ArticlePDF Available

Crony capitalism in the Palestinian Authority: a deal among friends

Authors:

Abstract

This article interrogates the multifaceted political–economic networks entrenched within the multiple structures of the West Bank-based Palestinian Authority (PA). The main argument of this article is that crony capitalism is a defining feature of the PA’s relations with a handful of capitalists and business groups. The demonstration of this argument is exhibited through the large-scale public and private monopolistic practices in strategic sectors of the Palestinian economy, which function within the framework of Israel’s settler-colonial reality and the persistent patterns of international aid to the occupied West Bank. While acknowledging the existence of cronyism as a feature of the capitalist system in its diverse typologies, crony capitalism may be more pronounced in situations characterised by political uncertainty, whereby political–business collusion strategizes the expansion of neo-patrimonial networks and rent-seeking opportunities as a meta-mechanism for social control and political stabilisation. In the Occupied Palestinian Territories, crony capitalism was developed as part of the political allegiances and economic alliances that underpin the structures created by the Oslo process, which are fostered by Israeli policies and the international donor community to maintain the cohesiveness of the PA regime.
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at
https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=ctwq20
Third World Quarterly
ISSN: 0143-6597 (Print) 1360-2241 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/ctwq20
Crony capitalism in the Palestinian Authority: a
deal among friends
Tariq Dana
To cite this article: Tariq Dana (2019): Crony capitalism in the Palestinian Authority: a deal among
friends, Third World Quarterly, DOI: 10.1080/01436597.2019.1618705
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/01436597.2019.1618705
Published online: 02 Jun 2019.
Submit your article to this journal
View Crossmark data
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY
Crony capitalism in the Palestinian Authority:
a deal among friends
Tariq Dana
Conict and Humanitarian Studies, Doha Institute of Graduate Studies, Doha, Qatar
ABSTRACT
This article interrogates the multifaceted political–economic networks
entrenched within the multiple structures of the West Bank-based
Palestinian Authority (PA). The main argument of this article is that crony
capitalism is a defining feature of the PA’s relations with a handful of
capitalists and business groups. The demonstration of this argument is
exhibited through the large-scale public and private monopolistic prac-
tices in strategic sectors of the Palestinian economy, which function
within the framework of Israel’s settler-colonial reality and the persistent
patterns of international aid to the occupied West Bank. While acknowl-
edging the existence of cronyism as a feature of the capitalist system
in its diverse typologies, crony capitalism may be more pronounced in
situations characterised by political uncertainty, whereby political–busi-
ness collusion strategizes the expansion of neo-patrimonial networks
and rent-seeking opportunities as a meta-mechanism for social control
and political stabilisation. In the Occupied Palestinian Territories, crony
capitalism was developed as part of the political allegiances and eco-
nomic alliances that underpin the structures created by the Oslo pro-
cess, which are fostered by Israeli policies and the international donor
community to maintain the cohesiveness of the PA regime.
Critical approaches used to study the political economy of the Occupied Palestinian Territories
(OPT) tend to focus on the impacts of Israel’s economic domination and policies that serve
to consolidate its colonial structure. These approaches investigate Israel’s systematic policies
and practices to transform the economy of the OPT into a captive market and a reserve of
cheap labour, with the land, natural resources, borders, trade, industrial development and
general macroeconomic framework of the OPT strictly controlled by Israel.1 Following the
1993 Oslo Accords and the establishment of the Palestinian Authority (PA) in 1994, the
impacts of international aid on the politics, society and economy of the OPT have emerged
as an additional research focus. Critiques suggest that donors’ substantial influence on the
PA institution-building, neoliberal economic policy and securitisation of the public sphere
has not only led to the demise of a Palestinian state but has also contributed to the formation
of ‘zombie peace’.
2
The complex interaction between these processes has subjected the local
political economy to ‘a unique form of neoliberal colonization, defined by Andy Clarno as a
ARTICLE HISTORY
Received 26 November
2018
Accepted 10 May 2019
KEYWORDS
Crony capitalism
monopolies
Palestinian Authority
private sector
state-building
© 2019 Global South Ltd
CONTACT Tariq Dana tariq.dana@dohainstitute.edu.qa Conict and Humanitarian Studies, Doha Institute of
Graduate Studies, Doha, Qatar
https://doi.org/10.1080/01436597.2019.1618705
2 T. DANA
by-product of a distinct combination of aggressive settler-colonialism and neoliberal racial
capitalism.3 In this context, the interplay between Palestinian capital operations and PA
state-building has rigorously developed into a predatory form of ‘crony capitalism’ whereby
political and profit-making activities are systemically manipulated by a narrow set of polit-
ical–business actors whose resources and opportunities are offered by the forces of neolib-
eral colonisation’.
The relations between Palestinian political and business/capitalist elites have always been
close; indeed, the Palestine Liberation Organisation (PLO) maintains strong connections with
diaspora capitalists who not only fund the PLO but also act as crucial interlocutors between
the national movement and regional and international powers.4 The Oslo process has trans-
formed the political–business connection into a form of solid coalition, implicating the PLO/
Fateh upper echelon, returnee capitalists, the PA technocrats and security leaders, whose
interest lies in dominating the political and economic centres of power. Since 2007, the
Palestinian capitalists developed an unprecedented influence over the PA decision-making
circles and the social realm, besides embarking on privileged relationships with their Israeli
counterparts. This development can be attributed to several factors, including the geograph-
ical and administrative division of the West Bank and Gaza Strip; the expansion and ampli-
fication of the PA security sector; the increased involvement of the banks in the economy
for the formation of a credit market; and the expansion of a predatory and unproductive
service sector characterised by telecoms, real estate and retail. The rising power of capitalists
has inevitably led to the exacerbation of class divisions and socioeconomic inequalities,
which are relatively mitigated by the PA and Fateh’s neo-patrimonial and patron–client net-
works that tend to promote acquiescence among social constituents.
A systematic analysis of the interplay between Palestinian political and business elites is
lacking, despite the high visibility of this phenomenon and the multi-layered incentives
driving it to mature and become more pronounced. Indeed, this article contends that to
understand the peculiar status of the political economy of the OPT, this pillar must be con-
sidered in the analysis. This article focuses on the West Bank for the following two main
reasons: (a) the West Bank, Gaza, East Jerusalem and the Palestinian community in Israel
have been subjected to Israeli policies of fragmentation and separation that have created
different political economies; therefore, these areas require a separate analysis, and (b)
Ramallah has become the de facto capital city of the PA, the location of its headquarters and
operations, and the centre of large businesses and investments.
This study used a qualitative method analysis, including systematic observation, review
of web-based archives and annual reports by conglomerates, donor agencies, the PA, as
well as unstructured, informal and conversational interviews with insiders from the PA and
the private sector who preferred to remain anonymous. This article is divided into seven
sections. The first section explores the concept of ‘crony capitalism’ and briefly discusses its
application to the occupied West Bank. The second section highlights the pre-Oslo relations
between the PLO political and business elites. The third section examines the structural
context driving the creation of crony capitalism in the West Bank. The fourth section provides
details about the post-Oslo emergence of two major conglomerates (PADICO and APIC) that
have played important roles in shaping the post-Oslo political economy. The fifth section
explores the early period of PA–business crony relations and the monopolies that dominated
during 1990s. The sixth section focuses on the reproduction of crony capitalism during the
previous decade (2007–2017), particularly in light of the PA reform programme. Finally, the
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY 3
article analyses the changing nature of monopolies and identifies key actors and sectors
that lie at the core of PA–business networks during the previous decade.
Crony capitalism
The term ‘crony capitalism’ has been widely used in the popular press and by political activists
to indicate predatory rent-seeking and the mutually beneficial relationships between poli-
ticians and capitalists. Recent scholarly efforts have used the term in inquiries into the corrupt
nature of elite collusion in dominating the economy and the resulting perilous social and
economic impacts on society.5 Crony capitalism is broadly defined as:
A system in which those close to the political authorities who make and enforce policies receive
favors that have large economic value. These favors allow politically connected economic
agents to earn returns above those that would prevail in an economy in which the factors of
production were priced by the market.6
While the liberal understanding typically minimises crony capitalism to deals and trans-
actions between politicians and a few privileged businesses, crony capitalism is essentially
underpinned by a wide range of overt/covert and formal/informal networks operating across
public institutions and private firms. Extensive studies have investigated key components
of crony arrangements such as rent-seeking, political entrepreneurship, money politics,
bribery and corrupt public–private deals.7 These studies have provided a crucial analytical
perspective from which to understand the political and economic behaviour of these net-
works and the redistribution of wealth among allies to ensure support and acquiescence.
Such networks extend from the elite level, who directly benefit from private business deals
and other forms of public embezzlement, to lower levels of the state’s managers, whose
discretionary power is often abused to advance self-serving agendas via competition for
political rent and financial awards. The involvement of different centres of power in these
networks serves to stabilise the status quo favouring the system of cronyism.8
In both democracies and autocracies, crony capitalism is a global phenomenon that is
hardly limited to a specific type of political system. Rather, crony capitalism is an endemic
political–economic system prevalent in the capitalist system and its different manifestations,
such as in models of state capitalism and neoliberalism. However, the intensity, the scale
and depth of crony relations in each model remain subject to debate.
In state capitalism or ‘big government’ systems, governmental intervention in the market
through regulation, taxation and subsidisation could drive businesses to seek political con-
nections to obtain preferential treatment and maximise their profitability.9 In exchange,
politicians benefit economically from privileged businesses in the form of bribes, favouritism
or public–private partnerships and involvement in monopolies. Favourable exchanges
between governments and key businesses in the context of state capitalism can impact
policy formulation in favour of enhancing the crony relations between the political and
economic elites, thereby forming the backbone of a crony capitalist system.10
Crony relations are also an integral feature of the neoliberal paradigm.11 Cronyism is
facilitated by a set of neoliberal measures, including market deregulation, privatisation and
discriminatory taxation. For example, the privatisation of a state’s firms may be delivered to
politically connected businesspeople, thus offering these individuals greater financial gains
and political power. Furthermore, cronyism is institutionalised by repressive taxation regimes,
4 T. DANA
with higher taxes placed on households and small- and medium-sized businesses, while
transnational corporations and the wealthiest experience slight fiscal pressures and, in many
instances, are rendered completely exempt from taxation.12 The ways in which politicians
benefit from this dynamic are generally revealed through scandalous leaks. For example,
the Panama Papers illustrate the extent to which politicians are involved in offshore tax
havens. It has been documented that politicians are the most frequently referenced individ-
uals in the Panama Papers.13
Crony capitalism in the OPT shares striking similarities with what Gilbert Achcar terms
‘neo-patrimonial crony capitalism’ to depict the political–economic system prevalent in many
Arab states, which is characterised by nepotism, the pillaging of public property, swollen
bureaucracies, generalised corruption and the impotence of the rule of law.14 This system is
defined not by state capitalism or neoliberalism but rather by a distorted mixture of both,
whereby ‘the state and its resources are a cash cow at the disposition of the autocrat and his
familial entourage, friends and henchmen’.15 In such contexts, the nature of crony capitalism
is exacerbated by autocratic and military regimes, unproductive capitalists and an entrenched
state security system. Yet, cronyism in the context of PA remains distinct in that it operates
in a context characterised by ongoing colonisation, international aid rentierism and the
absence of a state.
The modern formation of the Palestinian political and economic elite
The Nakba and displacement of 1948 led to a radical shift in the composition of the Palestinian
class structure. The old traditional elite, comprising urban ‘notables’ and semi-feudal land-
owners who governed the Palestinian society in the pre-Nakba era, had disintegrated. In
the 1950s and 1960s, a new process of class formation occurred among exiled Palestinian
communities, which introduced two prominent elite groups. The first is represented by the
leadership of the PLO and political factions that formed the backbone of the Palestinian
National Movement (PNM). The second group is made up of an exiled Palestinian capitalist
class whose wealth was largely acquired and developed as part of accumulation processes
at the regional level, most importantly ‘as a distinct sub-sector of the Gulf capitalist class’.16
The relationships between these political and economic elites depended on the ideolog-
ical stances of Palestinian leaders and factions. The decades of 1960s and 1970s have wit-
nessed tense debates among the forces of the PNM that aimed to settle the ideological
identity of Palestinians’ anti-colonial struggle. Central to these debates was the relationship
between the Palestinian capitalist class and the political movement, particularly the extent
to which the former should be engaged and their expected roles in the anti-colonial struggle.
Similar debates were integral to the development of national liberation and revolutionary
movements at the time.17 They centred on whether national capitalists could and should
serve as progressive allies of liberation and revolutionary movements or whether they would
act as a counterrevolutionary force that leads such movements in conservative directions.
Fateh, the PLO largest faction, embraced a pragmatic understanding of the ‘national
bourgeoisie’ and asserted its indispensable role in the PNM. From the beginning, Fateh
maintained close relations with and received support from the exiled Palestinian capitalists.
In contrast, the Palestinian left was divided on the question of the role of the ‘national bour-
geoisie’, and this division affected its cohesiveness. The Popular Front for the Liberation of
Palestine (PFLP) rejected the engagement of the capitalist class and viewed its interests as
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY 5
‘linked with the business and banking interests of imperialism’, asserting that ‘this class will
stand by its own interests, that is, with imperialism against the revolution’.18 However, the
PFLP acknowledged the role of the petty bourgeoisie in advancing national liberation objec-
tives. Opposition to this ideological stance was at the core of the defection of the Democratic
Front for the Liberation of Palestine (DFLP) from the PFLP in 1969 by a Maoist group that
rejected the strategy of engaging both the bourgeoisie and petty bourgeoisie classes and
asserted the leadership of the working class and peasants in the anti-colonial struggle.19
With Fateh dominance over the PLO institutions, the influence of exiled Palestinian cap-
italists gradually grew across the PLO’s centres of power. Although most capitalists were
self-defined as independent nationalists with no formal affiliation with factional politics,
these individuals in effect enjoyed a close affinity with the PLO chairperson, Yasser Arafat,
and the dominant leadership. These relationships allowed these individuals to occupy lead-
ing and representative positions within key PLO institutions, such as the Palestinian National
Council and the Palestinian Central Committee.
While nationalist impulses drove the material and moral support for the PLO by the
Palestinian capitalists, this support should be understood within the limitations imposed by
the process of capital accumulation. This was politically expressed in the capitalists’ conser-
vative position, frequently attempting to streamline the PLO’s political programme towards
a compromise with moderate Arab regimes and subsequently with Israel.
20
For example, the
capitalist members of the PLO National Council threw their weight behind Fateh’s ‘10-point
programme’ of 1974, which envisaged a national authority over any liberated part of
Palestine, thus supplanting the PLO’s original objective of anti-colonial liberation with the
two-state paradigm that gradually developed into the Oslo Accords.21
Influential capitalists mediated between the PLO and regional and international powers
in several pre-Oslo stages. For instance, following Black September, the battle between
Palestinian guerrilla fighters and the Jordanian regime in 1970, the Palestinian–Jordanian
business tycoon Munib Al-Masri, who was then the minister of public works of the Jordanian
government, established a formal channel of negotiations between the two conflicting par-
ties, resulting in the expulsion of PLO bases from the Jordanian territory. Another example
concerns the instrumental role of businessman Hasib Sabbagh in establishing secret diplo-
matic channels between Arafat and the US in the 1980s, which, despite initial obstructions
by the Reagan administration, resulted in the PLO accepting the American condition of openly
denouncing the use of ‘terrorism’, as echoed in the 1988 ‘declaration of independence’.
22
Global
changes of the late 1980s and early 1990s, including the disintegration of the Soviet Bloc and
the rise to dominance of the neoliberal paradigm, accelerated the PLO leadership’s search
for political compromise with Israel, which subsequently influenced Palestinian economic
thought toward liberalism as expressed in the signing of the Oslo Accords in 1993.
Structural context of PA–business cronyism
The Oslo framework entailed a dynamic and coordinated interplay among three structural
factors that shaped the interactions between the political and economic elites. These factors
have paved the way for the evolution and consolidation of crony capitalism in the PA.
The first concerns the fact that the Oslo Accords and its economic annex – the Paris
Economic Protocol (PEP) of the 1994 – did not alter the gross power asymmetries between
the Palestinians and Israel; indeed, Israel remains the sole sovereign power that tends to
6 T. DANA
manipulate the internal Palestinian affairs to its ends.
23
More specifically, the PEP agreement
granted Israel an exclusive power over key PA economic resources such as monetary policies,
trade and fiscal revenues, labour flows and industrial zoning rights. The PEP has institution-
alised the Palestinian economic dependency on Israel thus effectively restricting the PA
capacity to pursue independent macroeconomic policy.
The Oslo framework helped nurture the PA cronyism in two fundamental ways. First, the
Oslo process was structured on the logic of ‘peace dividends’ which prioritised the liberal
peace logic of economic cooperation and prosperity to achieve political settlement. Some
studies have dubbed the Oslo process as the ‘peace of business’ and the ‘peace of markets
to signify the profitable dimension of the inter-elite accommodations, which came at the
expense of major political issues that lie at the heart of the conflict.24 In the process of sta-
bilising the PA structures and functions, Israel embarked on economic pacification tech-
niques by devising a wide range of incentives and opportunities to a section of Palestinian
political and economic elite who have vested interests in stability. These incentives included
privileged access to essential resources such as easing of movement, trade and financial
transactions, in addition to initiating joint business ventures.25 Inevitably, therefore, the
interactions between the PA state-building and economic development have been shaped
by a policy framework set forth by the Israeli manipulation of the PA political and economic
elite. Second, the PEP arrangements established the revenue clearance system which allows
Israel to collect and transfer income taxes from Palestinian workers and customs duties on
imports from ports and borders controlled by Israel to the PA. The revenue clearance system
has in recent years become the single largest source of PA revenue, accounting for nearly
two-thirds of its budget.26 Besides ensuring a fiscally and economically dependent PA on
Israel, the revenue clearance system represents a strategic source of political rent that main-
tains the PA’s survival and stabilises its internal patron–client networks. Using economic
leverage to ensure PA political compliance, these transfers are often withheld by Israel to
pressure or punish the PA whenever it pursues policies not approved of by Israel (e.g. fol-
lowing the electoral victory of Hamas in 2006, the PA UN bid for statehood in 2012 and the
PA’s accession to the International Criminal Court in 2014).
The second factor pertains to the central involvement of Western donors and International
Financial Institutions in guiding PA institution-building and economic development. Donors’
involvement is strategically driven by the imperative of ensuring PA functionality and ability
to maintain stability, regardless of Israel’s colonial dynamics on the ground.27 One could
argue that donor policies in the OPT interact with Israeli colonial dynamics in subtle ways
in shaping PA crony capitalism. International aid to the PA is generally conditioned with the
Oslo framework and the promotion of neoliberal governance, private sector-led develop-
ment, lax regulatory mechanisms for investors and regressive taxation regime. In fostering
the private sector, donors appear to favour a few privileged capital groups who would invest
in large-scale projects, mainly in the service sector rather than in agriculture and industries.
Interestingly, donor-driven neoliberalisation of the Palestinian economy is carefully bal-
anced with the vast public sector because PA bureaucracy, employment services, social
provision and security forces constitute the institutional pillar of stabilisation. It is also clear
how donor politics tend to preserve the reinter nature of the PA while disregarding its author-
itarian character, widespread corruption and repressive security practices in exchange for
enforcing stability. Turner notes that donor promotion of these practices constitutes ‘a layer
of pacification techniques through the pursuit of a political economy that stabilises from the
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY 7
inside in partnership with a section of Palestinian elites’.28 Accordingly, donors’ aid to the PA
and certain private actors represents a strategic source for the formation of collusive net-
works in which the favoured PA–business elites are at the forefront of those capturing the
benefits of political rent and investments.
The third factor is associated with the neo-patrimonial politics in the Fateh-dominated
PLO and the PA, which serve to exert control over local constituents. The PA ensures a formal
rational-legal apparatus that accommodates donors’ technical requirements while simulta-
neously extending its informal patron–client system across the bureaucratic hierarchy and
the structures of governance. The coexistence between these arrangements is mutually
inclusive: meeting Israel’s and donors’ demands ensures the flow of external rent, which, in
turn, is redistributed by the PA to its loyal constituents, and as long as the PA’s neo-patrimonial
system secures political stability and weakens opposition, the donors cannot object. This
situation is exacerbated by the absence of democratic and accountability mechanisms thus
encouraging a broad range of corruption.29 The PA neo-patrimonial system rests on two
mutually sustaining pillars. At its base pillar, the PA relies heavily on forging patron–client
networks to ensure that constituents are subservient and stabilise its regime. Thus, a large
public sector and multiple security forces were established to absorb a large segment of the
population and connect this segment to the PA’s webs of interest. From the top, the returning
political and business elite have formed the backbone of the new political–economic reality
of the OPT. While these elite have been ostensibly distributed in both the public and private
sectors, they have jointly operated to construct public–private ventures and informal part-
nerships. Therefore, the PA has forged neo-patrimonial capital networks that bind elite busi-
ness actors to the PA officials, while the latter and their cronies venture into the private
business realm.
Oslo economic giants
Following the initiation of the Oslo process in 1994, and in preparation for the establishment
of new political and economic structures, the PLO chairperson and PA president Yasser Arafat
invited his pre-Oslo business allies to invest in building a viable economy to underpin the
state-building process. In response, a section of wealthy expatriate Palestinians directed
part of their capital surplus towards establishing large conglomerates that have enjoyed
considerable market power.
The Palestinian Development and Investment Company (PADICO) was founded in 1993
and registered in Liberia by small group businesspeople headed by the Al-Masri family with
declared capital of US$1 billion and paid-up capital of US$250 million. As the largest and
most influential holding company in the OPT, PADICO was initially formed to assume a lead-
ing role in the Palestinian private sector by bringing together multiple large business groups
whose capital was mostly headquartered in Jordan and the Arab Gulf region. PADICO estab-
lished subsidiaries in various vital sectors, including the real estate (AQARIA and Rabiyat
AlQuds), tourism (JIT, PTIC and Jericho Gate), telecommunications (Paltel), industrial (PIIC
and VOICE), industrial estate (PIEDCO), electricity (PEC and PPGC), poultry (PPC), electronics
(PEEC), plastics (PPIC), security exchange (PSEC), stock (PEX) and agricultural (Nakheel
Palestine Company) sectors. PADICO enjoys substantial political influence in PA policy for-
mulation and in peace negotiations with Israel. For example, as a staunch advocate of the
free-market economy, Maher Al-Masri, who served as a member of PADICO’s board and in
8 T. DANA
the Fateh ruling party, acted as the PA’s Minister of Economy, Trade and Industry from 1996
to 2002 and played a central role in the formation of the PA’s institutional and legal frame-
works. Maher Al-Masri was also central to the PEP negotiations with the Israelis in 1994 and
joined the Palestinian negotiating team during the Camp David Negotiations in 2000.
Another influential group of investors founded The Arab Palestinian Investment Co. Ltd
(APIC) in 1994 with authorised paid-up capital of US$70 million led by the Al-Aggad group.
APIC was registered in the British Virgin Islands. It quickly became an economic giant that
controlled various sectors of the Palestinian economy. APIC has several subsidiaries that
invest in key sectors, such as the Palestine Automobile Company, the Medical Supplies and
Services Company, the Siniora Food Industries Company, the National Aluminium and Profiles
Company, the Arab Palestinian Shopping Centres, the Arab Palestinian Storage and Cooling
Company, the Unipal General Trading Company and Sky Advertising Public Relations and
Events. Similarly, APIC has been influential in the political sphere by maintaining warm rela-
tionships with the PA political elite. As an example of these relationships, consider the mul-
tiple senior positions occupied by Tareq Abbas, son of PA president Mahmoud Abbas.
While other business entities are active in the Palestinian economy, PADICO and APIC are
the most dominant in terms of market share and political influence. PADICO’s and APIC’s
subsidiaries seem to have been carefully distributed across different economic sectors to
avoid direct competition and, therefore, facilitate quasi-monopolies across strategic sectors
of the economy. As noted by Hanieh, ‘these companies completely dominate the political
economy of the Palestinian territories, and it is almost impossible to find a large- or medi-
um-sized company in which they do not own a significant stake’.30 Thus, these companies
have virtually dominated the Palestinian economy by not only preventing the development
of smaller firms but also widening the socioeconomic gaps between the elite and the pop-
ulation. In a striking example, LeVine suggests that the total GDP of PADICO members is
roughly US$20 billion, which is nearly seven times that of the OPT.31
The 1990s: the era of predatory monopolies
The striking aspects of crony capitalism during the 1990s were expressed in different prac-
tices of predatory rent-seeking, financial corruption and neopatrimonialism. These practices
can be jointly summed up in the form of classical monopolies that characterised the collu-
sive PA–business relations in dominating the local economy. The driving dynamic of these
monopolies involved the expansion of rent-seeking opportunities and the consolidation
of the PA’s rentier structure and patron–client system. Strategically, the monopolies were
driven by a particular configuration of factors and interests that aimed to empower the
emergent PA political and business elite and marginalise non-compliant political actors.
These monopolies were embedded in a complex network of private companies in partner-
ship with political and security officials who went into business either directly or through
protégés. This process was essentially predicated on top-down linkages that were fully
managed by the PA’s president Yasser Arafat and his advisers. The institutionalisation of the
complex networks that operated these monopolies throughout the initial decade of the
PA state-building was described as a ‘security-monopolistic complex’.32 Moreover, this
dynamic was sustained by the direct involvement of Israeli authorities, individual contractors
and businesses, resulting in the mutual forging of beneficial deals through informal
Palestinian–Israeli arrangements.33 These monopolies can be divided into two distinct but
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY 9
interrelated monopolies distributed between the PA and conglomerates and included
public–private partnerships.
Private monopolies are exclusive rights granted by the PA to a selected group of private
investors to run large infrastructure projects such as telecommunications and electrifications.
These vital sectors were privatised from their initiation, thus echoing the World Bank’s policy
recommendation of fostering a private sector-led development. One of the early private
monopolies involved the establishment of the Palestinian Telecommunications Company
(Paltel) in 1995, which subsequently became the OPT’s largest private investment company,
with an initial authorised capital of US$63 million (raised to US$95 million in 1999). Paltel is
a subsidiary of PADICO and is chaired by Sabih Al-Masri. Paltel consists of five arms that
provide the largest telecommunications service network in the Palestinian market involving
fixed lines, mobile operators, internet services, contact centre and media services. In 1996,
the PA granted Paltel an exclusive license to operate the telecommunications sector of the
OPT for 20 years (the contract was renewed for another 20 years in 2016). Since its initial
operations, Paltel has faced accusations of monopoly, misuse of power, corruption and cli-
entelism because it ‘does not collect telephone bills from ministries, governmental estab-
lishments, major shareholders and officials, and it redistributes these costs to other customers
in the form of higher charges’.34 Another source of Paltel’s monopolistic power was the
involvement of the Israeli Peace Technology Fund (PTF) in pursuing a 3.3% share of Paltel,
thereby providing undeclared Israeli protection to the Palestinian telecommunications
company.
Public monopolies are companies that are effectively owned by the PA. According to a
report published in 1999 by the Council of Foreign Relations, the PA created unregulated
and unaccountable public import monopolies that have led to ‘undisclosed commercial
dealings by public servants and to privileged access for private actors to the award of con-
tracts, licenses, and exclusive dealerships’.35 Public monopolies were evident in the estab-
lishment of the Palestinian Commercial Services Company (PCSC) in the West Bank in 1994,
which was chaired by Arafat’s chief financial adviser Mohammad Rashid, and its equivalent
in Gaza, the Al-Bahr Company, which was operated by Hashem Abu Nada, another economic
adviser to Arafat. Both companies held shares in dozens of other private companies, including
APIC. Both companies controlled various imported products, such as tobacco, flooring, meat
and fuel, and oversaw the commercial activities of multiple public–private companies, such
as the Gaza Water and Sanitation Service, the Palestine Industrial Estate Development and
Management Company (PIEDCO), and the Electricity Distribution and Management Project.
Public monopolies have devastated Palestinian economic well-being. For example, the PA’s
fuel monopoly operated by the Palestinian Petroleum Commission has resulted in high prices
for essential petroleum and gas products, which subsequently devastated other economic
activities such as the industrial and agricultural sectors.36
Moreover, these monopolies were characterised by complex collusion between PA and
Israeli political and security officials and businesspeople. Israeli authorities supported the
PA’s public monopolies through the involvement of former Israeli security personnel in part-
nering with Palestinian officials and businessmen to supply and facilitate the entry of
imported commodities from Israel.37 Cooperation with Israel benefited PA businesses by
reducing transaction costs and other expenses at borders controlled by Israel. The revenues
earned from these monopolies were off budget and outside the supervision of the Ministry
of Finance, and they served to finance Arafat’s ‘secret accounts’ in several foreign banks,
10 T. DANA
including Israeli Bank Leumi.38 While these secret accounts helped consolidate Arafat’s power
over local constituents during the 1990s, some amounts were utilised in support of the PLO
fund to sustain martyrs’ families, prisoners and the refugee camps.
Reproduction of crony capitalism (2007–2017)
Over the previous decade (2007–2017), the political–economic relationships and interests
representing a continuation of the 1990s networks have grown in sophistication. The unprec-
edented ascendency of crony capitalism in the West Bank can be attributed to several factors.
First, the reforms undertaken by the PA Prime Minister Salam Fayyad (2007–2013) and the
resulting structures and policies maintained by the subsequent Prime Minister Rami
Al-Hamdallah not only developed and stabilised the crony nature of PA–business elite rela-
tions but also transformed these relations into a legitimate practice protected by legal and
institutional frameworks. Second, the PA’s growing authoritarianism, the professionalisation
of its internal policing and the complete absence of legislative oversight promoted the
concentration of power in the PA’s executive. In the absence of accountability mechanisms,
the ‘Law on the Encouragement of Investment in Palestine’ or the Investment Law of 1998
was amended in 2011 and 2014 by presidential decrees and awarded large businesses
numerous benefits, such as exemptions from capital gain taxes and other tax and non-tax
incentives without referring to the Council of Ministers or the Legislative Council.39 Third,
the PA’s success in incorporating several political factions and civil society organisations,
including labour unions, into its patron–client networks ensured that cronyism and business
elite dominance continued unchallenged. Fourth, the capacity of Israeli authorities to main-
tain compliant elites through a wide variety of economic and political incentives, such as
economic normalisation projects and VIP cards, was central to the empowerment of the PA
political–economic elites.40
The aftermath of the intra-Palestinian division in 2007 has seen new forms of governance
and policies that altered the political economy of the West Bank. These changes were the
product of two simultaneous processes. The first process was associated with the systemic
implementation of neoliberal policies introduced by Salam Fayyad. While neoliberalism had
constituted the guiding framework of the PA’s economic policies since its early years of estab-
lishment, Fayyad’s neoliberal re-arrangement involved technical professionalism, systemic
implementation and acceleratory dynamics.41 Echoing recommendations by international
financial institutions, Fayyad’s governmental programmes emphasised the central role of
the private sector in promoting export-led economic development and building a state.42
This neoliberal vision was sustained by efforts to introduce institutional modernisation and
security reform within an increasingly authoritarian context. By appointing pro-free-market
technocrats and people in business to ministerial positions in his 2007 and 2009 govern-
ments, Fayyad hoped to implement his vision professionally, uninterrupted by Fatah’s internal
competitions over the control of the PA’s ministerial positions. Fayyad’s overall objective was
to create the institutional and economic conditions necessary to establish a Palestinian state.
However, his vision suffered myriad limitations and flaws because it was heavily dependent
on technical approaches and disregarded the structures of colonial power relations.43
The second process was engineered by the Israeli right-wing strategy of ‘economic peace’,
which promised to unleash market forces to improve socioeconomic standards and eco-
nomic development in the West Bank. Key international donors aided these developments,
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY 11
primarily the US and EU, which undertook policy measures referred to in certain circles as
‘The West Bank First Strategy’, which was designed to ‘asymmetrically influence economic
conditions in the newly politically divided areas of the OPT in a bid to influence the political
orientation of their respective populations’.44
Critics suggest that ‘Fayyadism’ and ‘economic peace’ are two sides of the same coin, hinting
at an ideological encounter between the coloniser and colonised.45 In effect, this encounter
has been vastly profitable to Palestinian capitalists, who have benefited from various insti-
tutional and legal reforms implemented by the PA and by Israel’s relative facilitation of trade,
movement and opportunities for Israeli–Palestinian economic partnerships. In 2008 and 2010,
the Fayyad government organised the internationally celebrated Palestinian Investment
Conference (PIC) in Bethlehem, entitled ‘Palestine Open for Business’. PIC was attended by
American and EU officials as well as Palestinian, Arab, Israeli and international investors and
was facilitated by Israel’s easing of control over checkpoints and borders to allow unhindered
access to the business delegates. PIC resulted in several large-scale economic projects involv
-
ing Palestinian, Arab and regional capital with the implicit involvement of Israeli business
interests. In its ‘success stories’ report, PIC proclaims that it attracted substantial investment
in various sectors: initiated the construction of the new city of Rawabi; established industrial
zones; developed the banking and financial sectors; and spurred investments in IT and tele-
communications, particularly through the Paltel group.46 Unsurprisingly, PIC business part-
ners, such as PADICO and APIC, received the lion’s share of these investments.
By 2012, Fayyad’s economic policies had proven to be harmful to the socioeconomic
well-being of Palestinians in the West Bank. The crisis was partially caused by a shortfall in
international funding and the government’s inability to collect taxes from large businesses
due to exemptions granted by the Investment Law. This crisis led Fayyad to introduce aus-
terity measures that affected public sector salaries. In September 2012, weeks of demon-
strations and protests occurred throughout the West Bank, denouncing the government’s
economic policies and demanding Fayyad step down. Driven by concerns regarding his
political ambition, Fayyad presented a new plan of ‘progressive taxation’ that aimed to
increase taxes on large businesses and prevent tax evasion to allow the government to meet
its financial obligations and mitigate the uncertainties created by the PA’s dependence on
international aid. However, two powerful forces challenged Fayyad’s ‘progressive taxation’
plan. The first force involved a coalition of influential business lobbies that rejected Fayyad’s
plan because it would have hindered their capital operations and profits. The second pow-
erful force involved the Fateh party, which felt that Fayyad was externally imposed on PA to
weaken the party’s dominance over public institutions. Pressures from the coalition of large
business lobbies and the Fateh party led to Fayyad’s resignation in 2013. Following Fayyad,
the PA president appointed Rami Al-Hamdallah, who served as the president of the wealthy
Al-Masri family-backed Annajah University in Nablus. The appointment of Rami Al-Hamdallah,
who lacked Fayyad’s charisma and professionalism, was widely considered a reflection of
the power and influence of business elites, particularly of the Al-Masri family, over the PA.
Second-generation monopolies (2007–2017)
Despite the institutional and legal reforms implemented since 2007, the old-fashioned
monopolistic arrangements that hardened the crony relations between the PA and large
business groups in the 1990s have not entirely disappeared. While a few of these monopolies
12 T. DANA
are still active, the monopoly system has been replaced by the second generation of monop-
olistic practices that primarily rely on the inordinate market power and dominant market
share of large companies. Conglomerates such as PADICO and APIC have developed their
economic dominance by manipulating market prices, controlling profit margins and dis-
abling new entry into the market. Accordingly, the monopolies have transformed from pred-
atory, absolute and illegal practices to more subtle, sophisticated and relative monopolies
facilitated by the absence of effective legislative bodies and protected by the PA’s executive.
This transformation has further fuelled the process of power concentration whereby PADICO
and APIC have acquired far-reaching power.
Certain private monopolies remain persistent in strategic sectors. For instance, after hold-
ing a 20-year monopoly over the field of telecommunications (1996–2016), the PA agreed
to extend the Paltel group’s cellular and fixed line licenses for another 20 years. The deal was
signed secretly, consultation with consumer protection groups and civil society never
occurred, and the deal’s contents remain unpublicised. A brief official declaration stated that
Paltel would pay the PA the low amount of US$290 million (US$14.5 million annually) for the
upcoming 20-year period, and the company’s annual profits would amount to US$120,000.47
Critics suggest that by agreeing to the deal, the PA will lose a key source of revenue that
could help limit its reliance on international aid. Given that the telecommunications sector
is vital to the public interest, the deal sparked public outrage, resulting in several campaigns
complaining about Paltel’s expensive and poor services and calling for a boycott of its ser-
vices. Accusations by the public suggest that Paltel is able to continue its monopoly over
the telecommunication sector by bribing PA and Israeli officials to facilitate its operations
and hinder the entry of competitive companies into the local market.
Furthermore, while PA appears to have ostensibly abandoned direct public monopolies,
its current involvement in the market remains substantial. This involvement is managed by
‘independent entities’, most notably the Palestinian Investment Fund (PIF). The PIF was estab-
lished in 2003 to replace the infamous PCSC and act as the PA’s sovereign wealth fund. While
the PIF is supposed to enjoy financial, administrative and legal independence within the
framework of the PA reform programme, its Board of Directors is appointed by the PAs
president. In reality, the PIF Board of Directors and General Assembly exemplify the marriage
between the PA’s political elite and business elites, with both comprising representatives of
PADICO and APIC and other key figures of the PA’s upper echelon. This composition likely
fosters conflicts of interest and influences decision-making processes in favour of members
overlapping political and economic interests. In testimony before the subcommittee of the
Middle East and North Africa of the US House Foreign Affairs Committee in 2014, former US
adviser to the PA James Prince stated the following:
The Palestinian Investment Fund (PIF) is one of the most obvious and controversial tools used
by Abbas to wield inuence and direct favours … the PIF has largely operated as an extension
of the Presidency, a tool by which to curry favours, lavish gifts, and marginalize critics … Under
the rubric of creating jobs, the PIF serves as an economic powerbroker. Increasingly, the Fund is
viewed by average Palestinians as epitomizing the corruption associated with the intertwining
of power, politics, and business.48
The intertwining of power, politics and business is echoed in the case of the Fund’s
Chairman, Mohammad Mustafa, who also serves as a senior economic adviser to Mahmoud
Abbas. Mohammad Mustafa has also combined key positions in the PA’s government,
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY 13
including the former Minister of the National Economy and Deputy Prime Minister, and has
played a central role in launching various private sector initiatives in addition to serving as
a founding CEO of Paltel. Also, he is a member of APIC’s Board of Directors and, simultane-
ously, the PIF owns the sizeable share of 17.47% of APIC. As the main link between the PIF
and APIC, Mohammad Mustafa’s name appeared in the Panama Papers.49 While the involve-
ment of APIC/PIF in offshore activities is not discussed in detail, the Panama Papers confirm
that Palestinian political–economic collusion has become transnational.
The PIF manages several companies and investment portfolios in a range of vital sectors,
including real estate, energy, tourism, banking and the financial market. The PIF 2017 report
shows that it controls total assets of US$990 million, with a growth of 16% relative to the
prior year.50 The Fund’s most prominent monopolistic practice is represented by its ownership
of the Construction Industries Company (Sanad), which controls over 90% of the West Bank’s
cement market. The Israeli Nesher Cement Enterprise, which has a monopoly over the
Palestinian cement market, is the main supplier of raw materials and cement to Sanad.
However, due to its market power, Sanad has a broad capacity to manipulate the local market
regardless of the changing prices in the Israeli market. For instance, in March 2016, Sanad
announced a sudden increase in cement prices, even though cement prices had decreased
by 5% in the Israeli market. This price increase led to soaring construction and housing prices
that caused the Palestinian Contractors Union and the Palestinian Society for Consumer
Protection to protest Sanad’s decision, accusing it of monopoly and manipulation.
Conclusion
The growing interest in the critical political economy of the OPT has equipped the field of
Palestine studies with crucial analytical perspectives regarding subtle dynamics that are not
easily detectable by other single disciplines, and which play key roles in prolonging the Oslo
status quo. As part of this effort, this article demonstrated how crony capitalism as an integral
feature of PA–business relations has functioned as a mechanism to serve the narrow interests
of the elite, to ensure social control, and to dominate the political and economic spheres.
While crony capitalism has very much been in evidence since the establishment of the PA,
the practices of cronyism have grown in sophistication during the last 10 years. This system
emerged out of the exigencies of the Israeli colonial framework and, unwittingly, interna-
tional donors provided a conduit for its institutionalisation by fostering local political–busi-
ness alliances.
Moreover, cronyism is internally structured and promoted by powerful interest groups
who rely on neo-patrimonial and patron–client networks that operate across public institu-
tions, large private firms and Fateh-affiliated social constituents. The primary objective of
sustaining the PA’s robust cronyism networks is to maintain the compliance of the elite and
to ensure the stabilisation of the Oslo political status quo. For the PA political–business elite,
the continuation of the Oslo status quo constitutes a lucrative industry, and it is systemically
maintained by constant security coordination and economic normalisation with Israel.
The understanding of crony capitalism presented in this article offers some explanations
to the persistent unwillingness of the PA’s leadership to reintroduce a new strategy that
would break with the Oslo framework and challenge Israel’s colonialisation. On the surface,
it is clear that the PA crony capitalism helped stabilise the political status quo for a while. In
14 T. DANA
reality, however, crony capitalism is fed by excessive corruption and wealth concentration
in the hands of a few self-interested actors. The more crony practices prevail the more the
internal contradictions of the system intensify and become exposed to the crisis. Crony
capitalism in the West Bank is even more vulnerable because it operates in the highly repres-
sive context of ‘neoliberal colonisation’, which has produced vast inequalities and insecurities.
These outcomes are the antithesis of stabilisation. Indeed, recent years have seen growing
popular mobilisations that place socioeconomic demands at the forefront of the struggle
against PA policies, including the anti-Fayyad government protests in 2012, the teachers’
strike in 2016 and the series of countrywide protests that have broken out against the social
security law in 2018. Such dynamics will likely continue and increase in intensity, particularly
in light of the recent dramatic decrease of international aid to the PA and the subsequent
shift toward higher taxes and credit expansion; a matter that may lead to severe crisis and
probably blow the whole system apart.
Acknowledgements
I would like to thank the anonymous peer reviewers for useful comments made on an earlier draft,
however, any errors are my own. The Author would like to thank the LSE Middle East Center for sup-
porting this research. I am indebted to Mandy Turner for sharing her expertise and to Abdel Karim
Barghouthi and Ibrahim Abu-Lughod Institute of International Studies at Birzeit University for their
valuable support.
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.
Notes on contributor
Tariq Dana is a faculty member in the Program of Conict and Humanitarian Studies, Doha Institute
for Graduate Studies. He was Director of the Center for Development Studies and a Senior Research
Fellow at the Ibrahim Abu-Loughod Institute of International Aairs, Birzeit University, Palestine. He
is also a Policy Adviser for the Palestinian Policy Network (Al-Shabaka).
Notes
1. Abed, The Palestinian Economy; Farsakh, Palestinian Labour Migration to Israel; Hever, The
Political Economy.
2. Turner, “Peacebuilding as Counterinsurgency.
3. Clarno, Neoliberal Apartheid, 89.
4. Bouillon, The Peace Business; Nakhleh, Globalized Palestine.
5. Aligica and Tarko, “Crony Capitalism”; Kang, Crony Capitalism; Bai etal., “Crony Capitalism with
Chinese Characteristics.
6. Haber, “Introduction: The Political Economy, xii.
7. Faccio, “Politically Connected Firms”; Kelsall, “Neo-Patrimonialism, Rent-Seeking and
Development.
8. Manzetti and Carole, “Why Do Corrupt Governments Maintain Public Support?”
9. Haber, “Introduction: The Political Economy, xii.
10. Holcombe, “Crony Capitalism: By-Product of Big Government.
11. Alonso, “Crony Capitalism.
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY 15
12. Hobson, “Disappearing Taxes.
13. Sheeld, “Panama Papers Bubble Chart.
14. Achcar, The People Want, 74.
15. Ibid., 63.
16. Hanieh, “The Internationalisation of Gulf Capital,” 83.
17. Cabral, “1966 Address to the First Tricontinental Conference”; Fanon, The Wretched of the Earth.
18. Popular Front for the Liberation of Palestine, “Strategy for the Liberation of Palestine.
19. Sayigh, Armed Struggle and the Search for State, 231.
20. Nakhleh, Globalized Palestine.
21. Dana, “The Prolonged Decay.
22. Faucon, West Bankers, 72–73.
23. Khan, “Evaluating the Emerging Palestinian State.
24. Bouillon, The Peace Business.
25. Bishara, “Reections on the Realities,” 221.
26. Arafeh, “Long Overdue.”
27. Le More, “Killing with Kindness.
28. Turner, “Peacebuilding as Counterinsurgency,” 97.
29. Shehada, “Does Foreign Aid Accelerate Corruption?”
30. Hanieh, “The Internationalisation of Gulf Capital,” 95.
31. LeVine, Impossible Peace, 114.
32. Hajo, “The Political Economy of Palestine.
33. Roy, “Palestinian Society and Economy,” 12.
34. Nasr, “5 Monopolies and the PNA, 179.
35. S
.
ayigh etal., “Strengthening Palestinian Public Institutions,” 19.
36. Nasr, “5 Monopolies and the PNA.
37. Bouillon, The Peace Business; Roy, “Palestinian Society and Economy, 12.
38. Hilal and Khan, “State Formation under the PNA, 79.
39. Palestine Economic Policy Research Institute, “Evaluation of the 2014 Amendments,” 6.
40. Khatib, Palestinian Politics and the Middle East, 150.
41. Dana, “The Symbiosis Between Palestinian ‘Fayyadism.’”
42. Khalidi and Samour, “Neoliberalism as Liberation.
43. Seidel, “Neoliberal Developments, 4.
44. Samhouri, The ‘West Bank First’ Strategy, 3.
45. Abunimah, The Battle for Justice in Palestine, 29.
46. Palestine Investment Conference, “Success Stories.
47. Palestine News & Info Agency (WAFA), “Paltel, Jawwal Sign.
48. Prince, “Testimony before the Subcommittee,” 6.
49. Oshore Leaks Database, “Muhammad Mustafa’s Prole.
50. Palestine Investment Fund, “Annual Report 2017.
Bibliography
Abed, G. T. The Palestinian Economy: Studies in Development under Prolonged Occupation, London:
Routledge, 1988.
Abunimah, A. The Battle for Justice in Palestine: The Case for a Single Democratic State in Palestine.
Chicago: Haymarket Books, 2014.
Achcar, G. The People Want: A Radical Exploration of the Arab Uprising. Berkeley: University of California
Press, 2013.
Aligica, P. D., and V. Tarko. “Crony Capitalism: Rent Seeking, Institutions and Ideology. Kyklos 67, no. 2
(2014): 156–176. doi:10.1111/kykl.12048.
Alonso, J. L. M. A. “Crony Capitalism and Neoliberal Paradigm (Part I). Accessed May 25, 2016. http://blogs.
lse.ac.uk/eurocrisispress/2016/05/25/crony-capitalism-and-neoliberal-paradigm-part-i/
Arafeh, N. “Long Overdue: Alternatives to the Paris Protocol. The Palestinian Policy Network, 27
February 2018. https://al-shabaka.org/briefs/long-overdue-alternatives-paris-protocol/
16 T. DANA
Bai, C.-E., C.-T. Hsieh, and Z. M. Song. “Crony Capitalism with Chinese Characteristics.” Working Paper.
University of Chicago, 2014.
Bishara, A. “Reections on the Realities of the Oslo Process. In After Oslo: New Realities, Old Problems,
edited by George Giacaman and Dag Jerund Lonning, 223–224. London: Pluto Press, 1998.
Bouillon, M. E. The Peace Business: Money and Power in the Palestine-Israel Conict. London: IB Tauris,
2004.
Cabral, A. L. “1966 Address to the First Tricontinental Conference of the Peoples of Asia, Africa and Latin
America in Havana, Cuba, reproduced in the Journal of Pan African Studies, Vol. 3.e-Document,
December 2009.
Clarno, A. Neoliberal Apartheid: Palestine/Israel and South Africa after 1994. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 2017.
Dana, T. “The Prolonged Decay of the Palestinian National Movement. National Identities 21, no. 1
(2019): 39–55. doi:10.1080/14608944.2017.1343813.
Dana, T. “The Symbiosis between Palestinian ‘Fayyadism’ and Israeli ‘Economic Peace’: The Political
Economy of Capitalist Peace in the Context of Colonisation.Conict, Security & Development 15,
no. 5 (2015): 455–477. doi:10.1080/14678802.2015.1100013.
Faccio, M. “Politically Connected Firms. American Economic Review 96, no. 1 (2006): 369–386.
doi:10.1257/000282806776157704.
Fanon, F. The Wretched of the Earth. New York: Grove Press, 2007.
Farsakh, L. Palestinian Labour Migration to Israel: Labour, Land and Occupation, New York: Routledge,
2005.
Faucon, B. West Bankers. London: Mashrek Editions Ltd, 2010.
Haber, S. “Introduction: The Political Economy of Crony Capitalism.” In Crony Capitalism & Economic
Growth in Latin America: Theory & Evidence, Xii. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press, Stanford
University, 2002.
Hajo, R. “The Political Economy of Palestine: The Transformation of Economic Elites after Oslo”.
Paper given at PASSIA meeting. Accessed April 30, 1998. http://www.passia.org/media/
ler_ public/87/7c/877c0e91-58f3-4ba3-87ed-14c758277873/30_apri1.pdf
Hanieh, A. “The Internationalisation of Gulf Capital and Palestinian Class Formation. Capital & Class 35,
no. 1 (2011): 81–106. doi:10.1177/0309816810392006.
Hever, S. The Political Economy of Israel’s Occupation. London: Pluto Press, 2010.
Hilal, J., and M. Khan. “State formation under the PNA: Potential Outcomes and Their Viability.” In State
Formation in Palestine. Viability and Governance during a Social Transformation, edited by M. H.
Khan, G. Giacaman, and I. Amundsen, 13–63. London: Routledge, 2004.
Hobson, J. M. “Disappearing Taxes or the ‘Race to the Middle’? Fiscal Policy in the OECD.” In States in the
Global Economy, edited by L. Weiss, 37–57. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003.
Holcombe, R. G. “Crony Capitalism: By-Product of Big Government.The Independent Review 17, no. 4
(2013): 541–559.
Kang, D. C. Crony Capitalism: Corruption and Development in South Korea and the Philippines.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002.
Kelsall, Tim. “Neo-Patrimonialism, Rent-Seeking and Development: Going with the Grain?” New
Political Economy 17, no. 5 (2012): 677–682. doi:10.1080/13563467.2012.732275.
Khalidi, R., and S. Samour. “Neoliberalism as Liberation: The Statehood Program and the Remaking of
the Palestinian National Movement.Journal of Palestine Studies 40, no. 2 (2011): 6–25.
Khan, M. “Evaluating the Emerging Palestinian State: ‘Good Governance’ versus ‘Transformation
Potential.’” In State Formation in Palestine. Viability and Governance during a Social Transformation,
edited by M. H. Khan, G. Giacaman, and I. Amundsen, 13–63. London: Routledge, 2004.
Khatib, G. Palestinian Politics and the Middle East Peace Process: Consensus and Competition in the
Palestinian Negotiating Team. London: Routledge, 2010.
Le More, Anne. “Killing with Kindness: Funding the Demise of a Palestinian State.International Aairs
81, no. 5 (2005): 981–999. doi:10.1111/j.1468-2346.2005.00498.x.
LeVine, M. Impossible Peace: Israel/Palestine since 1989. London: Zed Books Ltd., 2013.
Manzetti, L. Neoliberalism, Accountability, and Reform Failures in Emerging Markets: Eastern Europe,
Russia, Argentina, and Chile in Comparative Perspective. University Park: Penn State Press, 2009.
THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY 17
Manzetti, L., and J. Carole. “Why Do Corrupt Governments Maintain Public Support?” Comparative
Political Studies 40, no. 8 (2007): 949–970. doi:10.1177/0010414005285759.
Mustafa, Tahani. “Damming the Palestinian Spring: Security Sector Reform and Entrenched
Repression. Journal of Intervention and Statebuilding 9, no. 2 (2015): 212–230. doi:10.1080/175029
77.2015.1020738.
Nakhleh, K. Globalized Palestine: The National Sell-Out of a Homeland. New Jersey: Red Sea Press, 2012.
Nasr, M. M. “5 Monopolies and the PNA. In State Formation in Palestine: Viability & Governance during a
Social Transformation, edited by M. H. Khan, 168–191. London: Routledge, 2004.
Oshore Leaks Database. “Muhammad Mustafa’s prole. https://oshoreleaks.icij.org/
nodes/15002201.
Palestine Economic Policy Research Institute. “Evaluation of the 2014 Amendments to the Investment
Promotion Law.” Palestine Economic Policy Research Institute (MAS). Background Paper:
Roundtable (7), 2014. http://www.mas.ps/les/server/20141911184613-1.pdf.
Palestine Investment Conference. “Success Stories. 2010 https://www.pipa.ps/les/le/publication/
Success%20Stories_PIC2010.pdf.
Palestine Investment Fund. “Annual Report 2017. Accessed September 28, 2018. http://www.pif.ps/
les/annual_report/AnnualReport2017en.pdf
Palestine News & Info Agency (WAFA). “Paltel, Jawwal Sign New 20-Year License Agreement for
US$290 Million.” Accessed December 28, 2016. http://english.wafa.ps/page.aspx?id=VSWxZ
1a51959051529aVSWxZ1
Popular Front for the Liberation of Palestine. “Strategy for the Liberation of Palestine- the Palestinian
Bourgeoisie. Popular Front for the Liberation of Palestine (PFLP). 1969. http://pp.ps/english/
strategy-for-the-liberation-of-palestine-the-palestinian-bourgeoisie/
Prince, J. “Testimony before the Subcommittee on the Middle East & North Africa of the House Foreign
Aairs Committee on the Palestinian Authority, Israel and the Peace Process: Where Do We Go
From Here?” 2014. http://docs.house.gov/meetings/FA/FA13/20140508/102207/HHRG-113-FA13-
Wstate-PrinceJ-20140508.pdf
Roy, Sara. “Palestinian Society and Economy: The Continued Denial of Possibility.Journal of Palestine
Studies 30, no. 4 (2001): 5–20. doi:10.1525/jps.2001.30.4.5.
Samhouri, M. The ‘West Bank First’ Strategy: A Political–economic Critical Assessment. Waltham: Crown
Center for Middle East Studies, Brandeis University, 2007.
Sayigh, Y. Armed Struggle and the Search for State: The Palestinian National Movement, 1949–1993.
Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1997.
S
. ayigh, Y., K. Shiqaqi, M. Rocard, and H. Siegman. “Strengthening Palestinian Public Institutions: Report
of an Independent Task Force Sponsored by the Council on Foreign Relations. New York: Council on
Foreign Relations, 1999. https://www.cfr.org/sites/default/les/pdf/1999/06/palinstfull.pdf.
Seidel, T. “Neoliberal Developments, National Consciousness, and Political Economies of Resistance in
Palestine.Interventions: International Journal of Postcolonial Studies (2019): 1–20. doi:10.1080/1369
801X.2019.1585921.
Sheeld, H. “Panama Papers Bubble Chart Shows Politicians Are Most Mentioned in Document Leak
Database. The Independent. 2016. http://www.independent.co.uk/news/business/news/the-
occupations-of-people-in-the-panama-papers-a7025736.html
Shehada, Y. “Does Foreign Aid Accelerate Corruption? The Case of the Palestinian National Authority.
Journal of Holy Land & Palestine Studies 14, no. 2 (2015): 165–187.
Smith, P. A. “The Exile Bourgeoisie of Palestine. MERIP Middle East Report 142 (1986): 23–27.
doi:10.2307/3011986.
Turner, Mandy. “Killing the Zombie Peace and Building a New Movement.Mediterranean Politics 21,
no. 3 (2016): 437–441. doi:10.1080/13629395.2015.1126393.
Turner, Mandy. “Peacebuilding as Counterinsurgency in the Occupied Palestinian Territory.Review of
International Studies 41, no. 1 (2015): 73–98. doi:10.1017/S0260210514000072.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. The Palestinian Economy: Macroeconomic and
Trade Policymaking under Occupation. New York: United Nations, 2012.
Woodcraft, C., and K. Islaih. “Company Law and Corporate Governance in Palestine. In The Economics
of Palestine: Economic Policy and Institutional Reform for a Viable Palestine State, edited by C., David
and N. Kanafani, 111–138, New York: Routledge, 2004.
... On a closer lens, the PA is influenced by the state capture of two large Palestinian conglomerates and one public independent entity; The Palestinian Development and Investment Company (PADICO), with critical subsidiaries in telecom, real estate, poultry, stock exchange, and agriculture; The Arab Palestinian Investment Co. Ltd (APIC) with a monopoly over automobiles, medical supplies, food, shopping centres, trading, and so on, and lastly, the Palestinian Investment Fund (PIF) with investment portfolios in tourism, financial markets, real estate, and energy sectors (Dana, 2020). This absolute control of public goods/services reflects the aforementioned "institutional power' of businesses in Palestine. ...
... These conglomerates collectively project cross-sectoral cohesion to block any new market entrants and hold stocks in almost all large or medium-sized companies (Hanieh, 2010). From 2007-2017, crony capitalism particularly thrived under Salam Fayyad's regime due lack of legislative oversight, PA's patron-client capture of labour unions, and VIP cards facilitation of business elites via Israeli authorities (Dana, 2020). ...
Research
Full-text available
This paper reviews the case of Palestine via the lens of instrumental and structural business power, supplemented with crony capitalism. It finds that in Palestine’s case, businesses do have significant power to influence policy decisions via deliberative actions. Hacker and Pierson (2007) rightly uphold that in capitalistic societies, like Palestine, the degree of structural or instrumental business power can vary at any given time. If structural power is not strong, then instrumental tactics like the Oslo Accords or PEP Agreements are utilized to benefit the economic interests of the business and political elite. In Palestine’s case, the structural dependency of the PA upon business conglomerates and Israel’s economy is irrefutable as they are the main sources of employment and production. But what is most unique about Palestine is the prevalence of crony capitalism by the indigenous capitalists who employ instrumental, institutional, and discursive power to maintain their interests. To conclude, businesses in Palestine and its colonizers tend to manoeuvre public policies in favour of their private gains. However, due to its occupied status, the external sources of capitalism tend to overpower the internal sources of capitalism in most cases.
... The most frequently debated proposals presuppose that the Palestinian Authority (PA) will assume governance of the Gaza Strip (Ibrahim, 2024). However, a critical weakness in this option is that the PA is not a capable or legitimate actor even in administering the West Bank let alone a beleaguered Gaza Strip in which it has little popular support (El Kurd, 2018;Dana, 2020). Furthermore, the population of Gaza will not accept an authority that comes into the Strip with a mandate provided by Israeli invasion and mass destruction, especially a Fatah-dominated Palestinian Authority (Molana-Allen, 2023). ...
Chapter
Full-text available
The Israeli war of aggression on the Gaza Strip from 7 October 2023 brought about devastating impacts on the beleaguered and besieged Palestinian territory. With a view to informing the emerging discourse around the “Day After,” this chapter outlines several strategic considerations for the future reconstruction of the Gaza Strip following the 2023–2024 war. It begins by providing a brief contextualisation of the Gaza Strip, the impact of Israel’s 2023–2024 war on the territory, and the estimated costs of reconstruction. The chapter presents several major lessons that can be learned from previous rounds of reconstruction in the Gaza Strip. These lessons are then reflected upon in terms of the extent to which they remain applicable in the context of any “Day After” scenario following the 2023–2024 war, entailing strategic discussion of the issue of who runs the Gaza Strip and the role of regional actors in resource mobilisation. Finally, the concept of “The Day After” is itself subject to critical interpretation in light of the need to end the cycle of rebuilding and destruction in Gaza. The purpose of the chapter is to provide analytical insights to support more effective and grounded reconstruction process in the Gaza Strip.
... 66 The powers embedded within these networks are frequently used, and abused, to reinforce the prevailing status quo, thereby perpetuating a system characterised by cronyism. 67 Most importantly, the Oslo framework and other proceeding frameworks, including the Paris Protocol, have been devised as a trajectory for establishing and maintaining peace, which is essential when understanding and discussing the role of the colonial apparatus in the PA's failures. 68 The Palestinian economy is overwhelmingly influenced by dynamics in the Israeli economy and guided by neoliberal policies pushed by international institutions, that render the Palestinian economy "less viable and more dependent on Israel. ...
Article
Full-text available
Where societal, political, and economic change is the only constant under colonisation, informal care in Palestine has become important within the Palestinian community during crises. This paper examines the question of why Palestinians turn to community solidarity in times of crisis. It argues that the economic and political structures since 1993 do not allow for the provision of formal care capable of mitigating socio-economic crises, thereby incentivising people to rely on informal care. Further, cronyism, corruption, and the ruling classes’ loyalties to social and political systems rather than their communities limit the Palestinian authorities’ political will to enact policies that protect the interests of marginalised individuals. In making this argument, this paper takes as case studies the Social Security Movement, a nation-wide campaign of over fifteen thousand people demanding the reform of the Social Security Law, and informal care practices during Israel’s ongoing aggression on Palestine since October 2023. It relies on press releases of formal and informal institutions, volunteer groups, and NGOs, media coverage, interviews with activists, and other news sources such as local newspapers and news agencies. The findings showcase that the tendency towards community solidarity during crises is an active and aware response to the inadequacy of formal social protection systems and the Palestinian Authority’s absence during crises. It also reveals a deep mistrust in the political system that roadblocks any formal attempts of formulating formal social protective systems.
... The international policy and trade relationship with Israel could be attributed to such an impact in these Pan-American countries.Additionally, the existence of conflict can have a substantial impact on a nation's infrastructure, public health, social order, economy and other areas (Bajpai and Singh, 2021). Moreover, the political dynamics in the area, such as foreign policy choices and crony capitalism, can influence the nature of economic ties and results for Pan-American nations (Dana, 2019). ...
Article
Purpose The study will add to the current discourse on the Israel-Hamas conflict by examining the impact of the war on the stock markets of trading partners. Stock market returns inevitably rise as globalization keeps integrating financial markets and economies around the world. Thus, the impact of war is assessed across a range of indicators that are similar in some way, such as geographic location, political climate or economic standing. Thus, the goal of this study is to investigate how the Israel-Hamas war affects trading partner countries' stock performance. Design/methodology/approach Event study methodology is applied using Morgan Stanley Capital Index (MSCI) as a benchmark index. The influence of the Israel-Hamas war on the world's major stock markets is evaluated using a market model. The study takes into account Israel and its 23 trading partners. To capture the locational asymmetry in the outcome, the countries are further categorized according to their geographic locations. The official declaration of war came on October 7, 2023, a non-trading day. Consequently, October 9, 2023, is designated as the event day in this study. The data was gathered between January 1, 2023, and December 31, 2023, with an estimation period of 140 days taken into account to minimize bias. Findings Asymmetric response is shown among the nations due to their economic standing, geographic proximity and trading links with Israel. While Austria, Greece, Egypt, Palestine and Israel had the greatest negative effects, Argentina, Japan and Chile saw significant beneficial effects. The remaining nations had little effect. The market quickly adjusted itself, eliminating anomalous returns. Research limitations/implications Taking into account the topic's criticality, the current work has certain limits. The study has used the daily data to limit its reach to the stock market exclusively. In the future, academics can combine high-frequency stock market data with data from other macroeconomic variables, such as currency or different commodities markets, to further their research. Furthermore, a cross-national comparison of the impact in terms of direction and intensity regarding developing global groups such as I2U2, LEVANT, BRICS, MIKTA, SCO, NATO, SAARC and OECD can provide a more comprehensive understanding in this context. To gain insight into the durability and adaptation of financial systems over time, longitudinal studies could be conducted to monitor the long-term effects of geopolitical crises on the stock markets of trading partner countries. Practical implications By better managing investment portfolios and evaluating potential risks associated with trading partners involved in such conflicts, investors and businesses can lessen the impact of geopolitical tensions on stock market performance. These results contribute to our understanding of how geopolitical conflicts affect stock markets. Originality/value This research provides an extensive analysis of the global impact of Israel-Hamas tensions on stock market volatility by taking into account trading partners. This allows for the investigation of how various market structures and economic systems react to geopolitical turmoil. The present study is one of the first attempts to look into how disturbances in one region might affect continents to better understand the dynamics of global trade and economic interdependencies.
... Third, the PA's institutional set-up is structured on modern legal and bureaucratic apparatuses and neo-patrimonial networks. This was made possible by the involvement of the international peacebuilding industry and by the flow of international aid and technical assistance by donor agencies and international organizations (Dana 2020). Israel benefited largely from this arrangement because the financial burden of its settler-colonial enterprise was transferred to external parties who have a vested interest in maintaining the very "stability" from which Israel profits. ...
... A common strategy of Western or Westernized politics is to flatten inequalities by constructing seemingly heterogeneous communities based on identity markers in the state's image. The implementation of neoliberal policies, including via the Palestinian Authority (PA), is one such example of creating additional divisionary dynamics among Palestinian communities (Dana, 2020). The initiatives of the people-to-people framework were held in English, promoting precisely such classist division of participants in favor of Palestinians with access to English courses, which are often private. ...
Article
Full-text available
Like roots reaching for the nourishment of familiar ground, generations of resistance lineages continue to weave a worldwide tapestry of solidarity. These efforts help to disrupt various forms of colonial violence, including under the guise of liberal democracies. One of the multiple mechanisms they target is how people and lands are pitted against one another through adversarial categories of difference. Such efforts are a powerful antidote to colonial fragmentations, mobilizing differences via shared goals based on grounded solidarities. This article seeks to answer how anti-colonial struggles in Palestine and Sápmi engage with three ways of structuring similarities and differences. We thereby utilize Coulthard’s (2014) framework of recognition politics, divided into (1) assimilation, (2) multiculturalism, and (3) place-based solidarity. Next to excerpts from local organizers and a speculative dialogue between interviewees, we reference Audre Lorde’s work to better understand the relational qualities of differences. Our research shows that the structural dominance of assimilatory and multiculturalist approaches to difference tends to stabilize injustices while normalizing colonial violence, including via Westernized peace politics like the Oslo Accords or state-led reconciliation initiatives. On the other hand, the integrity of place-based solidarity generates reciprocal relationships and interdependent responsibilities, which undermine colonial divide-and-conquer politics. With the help of our interviewees, this article provides a shared analysis to further the solidarity between the struggles of two of colonial modernity’s most critical fronts, Sápmi and Palestine.
Chapter
This chapter examines the Palestinian Authority’s 0(PA) role in reinforcing Israel’s colonial dominance over the West Bank, portraying it as integral to Israel’s control. It delves into how the Oslo Accords compelled the Fatah-led Palestine Liberation Organization (PLO) and subsequently the Fatah-led PA to serve as enforcers of Israeli interests, effectively co-opting segments of the national liberation movement. The analysis centres on three dimensions: the political, the security, and the economic. First, politically, the PA has stifled anti-colonial dissent through centralised institutions, eroding the PLO’s efficacy as a conduit for Palestinian aspirations. Second, in security matters, the PA’s collaboration with Israeli forces has aimed to suppress Palestinian resistance, ensuring a conducive environment for Israeli dominance. Lastly, economically, the PA perpetuates dependency that favours Israeli interests, prioritising stability over genuine development. These policies consolidate an elite-controlled system, amplifying inequality and stifling dissent. The chapter underscores the PA’s complicity in hindering Palestinian self-determination and its transformation into a mechanism of colonial subjugation.
Article
Full-text available
This essay explores the concept of political economies of resistance in Palestine as an alternative to the anticolonial imaginary articulated by nationalist visions, and the potential for liberation offered by local actors who articulate these political economies of resistance. It considers Frantz Fanon’s vision of national consciousness, its relevance to Palestinian resistance in the context of settler colonialism, and its aid in the articulation of political economies of resistance as a way to imagine otherwise in global politics. The impact of the Oslo peace process is discussed as a signalling of the end of a sort of Palestinian anticolonial utopia, with particular attention to the Palestinian nationalism embodied by leadership such as the Palestinian Authority, and its weddedness to liberal notions of economics and politics. It then considers contemporary Palestinian claims of politics and economies of resistance that are both local and transnational in their articulation, arguing that nationalist commitments to anticolonial utopias foreclose, not only the ability to imagine otherwise in global politics, but also obscure the otherwise already interrupting the histories of colonial modernity.
Article
Full-text available
While the failure of the Palestinian National Movement (PNM) in achieving its stated objectives is widely acknowledged, the causes of this failure are subject to interpretation. The central argument of this article is that the priority accorded by the PNM’s leadership to the statehood ambition over the liberation precondition is a principal factor as it led to transformation of the PNM through the Oslo process. As a consequence, the PNM was stripped of structures, functions, and characteristics typically associated with national liberation movements and therefore categorizing the PNM in its current state as an anti-colonial liberation movement is specious and flawed.
Article
Full-text available
The prospects for a just and sustainable peace are dire. The Oslo framework and the two-state solution are no longer fit for purpose (if indeed they ever were). And yet it is entirely possible that the current situation could limp on for a while longer – like a zombie that refuses to die. This short opinion piece argues that, in this context, a new movement and a new strategy are urgently required.
Chapter
The growing interconnectedness of national economies and an expanding awareness of global interdependence in the 1990s have generated lively debate over the future of national governance. In a world of mobile capital, are states vital to the social and economic wellbeing of their citizens? A number of changes in the state's domestic and international environment - ranging from regulatory reforms and welfare state restructuring to the proliferation of intergovernmental agreements - have promoted the view that globalisation has a negative impact, compromising state capacities to govern domestically. This book challenges the 'constraints thesis'. Covering vital areas of state activity (welfare, taxation, industrial strategy, and regulatory reform), the contributors focus on a range of issues (finance, trade, technology) faced by both developed and developing countries. The contributors argue that globalisation can enable as well as constrain, and they seek to specify the institutional conditions which sharpen or neutralise the pressures of interdependence.
Book
The Peace Business is a study of the evolution and consequences of business cooperation in the Middle East in the years of the peace process. Markus E. Bouillon examines how the engagement of entrepreneurs and businesspeople in the peace process, as well as how the nature of business ties between Israelis, Jordanians, and Palestinians, failed to strengthen and advance peace in the Middle East. In this important contribution to the Israel-Palestine debate, he argues that private business interests undermined economic and political stability domestically and thus contributed to the failure of the peace process.
Book
"The people want . . .": This first half of slogans chanted by millions of Arab protesters since 2011 revealed a long-repressed craving for democracy. But huge social and economic problems were also laid bare by the protestors' demands. Simplistic interpretations of the uprising that has been shaking the Arab world since a young street vendor set himself on fire in Central Tunisia, on 17 December 2010, seek to portray it as purely political, or explain it by culture, age, religion, if not conspiracy theories. Instead, Gilbert Achcar locates the deep roots of the upheaval in the specific economic features that hamper the region's development and lead to dramatic social consequences, including massive youth unemployment. Intertwined with despotism, nepotism, and corruption, these features, produced an explosive situation that was aggravated by post-9/11 U.S. policies. The sponsoring of the Muslim Brotherhood by the Emirate of Qatar and its influential satellite channel, Al Jazeera, contributed to shaping the prelude to the uprising. But the explosion's deep roots, asserts Achcar, mean that what happened until now is but the beginning of a revolutionary process likely to extend for many more years to come. The author identifies the actors and dynamics of the revolutionary process: the role of various social and political movements, the emergence of young actors making intensive use of new information and communication technologies, and the nature of power elites and existing state apparatuses that determine different conditions for regime overthrow in each case. Drawing a balance-sheet of the uprising in the countries that have been most affected by it until now, i.e. Tunisia, Egypt, Yemen, Bahrain, Libya and Syria, Achcar sheds special light on the nature and role of the movements that use Islam as a political banner. He scrutinizes attempts at co-opting the uprising by these movements and by the oil monarchies that sponsor them, as well as by the protector of these same monarchies: the U.S. government. Underlining the limitations of the "Islamic Tsunami" that some have used as a pretext to denigrate the whole uprising, Gilbert Achcar points to the requirements for a lasting solution to the social crisis and the contours of a progressive political alternative.