcients for investor size are signicant in Models 2 and 4 but not in Model 6 indirectly
appears to suggest that very large rms (58.6 per cent of investors see Table I) do not
experience the same pressure to agglomerate compared to their other compatriots. Similarly,
the nding in Model 4 that rms with market-seeking motives prefer to avoid ICs (Model 4)
and prefer COCs over ICs (Model 6) indirectly suggests that rms with asset-seeking
motives seem to prefer ICs, the latter point being reinforced by the fact that, as we could
expect, and in line with Zschoche (2016), manufacturing rms prefer ICs relative to those in
services (Model 4, coefcient = 0.88; p<0.1).
Discussion
In this paper, we provide insight into the potential inuence of the home country context on
foreign investorschoices with respect to location decisions within a country. Literature on
MNEsforeign investment strategies have traditionally taken the host country environment
as a whole and paid lesser attention to rmslocation patterns at the subnational level. Our
arguments suggest that investorsFDI location choice is not homogeneous within the host
country. By showing how foreign entrants can engage in and benet from a colocation
strategy in different ways, the argument on location choice goes one step beyond just where
to locate and shifts theemphasis toward with whom to co-locate.
Our results suggest that investors preferring co-location have distinct structural and
strategic characteristics. From a more structural point of view, Chinese FDI undertaken by
smaller rms and those without prior experience in the EU prefer an area where there are
other Chinese investors. From a more strategic perspective, these FDI ows are more likely
to tap into industry agglomerations when the investorsobjective is strategic asset seeking
and they have less knowledge-intensive investments.
In sum, the location of ones own home country rms in a certain area acts centripetally
in drawing membership from similar others, thus resulting in origin clusters. The entry of
these pioneersnot only provides examples to others with similar backgrounds, namely the
possibility of doing business, but also creates legitimacy for them in the same location. This
is important for the arrival in the same area of other compatriot rms who may lack
knowledge of the local context and suffer from lack of legitimacy. Unlike studies which
focus mainly on factors such as knowledge spillover, specialized labor and input providers
(Marshall, 1920;Porter,1990, 1998), this focus on contextual information and legitimacy
helps explain why investors are encouraged to co-locate with other rms of similar
background.
Our study also contributes to the growing research on emerging market multinationals
by providing further insight into understanding of FDI location behavior by rms from
MBR
emerging economies. In a way, such a location expansion path within the foreign country
would be the locational counterpart to the establishment mode expansion path suggested in
the traditional Uppsala internationalization process model (Johanson and Vahlne,1977,
2009). The Uppsala model emphasizes the gradual and direct accumulation of knowledge
and learning from rmsprior experience. To cope with uncertainty during a rms
internationalization process, the model proposes a pattern or order by which rms enter
foreign countries, whereby they tend to commence their foreign operations from more
familiar and culturally similar areas and move gradually to more unfamiliar and dissimilar
countries or regions. The locational perspective complements the model in the
understanding of MNEsforeign expansion behavior with respect to choice of location
within a country. In this argument, rmsknowledge, as well as legitimacy to carry out
business, can be gained not only from inside through direct experience but also indirectly
from the outside, wherein they can acquire information and resources and capture
opportunities through origin cluster participation.
Moreover, the ndings of this study may be of great practical value to practitioners and
policy makers. One important goal of management studies is to improve decision-making. A
knowledge of the advantages and disadvantages of the agglomeration networks can help
managers to balance the rewards and risks in their decision-making and to select a suitable
development path for their FDIs while remaining consistent with their investment
objectives. For policy makers, an understanding of the structure and formation of different
groups of rms in one location and the characteristics of investors who may enter the
location can help them to improve their regulatory work and to develop policies to attract
investments, thereby enhancing local economic development andcommunity stability.
Of course, our investigation is not without its limitations. First, a single home and host
country raises the issue of generalizability and may explain why a number of predicted
relations that were non-signicant. In a similar vein, perhaps prior exposure to other EU
countries may only be an imperfect proxy for Germany empirically. Second, with respect to
agglomeration economies, we have examined the independent effects of ICs and COCs. Yet
there is always the possibility that these two coincide in the same territory, i.e. cluster
overlap. Third, though scholars focusing on agglomeration economies usually argue that
new entrants are attracted by the associated benets, it remains unclear whether the effects
of such agglomeration are actually generated ex post, in other words, whether they are the
outcome of clusters not the cause. Ultimately, of course, the question of whether
agglomeration economies exist before agglomerations form or the reverse is a chicken-and-
egg question that is difcult to tease out empirically.
As a concluding remark, we know that rms do benet from locating in clusters due to
network externalities, but we know less about the evolution of such clusters. That is,
questions such as how they emerge, how they evolve over time and what role foreign market
entrants play in this process are ripe for further investigation. Researchers have begun to
look into these questions (Crescenzi et al., 2016;Nielsen et al.,2017;Shen and Puig, 2018), but
the focus has been more on industry-based agglomerations. Our arguments potentially
further additional insight into the phenomenon.
Notes
1. We use the term agglomeration or cluster to refer to both kinds.
2. Given their varied backgrounds, researchers use dierent terms to address what are in essence a
similar or closely related set of concepts (Martin and Sunley, 2003). In line with the IB tradition,
we use the term cluster.
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
3. In line with Urzelai and Puig (2019), we believe that though both newcomers and rms with prior
experience in the host country would want to benet from the knowledge and legitimacy, the
newcomers would benet more.
4. In 73.5% of the cases, the ownership of the subsidiary was completely Chinese (more than 95%
of the shares were owned by a Chinese investor), and in the remaining 26.5%, there was more
than one investor and each had less than 95% of shares (10% 94%, both included). In the latter
case, we selected only those cases in which the Chinese ownership was at least 51%.
5. Mainly their annual and semiannual reports, investment announcements, and other kinds of
internal documents.
6. As Tan and Meyer state: Conceptually, factors leading to a foreign investors choice to co-locate
with compatriots or foreign industry peers are likely to lead investors to co-locate with FDI rms
from the same industry and the same country if such a choice is available. Therefore, it is not
surprising that same country & industry FDI activity is highly correlated with the two variables
of interest in our study same country FDI activity and same industry FDI activity. We remove it
from the models to untangle individual eects of each type of FDI activity (p. 514) ... As we are
unable to disentangle the factors that lead to either country-of-origin agglomeration or industry
FDI agglomeration, we leave the variable out of the estimation, to avoid multicollinearity(p.518,
footnote 6).
7. The NUTS classication (Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics) is a hierarchical
system of the EUROSTAT for dividing up the economic territory of the EU, which has three
layers: NUTS-1 is the major socio-economic regions (states), NUTS 2 are basic regional units
dened for the application of regional policies (within the country) and the NUTS 3 are smaller
regions for specic diagnoses
8. Following Cromley and Hanink (2012), the LQ with reference to Chinese rms at observation
point (or location) i is a ratio of ratios. For example, the ratio for the local unit of observation
(country-of-origin cluster) can be written as e
i
/E
i
, where e
i
is the number of Chinese rms at
region i, and E
i
is the total of rms at region i. The ratio for the aggregate reference can be
written as e/E, where e and E are the total rms in Germany and the total of the overall rms in
the reference economy, respectively. Then: LQi = (e
i
/E
i
)/(e/E). To dene a subsidiary as Chinese
at least 51% of the shares were to be held by an investor of Chinese nationality.
9. https://europa.eu/european-union/documents-publications/statistics_en
10. However, as the correlation coecients between investment motivation and establishment mode
were of some concern, we re-estimated the models without the latter. The results, including the
Chi-squared statistic, not being signicantly dierent, we decided to retain both variables in the
nal analysis.
11. As one reviewer noted with regard to that results, one can argue whether SOEs are welcomed in
COCs or not. Due to their unlimited resources as well as connection to home country government
and their political power, there might be resistance from COCs to SOEs and their potential
inuence and domination in the cluster that could have negative impact on the performance of
the rms in COCs. We acknowledge this comment, and it remains open for future research.
References
Agarwal, S. and Ramaswami, S.N. (1992), Choice of foreign market entry mode: Impact of ownership,
location and internalization factors,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 23 No. 1,
pp. 1-27.
Aiken, L.S., West, S.G. and Reno, R.R. (1991), Multiple Regression: Testing and Interpreting Interactions,
Sage.
MBR
Alcacer, J. and Chung, W. (2014), Location strategies for agglomeration economies,Strategic
Management Journal, Vol. 35 No. 12, pp. 1749-1761.
Alcácer, J. and Zhao, M. (2016), Zooming in: a practical manual for identifying geographic clusters,
Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 37 No. 1, pp. 10-21.
Anand, J. and Delios, A. (2002), Absolute and relative resources as determinants of international
acquisitions,Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 23 No. 2, pp. 119-134.
Asmussen, C.G. and Goerzen, A. (2013), Unpacking dimensions of foreignness: rm-specic
capabilities and international dispersion in regional, cultural, and institutional space,Global
Strategy Journal, Vol. 3 No. 2, pp. 127-149.
Auster, E. and Aldrich, H. (1984), Small business vulnerability, ethnic enclaves and ethnic enterprise,
in Ward, R. and Jenkins, R. (Eds), Ethnic Communities in Business. Strategies for Economic
Survival, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 39-54.
Aw, B.Y. and Lee, Y. (2008), Firm heterogeneity and location choice of Taiwanese multinationals,
Journal of International Economics, Vol. 75 No. 1, pp. 167-179.
Bangara, A., Freeman, S. and Schroder, W. (2012), Legitimacy and accelerated internationalisation: an
Indian perspective,Journal of World Business, Vol. 47 No. 4, pp. 623-634.
Belderbos, R. and Zou, J. (2009), Real options and foreign afliate divestments: a portfolio perspective,
Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 40 No. 4, pp. 600-620.
Benito, G.R., Rygh, A. and Lunnan, R. (2016), The benets of internationalization for state-owned
enterprises,Global Strategy Journal, Vol. 6 No. 4, pp. 269-288.
Beugelsdijk, S. and Mudambi, R. (2013), MNEs as border-crossing multi-location enterprises: the role
of discontinuities in geographic space,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 44 No. 5,
pp. 413-426.
Boschma, R. (2005), Proximity and innovation: a critical assessment,Regional Studies, Vol. 39 No. 1,
pp. 61-74.
Brouthers, K.D. and Brouthers, L.E. (2003), Why service and manufacturing entry mode choices differ:
the inuence of transaction cost factors, risk and trust,Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 40
No. 5, pp. 1179-1204.
Brouthers, K.D. and Nakos, G. (2004), SME entry mode choice and performance: a transaction cost
perspective,Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 28 No. 3, pp. 229-247.
Buckley, P.J., Clegg, L.J., Cross, A.R., Liu, X., Voss, H. and Zheng, P. (2007), The determinants of
chinese outward foreign direct investment,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 38
No. 4, pp. 499-518.
Cader, H.A. and Leatherman, J.C. (2011), Small business survival and sample selection bias,Small
Business Economics, Vol. 37 No. 2, pp. 155-165.
Chang, S.J. and Xu, D. (2008), Spillovers and competition among foreign and local rms in China,
Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 29 No. 5, pp. 495-518.
Chang, S.J. and Park, S. (2005), Types of rms generating network externalities and MNCsco-location
decisions,Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 26 No. 7, pp. 595-615.
Chen, H. and Chen, T.J. (1998), Network linkages and location choice in foreign direct investment,
Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 29 No. 3, pp. 445-467.
Chung, W. and Alcácer, J. (2002), Knowledge seeking and location choice of foreign direct investment
in the United States,Management Science, Vol. 48 No. 12, pp. 1534-1554.
Clegg, J. and Voss, H. (2012), Chinese Overseas Direct Investment in the European Union, Europe China
Research and Advice Network, London.
Crescenzi, R., Pietrobelli, C. and Rabellotti, R. (2016), Regional strategic assets and the location
strategies of emerging countriesmultinationals in Europe,European Planning Studies, Vol. 24
No. 4, pp. 645-667.
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
Cromley, R.G. and Hanink, D.M. (2012), Focal location quotients: specication and applications,
Geographical Analysis, Vol. 44 No. 4, pp. 398-410.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2012), Extending theory by analyzing developing country multinational
companies: solving the goldilocks debate,Global Strategy Journal, Vol. 2 No. 3, pp. 153-167.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A., Inkpen, A., Musacchio, A. and Ramaswamy, K. (2014), Governments as owners:
State-owned multinational companies,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 45 No. 8,
pp. 919-942.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. and Genc, M. (2008), Transforming disadvantages into advantages: developing-
country MNEs in the least developed countries,Journal of International Business Studies,
Vol. 39 No. 6, pp. 957-979.
Cui, L. and Jiang, F. (2009), FDI entry mode choice of chinese rms: a strategic behavior perspective,
Journal of World Business, Vol. 44 No. 4, pp. 434-444.
Cui, L. and Jiang, F. (2012), State ownership effect on rmsFDI ownership decisions under
institutional pressure: a study of Chinese outward-investing rms,Journal of International
Business Studies, Vol. 43 No. 3, pp. 264-284.
Dau, L.A. (2012), Pro-market reforms and developing country multinational corporations,Global
Strategy Journal, Vol. 2 No. 3, pp. 262-276.
De Beule, F., Somers, D. and Zhang, H. (2018), Who follows whom? A location study of chinese private
and state-owned companies in the european union,Management International Review, Vol. 58
No. 1, pp. 43-84.
Delgado, M., Porter, M.E. and Stern, S. (2014), Clusters, convergence, and economic performance,
Research Policy, Vol. 43 No. 10, pp. 1785-1799.
Demirbag, M., Tatoglu, E. and Glaister, K.W. (2008), Equity-based entry modes of emerging country
multinationals: lessons from turkey,Journal of World Business, Vol. 44 No. 4, pp. 445-462.
Deng, P. (2009), Why do Chinese rms tend to acquire strategic assets in international expansion?,
Journal of World Business, Vol. 44 No. 1, pp. 74-84.
Dikova, D. and Van Witteloostuijn, A. (2007), Foreign direct investment mode choice: entry and
establishment modes in transition economies,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 38
No. 6, pp. 1013-1033.
DiMaggio, P.J. and Powell, W.W. (1983), The iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and
collective rationality in organizational elds,American Sociological Review, Vol. 48 No. 2,
pp. 147-160.
Dimitratos, P., Johnson, J., Slow, J. and Young, S. (2003), Micromultinationals: new types of rms for
the global competitive landscape,European Management Journal, Vol. 21No. 2, pp. 164-174.
Duanmu, J.L. (2012), Firm heterogeneity and location choice of Chinese multinational enterprises
(MNEs),Journal of World Business, Vol. 47 No. 1, pp. 64-72.
Dunning, J.H. (1988), The eclectic paradigm of international production: a restatement and some
possible extensions,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 19 No. 1, pp. 1-31.
Eden, L. and Miller, S.R. (2004), Distance matters: liability of foreignness, institutional distance and
ownership strategy,Theories of the Multinational Enterprise: Diversity, Complexity and
Relevance, Emerald Group PublishingLimited, pp. 187-221.
Erramilli, M.K. and Rao, C.P. (1993), Service rmsinternational entry-mode choice: a modied
transaction-cost analysis approach,Journal of Marketing, pp. 19-38.
Eurostat (2014), Annex 3 High-tech aggregation by NACE Rev. 2, Elaborated in January 2014,
available at: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_SDDS/Annexes/htec_esms_an3.pdf
Fan, D., Cui, L., Li, Y. and Zhu, C.J. (2016), Localized learning by emerging multinational enterprises in
developed host countries: a fuzzy-set analysis of Chinese foreign direct investment in Australia,
International Business Review, Vol. 25 No.1, pp. 187-203.
MBR
Folta, T.B., Cooper, A.C. and Baik, Y.S. (2006), Geographic cluster size and rm performance,Journal
of Business Venturing, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 217-242.
Gatignon, H. and Anderson, E. (1988), The multinational corporations degree of control over foreign
subsidiaries: an empirical test of a transaction cost explanation,The Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, Vol. 4 No. 2, pp. 305-336.
Giuliani, E. (2007), The selective nature of knowledge networks in clusters: evidence from the wine
industry,Journal of Economic Geography, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 139-168.
Globerman, S. and Shapiro, D. (2009), Economic and strategic considerations surrounding Chinese FDI
in the United States,Asia Pacic Journal of Management, Vol. 26 No. 1, pp. 163-183.
Goerzen, A., Asmussen, C.G. and Nielsen, B.B. (2013), Global cities and multinational enterprise
location strategy,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 44 No. 5,pp. 427-450.
Guillen, M.F. (2003), Experience, imitation, and the sequence of foreign entry: wholly owned and joint-
venture manufacturing by South Korean rms and business groups in China, 19871995,
Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 34 No. 2, pp. 185-198.
Gujarati, D.N. (2003), Basic Econometrics, 4th ed., Mcgraw-Hill, New York, NY.
Hair, J.F., Black, W.C., Babin, B.J., Anderson, R.E. and Tatham, R.L. (2006), Multivariate Data Analysis,
6th ed., Pearson Prentice Hall, NJ.
Hanemann, T. and Huotari, M. (2015), Chinese FDI in Europe and Germany. Preparing for a New Era of
Chinese Capital, Mercator Institute for China Studies and Rhodiun Group, Berlin.
He, W. and Lyles, M.A. (2008), Chinas outward foreign direct investment,Business Horizons, Vol. 51
No. 6, pp. 485-491.
Hernandez, E. (2014), Finding a home away from home effects of immigrants on rmsforeign location
choice and performance,Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 59 No. 1,pp. 73-108.
Hymer, S.H. (1960), The international operation of national rms: a study of direct foreign investment,
Doctoral dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Iammarino, S. and McCann, P. (2006), The structure and evolution of industrial clusters: transactions,
technology and knowledge spillovers,Research Policy, Vol. 35 No. 7, pp. 1018-1036.
Jean, R.J.B., Tan, D. and Sinkovics, R.R. (2011), Ethnic ties, location choice, and rm performance in
foreign direct investment: a study of Taiwanese business groups FDI in China,International
Business Review, Vol. 20 No. 6, pp. 627-635.
Johanson, J. and Vahlne, J.E. (1977), The internationalization process of the rm-a model of knowledge
development and increasing foreign market commitments,Journal of International Business
Studies, Vol. 8 No. 1, pp. 23-32.
Johanson, J. and Vahlne, J.E. (2009), The Uppsala internationalization process model revisited: from
liability of foreignness to liability of outsidership,Journal of International Business Studies,
Vol. 40 No. 9, pp. 1411-1431.
Kang, Y. and Jiang, F. (2012), FDI location choice of Chinese multinationals in East and Southeast
Asia: traditional economic factors and institutional perspective,Journal of World Business,
Vol. 47 No. 1, pp. 45-53.
Kim, J.U. and Aguilera, R.V. (2016), Foreign location choice: review and extensions,International
Journal of Management Reviews, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 133-159.
Klossek, A., Linke, B.M. and Nippa, M. (2012), Chinese enterprises in Germany: establishment modes
and strategies to mitigate the liability of foreignness,Journal of World Business, Vol. 47 No. 1,
pp. 35-44.
Kolstad, I. and Wiig, A. (2012), What determines Chinese outward FDI?,Journal of World Business,
Vol. 47 No. 1, pp. 26-34.
Kostova, T. and Zaheer, S. (1999), Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: the case
of the multinational enterprise,The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 24 No. 1,pp. 64-81.
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
Krugman, P. (1991), Increasing returns and economic geography,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99
No. 3, pp. 483-499.
Lazzeretti, L., Sedita, S.R. and Calof, A. (2014), Founders and disseminators of cluster research,
Journal of Economic Geography, Vol. 14 No. 1, pp. 21-43.
Li, J. and Li, Y. (2010), Flexibility versus commitment: MNEsownership strategy in China,Journal of
International Business Studies, Vol. 41 No. 9, pp. 1550-1571.
Liao, T.J. and Yu, C.M.J. (2012), Knowledge transfer, regulatory support, legitimacy, and nancial
performance: the case of foreign rms investing in China,Journal of World Business, Vol. 47
No. 1, pp. 114-122.
Lu, J., Liu, X. and Wang, H. (2011), Motives for outward FDI of Chinese private rms: rm resources,
industry dynamics, and government policies,Management and Organization Review, Vol. 7
No. 2, pp. 223-248.
Luo, Y. and Tung, R.L. (2007), International expansion of emerging market enterprises: a springboard
perspective,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 38 No. 4, pp. 481-498.
McCann, B.T. and Folta, T.B. (2008), Location matters: where we have been and where we might go in
agglomeration research,Journal of Management, Vol. 34 No. 3, pp. 532-565.
McCann, P., Arita, T. and Gordon, I.R. (2002), Industrial clusters, transactions costs and the
institutional determinants of MNE location behaviour,International Business Review, Vol. 11
No. 6, pp. 647-663.
Madhok, A. and Keyhani, M. (2012), Acquisitions as entrepreneurship: asymmetries, opportunities,
and the internationalization of multinationals from emerging economies,Global Strategy
Journal, Vol. 2 No. 1, pp. 26-40.
Makino, S., Lau, C.M. and Yeh, R.S. (2002), Asset-exploitation versus asset-seeking: implications for
location choice of foreign direct investment from newly industrialized economies,Journal of
International Business Studies, Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 403-421.
Mariotti, S., Piscitello, L. and Elia, S. (2010), Spatial agglomeration of multinational enterprises: the role
of information externalities and knowledge spillovers,Journal of Economic Geography, Vol. 10
No. 4, pp. 519-538.
Marshall, A. (1920), Principles of Economics, McMillan, London.
Martin, R. and Sunley, P. (2003), Deconstructing clusters: chaotic concept or policy panacea?,Journal
of Economic Geography, Vol. 3 No. 1, pp. 5-35.
Mesquita, L.F. (2016), Location and the global advantage of rms,Global Strategy Journal, Vol. 6
No. 1, pp. 3-12.
Meyer, K.E., Mudambi, R. and Narula, R. (2011), Multinational enterprises and local contexts: the
opportunities and challenges of multiple embeddedness,Journal of Management Studies,
Vol. 48 No. 2, pp. 235-252.
Meyer, K.E., Estrin, S., Bhaumik, S.K. and Peng, M.W. (2009), Institutions, resources, and entry
strategies in emerging economies,Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 61-80.
Miller, S.R., Thomas, D.E., Eden, L. and Hitt, M. (2008), Knee deep in the big muddy: the survival of
emerging market rms in developed markets,Management International Review, Vol. 48 No. 6,
pp. 645-665.
Nielsen, B.B., Asmussen, C.G. and Weatherall, C.D. (2017), The location choice of foreign direct
investments: empirical evidence and methodological challenges,Journal of World Business,
Vol. 52 No. 1, pp. 62-82.
ODonoghue, D. and Gleave, B. (2004), A note on methods for measuring industrial agglomeration,
Regional Studies, Vol. 38 No. 4, pp. 419-427.
Parr, J.B. (2002), Agglomeration economies: ambiguities and confusions,Environment and Planning
A: Economy and Space, Vol. 34 No. 4, pp. 717-731.
MBR
Peng, M.W., Wang, D.Y. and Jiang, Y. (2008), An institution-based view of international business
strategy: a focus on emerging economies,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 39
No. 5, pp. 920-936.
Porter, M.E. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, The Free Press, New York, NY.
Porter, M.E. (1998), Clusters and the new economics of competition,Harvard Business Review,
November/December, Vol. 76 No. 6, pp. 77-90.
Ramasamy, B., Yeung, M. and Laforet, S. (2012), Chinas outward foreign direct investment: location
choice and rm ownership,Journal of World Business, Vol. 47 No.1, pp. 17-25.
Rugman, A.M. and Verbeke, A. (2004), A perspective on regional and global strategies of multinational
enterprises,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 35 No. 1, pp. 3-18.
Schwens, C., Eiche, J. and Kabst, R. (2011), The moderating impact of informal institutional distance
and formal institutional risk on SME entry mode choice,Journal of Management Studies,
Vol. 48 No. 2, pp. 330-351.
Scott, W.R. (2008), Approaching adulthood: the maturing of institutional theory,Theory and Society,
Vol. 37 No. 5, p. 427.
Scott, W.R. (2002), The changing world of Chinese enterprise: an institutional perspective, The
management of enterprises in the Peoples Republic of China, Springer US, pp. 59-78.
Shaver, J.M. and Flyer, F. (2000), Agglomeration economies, rm heterogeneity, and foreign direct
investment in the United States,Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 21 No. 12, pp. 1175-1194.
Shen, Z. and Puig, F. (2018), Spatial dependence of the FDI entry mode decision: empirical evidence
from emerging market enterprises,Management International Review, Vol. 58 No. 1,
pp. 171-193.
Shuman, J.C. and Seeger, J.A. (1986), The theory and practice of strategic management in smaller rapid
growth rms,American Journal of Small Business, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 7-18.
Siedschlag, I., Smith, D., Turcu, C. and Zhang, X. (2013), What determines the location choice of R&D
activities by multinational rms?,Research Policy, Vol. 42 No. 8, pp. 1420-1430.
Stallkamp, M., Pinkham, B.C., Schotter, A.P. and Buchel, O. (2017), Core or periphery? The effects of
country-of-origin agglomerations on the within-country expansion of MNEs,Journal of
International Business Studies, pp. 1-25.
Tan, D. and Meyer, K.E. (2011), Country-of-origin and industry FDI agglomeration of foreign investors
in an emerging economy,Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 42 No. 4, pp. 504-520.
Tsui-Auch, L.S. and Möllering, G. (2010), Wary managers: unfavorable environments, perceived
vulnerability, and the development of trust in foreign enterprises in China,Journal of
International Business Studies, Vol. 41 No. 6, pp. 1016-1035.
Tung, R.L. (1998), American expatriates abroad: from neophytes to cosmopolitans,Journal of World
Business, Vol. 33 No. 2, pp.125-144.
UNCTAD (2013), Inward and outward foreign direct investment ows, annual, 19702013, available
at: http://unctadstat.unctad.org (accessed 6 August 2014).
Urzelai, B. and Puig, F. (2019), Developing international social capital: the role of communities of
practice and clustering,International Business Review, Vol. 28 No. 2, pp. 209-221.
Wang, L., Madhok, A. and Li, (2014), Agglomerationand clustering over theindustry life cycle:toward
a dynamic model of geographic concentration,Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 35 No. 7,
pp. 995-1012.
Wu, Z., Salomon, R. and Martin, X. (2017), Complex strategic choices: a new approach with an
application to adaptive agglomeration strategies among foreign entrants,Global Strategy
Journal, Vol. 7 No. 3.
Yeung, H.W. and Liu, W. (2008), Globalizing China: the rise of mainland rms in the global economy,
Eurasian Geography and Economics, Vol. 49 No. 1, pp. 57-86.
Investigating
rm
heterogeneity
Zaheer, S. (1995), Overcoming the liability of foreignness,Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 38
No. 2, pp. 341-363.
Zhang, J., Zhou, C. and Ebbers, H. (2011), Completion of Chinese overseas acquisitions: institutional
perspectives and evidence,International Business Review, Vol. 20 No.2, pp. 226-238.
Zhou, N. and Guillen, M.F. (2016), Categorizing the liability of foreignness: ownership, location, and
internalization-specic dimensions,Global Strategy Journal, Vol. 6 No. 4, pp. 309-329.
Zhou, W. (2013), Political connections and entrepreneurial investment: evidence from Chinas
transition economy,Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 28 No. 2, pp. 299-315.
Zschoche, M. (2016), The effects of foreign direct investment colocation: differences between
manufacturing and service rms,Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 37 No. 7,
pp. 447-460.
Further reading
Dunning, J.H. (1998), Location and the multinational enterprise: a neglected factor?,Journal of
International Business Studies, Vol. 29 No. 1, pp. 45-66.
Zaheer, S., Lamin, A. and Subramani, M. (2009), Cluster capabilities or ethnic ties? Location choice by
foreign and domestic entrants in the services offshoring industry in India,Journal of
International Business Studies, Vol. 40 No. 6, pp. 944-968.
Corresponding author
Francisco Puig can be contacted at: francisco.puig@uv.es
For instructions on how to order reprints of this article, please visit our website:
www.emeraldgrouppublishing.com/licensing/reprints.htm
Or contact us for further details: permissions@emeraldinsight.com
MBR
... Second, because it involves different contexts and firms, international business is also heterogeneous, which calls for theorizing that is both suitably general and sufficiently flexible to accommodate diversity in firm decision-making. The dynamism and diversity observed in firm behavior (Puig, Madhok, & Shen, 2020;Santangelo & Meyer, 2017) suggests that internationalization decisions are more complex than current models would predict, partly reflecting different decision-maker experiences, goals and expectations. Also, decisions made in an international context require some level of flexibility as firms inevitably face varying levels of uncertainty and may regularly need to adjust their behavior in different markets (Aharoni, Tihanyi, & Connelly, 2011). ...
... We discuss how, so far, the decision to internationalize is often explained in terms of the push to escape a declining home market and utilize firm-specific advantages. Even so, firm behavior is far less rational than that and much more influenced by individual and firm-level goals (Buckley et al., 2007;Puig et al., 2020). These goals may in turn be heterogeneous across firms and lead to specific aspiration levels which, when not met at a given point in time, may drive a change in firm behavior such as the decision to internationalize. ...
Article
Full-text available
International business (IB) scholars' over-reliance on a select few theories leaves our understanding of firm internationalization incomplete. The behavioral theory of the firm (BTF) can offer new insights and can be used to model a broad range of firm actions. We focus on the three basic BTF components: problemistic search, learning by doing, and vicarious learning. These components help us understand why firm behaviors are more dynamic and heterogeneous than other theories allow. BTF, with its emphasis on how firms assess performance according to aspiration levels, selectively learn and update routines, and selectively incorporate the learning of others, is better suited to examine the diversity and change increasingly observed in internationalization decisions. We explain why scholars should move beyond ''dynamizing'' static theories and show BTF's applicability to behaviors involving change such as multi-mode market entries and market re-entries. BTF also helps examine the decision to internationalize in the first place, nascent firm internationalization, location choices, international market adaptation, and headquarter-subsidiary relationships. We encourage IB scholars to use theories that can handle the complexity increasingly associated with modern firm growth, and propose BTF as a promising starting point. Journal of International Business Studies (2020).
... In explaining the spatial dimensions of MNEs, access to localized knowledge has been cited as one of the critical factors in choosing host locations (Alca´cer et al., 2016). Whilst AC enables the host location to effectively internalize, adopt and integrate the knowledge disseminated by the home country MNE during offshoring, high KC explicitly enables the host location to adopt the SECI process to transfer that knowledge within the firm through the creation of procedures, process flows and formal training, as well as transform old knowledge into new knowledge to produce process, service, or product improvements which create FSAs and CSAs for MNEs (Ferreira et al., 2022;Puig et al., 2019). This is especially relevant to industries whose business models rely on capitalizing internalization advantages through the transformation and efficient use of their strategic business units (SBUs) in a global network (e.g., Shared Services). ...
Article
Full-text available
Plain language summary Whilst traditionally the offshoring spatial dimensions have been largely predictable, the emergence of Covid-19 and technology revolution has significantly altered the playing field. The traditional factors which influenced host location attractiveness in the past may no longer be applicable. There is an impending need to identify the determinants which are relevant and applicable in the new norm. Moreover, despite the intellectual continuity and diversity driving the premise of FDI-foreign location research stream, a comprehensive literature review of location attractiveness is lacking, especially in the context of the new norm. With these in mind, this paper systematically reviews the theoretical and empirical research on FDI location by analyzing 221 articles published between 1999 and 2023, to identify the emerging trends on what makes a location attractive for FDIs by MNEs. Through rigorous content analysis, the emerging themes and trends on locational studies were first identified, and subsequently these were linked to recent global phenomenon (Industry 4.0 led digitalization and disruptive technologies and ripple effects from Covid-19 pandemic) to draw implications on the critical factors which influence host-location attractiveness in the new norm. Based on the review, five key determinants were predicted to have a dominant influence: human capital investment, absorptive capacity, knowledge creation, innovation capability, and ICT infrastructure advancement. These factors can be exploited to create or upgrade competitive advantages in order to amplify host location attractiveness. Future research avenues are also recommended based on the findings from this review.
... As SMEs, by definition, possess more limited resources, their CEOs are constantly involved in decision-making processes (Cortellazzo et al., 2020) over the appropriate allocation of the resources of their SMEs in keeping with what they encounter in the target country (Kraus et al., 2017). The dynamism and diversity reported by analysis of company behaviours when they undertake decisionmaking in international contexts displays their levels of flexibility as companies invariably encounter obstacles, producing the levels of uncertainty that mean managers need to regularly realign their behaviours for diverse and different international markets (Puig et al., 2020). ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose This study aims to obtain insights based on empirical evidence that identify the key drivers and obstacles that lead companies to (re)/enter markets and distinguish the different paths SMEs take. This also provides deeper insights into internationalisation, success, failure and the potential for the re-internationalisation of the SMEs. Design/methodology/approach The authors used a qualitative research methodology based on six case studies and with recourse to semi-structured interviews with the senior managers of exporting SMEs. Findings The results report that SMEs with major investments deployed in their internationalisation processes, through recourse to high levels of bank financing, in association with the COVID-19 pandemic period, were not able to successfully overcome the process of internationalisation and culminating in their own bankruptcies. Originality/value This study shows how, despite such failures, the attractiveness and reputation of the brand, supported by the strategic vision and perseverance of new investors (entrepreneurs), enabled the rebirth of the brands and opening the door to their re-entering international markets.
... Our main contribution is to the literatures on the D-P relationship and home-country governance by providing robust evidence of how formal institutional quality impacts the efficacy of related and unrelated diversification. Prior research on home-country governance has considered its effects on firms' strategy and organization, including rates of internationalization (Luo and Tung, 2007), location decisions (Puig et al., 2019), capital structures (Li et al., 2011), headquarter-subsidiary relationships (Singh et al., 2016), practice adoption (Kostova and Roth, 2002), corporate social performance (Tashman et al., 2019), as well as firms' financial performance (Bell et al., 2012). We extend research in this area by demonstrating that related diversification becomes increasingly rational relative to unrelated diversification when firms hail from countries with stronger formal institutions. ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose The authors meta-analyze research on the diversification–performance relationship to empirically establish the impact of home-country formal institutional quality on this relationship. Prior research assumes that a country’s formal institutional quality negatively affects the diversification–performance relationship, especially when it involves unrelated diversification. However, empirical evidence for these propositions is inconclusive because existing studies consider blocks of countries with limited institutional heterogeneity. To provide more clarity, this study aims to consider the diversification–performance relationship across developed, emerging and developing countries. Design/methodology/approach The meta-analysis relies on a sample of 293 effect sizes of the diversification–performance relationship from 76 primary studies across 15 countries between 1988 and 2019. The sample excludes effects sizes from papers that consider both product and international diversification to control for complex interactions between the strategies, as well as papers that did not consider both related and unrelated diversification. Findings The results confirm that stronger home-country formal institutions weaken the diversification–performance relationship by decreasing the relative efficiency of internal markets versus external ones. Further, the effect is less negative for related diversification because this strategy can better exploit market frictions in countries with stronger formal institutions and more efficient external markets than its unrelated counterpart. Originality/value The study contributes to the literatures on the diversification–performance relationship and home-country governance by providing robust evidence for how formal institutional quality impacts the efficacy of related and unrelated diversification.
... Furthermore, we also found that extant studies and theories offer little insights into how innovation helps firms adjust and sustain their ID post market entry. Internationalized firms are thought to act and behave flexibly, resulting in idiosyncratic, diverse and dynamic firm behaviours (Hermans & Reyes, 2020;Puig, Madhok & Shen, 2020). Indeed, many firms use multiple entry modes simultaneously, exit and even re-enter foreign markets as well as form seemingly unconventional strategic alliances (Bamford, Baynham & Ernst, 2020;Surdu, Greve & Benito, 2020). ...
Article
We conduct a systematic review of the relationship between international diversification (ID) and firm-level innovation (I), considering articles published between 1989 and 2020. The relationship between international diversification and innovation strategies is dynamic and complex, and recent evidence challenges the traditional notion that upgrading firm-specific advantages through technological innovation can be sufficient to guarantee international firm growth and performance. We develop a unified framework that integrates findings from extant ID-I research while also proposing new avenues for further research on topics such as: how firms deal with potentially conflicting ID-I goals, how underlying firm motives shape the interactions between these goals, and how new technologies and institutional dynamism increasingly influence the ID-I relationship. We also discuss how and why the new contexts in which decisions are made, together with the prevalence of relatively newer types of firms (e.g., those associated with global value chains, latest wave of emerging market multinationals, digitalized service MNEs), require a more modern conceptualization of the ID-I relationship.
... Furthermore, we also found that extant studies and theories offer little insights into how innovation helps firms adjust and sustain their ID post market entry. Internationalized firms are thought to act and behave flexibly, resulting in idiosyncratic, diverse and dynamic firm behaviours (Hermans & Reyes, 2020;Puig, Madhok, & Shen, 2020). Indeed, many firms use multiple entry modes simultaneously, exit and even re-enter foreign markets as well as form seemingly unconventional strategic alliances (Bamford, Baynham, & Ernst, 2020;Surdu, Greve, & Benito, 2020). ...
... Furthermore, location decisions are also contingent on firm-specific internal aspects regarding governance structures, business models, dependencies due to existing locations, ownership structures and the endowment with capabilities (Puig et al., 2019;Verbeke et al., 2016). For example, collocating a new facility with or relocating an existing foreign production site to the home market where other value chain activities of the same firm are already situated may be beneficial due to knowledge spillovers, advantages from internal labor markets, access to specialized suppliers, better control and superior coordination. ...
Article
Purpose This paper aims to investigate the strategic consequences of manufacturing location decisions, with a focus on understanding the link between collocating manufacturing with other value chain activities, via reshoring or retaining and organizational agility. Design/methodology/approach The paper uses qualitative data from 115 interviews with executives from UK high value manufacturing companies to explore the recent phenomenon of reshoring and the strategic effects of manufacturing location. Findings The location of manufacturing is operationally and strategically important for multinational companies. The spatial dispersion of manufacturing is determined by firm-specific and external factors, both of which are subject to constant change. The analysis shows that concentrating on manufacturing in their home countries enables firms to increase organizational agility and stimulate innovation. Better integration with and more extensive collaboration between related value chain activities, such as research and development, sales and marketing, leads to higher flexibility, speed and responsiveness to customer requirements. However, under certain conditions, firms also continue to benefit from the known advantages of offshoring. Originality/value This research sheds light on possible strategic downsides of global value chains, characterized by dispersed activities and intermitted processes. The results provide evidence that retaining manufacturing or bringing back manufacturing operations to a company’s home country can increase organizational flexibility, speed, adaptability, innovativeness and responsiveness to customer requirements. As these capabilities are critical for long-term survival, especially in dynamic environments, firms need to review their global factory configurations and determine whether the short-term advantages of foreign locations continue to justify offshoring practices.
Article
Full-text available
Os clusters empresariais são reconhecidos como motores do crescimento econômico regional, podendo proporcionar muitas vantagens, como acesso à inovação, especialização dos processos, dentre outras. Um dos primeiros passos para fomentar o desenvolvimento dos clusters é identificá-los, deste modo esta pesquisa tem como objetivo identificar de forma quantitativa os principais aglomerados presentes no Estado do Piauí. A metodologia consistiu na adaptação de procedimentos de trabalhos anteriores que utilizaram o índice de quociente locacional e algumas variáveis de controle para a identificação de aglomerados. Como principais resultados destacam-se que apenas 9% dos municípios do Piauí possuem algum tipo de aglomerado empresarial, e que a capital, Teresina, não apontou vocações com classificação elevada, apesar de ter 42 aglomerados com classificação reduzida, mostrando diversificação em seus aglomerados. Na capital o setor de atividades de atenção à saúde humana possui alta relevância por conter o maior quantitativo de vínculos empregatícios e de empresas, além de apresentar um alto nível de crescimento.
Article
This paper takes micro-level evidence as the basis on which to investigate to what extent firms' heterogeneity is relevant in the internationalization strategy and location choice of European multinational enterprises. We present a model that illustrates how the firm's decision to enter a specific destination to serve all markets globally will depend on the firm attributes related to its efficiency, given the characteristics of the host countries. Our empirical results from a set of multinomial and sequential logistic models confirm that (i) European firms investing in third markets outside Europe are more productive than those that only produce at home and export. For some regions and sectors, they are also more R&D intensive and innovative, and have higher labor skills. In addition, our estimates reveal that (ii) the location choice of their affiliates is mainly defined by differences in productivity and, in some cases, in R&D intensity and innovation.
Article
Full-text available
 This study investigates the effect of state ownership on Chinese firms’ foreign direct investment (FDI) ownership decisions. It adopts a political perspective to extend the application of institutional theory in international business research. Specifically, it examines firms’ heterogeneous responses to external institutional processes during foreign market entry, while taking into consideration the political affiliation of firms with the external institutions. We argue that state ownership creates the political affiliation of a firm with its home-country government, which increases the firm’s resource dependence on home country institutions, while at the same time influencing its image as perceived by host-country institutional constituents. Such resource dependence and political perception increase firms’ tendency to conform to, rather than resist, isomorphic institutional pressures.
Article
Full-text available
The entry mode and location choices are two fundamental decisions made by firms after they decide to proceed with foreign direct investment (FDI). In previous studies, these two strategic concerns have usually been studied separately as independent decisions. Following recent claims, we extend beyond the macro-environment of the host country or geographical space to study the interdependence between these two decisions by comparing the effects of two different colocation strategies on the establishment mode and ownership structure of investors in FDI. We tested our hypotheses based on a sample of 162 Chinese-owned subsidiaries in Germany and found spatial dependence in the entry mode strategies, where the existing theories regarding ownership structure prediction for the sampled firms had limited explanatory power. We also observed that the experience of investors had a negative moderating effect on these interactions. Our results suggest the following: (1) the FDI strategies of foreign investors consider conditions that vary among countries as well as within the host economy and place; (2) the entry mode and location choices can be alternative strategies for overcoming barriers to entry in FDIs where a trade-off between both is required; and (3) more efforts are still needed to interpret the FDI behaviors of investors from emerging economies.
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyses the location decision of Chinese manufacturing firms for their greenfield investments in Europe. The analysis draws on neo-institutional theory to formulate hypotheses on the importance of mimicry in Chinese firms’ location decisions and how this differs between private and state-owned enterprises. The analysis is conducted at the subnational (regional) level while taking into account economic integration across regions. The results confirm the importance of mimicry and show that Chinese firms not only follow previous Chinese investors in the same sector but also in unrelated sectors. Furthermore, Chinese investors only follow previous investments by Chinese private-owned companies while the results also show that Chinese private-owned companies generally have a higher tendency than state-owned companies do to follow prior investment decisions by compatriot firms. As the empirical evidence demonstrates the importance of bandwagon effects, the implication is that investment decisions can have a lasting influence on the geographical pattern of Chinese investments across regions.
Article
Full-text available
We show how the initial subnational entry location of foreign multinational enterprises (MNEs) in China influences their subsequent within-country location choices and expansion speed. We distinguish between MNEs that establish their first subsidiary in co-ethnic cores – dense agglomerations of other firms from the same country of origin – and MNEs that locate their first subsidiary in the periphery, i.e., outside of these co-ethnic cores. To identify co-ethnic cores in China, we employ a geo-visualization methodology, which draws the boundaries of cores organically and dynamically over time. We contrast our findings with the prevailing approach of using static administrative boundaries for identifying agglomerations. Our results provide evidence of path dependency, in that (a) entry through subnational locations with strong co-ethnic communities is followed by expansion into other locations where co-ethnic communities are present, and that (b) entry through co-ethnic communities accelerates the pace at which MNEs establish additional subsidiaries in China. We also find that co-ethnic community effects continue to influence within-country MNE activities over time, despite a host of economic, institutional, and investment developments. Journal of International Business Studies (2017): http://link.springer.com/article/10.1057/s41267-016-0060-x/fulltext.html
Article
This study investigates the effect of state ownership on Chinese firms’ foreign direct investment (FDI) ownership decisions. It adopts a political perspective to extend the application of institutional theory in international business research. Specifically, it examines firms’ heterogeneous responses to external institutional processes during foreign market entry, while taking into consideration the political affiliation of firms with the external institutions. We argue that state ownership creates the political affiliation of a firm with its home-country government, which increases the firm’s resource dependence on home country institutions, while at the same time influencing its image as perceived by host-country institutional constituents. Such resource dependence and political perception increase firms’ tendency to conform to, rather than resist, isomorphic institutional pressures.
Article
One criteria regarding where to invest in foreign markets is linked to the international social capital (ISC) that exists on the place, which enables the access to local knowledge and other location-specific advantages. There are alternative ways to create and make use of that ISC that are still unexplored by International Business literature. In this paper, we study the geographic communities of practice (CoP) that are formed by FDI firms from the same country-of-origin (the so-called country-of-origin clusters). For that purpose, the paper adopts a qualitative methodological approach through an inductive case study of expatriates from 13 Spanish subsidiaries co-located in China. Our findings suggest that there are particular mechanisms based on the informal connections and repeated interactions facilitated by a common language and non-competitive relationships that create an ISC in the CoP. Moreover, our analysis shows there is a heterogeneity in the way these mechanisms are developed and used by the member firms, and this is due to organizational and individual factors, as well as leadership dynamics. Our work contributes to Internationalization and Network theories by identifying unexplored mechanisms through which the ISC is developed at the host country level. Besides, it helps identifying competences (i.e. clustering competences) that help expatriate managers to be successful in their international assignments.
Article
Research summary In this study, we introduce a new statistical technique to the field of strategy that accounts for complex interrelated decisions. The technique is meant for situations in which one strategic decision depends critically upon another—e.g., where companies must commit to one decision before making another. We demonstrate the value of the technique in the context of companies choosing countries in which to invest, followed by areas within those countries in which to locate their facilities. We then describe the generic benefits of the statistical technique, offer guidance for how to use it, and provide the programming code so that others can implement it. We explain how the technique is particularly well suited to problems in which companies must decide between multiple options and the sample size is small relative to the number of initial options. Managerial summary Research in strategy and international business has increasingly adopted two‐stage models to account for endogeneity. Established approaches, however, deal most effectively with problems characterized by binary first‐stage models. We introduce an alternative that allows for multiple choices in the first stage. We use the technique to examine the agglomeration patterns of foreign firms, while accounting for country selection. We find that, conditional on country selection, foreign firms tend to agglomerate in host countries characterized by collectivist cultures, political uncertainty, and economic uncertainty. The results imply that host country characteristics exert a strong influence on the agglomeration preferences of foreign firms. We provide guidance on when to use the empirical estimation technique and furnish details of the estimation procedure so that others can apply the technique to a broader class of selection problems. Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society.
Article
The choice of location of foreign direct investments (FDI) by multinational enterprises (MNEs) has been the subject of intense scrutiny for decades and continues to be so. Yet, the vast diversity in methodological approaches, levels of analysis, and empirical evidence precludes a comprehensive understanding of the phenomenon. We review and evaluate 153 quantitative studies on FDI location choice over four decades from 1976 to 2015 across multiple disciplines, including international business, management, economics, urban and regional studies, and economic geography. Our review provides a comprehensive analysis of the empirical evidence and methodological implications to guide future empirical research on FDI location choice.
Article
Plain language summary We investigate whether listed state‐owned enterprises (SOEs) benefit more from internationalization than listed private enterprises. We argue that SOEs have a greater scope for benefitting from internationalization because of their previous domestic focus and because of government‐related firm‐specific advantages they can utilize for their internationalization. In listed SOEs, these factors may matter more than noneconomic objectives and corporate governance deficiencies that could reduce SOEs' economic benefits from internationalization. Empirical analysis on a sample of listed Norwegian firms provides modest support for the hypotheses. There is no indication that state ownership reduces the benefits of internationalization. Technical summary We consider state ownership as a moderator of the relationship between internationalization and performance in listed firms, developing theoretical arguments on the scope for benefits from internationalization, corporate governance, and government‐related firm‐specific advantages. We propose hypotheses on a positive moderation effect from state ownership overall and on more positive effects in majority state‐owned enterprises (SOEs) than in minority SOEs, on more positive effects in SOEs previously part of the government administration, and on more positive effects from market‐seeking internationalization than from efficiency or resource‐seeking internationalization. Panel data analyses considering listed Norwegian firms (2000 to 2010) provide modest support for the hypotheses. Copyright © 2016 Strategic Management Society.