Content uploaded by Abdul Bashir
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Abdul Bashir on Jun 26, 2020
Content may be subject to copyright.
Available via license: CC BY-SA
Content may be subject to copyright.
SIJDEB, Vol 3(1), 2019, 134-145
p-ISSN: 2581-2904, e-ISSN: 2581-2912
DOI: https://doi.org/10.29259/sijdeb.v3i2.134-145
SRIWIJAYA INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF DYNAMIC
ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS
Indonesia’s Economic Growth Forecasting
Muhammad Teguh1 and Abdul Bashir2*
1,2Faculty of Economics, Universitas Sriwijaya
1muhammadteguh@fe.unsri.ac.id; 2abd.bashir@unsri.ac.id
Abstract: The high economic growth is very important for Indonesia to accelerate the
development process at this period. Although, the growth rate was reached at 5.17 % in
2018 is likely high enough, some domestic economists even point out, it really can be raised
to a higher level. This research tries to investigate and formulate again Indonesia’s
economic growth rate in 2018 and forecast it for 2019. By doing analysis recent real GDP
data by industrial origin and by type of expenditures, and also consider all of the available
potential economic resources, this research shows that Indonesia’s economic growth rate
could stand at 6.03 % in 2018 and also at 6.03 % in 2019. Anyway, the government need a
good economic plan and consistently performing appropriate strategies which are suited to
targets in order to have rapid and stable economic growth rate.
Keywords: Economic Growth, Forecasting, Indonesian Economy
Introduction
When we talk about the social and economic welfare of people of a nation, one important
aspect of actual topics must be discussed is a discussion about an economic growth rate
which can be reached by a country. It is reasonable why all of the countries in the world
like positive economic growth rates, and even now most of developing countries put a
priority on a high economic growth rate over others to develop their economy (Soebyakto
& Bashir, 2017). Economic growth rate reflects economic performance which can be
reached in the process of economic development, a rapid growth rate means a large GDP,
and hence increasing the social and economic welfare of people.
Economic growth deals with an increase in the level of GDP. As economist Sen (2017)
points out, economic growth is one aspect of the process of economic development. That
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
*!Corresponding author!
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
135
growth causes development because some of the increase in income gets spent on human
development factors. Economic growth benefiting human development, since economic
growth is likely to lead families and individuals to use their heightened incomes to increase
expenditures, which in turn furthers human development. At the same time, with the
increased consumption and spending, health, education, and infrastructure systems grow
and contribute to economic growth.
Although, it is not always true, when we compare between economic growth rates in
developing countries with economic growth rates in developed countries. Recently, many
developed countries have low economic growth rates, for examples: Japan and South
Korea, both of them have low economic growth rates at 0.5 % and 2.6 % in 2015. A
possible answer to that problem, that they have different stages of economic development
with each other. Formerly, the real national income of Japan was 5.4 times as large in 1973
as it was in 1953 (Lipsey & Chrystal, 2015). During this period, Japan’s economic growth
rate was more than double the average rate in the 10 major North American and European
countries. Korea also has experienced rapid growth in the quarter century, and it
increasingly rivals Japan in the world market for many manufactured goods. From 1960
through 1985, growth in Korea was even faster than in Japan; real per capita GNP in
Korea rose 12% of the U.S. level to 31%, while in Japan it rose from 33 to 77%.
Economic growth is a phenomenon of market productivity and rises in GDP. As far as we
know, most developing countries have a lot of unemployed resources can be used up in
production, which in turn furthers economic growth. The People’s Republic of China
(RRC) is one interesting example of most of the available examples, its economic growth
rates stood at 10.6 % in 2010, 7.0 % in 2014 and 6.9 % in 2015. But, Indonesia is likely
different from RRC. Compared to RRC, real GDP in Indonesia grew lower, which only
rose 6.1 % in 2010, 5.0 % in 2014 and 4.8% in 2015 than in RRC. However, Indonesia
abundantly has unemployed resources, such as available natural resources, and a high
unemployment rate could be used to accelerate the economic development process.
Besides that it also has a potential market to absorb output will be supplied in the market.
Moreover, Indonesia previously ever had rapid economic growth rates in the period of
Orde Baru’s regime. That’s logic, why some of the domestic economists Ramli (1998) and
(Gie, 2006) they want Indonesia also to have rapid economic growth rates likes had by
RRC. Therefore, this paper tries to investigate and formulate again Indonesia’s economic
growth rate, mainly in 2018 and forecast it in 2019.
Literature Review
As economists Meier & Rauch (2005) point out, economic development is the process of
the increase in real national income of a nation for a long period (Meier & Rauch, 2005). If
the increase in the level of economic development is larger than the increase in the level of
population, it increases real income per capita. The increase in national output does not
only reflect final results, but it also brings structural changes in supply factors and demand
factors.
The theory of economic growth is a long-run theory. It ignores short-run fluctuations of
actual national income around potential income and concentrates on the effects of an
investment in raising potential income (Lipsey & Chrystal, 2015). In the short-run, any
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
136
activity that puts income into people’s hands will raise aggregate demand. Thus, the short-
run effect on national income is the same whether a firm invests in digging holes and
refilling them or in building a new factory. The long growth of potential income, however,
is affected only by the part of the investment that adds to the nation’s productive capacity,
by the factory but not by the refilled hole.
Similar observations are true of public-sector expenditure. Any expenditure will add to
aggregate demand and raise national income if there are unemployed resources, but only
some expenditure adds to the growth of full-employment income. Public-investment
expenditure that shores up a declining industry in order to create employment may have an
adverse effect on growth. Such expenditure may prevent the reallocation of resources in
response to shifts both in the pattern of world demand and in the country’s comparative
advantage. Thus, in the long run, the country’s capacity to produce commodities that are
demanded on open market may be diminished. It also happens in savings. Higher savings
are necessary for higher investment. In the long run, there is no paradox of thrift; Societies
with high savings rates have high investment rates, other things being equal, high levels of
real income.
As economist Sen (2017) points out, economic growth is one aspect of the process of
economic development. That growth causes development because some of the increase in
income gets spent on human development factors. As economist Ranis points out, the first
chain consists of economic growth benefiting human development, since economic growth
is likely to lead families and individuals to use their heightened incomes to increase
expenditures, which in turn furthers human development. At the same time, with the
increased consumption and spending, health, education, and infrastructure systems grow
and contribute to economic growth.
To support economic development runs smoothly, the government must appropriately
apply economic policies. It is important to government increases the level of real GDP
going rapid from time to time. Indonesia ever has experienced slowdown economic growth
(Soebyakto & Bashir, 2017). The legacy of promoting investment under protective barriers
and insulation from competition became more apparent in the early-1980s following the
collapse of oil prices (Bhattacharya & Pangestu, 1992). The government’s initial response
was to protect the industrial sector further through a proliferation of NTBs. Capital
productivity fell sharply during 1982-85 as did the rate of return on investment (from 31.4
% in 1973-81 to 13.1% in 1982-85). Following the reforms of the mid-1980s, there has
been a turnaround in productivity and efficiency indicators. ICOR levels have fallen
steadily as more as labour-intensive export industries have emerged as the engine of
growth. The decline in Total Factor Productivity (TFP), -2.5 in 1982-85 and -1.1 in 1985-
87, was reversed and the level of TFP growth in 1988-91(2.2) was matched only by the
performance during the 1967-73 period (2.1).
As economist Sundrum (1988) points out, since 1981, when oil prices fell and government
revenues declined, the government has been trying to reduce its expenditures (Sundrum,
1988). This was the result of a balanced budget policy of adjusting expenditures to equal
expected receipts. This was also the advice the government was being given by
international economic agencies, such as the International Monetary Fund and World
Bank. The reason for advocating this policy was that a reduction in aggregate demand was
necessary to reduce the level of import. Those policies were not very effective in 1982 and
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
137
1983, when the domestic budget deficit and the level of investments remained high. The
result was that import continued to come in at a high rate, leading to a large increase in the
current account deficit. This deficit was largely financed by foreign borrowing, thereby
increasing the debt service obligations in future years. Because of the deterioration balance
of payments situation, there was a substantial devaluation of rupiah in late 1983, which
proved quite effective in reducing import in 1984. But even with this fall in imports, there
continued to be a large deficit in the current account. Therefore, the government continued
with its contractive policy, which reduced investment in 1985 and the domestic budget
deficit in 1986.
However, Indonesia has experienced rapid economic growth rates in the early part of the
Orde Baru regime. One of the most important economic policies was performed by the
government is a five-year plan of development. Total reforms were conducted by the
government, the most famous real sector policies, such as BIMAS and INMAS Packages,
they were introduced to the agriculture sector in order to increase output in this sector
(Mccawley, 2013). The government also performed monetary reforms, one of the most
famous monetary policies, such as tightened money policy by cutting money to lower
inflation rate. Another important one of monetary policies is regulating again the main
function of the bank to loan credit to the private sector by reducing financing funds to the
government’s expenditures. Following totally reforms of the early part of Orde Baru
increased economic growth rapidly.
Many economists have developed their theories to study how many outputs will be
produced in the economy. One of the most famous theories is a Theory of Production
which was written by Cobb and Douglas. Both of them studied American Economy, their
production function in a mathematical analysis written as follows:
P=b.L!.C!!!,
where b is independent of L and C and (to fix the ideas) k is supposed constant and equal
¾ (Solow, 1956). By using data 1899-1922, they found American production function, as
follows:
P!=1.01.L!/!C!/!
where L is labor and C is capital. From that equation, by using the elasticity of the product
with respect to small changes in labor and capital, we can estimate the economic growth
rate.
As economist Branson (2005) points out, there is a relationship between output elasticity to
relative shares (Branson, 2005). First, they should be recognized as the elasticity of output
with respect to changes in input (ȵK and ȵL). The second interesting interpretation follows
if we assume the competitive pricing of factor inputs. For example, with competitive
pricing, the real wage rate w is equal to marginal of labor ӘF/ӘL. If this is the case, ȵL also
gives the labor share of output, as follows:
!=
ӘF
ӘL
.
L
Q
=
W
Q
=Labor share,
From the output equation (Q = ȵK K + ȵL L), we can compute output growth. A long
trend in the U.S. economy, capital stock, and output are growing at about 3.5%, and the
labor force is growing at about 1.5%, then the labor share of national income is about 75%,
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
138
and the capital share is about 25%, then an explained output growth of (0.25 (0.035) +
0.75(0.015) is 0.02 (Branson, 2005).
Another economic growth model comes from (Harrod, 1939) and Domar (1946). The
Harrod-Domar Model use capital coefficient (ơ = Y/K) to estimate the economic growth
rate (Glassburner & Aditiawan, 1982), is written as follows:
∆Y= σ.∆K
This model states that output will rise if capital (K) rises if is stable, output growth (∆Y).
Methods
To answer a research problem which formerly has been stated, this research using
secondary data consists of quantitative data and qualitative data. The main sources of data
used in this research come from some Indonesia Financial Statistics books which were
reported by the Bank of Indonesia and some Indonesia Statistics books which were
reported by the Central Bureau of Statistics Indonesia. The main period of observed data is
the period 2010-2018. Other data sources come from some articles and books were written
by some selected economists. In this research, the method used with a quantitative
approach by applying trend analysis and we also compute rates of economic growth (∆Y)
using a usual method, which can be written as follows:
Y= α+β!
To find the value of α can be formulated in the following equation:
α=
Y!
n
and to find the value of β can be formulated in the following equation:
β=
t!Y!
t!
!
Where: α is the intercept Y, which is the estimate of the value of Y when t = 0 (the y-axis
cutting line) β is the slope of the line, namely the change in the average Y for each increase
of one unit t; and 𝑡 is the value/code selected.
Furthermore, to calculate forecast errors are usually used Mean Absolute Percentage Error
(MAPE), while the MAPE formula is presented in the following equation (Sorogho, 2017):
MAPE =(X!−F!)!
nx 100%
where Xi is observation value to t; Fi is forecast value to t; and n is number of observations.
∆Y=
Y!
Y!!!
−1
where n is exhibits years of observed time.
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
139
That formula explains to us that the variety of growth rates depend on the variety of Y
(real GDP) from time to time. In this research, we also use another method, which follows
the concept of output elasticity’s and relative shares, which consists of, first, studying
existing data to be evaluated, such as available real GDP data by industrial origin and type
of expenditures. At the same time, this research also studies available data regarding
economic resources relate to existing GDP data in order to find out a lot of information
get used in the next step; second, set growth rates target for every observation of GDP
data. Finally, use this following method to find out economic growth, which can be written
as followed:
G!=(η!g!+η!g!+ ...+η!g!)
where GY is economic growth rate; ȵ is exhibits relative share; g is exhibits growth targets;
(1…n) exhibits observed sectors or observed expenditures.
Findings
We can see Indonesia’s annual economic growth from year to year as shown by Figure 1.
That table shows that Indonesia ever has a highly economic growth for some years.
Indonesia’s economic growth reached more than 6 % in the years of observation, 2011 and
2012. After those years, Indonesia experienced slow economic growth and reached only by
4.88 % in 2015. Indonesia experienced slowdown economic growth for that year.
Figure 1. Annual Indonesia’s Economic Growth Rates, 1985-2018 (%)
Source: World Bank (2017) World Development Indicator (Author calculation)
The slowdown economic growth also has been experienced by Indonesia in the decade of
the Orde Baru during. Sundrum (1988) reports that the slowdown Indonesia’s economic
growth had been existing in 1975 and 1978, the economic growth reached only at 2.9 %
and 4.78% (at 1983 constant prices) or -0.33% and 2.24 % (at 1973 constant prices) in
1982. Indonesia also has experienced the real slowdown economic growth in the period
1981-1986 which it grew 2.89% per annum. It became worse continuously until the fallen
down of Soeharto’s regime, which Indonesia’s economic growth only reached at 4.6% in
1997, and sharply declined reached at -13,2 % in 1998 (Figure 1). After the economic
meltdown (Johnson, 1998) was disappeared, Indonesia turned back to have some positive
economic growth numbers, although they grew slowly.
-15.00
-10.00
-5.00
0.00
5.00
10.00
15.00
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Economic Growth (%)
year on year
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
140
In spite of that, Indonesia has ever experienced a highly economic growth rate. Mccawley
(2013) yearly Indonesia’s economic growth reached at 6% per annum in the period of
1965-1971, and 7 % per annum in the period of 1971-1971. Djojohadikusumo (1989) also
reports, Indonesia’s economic growth rate reached at 7.7 % per annum (Pelita I), 6.9% per
annum (Pelita II) and 6.1% per annum (Pelita III). Indonesia also reached a highly
economic growth rate at 7.5% (1995) and 8.2% (1995) which happened before the
economic crisis (Figure 1).
From those various data shown above, we can conclude that the condition of the economy
depends on not only the existing real and potential market but also an adequate
governmental intervention in the economy by a good plan and controlled actions. It is logic
when some domestic economist argued that Indonesia’s economic growth rate should have
gone faster. Moreover, Indonesia could not efficiently produce output, with ICOR 7.8
during 1982-85, 5.3 during 1985-87, and 3.7 during 1988-91 (Bhattacharya & Pangestu,
1992), it also decreased continuously, by 3.5 in 2016 to 2.6 in 2017, and 2.4 in 2018
(tabulated data).
In addition, Indonesia potentially still can produce national output more. As far as we
know, Indonesia has under capacity production processes until now. Therefore, by
implementing a good plan and using unemployed resources optimally, we can improve
Indonesia’s economic performance, and make the next Indonesia’s economic growth going
faster than before.
Table 1. Actual and estimated GDP by industrial origin and its growth rate
No
Industrial Origin
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Growth
(%)
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Growth
(%)
2017
2018
2017-2018
2018
2017-2018
1
Agriculture, forestry and fishery
1,57,876
1,307,026
3.91
1,307,026
3.91
2
Mining and quarrying
779,678
796,505
2.16
796,505
2.16
3
Manufacturing
2,103,466
2,278,474
8.32
2,193,266
4.27
4
Electricity and gas supply
101,551
107,109
5.47
107,109
5.47
5
Water supply, sewerage, waste
management and remediation
activities
7,986
8,422
5.46
8,422
5.46
6
Construction
987,925
1,048,083
6.09
1,048,083
6.09
7
Wholesale & retail trades, repair of
motor vehicles and motorcycles
1,311,763
1,376,937
4.97
1,376,937
4.97
8
Transport and storage
406,679
435,185
7.01
435,185
7.01
9
Accommodation and food service
activities
298,079
314,955
5.66
314,955
5.66
10
Information and communication
503,421
538,875
7.04
538,875
7.04
11
Financial and insurance services
398,959
415,579
4.17
415,579
4.17
12
Real estate activities
289,730
300,107
3.58
300,107
3.58
13
Business services
172,764
187,691
8.64
187,691
8.64
14
Public administration and defence;
compulsory social security
326,571
349,507
7.02
349,507
7.02
15
Education
304,762
321,084
5.36
321,084
5.36
16
Human health and social work
activities
109,504
117,315
7.13
117,315
7.13
17
Other services activities
170,177
185,469
8.99
185,469
8.99
18
Gross value added at basic price
9,530,892
10,088,321
5.85
10,003,114
4.95
19
Taxes less subsides on products
381,812
422,203
10.58
422,203
10.58
Gross Domestic Product
9,912,704
10,510,524
6.03
10,425,316
5.17
Source: Bank of Indonesia (2018), Bank Indonesia (Author calculation)
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
141
Table 1 shows us about Indonesia’s economic performances, using real GDP by industrial
origin. In the year of observation, 2018 Indonesia has GDP at 2010 constant prices
Rp.10,425,316 billion, and its economic growth rate reached at 5.17 %. If we want to have
a higher economic growth rate, for an example; 6.03 %, it would happen, of course, should
have a better economic plan and controlled actions. We could have an economic growth
rate reached at 6.03% if everything we did going well.
There are some factors have to be considered. First of all, identifying all of the available
economic resources we have. Please choose some alternative potential economic resources
from available potential resources, one or more can be chosen, and it all depends on the
results of the evaluation. After that, doing an examination on them to be used optimally.
Third, making economic growth targets from selected posts of GDP by industrial origins
should be repaired. Fourth, by using a selected method we have, we can measure all of the
estimated economic growth numbers. Of course, will have many home works should be
done later. The government should make a better plan and controlled actions to be
implemented, by using the best strategies, in order to make output by industrial origin can
run faster according to determined targets. From this point, a real sector and a monetary
sector must walk hand in hand together, and the monetary sector must guarantee real
sector can grow well.
In our examples presented, we just push the manufacturing sector growing faster at 8.32%
instead of at 4.27%. As a result, Indonesia’s economic growth rate can reach 6.03 %. A
Well planned economy enables output by sectors are able to grow faster whenever
increased investment and output. It means that the real sector growing faster and at the
same time the monetary sector guarantees investment and production process running well.
We can also hope the manufacturing sector grows at 13.3 % per annum as like as occurred
in The Orde Baru regime during 1971-1977, by implementing a good economic plan.
However, we have to be careful to determine growth rate targets, it all logically must be
considered.
Table 2. Estimated GDP by industrial origin and its growth rate, in 2018 and 2019
No
Industrial Origin
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Growth
(%)
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Growth
(%)
2017
2018
2017-2018
2019
2018-2019
1
Agriculture, forestry and fishery
1,257,876
1,307,026
3.91
1,358,096
3.91
2
Mining and quarrying
779,678
796,505
2.16
813,695
2.16
3
Manufacturing
2,103,466
2,278,474
8.32
2,468,043
8.32
4
Electricity and gas supply
101,551
107,109
5.47
112,970
5.47
5
Water supply, sewerage, waste
management and remediation
activities
7,986
8,422
5.46
8,881
5.46
6
Construction
987,925
1,048,083
6.09
1,111,904
6.09
7
Wholesale & retail trades, repair of
motor vehicles and motorcycles
1,311,763
1,376,937
4.97
1,445,351
4.97
8
Transport and storage
406,679
435,185
7.01
465,689
7.01
9
Accommodation and food service
activities
298,079
314,955
5.66
332,786
5.66
10
Information and communication
503,421
538,875
7.04
576,825
7.04
11
Financial and insurance services
398,959
415,579
4.17
432,891
4.17
12
Real estate activities
289,730
300,107
3.58
310,855
3.58
13
Business services
172,764
187,691
8.64
203,908
8.64
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
142
No
Industrial Origin
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Growth
(%)
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Growth
(%)
2017
2018
2017-2018
2019
2018-2019
14
Public administration and defence;
compulsory social security
326,571
349,507
7.02
374,053
7.02
15
Education
304,762
321,084
5.36
338,279
5.36
16
Human health and social work
activities
109,504
117,315
7.13
125,683
7.13
17
Other services activities
170,177
185,469
8.99
202,135
8.99
18
Gross value added at basic price
9,530,892
10,088,321
5.85
10,682,044
5.89
19
Taxes less subsides on products
381,812
422,203
10.58
462,354
9.51
Gross Domestic Product
9,912,704
10,510.524
6.03
11.144.398
6.03
Source: Bank of Indonesia (2018), Bank Indonesia (Author calculation)
We can make another calculation regarding Indonesia’s economic growth in different way.
In this work, Indonesia’s economic growth rates are determined to grow at the same
numbers as different years, which shown in Table 2. Here, we have chosen a certain sector
enables her to growing faster than others. We then could have the same numbers of
economic growth for planned different years, by only using steady and consistent actions.
In our examples, we have just pushed taxes fewer subsidies on products growing lower,
meanwhile, we do not others. The fact of the matter is we finally have the same numbers
of Indonesia’s economic growth from year to year.
Now, we study another field of GDP, using GDP data from a type of expenditures by
applying the same method as the former. Once again, this research performs some mixed
policies to enable us to have the same numbers of Indonesia’s economic growth like the
numbers of Indonesia’s economic growth which have been calculated from GDP by
industrial origin. We again have Indonesia’s economic growth rate at 6.03 % in 2018,
explained by Table 3.
There are some steps to find that result. First of all, let all of the expenditures grow with
facts. The second step is paying attention to all of the available expenditures, then take
some potential expenditures to be evaluated. Here, we have a private consumption
expenditure which has an important role to enlarge real GDP by type of expenditures.
Private consumption expenditure has contributed 85.59 % to its GDP, or 54.21% to GDP
by type of expenditures at 2010 constant prices in 2018. From this point, we try to consider
people will exhaust their income in goods consumption and services consumption to be
evaluated.
Table 3. Actual & estimated GDP (type of expenditures) and its growth rate in 2018
No
Type of Expenditures
GDP (Billion Rp)
G
(%)
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Gi (%)
2017
2018
2018
2018
2018
1
Consumption expenditures
6,283,206
6,602,839
5.09
6,608,548
5.78
2
Private consumption expenditure
5,379,753
5,651,230
5.05
5,656,940
5.15
3
NPI serving household consumption
expenditure
112,664
122,894
9.08
122,894
9.08
4
Consumption expenditure
government
790,789
828,714
4.79
828,714
4.79
5
Gross fixed capital formation
3,228,763
3,444,118
6.67
3,487,064
8.00
6
Changes in inventories
126,884
197,370
55.55
197,370
55.55
7
Statistical discrepancy 1)
91,650
96,245
5.01
96,245
5.01
8
Export of goods and services
1,915,705
2,039,737
6.47
2,039,737
6.47
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
143
No
Type of Expenditures
GDP (Billion Rp)
G
(%)
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Gi (%)
2017
2018
2018
2018
2018
9
Export of services
231,098
246,135
6.51
282,688
22.32
10
Import of goods (-/-)
1,694,587
1,918,440
13.21
1,918,440
13.20
11
Import of services (-/-)
270,015
282,688
4.69
282.688
4.69
Gross Domestic Product
9,912,704
10,425,316
5.17
10,510,524
6.03
Source: Bank of Indonesia (2018), Bank Indonesia (Author calculation)
As we know from labor statistics, Indonesia still has a high unemployment rate in this
period. From labor statistics, we find that Indonesia’s unemployment rate stood at 5.50%
in August of 2017 and 5.34% in August of 2018. Those numbers were higher than before,
for examples at 2.55% in 1990. Then, let assume Indonesia’s unemployment rate only stand
at 3%, and it will add around 3,070,522 workers to employed labor.
Whenever each of them receives salary Rp.3 million per worker, and all of their money
exhausted to buy goods and services, it will add of Rp.4,894,11 billion to the private
consumption expenditure. Indonesia’s private expenditure growth rate now stands at
5.15% in 2018, and it is higher than 5.05%. Then, by treating between export of services
and import of services become balance, and at the same time let gross fixed capital
formation growing faster at 8.00% in 2018, they cause GDP to grow at 6.03 % in 2018.
Table 4. Estimated GDP (type of expenditure) and its growth rate, in 2018 & 2019
No
Type of Expenditures
GDP (Billion Rp)
G (%)
GDP
(Billion Rp)
Gi (%)
2017*
2018**
2018**
2019**
2019**
1
Consumption Expenditures
6,283,206
6.608.548
5.18
6,950,920
5.18
2
Private Consumption Expenditure
5,379,753
5.656.940
5.15
5,948,409
5.15
3
NPI Serving Household
Consumption Expenditure
112,664
122.894
9.08
134,053
9.08
4
Government Consumption
Expenditure
790,789
828.714
4.79
868,458
4.79
5
Gross Fixed Capital Formation
3,228,763
3.487.064
8.00
3,766,029
8.00
6
Changes in Inventories
126,884
197.370
55.55
307,012
55.55
7
Statistical Discrepancy 1)
91,650
96.245
5.01
101,070
5.01
8
Export of Goods and Services
1,915,705
2.039.737
6.47
2,191,230
7.43
9
Export of Services
231,098
282.688
22.32
295,954
4.69
10
Import of Goods (-/-)
1,694,587
1.918.440
13.21
2,171,864
13.21
11
Import of Services (-/-)
270,015
282.688
4.69
295,954
4.69
Gross Domestic Product
9,912,704
10.510.524
6.03
11.144.398
6.03
Source: Bank of Indonesia (2018), Bank Indonesia (Author calculation)
In this case, we have done mixed strategies, which all of the economic strategies relate to all
of the available potential resources. Then, let them walk hand in hand together so that
GDP could grow faster. Thus, when the government implements a lot of appropriate
policies to the economy, it can cause economic growth rate growing faster.
Table 4 shows us about predictions of Indonesia’s growth rate in 2018 and 2019.
Indonesia’s growth rate stood at 6.03 % in 2018 and maintained to be constant at 6.03% in
2019. In this case, most of expenditures in 2019 are maintained growing as the same as
growth rate in 2018. We just push the volume of export of services in 2019 as many as the
volume of import of services, hence trade balance was maintained.
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
144
Conclusions
It is not so bad Indonesia’s economic growth rose 5.07 % in 2017 and 5.17 % in 2018,
those are better than Indonesia’s economic rate at 4.88 % in 2015. Some economic policies
might be conducted by the government so that they could improve the level of real GDP
increased higher. However, It becomes bad when we compare that result in the economic
growth rate in 2012, which stood at 6.03 %. That all even, questioned by some domestic
economists, they said; Indonesia’s Real GDP could have grown faster like RRC’s real
GDP. One of them even said that Indonesia has performed messy economic policies. Of
course, if his notion is true it means that Indonesia’s economic growth rate at 5.17 % in
2018 is just saved by a miracle.
From this research, we find that, if all of everything can run well, it is true to say that
Indonesia could have rapid economic growth rates. Of course, it comes from a good plan.
We have estimated Indonesia’s real GDP can be raised up to 6.03 in 2018 % by doing
analysis on available potential economic resources. And then, by doing the same way as
before, this research also estimates Indonesia’s real GDP in 2019 can grow at the same rate
as in 2018, stands at 6.03 %. In the economic system, all elements in the system must work
together. They are related one to another. This is reasonable, why a good plan is very
important. Any policy cannot walk by its self, but it must be suited to targets. Do the
adjusting process, when it is needed.
References
Bank of Indonesia. (2018). Indonesian Financial Statistics. Jakarta, Indonesia.
Bhattacharya, A., & Pangestu, M. (1992). Indonesia: Development Transformation Since
1965 and The Role of Public Policy. In Paper prepared for the World Bank Workshop on the
Role of Government and East Asian Success (pp. 19–21). World Development Report:
World Bank.
Branson, W. H. (2005). Macroeconomics : Theory and Policy (3rd editio). New Delhi, India:
Affilated East-west Press Pvt Ltd.
Djojohadikusumo, S. (1989). Perkembangan Ekonomi Indonesia Selama Empat Tahap
Pelita 1969/1970-1988/1989. In Seminar dan Konferensi Ikatan Sarjana Ekonomi Indonesia.
Jakarta, Indonesia: Ikatan Sarjana Ekonomi Indonesia.
Domar, E. D. (1946). Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and Employment. Econometrica,
14(2), 137–147.
Gie, K. K. (2006). Kebijaksanaan Ekonomi Politik dan Hilangnya Nalar (1st ed.). Jakarta:
Kompas Gramedia.
Glassburner, B., & Aditiawan, C. (1982). Teori dan Kebijaksanaan Ekonomi Makro. edisi kedua.
Jakarta: LP3ES. (2rd ed.). Jakarta: LP3ES Press.
Harrod, R. F. (1939). An Essay in Dynamic Theory. The Economic Journal, 49(193), 14–33.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2225181
Johnson, C. (1998). Survey of Recent Developments: Why has Indonesia’s Financial Crisis
Been So Bad? Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 34(2), 3–59.
https://doi.org/10.1080/00074919812331337320
Lipsey, R. G., & Chrystal, A. K. (2015). Economics (9th ed.). Oxford, Britania Raya: Oxford
University Press.
Mccawley, P. (2013). The Indonesian Economy During The Soeharto Era : A Review.
Masyarakat Indonesia, 39(2), 269–287.
Teguh, Bashir/SIJDEB, Vol (2), 2019, 122-132
145
Meier, G. M., & Rauch, J. E. (2005). Leading Issues in Economic Development (8th ed.). Oxford,
Britania Raya: Oxford University Press.
Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesian Economy 1998: A Year of Correction. Jurnal Ketahanan
Nasional, 3(1), 1–21.
Sen, A. (2017). Collective Choice and Social Welfare: An Expanded Edition (1st ed.). Cambridge:
Harvard University Press.
Soebyakto, B. B., & Bashir, A. (2017). The effect of short-term aggregate demand in
indonesian economy: The era of ASEAN economic community. Journal of Applied
Economic Sciences, XII(2(48)), 594–605.
Solow, R. M. (1956). A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94. https://doi.org/10.5897/JEIF2013.0518
Sorogho, S. A. (2017). The Determinants of Sell-side Analysts ’ Forecast Accuracy and
Media Exposure. Sriwijaya International Journal of Dynamic Economics and Business, 1(2),
133–152.
Sundrum, R. M. (1988). Indonesia’s Slow Economic Growth: 1981–86. Bulletin of Indonesian
Economic Studies, 24(1), 37–72.
World Bank. (2017). World Development Indicators 2018. https://doi.org/CC BY 3.0
IGO
!