PresentationPDF Available

Perspectives on the future of the EU Cohesion Policy. Not doing more but better !

Authors:

Abstract

The #EUCohesionPolicy do not needs to do more but better ! I also raise some difficulties with the smart specialization strategy
Perspectives on the future of the EU
Cohesion Policy
By Sebastien Bourdin (Associate Professor at the Normandy Business School).
Introduction: Not doing more but better
European Union’s Cohesion Policy has been in existence for about twenty years. The implementation
of this policy acknowledges that the market forces are not necessarily sufficient to significantly
reduce regional disparities. The EU therefore created this tool of financial solidarity between
member states with the aim of improving the competitiveness of slow-growth regions and correcting
regional unbalance. Since its creation, this policy has always reflected the need for a territorial
cohesion and aimed at reducing regional disparities, restructuring regional economies, creating jobs
and stimulating private investment.
With the present Multiannual financial framework (2014-2020) coming to an end, the traditionally
long and difficult discussions are now under way. The future EU budget, the EU Multiannual
Financial Framework 2021-2027, has been intensively negotiated. For the European entities, it
seems clear that profound changes are needed if the EU is to be able to face the most pressing
challenges of the moment and to continue to have an impact in globalisation. Jean-Claude Juncker,
President of the European Commission, described that the EU has been going through a “polycrisis”
for about a decade and it is now necessary to draw conclusions. This requires an amended multi-year
budget: Firstly, to gain flexibility, in order to be able to react to unavoidable emergencies; secondly,
to gain in strength, to relaunch economic and social convergence and to face crises; and thirdly, to
increase efficiency, even if it means reviewing established rules.
Territorial inequalities that are not always visible
The European Commission publishes a report on progress towards economic, social and territorial
cohesion approximately every three years. Comparisons with the wealth gaps observed at different
times show the extent to which Member States (NUTS 0 level) and EU regions (NUTS 2 level) are
catching up. Although there is a global convergence process, there are nevertheless still some
disparities that remain evident. For example, regions of Central and Eastern Europe situated close
to the former Iron Curtain tend to experience higher growth rates than the regions situated in the
East.
This can be partially explained by the fact that trade is more intense due to the existence of
differentials (in cost, offering, structure by age, etc.) and associated regional growth distribution
phenomena. From this point of view therefore, there is a shift from the Iron Curtain to the Golden
Curtain (Bourdin 2015). Not all regions enjoy the same benefits depending on their location. A first
challenge is therefore to be able to take into account this question of the (advantages of) location in
the allocation of European funds.
Moreover, if the scope is changed, the convergence observed between EU Member States
sometimes actually masks an increase in regional intra-state inequalities. Convergence phenomena
observed at NUTS 3 level produce either convergence or divergence locally (Bourdin, 2015; Butkus
et al., 2018). Some studies have particularly highlighted a quick growth recorded in metropolitan
regions due to a concentration of service activities, direct foreign investment, and a significant
number of start-up launches. On the contrary, Eastern regions find it difficult to reduce the gap with
developed regions. Their industry is declining, their agriculture is fragmented and not very
competitive, there is a lack of infrastructure, and hardly any money is spent on research and
innovation. The most recent developments confirm that some regional disparities, due to regional
economic and social structures, geography or population density, persist and that the least
developed territories remain the most vulnerable to the crisis (Crescenzi et al., 2016). The question
of the scale at which we look at these inequalities and seek to reduce them is crucial.
A second challenge for the future Cohesion Policy 2021-2027 would be therefore to take into account
the disparities in wealth that may exist within the same region, even when it benefits from a strong
overall economic dynamism, such as the Ile-de-France region. It is essential that the search for
territorial cohesion be carried out at all levels, and not only at European level, otherwise, there is a
risk that some territories feel too neglected and victims of inequalities, with consequences in terms
of the rise of populism (Rodríguez-Pose, 2018).
One of the difficulties also lies in the identification of intermediate regions, which may be partly
forgotten by Cohesion Policy: some of them suffer from economic difficulties although they are not
considered to be lagging behind in development from a statistical point of view (threshold of 75% of
the EU average). In this respect, the allocation of regional funds according to the unemployment
rate and no longer only GDP per capita could be a solution.
A Cohesion Policy that is more or less effective depending on the territory
As pointed out by Becker et al. (2012), Sotiriou and Tsiapa (2015) or Bourdin (2018), the impact of
the EU funds on regional growth is not the same everywhere. One reason for this is that some
regions do not only spend money in the sectors most likely to have the best economic returns
(infrastructure versus education or R&D), but also on differentials in administrative capacity and
regional governance. This spatial variation of the differentiated impact of structural funds across EU
regions, combined with the heterogeneity of current regional economic development, questions the
capacity of the European funds to reduce this unbalance.
In this context, a more targeted concentration of the aid would increase the effectiveness of the
spent funds. The expertise regarding the regional policy has developed in this direction and, at the
end of the first decade of the new millennium, a certain number of very convincing reports about the
intervention of the policy on regional development were published by important international
entities such as the OECD, the World Bank, and the European Commission. These reports revealed
two opposing points of view about an animated debate over European regional policy. On the one
hand, there is the idea of a space-neutral regional development policy, emphasizing the advantages
of agglomeration and the spillover from geographic concentration. On the other hand, a territorial
approach (called place-based), which supposes that it is essential to take the geographic context into
account—especially the role of institutions, the importance of local knowledge and socio-economic
characteristics. With the Cohesion Policy 2014-2020, it was decided to propose a territorialized
approach to the Cohesion Policy by taking account of its unequal effectiveness in Europe. From this
point of view, the new architecture of the Cohesion Policy breaks tradition with the projects
supported by the European Funds beforehand (European Commission, 2014). For the period
2014-2020, the European Commission invited each region to present its strengths and to establish a
Smart Specialisation Strategy, known as RIS3.
The smart specialization strategy questioned
The resulting regional development strategies have been guided by the concept of intelligent
specialisation, which attempts to translate a sectoral concept into a spatial context, linking the
European Union’s innovation strategy to Cohesion Policy (McCann and Ortega-Argilés, 2015).
However, even though Cohesion Policy has contributed to growth and increased convergence at
Member State level, we argue that it is likely to support the current processes of polarisation
between EU regions. As Cohesion Policy focuses on maintaining the EU’s global economic
competitiveness, it moves away from its traditional objective of promoting territorial cohesion by
supporting global development. Besides, it questions the EU’s capacity to pursue its objectives of
cohesion and competitiveness at the same time. Several questions are asked.
The first one concerns the ability of some regions with difficulties to implement such strategies due
to their structural lag (low capacity of innovation, declining demographics, low level of training, low
capacity to unleash European Funds, etc.). Specialization, based on performance and
competitiveness between the regions, makes the unbalance worse. Some regions (the most
developed ones) already have the adequate skills (soft skills) to enable them to use the European
structural funds in the best possible way, and others (more fragile) are not in a position to make the
most of what such funding allows.
The approach implies that each region defines its own strategy of intelligent specialisation enabling
it to find its own development path and strengthen its competitiveness at national and international
level on the basis of the resources at its disposal (place-based policy). However, there is a “copy and
paste” phenomenon where regions finally find themselves doing “smart” and “green” by proposing
strategies based on innovation in new technologies; it should be noted that the polysemy of the
terms used leaves great scope for all regions to put in place what they want in terms of strategy. It is
also questionable whether the most difficult regions can implement this strategy of intelligent
specialisation based on innovation, while some of them, more than ten years after their integration
into the EU, are still struggling to find their way to growth in the face of capital regions that
continue to attract a large proportion of investment. Not all regions may have the territorial
resources to implement such strategies (based on knowledge-intensive value creation) that are
better suited to regions in advance than to regions lagging behind. However, among the European
policies that should have significant funding, there is research and innovation, whose budget is up
by 50% compared to the previous multiannual financial framework.
Seems legitimate,therefore, to question the contradictions between the objectives of EU Cohesion
Policy, the requirements of the RIS3 programme and the ability of peripheral regions to implement
this strategy. Thus, more than a place-based policy, there is a need for a place-sensitive policy,
aiming at maximising the development potential of each territory (Rodriguez-Pose, 2018) regarding
their real regional specificities. Some regions would probably feel more comfortable with the idea of
building an intelligent specialization strategy based on industrial development than on knowledge
development. The following priorities have been defined: security, defence, strengthening of certain
policies, in particular in favour of youth mobility, climate change. The future Multiannual Financial
Framework will therefore have to combine, in the same proportion, savings in existing programmes
and additional resources on new priorities. It will also have to propose a Cohesion Policy for all
regions, taking into account their specific territorial characteristics.
References
Bourdin, S. (2018). Does the Cohesion Policy Have the Same Influence on Growth Everywhere? A
Geographically Weighted Regression Approach in Central and Eastern Europe. Economic
Geography, 1-32.
Bourdin, S. (2015). National and regional trajectories of convergence and economic integration in
Central and Eastern Europe. Canadian Journal of Regional Science, 38(1/3), 55-63.
Becker, S. O., Egger, P. H., & Von Ehrlich, M. (2012). Too much of a good thing? On the growth
effects of the EU’s regional policy. European Economic Review, 56(4), 648-668.
Butkus, M., Cibulskiene, D., Maciulyte-Sniukiene, A., & Matuzeviciute, K. (2018). What Is the
Evolution of Convergence in the EU? Decomposing EU Disparities up to NUTS 3 Level.
Sustainability, 10(5), 1552.
Crescenzi, R., Luca, D., & Milio, S. (2016). The geography of the economic crisis in Europe: national
macroeconomic conditions, regional structural factors and short-term economic performance.
Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 9(1), 13-32.
McCann, P., & Ortega-Argilés, R. (2015). Smart specialization, regional growth and applications to
European Union cohesion policy. Regional Studies, 49(8), 1291-1302.
Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2018). The revenge of the places that don’t matter (and what to do about it).
Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 11(1), 189-209.
Sotiriou, A., & Tsiapa, M. (2015). The asymmetric influence of structural funds on regional growth in
Greece. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 33(4), 863-881.
About the author
Sebastien Bourdin is associate professor at the Normandy Business School. He is an economic
geographer. Since its PhD in Geography, he is working on the evaluation of public policies of
territorial development, and more specifically on the EU Cohesion Policy.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
The latest successive enlargements to Central and Eastern European countries and their differentiated convergence raise the question of the effectiveness of the European structural funds that have been greatly enjoyed by such countries. The literature on this question is nevertheless not unanimous. I therefore offer an analysis of the cohesion policy and its role in regional growth specifically in Central and Eastern Europe, using a method developed in spatial analysis, namely, GWR (geographically weighted regression) at the NUTS 3 level. My findings reveal the existence of a multipolar convergence. The differentiated spatial variations of the influence of European funds on regional economic growth call for reorientation of the cohesion policy, especially in favor of a more territorialized policy..
Article
Full-text available
Research on convergence deals with the question of whether regional disparities are decreasing over time. Aiming to decompose EU disparities covering regions of all levels, this paper fills the gap of the empirical research on convergence in the EU in the following ways: (i) the research updates the assessment of regional disparities in the EU emphasizing, but not limited to, the analysis at the NUTS 3 level; (ii) based on a constructed three-level Theil index, the research decomposes EU disparities into between-country, within-country at the NUTS 2 level, and within the NUTS 2 region at the NUTS 3 level components, covering the period of 1995-2014 and all EU regions, (iii) it examines the linkages between the development of innovation and technology, sustainability, and evolution of disparities. Our main findings suggest that convergence in the EU is still present at different regional levels, but its speed is slowing down. Total EU disparities were decreasing mainly because of reducing disparities between member states. At the same time, in the majority of EU member states, old and new, within-country disparities were growing at all regional levels, and now within-country disparities account for almost two-fifths of total EU disparities.
Article
Full-text available
This article tests the hypothesis that the geographical location plays a major role in differentiated economic integration of central and eastern regions at different geographical scales. We implement a local measure of Gini index allowing to measure the economic catching-up of regions (across the period 1995-2007 at the NUTS 2-3 level). The findings indicate that a convergence of the CEEC toward the EU-15 seems to take place but at the cost of widening regional inequalities within each state. Our results suggest also the existence of a west-east gradient of regional economic integration.
Article
Full-text available
This article explores the linkages between pre-2008 crisis national macroeconomic conditions, regional resistance factors and depth of the crisis in the regions of the EU27. The results suggest that only a limited set of macroeconomic factors shape the regional reaction to the crisis. A healthy current account surplus is associated with stronger economic performance during the post-2008 recession. Conversely, high public debt countries are more successful in sheltering their regional economies in the short run. When looking at regional-level resistance, human capital is the single most important positive factor. Conversely, research and development-intensive regions are more exposed to negative shocks.
Article
Full-text available
This paper aims to explore the conditioning effect of structural funds (SF) on regional growth in Greece for the period 1994–2006 by detecting whether the ability of regions to convert any financial aid into welfare gains is related to certain region-specific characteristics. The analysis shows that albeit the important financial aid that has been channelled to the less developed regions, the most advanced regions seem to have benefited more from it. Further, we divide the SF into expenditure categories and conclude that the SF have a positive impact on growth only for those regions in which the regions’ endowments are related to the expenditure received. The interaction of the expenditure categories with the characteristics of the recipient region accentuates the role of the ‘identity’ of each region to the impact of the SF on regional growth, thereby, signifying valuable policy implications.
Article
Full-text available
This paper examines the arguments underpinning the smart specialisation concept, an idea which originally emerged from the sectoral growth literature, and one which has recently been applied with to the regional policy context. The shift from a sectoral to a regional context appears prima facie to be quite straightforward but this paper explains that translating the idea to a regional policy context is rather more complex that it at first appears and implies some changes in both interpretation and implications. The outcomes of this are that in a regional policy setting the smart specialisation logic is seen to be broadly consistent with the overall reforms of EU Cohesion Policy. However, in a regional policy setting there is no reason why ICTs should be prioritised over many forms of intangible capital, and the promotion of technological diversification via entrepreneurship may need to be related to specific sectors or activities.
Article
Persistent poverty, economic decay, and lack of opportunities are at the root of considerable discontent in declining and lagging-behind areas the world over. Poor development prospects and an increasing belief that these places have ‘no future’ – as economic dynamism has been posited to be increasingly dependent on agglomeration economies – have led many of these so-called ‘places that don’t matter’ to revolt against the status quo. The revolt has come via an unexpected source: the ballot-box in a wave of political populism with strong territorial, rather than social foundations. I will argue that the populist wave is challenging the sources of existing well-being in both the less-dynamic and the more prosperous areas and that better, rather than more, place-sensitive territorial development policies are needed in order to find a solution to the problem. Place-sensitive development policies need, however, to stay clear of the welfare, income-support, and big investment projects of past development strategies if they are to be successful and focus on tapping into untapped potential and on providing opportunities to those people living in the places that ‘don’t matter’.
Article
The European Union (EU) provides grants to disadvantaged regions of member states from two pools, the Structural Funds and the Cohesion Fund. The main goal of the associated transfers is to facilitate convergence of poor regions (in terms of per-capita income) to the EU average. We use data at the NUTS3 level from the last two EU budgetary periods (1994-99 and 2000-06). Using generalized propensity score estimation, we analyze to which extent the goal of fostering growth in the target regions was achieved with the funds provided and whether more transfers generated stronger growth effects or not. We find that, overall, EU transfers enable faster growth in the recipient regions as intended, but we estimate that in 36% of the recipient regions the transfer intensity exceeds the aggregate efficiency maximizing level and in 18% percent of the regions a reduction of transfers would not even reduce their growth. We conclude that some reallocation of the funds across target regions would lead to higher aggregate growth in the EU and could generate even faster convergence than the current scheme does.