Technical ReportPDF Available

Informal sector employment and poverty in South Africa: identifying the contribution of 'informal' sources of income on aggregate poverty measures

Authors:
REDI3x3 Working paper 34 March 2017
Informal sector employment and poverty in
South Africa: identifying the contribution of
‘informal’ sources of income on aggregate
poverty measures
Paul Cichello and Michael Rogan
Abstract
We examine the role that informal sector employment plays in poverty reduction using data
from the National Income Dynamics Study (NIDS). Using a Shapley decomposition approach,
we find that government transfers and formal sector jobs are the dominant drivers of
aggregate poverty reduction. Informal sector jobs currently play a limited role in poverty
reduction at the national level. This is primarily driven by the fact that there are relatively
few informal sector jobs compared to formal sector jobs. On a per-job basis, the poverty
reduction associated with formal sector jobs and informal sector jobs is quite similar. The
poverty reduction associated with one informal sector job is generally between 50 to 100 per
cent of the poverty reduction associated with one formal sector job (depending on the
poverty measure, poverty line and year chosen). Therefore, from a poverty reduction
standpoint, policy makers are encouraged to view job gains and losses in the informal sector
approximately on par with gains and losses of formal sector jobs.
The Research Project on Employment, Income Distribution
and Inclusive Growth is based at SALDRU at the University of
Cape To wn and supported by the National Treasury. Views ex-
pressed in REDI3x3
Working Papers are those of the authors
and are not to be attributed to any of these institutions.
© REDI3x3 1 www.REDI3x3.org
Informal sector employment and poverty in South Africa: identifying the
contribution of ‘informal’ sources of income on aggregate poverty measures
Paul Cichello
Department of Economics, Boston College, Boston, Massachusetts
Michael Rogan
Neil Aggett Labour Studies Unit (NALSU), Institute of Social and Economic Research (ISER),
Rhodes University
1. Introduction
Against the backdrop of very high rates of unemployment in post-apartheid South Africa, the
role of the informal sector, the informal economy or informal employment, more broadly1, in
employment creation and overall development has been marginalised. Former state president
Thabo Mbeki famously, and somewhat controversially, identified informal workers as part of
the ‘second economy’ which is characterised by poverty and under-development and which is
structurally disconnected from the formal economy (see Devey et al., 2006; Valodia &
Devey, 2012). Even where there has been some degree of recognition of the importance of
the informal sector to employment creation and livelihoods, policy responses are often
unsupportive. For example, the government’s principle policy document, the National
Development Plan (NDP), has projected that between 1.2 and two million new informal
sector ‘jobs’ (including domestic work) will be needed by 2030 if the country is to meet its
targets in reducing unemployment (National Planning Commission, 2012: 121). The
document is almost completely silent, however, in terms of how the informal sector will be
supported or how current policies can be extended to ensure that the informal sector grows in
line with overall employment growth.
Policy gaps and the lack of recognition of the importance of the informal sector are not
unique to the South African context and two of the key contrasting views of the informal
sector have often suggested that, on the one hand, the sector is an indicator of a ‘backward
and unproductive economy while, on the other hand, it is understood as a critical source of
employment and earnings for workers on the margins of the labour market. In this paper we
explore the case for supporting informal types of employment by considering the extent to
which earnings from informal sector self-employment (and informal employment, more
broadly) contribute to a reduction in income poverty. We argue that, by using a popular,
intuitive and widely understood indicator of development, namely the poverty headcount rate,
1 See the ILO (2013) or Hussmanns (2004) for an overview of these terms.
© REDI3x3 2 www.REDI3x3.org
it is possible to make the case that the informal sector should be an important part of
government’s strategy to reduce income poverty.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section two provides a brief description
of the informal sector in South Africa. In linking the sector to income poverty, the section
also offers a brief review of the post-apartheid poverty literature as well as recent work on
low earnings and ‘working poverty’. Section three identifies the sources of data which are
suitable for measuring both informal sector employment and income poverty. It then
describes the decomposition method and the simulation techniques which we use to measure
the contribution of various employment types to poverty reduction. Section four presents our
findings of the decomposition, highlighting poverty reduction of various types of
employment on both an aggregate and a per-job basis. We place special emphasis on
comparing income from informal self-employment, where jobs are exclusively informal to
income from our formal employment income, where jobs are almost exclusively from formal
sector employers but also present results from other employment types that are either ‘mixed’
(i.e. incorporating both informal sector employers and formal sector employers) or other
employment (i.e. neither formal nor informal sector employers). Section five presents
alternative approaches. First, we decompose the change in poverty reduction over the 2008
and 2012 period. Second, we show the results of a simple simulation of poverty reduction
following the addition of 1 million new informal self-employment jobs. Section six concludes
by considering the case for supporting or developing the informal sector as a way of
contributing to the reduction of poverty.
2 The informal sector and poverty in South Africa
2.1 The informal sector in South Africa
The informal sector constitutes a small share of the total workforce in South Africa, relative
to other sub-Saharan African countries (ILO, 2013; Kingdon & Knight, 2004). Nonetheless,
the sector still accounts for about 17 per cent of total employment or about 2.4 million jobs
according to Statistics South Africa’s official estimates (Statistics South Africa, 2015). A
number of stylised facts about the broad characteristics of employment in the informal sector
in South Africa are now widely accepted. For example, activities in the informal sector are
concentrated largely in the wholesale, retail and trade sector (44 per cent), services (16 per
cent), and construction (16 per cent) (Statistics South Africa, 2015). In terms of status in
employment, most of those working in the informal sector (61 per cent) are self-employed
while 36 per cent are employees (ILO, 2013).
While the informal sector remains a crucial livelihood source for many workers who exist at
the margins of the labour market, it is vulnerable in a number of ways. An analysis (Verick,
© REDI3x3 3 www.REDI3x3.org
2010) of the South African labour market during the 2008 global financial crisis suggested
that, instead of absorbing workers who were displaced from the formal sector, the majority
(64 per cent) of job losses during the immediate crisis period were actually in the informal
sector. Moreover, the informal sector is often ignored in policy documents and, in some
cases, policy responses are openly hostile towards workers in the sector. Further evidence
that the informal sector is vulnerable is seen in work which has shown that informal self-
employment is not a free-entry sector (Kingdon & Knight, 2004) and that there are a number
of barriers to entry (Cichello et al. 2011). A more nuanced analysis, moreover, has suggested
that there is significant segmentation within the South African informal sector itself (Heintz
& Posel, 2008). The informal sector in South Africa, therefore, should not be characterised as
a homogenous sector which can provide free-entry to the unemployed.
2.2 Poverty and the informal sector in South Africa
The main link between the informal sector and income poverty, in broad terms, is through its
contribution to employment creation and earnings. According to a World Bank firm survey in
Johannesburg, informal enterprises were found to generate an average of three jobs- the same
number as small formal firms. While about 44 per cent of these jobs were allocated to
household members, the vast majority (93 per cent) were full-time, paid jobs (Chandra et al.,
2002). With respect to informal traders, in particular, there is additional evidence that
opportunities to trade on a greater scale in concentrated areas (i.e. city centres and markets)
creates the possibility of new opportunities, additional service industries and products (Philip,
2010).
Although earnings tend to be low in the informal sector, an estimate of the contribution by
informal self-employment to total income earned from all employment in South Africa is
about five per cent (Wills, 2009a). In terms of the wider economy, one measure suggests that
the informal sector contributes about 26 per cent of total value added in South Africa. The
same study found that, the sector contributes between 7-12 per cent of South Africa’s total
gross domestic product (GDP) (Budlender et al., 2001; Ligthelm, 2006). In terms of
expenditure, an estimated R51.7 billion (or 6.3 per cent of total household expenditure) was
spent at informal businesses in 2004 (Ligthelm, 2006).
Turning now to income poverty specifically, the main finding from the poverty literature in
South Africa is that the increase in government transfers (in the form of means tested social
grants) during the early 2000s has been the main driver of the well-documented decrease in
income poverty over the past decade (Leibbrandt et al., 2010; Posel & Rogan, 2012; van der
Berg et al., 2008). To some extent, this large impact of government transfers on poverty
reduction has tended to overshadow the contribution of other income sources to reducing
aggregate poverty levels. Nonetheless, a handful of studies (Posel & Casale, 2006; Rogan &
© REDI3x3 4 www.REDI3x3.org
Reynolds, 2015; Vermaak, 2010, 2012) have investigated the link between labour market
earnings and income poverty, specifically. However, most of this work does not distinguish
between formal and informal sector earnings in their respective analyses. One exception is a
study by Rogan and Reynolds (2015) which found that about 41 per cent of workers (both the
self-employed and employees) in the informal sector were below the poverty line in 2012
(compared with 17 per cent of workers in the formal sector) and that about 37 per cent of the
working poor in South Africa are from the informal sector (Rogan & Reynolds, 2015). To the
best of our knowledge, however, there is no research on the contribution of the informal
sector to poverty reduction in South Africa.
3. Data and methods
3.1 Data options: Statistics South Africa’s household surveys
To estimate the contribution of informal-sector earnings to poverty reduction, two types of
information are required. First, the survey must collect information on employment status
which can be used to measure informal-sector employment. Second, the same survey needs to
have comprehensive information on total household income with which to identify
households that are below the poverty line. Despite the availability of many household
surveys in South Africa, there are surprisingly few data sources that capture comprehensive
and well-defined information on both employment and total household income.
Perhaps the logical starting point would be the official Labour Force Surveys (LFSs)
(collected bi-annually between 2000 and 2007 and then quarterly from 2008). Both the LFSs
and the Quarterly Labour Force Surveys (QLFSs) capture comprehensive information on
labour-market status and earnings, and can clearly identify employment in the informal
sector. Estimates of income poverty, however, are difficult to undertake when using the LFSs
since they do not capture comprehensive information on total household income (e.g. income
from social grants and remittances are not measured by most LFSs). The QLFSs are even less
appropriate for poverty analyses since they only capture information on labour-market
earnings (i.e. not total household income). There is, therefore, no possibility for using these
data to analyse household poverty.
In terms of Stats SA’s national household surveys, the 2008/09 Living Conditions Survey
(LCS) and the Income and Expenditure Surveys (IES) are arguably the ideal sources for the
analysis of poverty. The LCS is the source of Stats SA’s official reports on both poverty lines
and poverty levels; it was originally designed as a tool to monitor changes in living standards
and poverty risks over time. In addition to comprehensive information on household income
and expenditure (from which poverty can be measured), the LCS also captures some
potentially useful data on employment. In practice, however, the LCS cannot be used to link
© REDI3x3 5 www.REDI3x3.org
informal-sector earnings to poverty reduction because Stats SA released an aggregated
income variable only, therefore it is not possible to link income with specific types of
employment.2 The IES is, of course, the other main source of poverty estimates in South
Africa but it captures very little information on self-employment and wage-employment.
This leaves the annual General Household Surveys (GHSs) as the last possible source of
‘official’ data on the link between informal employment and poverty. However, the module
on employment is not very detailed and the surveys, therefore, are fairly blunt tools with
which to measure both poverty and informal-sector earnings.
3.2 Preferred data option: The National Income Dynamics Study (NIDS)
Given the limitations of Stats SA’s official surveys in terms of linking informal-sector
earnings with household poverty status, we turn now to an alternative source of data. The
National Income Dynamics Study (NIDS) is a nationally representative household panel
survey which is conducted by the Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit
(SALDRU) at the University of Cape Town every two years (2008, 2010, 2012, 2014). The
NIDS data currently offer the best possible way to link informal earnings with poverty
reduction in South Africa, since a wide range of income sources are captured and the survey
collects detailed information on employment.
However, in terms of the measurement of informal-sector employment there are two
limitations associated with using the NIDS data. These relate to the important distinction
between (1) informal-sector employment and (2) informal employment, a broader and
different concept developed by the International Labour Organization (ILO) and the
International Conference of Labour Statisticians (ICLS). The latter concept is concerned
mainly with working conditions and specifically also includes employees in the formal sector
that work ‘informally’ without regular contracts and/or benefits (also called ‘unprotected
workers’).
Unfortunately, analyses of the NIDS data are not able to provide estimates of employment
numbers for the informal sector as such. This is because the questionnaire does not allow for
a distinction between informal employees in the informal sector and those in the formal
sector. Thus, some formal-sector employees that work ‘informally’ are included in the NIDS
‘informal wage-employment’ numbers. A second limitation is that, when using the NIDS
data, it is not possible to distinguish, among the informally self-employed, between own-
account workers (enterprise owners without employees) and employers (enterprise owners
with employees).
2 Stats SA itself no longer has access to the raw earnings data from the survey so it is not possible to attempt to
reconstruct the aggregate income variable in any way (personal correspondence with Stats SA).
© REDI3x3 6 www.REDI3x3.org
The questionnaire is also different from Stats SA’s labour market and household surveys in
that it includes a separate section of questions for ‘casual workers’. According to the
fieldworker instructions, this category includes a range of occupations such as ‘construction
work, waitressing, gardening or paid domestic work’. Based on the definition3 of casual
work, it is likely that most workers identified in this category would be informal employees
but, again, it is not possible to distinguish whether this employment is in the informal sector
or in the formal sector. Moreover, it is not possible to identify the domestic workers within
this category because ‘domestic work’4 is not an occupational code in the NIDS and there is
no industry-code variable linked with casual work. (In any case, domestic workers are not
part of the standard definition of the informal sector see ILO 2013.) Consequently, the
‘casual worker’ category is problematic as well.
Therefore, the NIDS data leave us with a potentially useful but constrained data source in
terms of analysing employment in the informal sector. Still, it appears to be the best source of
data for the complex task at hand.
3.3 Definitions
We use the NIDS data to define five distinct employment categories (see Table 1). The two
categories of primary use to this analysis are informal self-employment and informal regular
wage-employment. The former includes only the self-employed in enterprises that are not
registered for income tax or VAT. The latter category corresponds to the broad informality
definition of the 17th ICLS. It includes a subset of regular5 wage employees (from both
formal- and informal-sector firms) that are deemed to have informal employment. For our
purposes, we would like this category to be limited to only those workers hired by informal-
sector firms. Therefore, the category adds an additional criterion, ‘non-payment of UIF6
contributions’, to the standard (worker-based) definition of informal wage-employment. This
will improve the likelihood that workers captured in this category are working in the informal
sector.7 (See Table 1 for definitions of the five categories.) As we still cannot eliminate all
3 The actual definition for casual work is given as ‘work that is irregular and short-term, or any work that the
respondent does in addition to any work that she/he had described in the previous questions’.
4 Only domestic workers with regular (i.e. not casual) wage-employment can be identified as a specific
occupational category in the NIDS.
5 The NIDS is unique in that it distinguishes between ‘regular’ employment and ‘casual’ employment and, as
outlined earlier, the questionnaire has two separate modules for regular and casual employees. This makes the
NIDS questionnaire somewhat different from the LFS and QLFS questionnaires.
6 The Unemployment Insurance Fund (UIF) is a government-administered fund to which employees contribute,
through monthly deductions from their wages. Upon involuntarily losing a job, the employee can claim benefits
for a period, an amount that depends on the period of employment and ending wage/salary.
7 This specific criterion has not been used in the South African literature (compare Heintz & Posel 2008 and
Wills 2009). UIF payment is a potentially useful proxy for employment in the formal sector since all employers
and workers are required by law to contribute to the UIF. The only exemptions are for workers working less
than 24 hours a month for an employer; public servants; foreigners working on contract; workers who get a
monthly state (old age) pension; or workers who earn only commission.
© REDI3x3 7 www.REDI3x3.org
those employees who are working for formal-sector firms, this category is recognised as
coming from ‘mixed’ sectors.
Table 1: Informal employment definitions
INFORMAL SECTOR
Informal self-
employment
Self-employed in enterprises that are not registered for income tax or VAT
MIXED: INFORMAL SECTOR PLUS FORMAL SECTOR
Informal
(regular) wage
employment
(augmented)
Employees with regular employment who do not receive both pensions and
medical aid from their employers, and do not contribute to the Unemployment
Insurance Fund (UIF) and who do not have written employment contracts
Casual
employment
Employees with work that is irregular and short-
term, or any work that the
respondent does in addition to their first two wage jobs/self-employment
businesses
FORMAL SECTOR
Formal sector
employment
Self-employed in VAT or tax-registered enterprises;
and
Employees with regular employment who have a written contract or who pay
UIF contributions or who receive both employer-based pensions and medical
aid
OTHER EMPLOYMENT CATEGORIES
Domestic work Employees with regular employment who work in ‘private households’
Subsistence
agriculture Individuals engaged in subsistence agriculture. This is a relatively small
component in the data and is often omitted in the analysis that follows
We suggest that the addition of the UIF criterion to the worker-based definition of informal
wage-employment (i.e. the one frequently used in the South African literature) is a potentially
useful way of narrowing the definition and measurement of ‘informal employees’ to increase
the proportion of those inside the informal sector (i.e. since it is unlikely that informal-sector
employers would deduct UIF payments from their employees). This might be particularly
important when analysing the NIDS data since these data preclude the possibility of
replicating the estimates of informal wage-employment inside the informal sector, as reported
by Stats SA (2015) and the ILO (2013).
Despite the substantial differences in the way in which the NIDS questionnaire measures
employment (compared to the QLFSs), 20088 estimates from the NIDS of the categories of
employment in Table 1 are broadly in line with those from the QLFS. For example, we
estimate that there were roughly 1.3 million workers in informal self-employment in wave 1
of the NIDS (2008), compared with about 1.5 million in the LFS of the second quarter of
2008 (own calculations from wave 1 of the NIDS and 2008 Q2 of the QLFS).
8 We make this comparison with the first (2008) wave because NIDS is a longitudinal survey and the 2008 wave
is the only one that is not affected by any type of survey attrition.
© REDI3x3 8 www.REDI3x3.org
Notwithstanding the important limitations of using the NIDS data to measure informal
employment and the informal sector, we therefore have some confidence that our estimates
are broadly in line with those derived from the official QLFS.
3.4 Methods
In order to estimate how formal and informal sector employment impact poverty, we must
first define and calculate poverty. In this paper, we use the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke (FGT)
class of poverty measures. These measures include the popular poverty headcount ratio (P0),
as well as the poverty gap index (P1) and the severity of poverty (P2) which place increasing
importance on reductions in poverty that occur further below the poverty line. We will
construct these estimates using three possible poverty lines.9
The extent to which (formal or) informal sector employment reduces national poverty rates
depends on three things: the number of jobs the sector creates, the earnings that these jobs
bring to households and the extent to which that increased income reduces poverty in
households below the poverty threshold. We begin our analysis by identifying how income
from various income sources- both labour income and non-labour income- reduce national
poverty levels in both absolute and relative terms, where the relative values are a per cent of
total poverty reduction as compared to a counterfactual with no income. We use the Shapley
decomposition approach (see Appendix A) to estimate the average marginal effect of
individual income sources on the reduction of aggregate poverty rates (Shorrocks 2013). In
order to estimate the decomposition, our analysis makes use of the Distributional Analysis
STATA Package (DASP) module developed by Araar and Duclos (2007). The decomposition
(Araar & Duclos, 2009a) identifies the contribution of each income source to the elimination
of poverty by comparing what the FGT measures would have been without each respective
source of income. By making use of the Shapley values, the model estimates the average
marginal effect of each income source over all possible combinations of income sources.
Next, we consider the total number of jobs classified under each employment category (from
Table 1) and estimate the per-job ‘impacton poverty for each type of employment. For ease
of interpretation, we consider the per million jobs impact on national poverty rates. We then
create ratios using formal employment as the numeraire so that we can estimate the impact of
a typical informal self-employment job on poverty levels relative to a typical formal
employment job.
We then use a similar approach to examine the change in poverty over the 2008 to 2012
period. We decompose the change in poverty rates over the 2008 to 2012 period based on the
9 These poverty lines are as follows: R307, R424, and R594 monthly per capita household income in March
2010 (see Statistics South Africa 2014, Table 2).
© REDI3x3 9 www.REDI3x3.org
changes in income from various income sources. In this case, the relative contributions
represent the change in poverty rates due to an income source relative to the total change in
poverty rates observed of the 2008 to 2012 period, i.e. the poverty reduction since 2008 is
accounted for rather than poverty reduction compared to a counterfactual scenario with no
income whatsoever. These poverty dynamics offer a different perspective and emphasise the
recent changes in the economy. For example, using this approach, even a very valuable sector
of the economy, if stagnant, will automatically offer no impact on the change in poverty,
despite the fact that the income source may well have different poverty reduction levels
attributed to it in the two cross-sectional periods. In practice, we estimated these changes over
time by modifying the Araar and Duclos decomposition coding slightly to allow for an initial
level of income and to list results more suitable for analysing changes over time.
Finally, we demonstrate a simple simulation which illustrates a back of the envelope
assessment of the impact that adding one million new informal self-employment jobs would
have on national poverty rates. This simulation assumes that all jobs would be given to
randomly selected unemployed individuals (either searching or non-searching) and that no
other household income would be affected. We assume the new earnings would come from
random draws from the distribution of earnings from current informal self-employment
jobs.10
4. Findings
4.1 Poverty and informal employment
We begin by presenting aggregate poverty estimates for the South African population as a
whole at Statistics South Africa’s three official poverty lines. In line with the broader post-
apartheid poverty literature, the table shows that, at the official upper-bound poverty
threshold (R594 per capita monthly household income) roughly half of the population is
identified as income poor in the first round (2008- wave 1) of NIDS. At the food poverty line
(R307) about 30 per cent of South Africans live in poor households and therefore are not
likely to be able to meet even their basic food and nutritional needs. While much more could
be discussed in relation to the findings presented in the table, the key point is that the
aggregate estimates of income poverty based on the NIDS data are closely in line with
estimates from Statistics South Africa’s household surveys (in particular the LCS and the
GHSs). As such, the analysis can now be narrowed to a focus on poverty and informal
employment.
10 In practice, we identify the mean (µ) and standard deviation (s) of log earnings for existing informal self-
employment jobs. For each unemployed individual that is randomly selected to get one of these new jobs, we
create pay by taking e(µ+zs) where z is a randomly generated number from the standard Normal distribution.
© REDI3x3 10 www.REDI3x3.org
Table 2 Poverty estimates (Pα) for South Africa, 2008
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
P0
0.287
0.406
0.521
(0.004)
(0.004)
(0.005)
P1
0.122
0.183
0.264
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.003)
P2
0.073
0.112
0.168
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
Source: Own calculations from NIDS (2008)
Notes: Standard errors are in brackets. All poverty lines and income are
measured in March 2010 prices. Household well-being is estimated as average
per capita total household monthly income.
Income from the formal sector is of unparalleled importance when it comes to overall income
received by South Africans. This is immediately apparent in the first column of Table 3,
which shows that such income comprises 56.7% of total per capita income received by
households. In comparison, informal self-employment adds just 3.1% and our two mixed
categories- informal wage employment and casual employment- comprise just 2.4 and 2.2 per
cent of income, respectively. Non-labour income categories are also important but none,
other than imputed rental income (15.6%), garner more than a 7 per cent share of income.
However, the relative importance of income sources to poverty reduction11 looks markedly
different. When we decompose the contribution of income sources to poverty using, for
example, the food poverty line of 307 Rand, income from formal sector employment
accounted for a 26.9 percentage point reduction in the 2008 poverty headcount (see column
3). This 26.9 percentage point reduction in poverty represents 37.7 per cent of the total
reduction in poverty (see column 2). While still the largest single contributing income source
to poverty reduction, formal sector earnings now account for just 37.7 per cent of poverty
reduction even though it accounted for 56.7 per cent of total income received. In contrast,
social grants account for 20.7 per cent of overall poverty reduction despite accounting for just
6.6 per cent of all income received by households.
The reason for this is that social grant income is well targeted to households that would
otherwise be below the poverty line. Additionally, the grant income is not so large that
households who receive it end up well above the poverty line. Much more of the money is
having a poverty reducing impact. In contrast, formal sector earnings are either not going to
households that would otherwise be poor or are adding so much to those household incomes
that the household ends up far beyond the poverty level (i.e. much of the income is not
poverty-reducing).
11 For the full poverty decomposition results for P1 and P2 see Appendix B.
© REDI3x3 11 www.REDI3x3.org
Table 3 Decomposition of the poverty headcount (P0) by income source, 2008
In Table 4 we present the share of poverty reduction from each income source divided by the
overall share of income. These ‘poverty-effectivenessratios fall between a range of 0.4 for
investment income to 3.21 for social grants. The key finding from the table is that income
from types of employment other than the formal sector is relatively effective in reducing
poverty even if their absolute contribution to aggregate reductions in poverty was small. For
example, the ratio of poverty reduction shares to income shares is greater than two (at all
three poverty lines) for domestic work. This suggests, as outlined above, that income from
domestic work is particularly well targeted to workers from poor households and that it is
important in lifting domestic workers and their households above the poverty line. In terms of
earnings from our two mixed categories of informal employment, the poverty-reducing
effectiveness of these types of jobs is also relatively high. The ratios for informal regular
wage jobs are just under two at all three poverty lines. Interestingly, the ratios for informal
sector employment are somewhat lower (1.14, 1.13 and 1.16 at the three poverty lines,
respectively). This suggests that income from informal sector enterprises is either less well
targeted to workers below the poverty line or that, where it is received, it is not enough to
move households out of poverty (relative to income from other types of informal
employment). More broadly though, the income from informal sector self-employment still
Income Source
Income
Share
Relative Absolute Relative Absolute Relative Absolute
0.031 -0.036 -0.025 -0.035 -0.021 -0.036 -0.017
(0.005) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001)
0.024 -0.044 -0.031 -0.045 -0.027 -0.043 -0.020
(0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.003) (0.001)
0.022 -0.038 -0.027 -0.038 -0.023 -0.033 -0.016
(0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001)
0.010 -0.026 -0.018 -0.024 -0.014 -0.021 -0.010
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001)
0.567 -0.377 -0.269 -0.438 -0.260 -0.500 -0.239
(0.012) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.006) (0.004)
0.066 -0.207 -0.147 -0.148 -0.088 -0.099 -0.047
(0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.001)
0.070 -0.028 -0.020 -0.033 -0.020 -0.037 -0.018
(0.007) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001)
0.048 -0.056 -0.040 -0.054 -0.032 -0.048 -0.023
(0.008) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001)
0.156 -0.180 -0.129 -0.179 -0.106 -0.176 -0.084
(0.004) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.004) (0.002)
Total 11 -0.713 1 -0.594 1 -0.479
(0) (0) (0.004) (0) (0.004) (0) (0.005)
Remittance
income
Imputed rental
income
Casual
employment
Domestic work
Formal sector
employment
Social grant
income
Investment
income
Informal regular
wage emp.
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
Informal self-
employment
© REDI3x3 12 www.REDI3x3.org
has a substantially higher ‘poverty-effectiveness’ ratio than earnings from the formal sector
(0.66, 0.77 and 0.88, respectively).
Before moving on, a few points are worth noting. First, using this simple approach, social
grant income appears well targeted and it is clearly a critical lynchpin in aggregate poverty
reduction. Second, formal sector employment- in aggregate- is crucial to overall poverty
reduction in South Africa. Formal sector income may not be particularly well distributed (i.e.
among those residing in poor households), but it is such a dominant portion of the overall
income that it is a vital component to poverty reduction overall (even though the ratio of
relative poverty reduction to overall income share is only 0.66). Third, policymakers should
also distrust notions that increases in informal sector employment, alone, would solve
national poverty issues. Despite a moderate level of poverty-effectiveness (the ratio of
poverty reduction to the overall income share derived from informal self-employment, for
example, is 1.14 at the food poverty line), the total income provided by this sector is too
small to eliminate national poverty.
Table 4 Poverty-effectiveness ratios for the decomposition of the poverty headcount (P0), 2008
Income Source Income Share Z = 307 Z = 424 Z = 594
Poverty-effectivenss ratios
Informal self-
employment
0.03
1.14
1.13
1.16
1.81
1.48
Informal regular
wage emp.
0.02
1.86
1.90
2.13
Casual
employment
0.02
1.74
1.72
Domestic work
0.01
2.59
2.41
0.88
Formal sector
employment
0.57
0.66
0.77
Social grant
income
0.07
3.12
2.24
1.49
0.53
Remittance
income
0.05
1.18
1.14
1.02
Investment
income
0.07
0.40
0.47
1.12
Imputed rental
income
0.16
1.15
1.14
© REDI3x3 13 www.REDI3x3.org
Tables 5 and 6 present the results of the same decomposition analysis for each of the FGT
indicators based on 2012 data (using the official upper-bound poverty threshold of R594)12.
These results demonstrate how the poverty-effectiveness of social grant income becomes
more prominent for P1 and P2 measures as compared to the simple poverty headcount ratio
(P0). Likewise, formal sector earnings perform worse in poverty effectiveness as the alpha
increases to 1 and 2. This is again intuitive. As the alpha increases, our poverty measure
places increasing emphasis on income that draws households closer to the poverty line even if
they don’t reach it outright. Well-targeted social grant income, which flows into poor
households that still don’t get above the poverty line, will now receive more weight in
poverty reduction measures, whereas a sizeable portion of formal sector earnings would have
zero poverty impact once the household has crossed the poverty line.
The change in poverty-effectiveness of income from informal self-employment also tends to
decline but only slightly as the p-alpha measures increase. For example, the decline in 2008
for the R 307 poverty line is from 1.14 to 1.06 as compared to a decline from 0.66 to 0.44 for
formal sector employment. This small decline holds up across all our various poverty lines in
each year. The same is true for informal wage employment. For casual employment, the
12 Appendix C shows the results at the two lower poverty lines.
Income Source
Income
Share
Relative Absolute Relative Absolute Relative Absolute
0.026 -0.037 -0.022 -0.037 -0.030 -0.036 -0.032
(0.003) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
0.024 -0.037 -0.022 -0.037 -0.030 -0.036 -0.032
(0.004) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
0.013 -0.027 -0.016 -0.029 -0.024 -0.030 -0.026
(0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
0.012 -0.023 -0.014 -0.029 -0.024 -0.028 -0.025
(0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
0.635 -0.543 -0.323 -0.390 -0.317 -0.339 -0.301
(0.013) (0.006) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004)
0.071 -0.116 -0.069 -0.226 -0.184 -0.259 -0.230
(0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002)
0.057 -0.027 -0.016 -0.023 -0.019 -0.023 -0.020
(0.007) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
0.024 -0.034 -0.020 -0.042 -0.034 -0.043 -0.039
(0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
0.135 -0.150 -0.089 -0.181 -0.147 -0.200 -0.178
(0.005) (0.004) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Total 1 1 -0.595 1 -0.813 1 -0.888
(0) (0) (0.005) (0) (0.002) (0) (0.002)
Investment
income
Remittance
income
Imputed rental
income
Social grant
income
Table 5 Decomposition of poverty (Z = 594) by income source, 2012
P
0
P
1
P
2
Informal self-
employment
Informal regular
wage emp.
Casual
employment
Domestic work
Formal sector
employment
© REDI3x3 14 www.REDI3x3.org
poverty-effectiveness ratios actually increase or hold almost identical. This is in stark contrast
to the consistent large increases for social grants and decreases in formal sector earnings.
We now turn our focus to the per-job impact on poverty rather than the aggregate impacts.
While the NIDS survey does not necessarily capture every job an individual has, it does
capture the vast majority of jobs. For example, self-employment jobs are captured separately
from regular (formal or informal) wage employment and casual employment. So if an
individual has two jobs of different types, the survey captures both. Additionally, the NIDS
questionnaire captures information on the first two of each respondent’s regular wage
employment jobs. The survey also captures whether the individual has more than one self-
employment job but does not collect any information on this second job. In the analysis
below, we assume the second self-employment job is in the same sector (formal or informal)
as the first self-employment job.
Table 7 again shows that the formal sector employment is, by far, the largest source of
employment, providing more than 10 million jobs in 201213. Formal employment is also
dominant with respect to the income it provides per job. The income from one million formal
(sector) jobs would constitute a 6.1 per cent share of total income, while other types of
employment provide no more than 2.0 per cent of aggregate income per million jobs. For the
13 Appendix D shows the same estimates for the depth and severity of poverty. Similarly, Appendix E shows the
full range of relative poverty impacts at all three poverty lines for P0-P2.
Poverty-effectiveness ratios
Income Source Income Share P0P1P2
Table 6 Poverty-effectiveness ratios for the poverty (Z = 594) by income source, 2012
Informal self-
employment
0.03
1.40
1.39
1.36
1.53
Casual
employment
0.01
2.10
2.30
2.35
Informal regular
wage emp.
0.02
1.56
1.57
2.43
Formal sector
employment
0.63
0.86
0.61
0.53
Domestic work
0.01
1.97
2.48
3.64
Investment
income
0.06
0.48
0.41
0.40
Social grant
income
0.07
1.64
3.19
1.78
Imputed rental
income
0.14
1.11
1.34
1.48
Remittance
income
0.02
1.38
1.71
© REDI3x3 15 www.REDI3x3.org
reasons highlighted previously, namely the relatively low poverty effectiveness of income
from formal sector employment, the total poverty reduction per million jobs from formal
sector employment is not exceptionally larger than the reduction from the other employment
categories shown in the table. For example, the per-job impact on poverty from informal
sector self-employment is approximately 63 per cent of that of a formal job if one uses the
food poverty line (see column 4). Informal regular wage employment is even higher at 81 per
cent. In other words, the decomposition analysis suggests that the loss of 100 informal sector
self-employment jobs and the loss of 63 formal jobs have a similar impact in terms of overall
poverty reduction.
Across all three poverty lines and p-alpha values, the per-job impact on poverty reduction,
relative to formal jobs, ranges from 39 per cent (for casual work when measuring P0 at the
R594 poverty line) to 108 per cent (for both informal regular wage employment and domestic
work when measuring P2 at the R307 food poverty line). In other words, the relative
contribution of different types of ‘informal’ jobs to poverty reduction varies considerably
depending on the poverty line and the FGT measure (p-alpha values). More specifically,
however, the decompositions show that, at the food poverty line, informal regular wage jobs
and domestic work actually have a larger relative impact on the severity of poverty (P2) per
job than formal types of employment (as shown in Table E-3 in Appendix E). In terms of the
impact of informal sector self-employment, the relative per-job impact on poverty reduction
ranges from 48 per cent (P0 at the R594 line) to 88 per cent (P2 at R307 line). The key
conclusion here, therefore, is that the importance of informal sector self-employment to
poverty reduction is greater at the lowest poverty line and particularly for workers who live in
households further below the poverty threshold. This particular finding is critically important
for policymakers since it demonstrates that, for the poorest households, the impact of
earnings from informal sector self-employment are almost as important as earnings from
formal jobs, even though earnings are considerably lower in the informal sector. This again
points to the conclusion that informal sector jobs are ‘well targeted’ to poor households and
particularly to households relatively far below the poverty line.
© REDI3x3 16 www.REDI3x3.org
Income Source
Number of
jobs
Share of
income per
million jobs
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Informal self-
employment
1,462,314 0.018 -0.021 0.63 -0.018 0.56 -0.015 0.48
Informal regular
wage emp.
1,185,124 0.020 -0.027 0.81 -0.023 0.71 -0.019 0.60
Casual
employment
1,358,512 0.009 -0.018 0.54 -0.015 0.45 -0.012 0.38
Domestic work 923,511 0.013 -0.028 0.85 -0.024 0.74 -0.015 0.48
Formal sector
employment
10,400,000 0.061 -0.033 1-0.033 1-0.031 1
Table 7 Relative impact of jobs on poverty headcount (P0) by income source, 2012
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
© REDI3x3 17 www.REDI3x3.org
5. Additional approaches
5.1 Change in poverty over time
Next we examine the changes in poverty over time during the 2008 to 2012 period using a
panel of respondents in both the 2008 and 2012 survey and weights that adjust for attrition
over time.14 Table 8 shows the considerable decline in poverty over the 2008 to 2012 period
is visible under all measures of poverty regardless of the poverty line.
Table 8 Change in poverty estimates (P
α
) for South
Africa, 2008-2012
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
P0
-0.077
-0.092
-0.104
(0.004)
(0.004)
(0.004)
P1
-0.038
-0.049
-0.064
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.003)
P2
-0.024
-0.034
-0.045
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
Growth in earnings from formal employment accounted for nearly all the change in income
over the 2008 to 2012 period (See Table 9). Some income categories, such as informal self-
employment, saw little change in aggregate income while the change in other categories
counterbalanced each other, with some categories gaining income (informal regular wage
employment and social grant income) and others suffering significant losses (remittances).
Formal sector employment accounts for the majority (60 per cent) of the reduction in the
poverty headcount ratio in the 2008 to 2012 period. Social grants, again, play a vital role at
18 per cent. Despite a large decline in remittances, this had little to no impact on poverty
rates. Informal wage employment seems to play a larger role on poverty reduction (8.0 per
cent) than in the cross-sectional results while informal self-employment income has a similar
relative effect on poverty reduction, accounting for 3.2 per cent of the change in poverty.
14 One important caveat is that the aggregate poverty changes shown in Table 8 are much larger than those
reported in the broader literature. Since NIDS is the only nationally representative panel survey in South Africa,
the poverty results presented here are not easily comparable with repeated cross-sectional surveys. Nonetheless,
caution should be exercised when interpreting the decompositions over time since the decreases in poverty are
not in line with aggregate estimates from other studies. The results presented in Tables 9 and 10 are therefore
only broadly illustrative of how informal sources of income contributed to poverty reduction in the NIDS
sample.
© REDI3x3 18 www.REDI3x3.org
Table 10 reminds us that the aggregate impact on poverty from one particular income source
depends on both the size of the change in income and the resulting per-Rand reduction in
poverty. As before, the per-Rand impact of formal sector income on poverty reduction
appears to be quite low compared to many other sources of income. Informal self-
employment and domestic work stand out for their high per-Rand effects on poverty
reduction.
There is some caution in these results, however. The odd sign on the casual employment
figures and the extremely large relative ratios for informal self-employment are likely signals
that some of these results are driven by the change in the composition of households that are
engaged in these activities over time, which this method does not model. For example,
informal self-employment accounts for 3.2 per cent of poverty reduction despite only
accounting for 0.2 per cent of income growth. It’s unlikely that the same households were
taking part in informal self-employment in both years and that this small increase in income
suddenly moved a large number of them out of poverty. Instead, there was likely a shift in the
composition of households that were engaged in informal self-employment, with a higher
proportion of households who were just over the poverty line taking part. These small
compositional shifts, and even measurement error problems, can have large impacts on our
results in Table 10 as these are ratios where we use the change in the share of income over
time in the denominator rather than the share of income at a point in time. These ratios are
particularly susceptible if the ratio is near zero, as is the case with informal self-employment
income (.002). Thus, while the results actually amplify the importance of informal
Income Source
Income
Share
Relative Absolute Relative Absolute Relative Absolute
0.002 0.032 -0.003 0.035 -0.002 0.031 -0.001
(0.042) (0.011) (0.001) (0.012) (0.001) (0.013) (0.001)
0.064 0.080 -0.008 0.064 -0.004 0.058 -0.003
(0.03) (0.011) (0.001) (0.012) (0.001) (0.014) (0.001)
-0.016 0.030 -0.003 0.031 -0.002 0.032 -0.001
(0.011) (0.011) (0.001) (0.013) (0.001) (0.016) (0.001)
0.022 0.053 -0.005 0.048 -0.003 0.035 -0.002
(0.011) (0.008) (0.001) (0.009) (0.001) (0.01) (0)
0.971 0.596 -0.062 0.558 -0.036 0.542 -0.025
(0.113) (0.025) (0.003) (0.027) (0.002) (0.032) (0.002)
0.081 0.178 -0.019 0.258 -0.016 0.288 -0.013
(0.017) (0.014) (0.002) (0.018) (0.001) (0.022) (0.001)
0.014 0.005 0.000 0.018 -0.001 0.022 -0.001
(0.038) (0.006) (0.001) (0.006) (0) (0.007) (0)
-0.171 -0.007 0.001 -0.016 0.001 -0.011 0.000
(0.108) (0.012) (0.001) (0.013) (0.001) (0.015) (0.001)
0.043 0.043 -0.004 0.017 -0.001 0.016 -0.001
(0.034) (0.012) (0.001) (0.014) (0.001) (0.018) (0.001)
Total 1 1 -0.104 1-0.064 1-0.045
(0) (0) (0.004) (0) (0.003) (0) (0.002)
Investment
income
Remittance
income
Imputed rental
income
Social grant
income
Table 9 Decomposition of change in poverty (Z = 594) by income source.
P
0
P
1
P
2
Informal self-
employment
Informal regular
wage emp.
Casual
employment
Domestic work
Formal sector
employment
© REDI3x3 19 www.REDI3x3.org
employment relative to formal employment compared to our earlier cross-sectional analysis,
they are likely more prone to errors.
Our dynamic analysis also looked at the change in employment over time for each type of
employment (results not shown). Despite the stagnant income, there was a considerable loss
of informal self-employment jobs. The decline in informal self-employment jobs appears to
be a lost opportunity for increased poverty reduction during this period.
5.2 Simulated increase of one million new informal self-employment jobs
The previous analysis offered one approach to understanding the impact of informal-sector
jobs on poverty. The Shapley decomposition demonstrated a way to look at the observed
aggregate poverty reduction at a point in time (or change across time) and attribute the
influence of each income source to this poverty reduction. From the results of that
decomposition, we could calculate the implied per-job impact on poverty reduction of an
informal self-employment job or an informal wage-job. We could also use this information to
identify the poverty reduction per one million informal-sector jobs.
In this section, we take an entirely different approach. We simulate a situation with additional
informal self-employment jobs directly. Then, we see how much the poverty rates decline
once the simulated additional earnings are added to household income per capita.
Specifically, we simulate the impact that adding one million new, informal, self-employment
jobs would have on national poverty rates using the 2012 data. We assume that the new jobs
Income Source
Income
Share
Relative
Ratio
Absolute
Ratio
Relative
Ratio
Absolute
Ratio
Relative
Ratio
Absolute
Ratio
0.37
0.02
Imputed rental
income
0.04
0.99
0.10
0.39
0.03
1.60
0.07
Remittance
income
-0.17
0.04
0.00
0.09
0.01
0.06
0.00
Investment
income
0.01
0.32
0.03
1.29
0.08
Social grant
income
0.08
2.22
0.23
3.20
0.20
3.58
0.16
0.56
0.03
0.04
Formal sector
employment
0.97
0.61
0.06
0.57
0.14
1.57
0.07
Casual
employment
-0.02
-1.86
0.19
-1.96
0.12
Domestic work
0.02
2.37
0.25
2.16
0.06
0.91
0.04
-2.00
0.09
Informal regular
wage emp.
0.06
1.25
0.13
0.99
Table 10 Ratios for the decomposition of the change in poverty (Z = 594) by income source.
P
0
P
1
P
2
Informal self-
employment
0.00
14.70
1.54
15.75
1.00
14.01
0.63
© REDI3x3 20 www.REDI3x3.org
would be given to randomly selected unemployed individuals (either searching or non-
searching) and that no other household income would be affected. Likewise, we take
household formation as exogenous. We also assume that the new earnings would come from
random draws from the distribution of earnings from current informal self-employment jobs.
Given that we start at the current household income level, there may be considerably lower
impact on poverty rates than that found in earlier decomposition results. However, income
levels in households with unemployed individuals could be lower than that of the current self-
employed, resulting in a larger poverty impact.
In Table 11 we report results from this simple simulation by presenting the change in poverty
for all the three poverty measures. For example, if one million more of these informal self-
employment jobs were added to the economy, we estimate that the poverty rate at the R307
threshold would decrease from 19.2% to 17.5% (or decrease by 8.5%). At the upper-bound
poverty line, the relative decrease in the poverty headcount after ‘adding’ these jobs would be
about 6%. Again, this demonstrates that income from self-employment in the informal sector
is particularly important for individuals in the poorest households. The fact that relative
decreases in the severity of poverty are even greater after simulating one million new jobs,
reinforces this point (e.g. the severity of the poverty index would decrease by 12.5% as
compared to the 8.5% decline in the poverty headcount at the lowest poverty line under this
simulated scenario). Across the various poverty lines and p-alpha measures, the simulation
results in a reduction of poverty of between 6.0 and 12.5 per cent, with an average reduction
of 9.6 per cent.
One of the initial findings of this chapter was that formal employment is the dominant factor
in explaining aggregate poverty reduction, with informal-sector employment offering
relatively little impact on aggregate poverty rates. On the other hand, we found that, in terms
of relative poverty-reducing effectiveness, changes in informal-sector income are more potent
than formal-sector income as also illustrated in the per-million-jobs impact analysis earlier.
The simulation results here also suggest that a massive surge in informal self-employment
jobs would lead to a significant reduction in national poverty figures. Therefore, this should
be considered as an element of addressing poverty; however, even with such a massive
growth in informal-sector jobs, there would still be vast swathes of poverty remaining. Thus,
it cannot be the only strategy in the fight to reduce poverty.
2012 Simulated % change 2012 Simulated % change 2012 Simulated % change
P(0) 0.192 0.175 -8.5% 0.294 0.269 -8.5% 0.405 0.381 -6.0%
P(1) 0.074 0.065 -11.5% 0.121 0.109 -10.0% 0.187 0.171 -8.5%
P(2) 0.041 0.036 -12.5% 0.068 0.061 -11.1% 0.112 0.101 -9.8%
Z = 594
Z = 424
Z = 307
Table 11 Simulation: Change in poverty headcount if add 1 million new informal self-employment jobs
© REDI3x3 21 www.REDI3x3.org
6. Concluding remarks
Formal sector earnings and social grants are, by far, the most important sources of income in
explaining the total amount of poverty alleviation in South Africa in 2008 and in 2012. Yet,
the reasons are quite distinct. A large amount of formal sector earnings flows into non-poor
households but the earnings form such a dominant share of total income in South Africa,
63.5% in 2012, that formal sector earnings accounts for 42.6% of poverty reduction using the
food-poverty line. Social grants, on the other hand, are targeted overwhelmingly towards
poor households. Thus, while they comprise just 7.1% of total income, they account for
20.9% of overall poverty reduction.
Similarly, earnings from formal sector jobs account for 24.1 times the amount of overall
income as informal self-employment jobs but just 11.4 times the amount of aggregate poverty
reduction as informal self-employment jobs. Still, this large disparity may make it tempting
for policymakers to focus very heavily on improving the number of formal sector jobs in an
attempt to ease poverty. We believe that is a faulty interpretation of reality.
The large disparity in aggregate poverty reduction is primarily driven by the fact that there
are many more formal sector jobs not by the difference in poverty impact of a given job.
When considering poverty impacts on a per-job basis, the relative worth of informal sector
jobs is greatly amplified. For example, in 2012, there were 7.1 times as many formal sector
jobs as informal self-employment jobs. Thus, on a per-job basis, in 2012, formal sector jobs
were providing just 1.60 times the poverty reduction as informal self-employment jobs. Put
differently, on average, an informal self-employment job had 63% of the poverty reduction
impact of a formal employment job in 2012.
So what is a policy maker to learn from these results? First, do not shut down any informal
sector jobs unless there is a dire reason to intervene. If you are considering a policy that
would eliminate 100 typical informal self-employed jobs, ask yourself the following, “Would
I be willing to lose 63 typical formal sector jobs to implement this policy?” Our
decomposition analysis suggests that the poverty effects associated with those two scenarios
is the same. Obviously poverty is not the only consideration, but we hope this puts the stark
nature of the decision making in perspective.
Second, we believe the potential poverty reduction from growing informal sector jobs has
been understated in policy discussions. While we long for the day when all South Africans
can enjoy jobs with earnings levels well beyond the poverty line, we should not denigrate
work that brings people in very low incomes closer to or just past the poverty line.
Government should pride itself on helping these jobs to exist and should search for ways to
promote such jobs. The search for cost-effective strategies of promoting such employment
© REDI3x3 22 www.REDI3x3.org
should cover the entire spectrum of options, from street lighting or other infrastructure
changes that can be provided, to improved regulatory environments for the informal sector, to
provision of social protection, to helping informal sector firms bargain with formal firms, to
effective training of such workers. A period of exploratory approaches, ideally accompanied
by proper evaluations of effectiveness, could greatly improve the number and quality of
informal sector jobs.
References
Araar, A.,Duclos, J.-Y. (2007). DASP: Distributive Analysis STATA Package. PEP, CIRPÉE and
World Bank, Université Laval.
Araar, A.,Duclos, J.-Y. (2009a). An algorithm for computing the Shapley value. PEP and CIRPÉE.
Araar, A.,Duclos, J.-Y. (2009b). User Manual for STATA Package DASP: Version 2.0. PEP,
CIRPÉE, World Bank and WIDER.
Budlender, D.,Buwembo, P.,Shabalala, N. (2001). The informal economy: statistical data and
research findings: country case study: South Africa. Report prepared for Women in Informal
Employment: Globalizing and Organizing (WIEGO).
Chandra, V.,Nganou, J.,Noel, C. (2002). Constraints to growth in Johannesburgs black informal
sector: evidence from the 1999 informal sector survey. World Bank Report No. 24449-ZA.
Washington D.C., The World Bank.
Devey, R.,Skinner, C.,Valodia, I. (2006). Definitions, data and the informal economy in South Africa:
A critical analysis, in V. Padayachee (ed.), The Development Decade? Economic and Social
Change in South Africa, 19942004. Cape Town, HSRC Press
Duclos, J.-Y.,Araar, A. (2006). Poverty and equity: measurement, policy and estimation with DAD.
CIRPÉE, Université Laval, Quebec.
Heintz, J.,Posel, D. (2008). Revisiting informal employment and segmentation in the South African
labour market, South African Journal of Economics,Vol. 76, No. 1, 26-44.
Hussmanns, Ralf. (2004). Measuring the informal economy: from employment in the informal sector
to informal employment Working Paper No. 53. Geneva: International Labour Office
ILO. (2013). Women and men in the informal economy: a statistical picture (second edition). Geneva,
International Labour Office.
Kingdon, G.,Knight, J. (2004). Unemployment in South Africa: the nature of the beast, World
Development Vol. 32, No. 3, 391-408.
Leibbrandt, M.,Woolard, I.,Finn, A.,Argent, J. (2010). Trends in South African income distribution
and poverty since the fall of apartheid. OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working
Paper No. 101, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
Ligthelm, A. (2006). Size estimate of the informal sector in South Africa, Southern African Business
Review,Vol. 10, No. 2, 32-52.
National Planning Commission. (2012). National Development Plan 2030: Our future-make it work.
Pretoria, The Presidency, Republic of South Africa
Philip, K. (2010). Inequality and economic marginalisation: how the structure of the economy impacts
on opportunities on the margins, Law, Democracy & Development,Vol. 14, No. 1-28.
Posel, D.,Casale, D. (2006). Who replies in brackets and what are the implications for earnings
estimates? An analysis of earnings data from South Africa. ERSA Working Paper No. 7. Cape
Town, Economic Research South Africa.
© REDI3x3 23 www.REDI3x3.org
Posel, D.,Rogan, M. (2012). Gendered trends in poverty in the post-apartheid period, 1997–2006,
Development Southern Africa,Vol. 29, No. 1, 97-113.
Rogan, M.,Reynolds, J. (2015). The working poor in South Africa, 1997-2012. ISER Working Paper
No. 2015/4. Grahamstown, Institute of Social and Economic Research.
Shorrocks, A. (2013). Decomposition procedures for distributional analysis: A unified framework
based on the Shapley value, Journal of Economic Inequality,Vol. 11, No. 1, 99-126.
Statistics South Africa. (2015). National and provincial labour market: the informal sector. Statistical
release P0211.4.3. Pretoria.
Valodia, I.,Devey, R. (2012). The Informal Economy in South Africa: Debates, Issues and Policies,
MarginThe Journal of Applied Economic Research,Vol. 6, No. 2, 133157.
van der Berg, S.,Louw, M.,Yu, D. (2008). Post-transition poverty trends based on an alternative data
source, South African Journal of Economics,Vol. 76, No. 1, 59-76.
Verick, S. (2010). Unravelling the impact of the global financial crisis on the South African labour
market. Employment Working Paper No. 48. Geneva, International Labour Organization.
Vermaak, C. (2010). The impact of multiple imputation of coarsened data on estimates of the working
poor in South Africa. UNU-WIDER Working Paper No. 2010/86. Helsinki, World Institute
for Development Economics Research, United Nations University.
Vermaak, C. (2012). Tracking poverty with coarse data: evidence from South Africa, Journal of
Economic Inequality,Vol. 10, No. 239-265.
Wills, G. (2009a). South Africa’s informal economy: a statistical profile. Wiego Working Paper
(Urban Policies) No 6. Manchester, Women in Informal Employment: Globalizing and
Organizing (WIEGO).
Wills, G. (2009b). South Africa’s Informal Economy: A Statistical Profile. Urban Policies Research
Report No. 7, WIEGO.
© REDI3x3 24 www.REDI3x3.org
Appendix A:
The poverty measures used in this decomposition are the p-alpha measures:
;;=
 =
 1

where y is income, z is the poverty line, there are K income sources and Sk represents income
from source k. Wi is the weight given to individual i and n is the sample size.
The Shapley decomposition approach calculates the average marginal reduction in poverty
when adding an income source over all possible combinations of income sources and all
possible orderings. The method starts at zero income (Pα = 1) and adds in one income source
at a time, assessing the marginal poverty reduction at each step, until all income sources are
included. The approach repeats this procedure over all possible orderings for our 11 different
income sources. Conveniently, the Araar and Duclos coding reweights outcomes so that we
can reduce this to 2k orderings and poverty calculations, rather than completing the procedure
using k! orderings (Araar & Duclos, 2009a, 2009b; Duclos & Araar, 2006).
© REDI3x3 25 www.REDI3x3.org
Appendix B:
Table B-1 Decomposition of the poverty gap (P1) by income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
Income Source Income
Share Relative Absolute Relative Absolute Relative Absolute
Informal self-
employment
0.031
-0.034
-0.030
-0.034
-0.028
-0.034
-0.025
(0.005)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Informal regular
wage emp.
0.024
-0.041
-0.036
-0.042
-0.034
-0.042
-0.031
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
Casual
employment
0.022
-0.039
-0.034
-0.039
-0.032
-0.038
-0.028
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Domestic work
0.010
-0.026
-0.023
-0.026
-0.021
-0.025
-0.019
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Formal sector
employment
0.567
-0.278
-0.244
-0.306
-0.250
-0.340
-0.250
(0.012)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.004)
(0.003)
(0.004)
(0.003)
Agricultural
income
0.001
-0.004
-0.003
-0.003
-0.003
-0.003
-0.002
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
Other income
0.005
-0.006
-0.005
-0.006
-0.005
-0.006
-0.004
(0.001)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
Social grant
income
0.066
-0.264
-0.232
-0.245
-0.200
-0.219
-0.161
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
Investment
income
0.070
-0.025
-0.022
-0.026
-0.021
-0.028
-0.021
(0.007)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Remittance
income
0.048
-0.056
-0.049
-0.056
-0.046
-0.055
-0.040
(0.008)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
Imputed rental
income
0.156
-0.228
-0.200
-0.217
-0.178
-0.209
-0.154
(0.004)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
Total
1
1
-0.878
1
-0.817
1
-0.736
(0)
(0)
(0.002)
(0)
(0.002)
(0)
(0.003)
Source:
Own calculations from NIDS using the DASP module developed by Araar and Duclos (2007)
Notes:
The data are weighted.
Standard errors in brackets.
Income sources are expressed in monthly per capita terms (2010 prices).
© REDI3x3 26 www.REDI3x3.org
Table B-2 Ratios for the decomposition of the poverty gap (P1) by income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
Income Source Income
Share Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio
Informal self-
employment 0.03 1.09 0.95 1.09 0.89 1.10 0.81
Informal
regular wage
emp. 0.02 1.74 1.53 1.77 1.45 1.79 1.32
Casual
employment 0.02 1.76 1.54 1.75 1.43 1.72 1.26
Domestic work 0.01 2.63 2.31 2.61 2.13 2.52 1.85
Formal sector
employment 0.57 0.49 0.43 0.54 0.44 0.60 0.44
Agricultural
income 0.00 3.88 3.41 3.43 2.80 3.18 2.34
Other income 0.00 1.37 1.20 1.32 1.08 1.24 0.92
Social grant
income 0.07 3.99 3.50 3.70 3.02 3.31 2.44
Investment
income 0.07 0.35 0.31 0.37 0.30 0.40 0.30
Remittance
income 0.05 1.17 1.03 1.17 0.95 1.15 0.85
Imputed rental
income 0.16 1.46 1.28 1.39 1.14 1.34 0.99
© REDI3x3 27 www.REDI3x3.org
Table B-3 Decomposition of the squared poverty gap (P2) by income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
Income Source Income
Share Relative Absolute Relative Absolute Relative Absolute
Informal self-
employment
0.031
-0.033
-0.031
-0.034
-0.030
-0.034
-0.028
(0.005)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Informal regular
wage emp.
0.024
-0.039
-0.036
-0.040
-0.036
-0.041
-0.034
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
Casual
employment
0.022
-0.038
-0.036
-0.039
-0.034
-0.038
-0.032
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Domestic work
0.010
-0.025
-0.023
-0.026
-0.023
-0.026
-0.021
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Formal sector
employment
0.567
-0.248
-0.230
-0.268
-0.238
-0.294
-0.244
(0.012)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
Agricultural
income
0.001
-0.004
-0.004
-0.004
-0.004
-0.004
-0.003
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
Other income
0.005
-0.006
-0.006
-0.006
-0.005
-0.006
-0.005
(0.001)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
Social grant
income
0.066
-0.273
-0.253
-0.265
-0.235
-0.249
-0.207
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
Investment income
0.070
-0.024
-0.022
-0.025
-0.022
-0.026
-0.021
(0.007)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Remittance income
0.048
-0.055
-0.051
-0.055
-0.049
-0.055
-0.046
(0.008)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
Imputed rental
income
0.156
-0.254
-0.236
-0.240
-0.213
-0.227
-0.189
(0.004)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
Total
1
1
-0.927
1
-0.888
1
-0.832
(0)
(0)
(0.002)
(0)
(0.002)
(0)
(0.002)
Source:
Own calculations from NIDS using the DASP module developed by Araar and Duclos (2007)
Notes:
The data are weighted.
Standard errors in brackets.
Income sources are expressed in monthly per capita terms (2010 prices).
© REDI3x3 28 www.REDI3x3.org
Table B-4 Ratios for the decomposition of the squared poverty gap (P2) by income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
Income Source Income
Share Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio
Informal self-
employment 0.03 1.06 0.99 1.08 0.96 1.09 0.90
Informal
regular wage
emp. 0.02 1.66 1.54 1.70 1.51 1.74 1.45
Casual
employment 0.02 1.73 1.61 1.74 1.55 1.74 1.45
Domestic work 0.01 2.53 2.34 2.57 2.28 2.57 2.13
Formal sector
employment 0.57 0.44 0.41 0.47 0.42 0.52 0.43
Agricultural
income 0.00 4.45 4.13 4.08 3.62 3.71 3.08
Other income 0.00 1.36 1.27 1.36 1.21 1.32 1.10
Social grant
income 0.07 4.13 3.83 4.00 3.55 3.77 3.13
Investment
income 0.07 0.34 0.32 0.35 0.31 0.37 0.31
Remittance
income 0.05 1.14 1.06 1.16 1.03 1.16 0.96
Imputed rental
income 0.16 1.63 1.51 1.53 1.36 1.45 1.21
© REDI3x3 29 www.REDI3x3.org
Appendix C:
Table C-1 Decomposition of poverty (Z = 307) by income source
P0
P1
P2
Income Source Income
Share Relative Absolute Relative Absolute Relative Absolute
Informal self-
employment
0.026
-0.038
-0.030
-0.036
-0.033
-0.035
-0.033
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Informal regular
wage emp.
0.024
-0.039
-0.032
-0.036
-0.034
-0.035
-0.033
(0.004)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Casual
employment
0.013
-0.030
-0.024
-0.030
-0.028
-0.030
-0.029
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Domestic work
0.012
-0.032
-0.026
-0.028
-0.026
-0.027
-0.026
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Formal sector
employment
0.635
-0.426
-0.344
-0.320
-0.297
-0.286
-0.274
(0.013)
(0.005)
(0.004)
(0.004)
(0.004)
(0.003)
(0.003)
Agricultural
income
0.001
-0.003
-0.003
-0.004
-0.003
-0.004
-0.004
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
Other income
0.002
-0.003
-0.002
-0.002
-0.002
-0.002
-0.002
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
Social grant
income
0.071
-0.209
-0.169
-0.275
-0.255
-0.286
-0.274
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
Investment
income
0.057
-0.023
-0.019
-0.022
-0.021
-0.022
-0.021
(0.007)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Remittance
income
0.024
-0.042
-0.034
-0.044
-0.041
-0.044
-0.043
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Imputed rental
income
0.135
-0.155
-0.125
-0.202
-0.187
-0.228
-0.219
(0.005)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
Total
1
1
-0.808
1
-0.926
1
-0.959
(0)
(0)
(0.003)
(0)
(0.002)
(0)
(0.001)
Source:
Own calculations from NIDS using the DASP module developed by Araar and Duclos (2007)
Notes:
The data are weighted.
Standard errors in brackets.
Income sources are expressed in monthly per capita terms (2008 prices).
© REDI3x3 30 www.REDI3x3.org
Table C-2 Ratios for the decomposition of poverty (Z = 307) by income source
P0
P1
P2
Income Source Income
Share Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio
Informal self-
employment 0.03 1.42 1.15 1.35 1.25 1.32 1.27
Informal regular
wage emp. 0.02 1.65 1.33 1.52 1.41 1.45 1.39
Casual
employment 0.01 2.36 1.90 2.36 2.19 2.41 2.31
Domestic work 0.01 2.76 2.23 2.42 2.24 2.30 2.20
Formal sector
employment 0.63 0.67 0.54 0.50 0.47 0.45 0.43
Agricultural
income 0.00 2.68 2.17 3.06 2.83 3.58 3.43
Other income 0.00 1.29 1.04 1.13 1.05 1.15 1.10
Social grant
income 0.07 2.95 2.38 3.88 3.59 4.03 3.86
Investment
income 0.06 0.40 0.33 0.39 0.36 0.39 0.37
Remittance
income 0.02 1.72 1.39 1.82 1.68 1.82 1.75
Imputed rental
income 0.14 1.15 0.93 1.49 1.38 1.69 1.62
© REDI3x3 31 www.REDI3x3.org
Table C-3 Decomposition of poverty (Z = 424) by income source
P0
P1
P2
Income Source Income
Share Relative Absolute Relative Absolute Relative Absolute
Informal self-
employment
0.026
-0.038
-0.027
-0.036
-0.032
-0.035
-0.033
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Informal regular
wage emp.
0.024
-0.039
-0.028
-0.037
-0.033
-0.036
-0.033
(0.004)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Casual
employment
0.013
-0.028
-0.020
-0.030
-0.026
-0.030
-0.028
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Domestic work
0.012
-0.032
-0.022
-0.029
-0.026
-0.028
-0.026
(0.001)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Formal sector
employment
0.635
-0.483
-0.341
-0.353
-0.310
-0.310
-0.289
(0.013)
(0.005)
(0.004)
(0.004)
(0.004)
(0.004)
(0.004)
Agricultural
income
0.001
-0.002
-0.002
-0.003
-0.003
-0.004
-0.004
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
Other income
0.002
-0.003
-0.002
-0.002
-0.002
-0.002
-0.002
(0)
(0.001)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
(0)
Social grant
income
0.071
-0.160
-0.113
-0.253
-0.222
-0.276
-0.257
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.003)
Investment
income
0.057
-0.025
-0.017
-0.023
-0.020
-0.022
-0.021
(0.007)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Remittance
income
0.024
-0.038
-0.027
-0.043
-0.038
-0.044
-0.041
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Imputed rental
income
0.135
-0.151
-0.106
-0.190
-0.167
-0.213
-0.199
(0.005)
(0.003)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
Total
1
1
-0.706
1
-0.879
1
-0.932
(0)
(0)
(0.004)
(0)
(0.002)
(0)
(0.002)
Source:
Own calculations from NIDS using the DASP module developed by Araar and Duclos (2007)
Notes:
The data are weighted.
Standard errors in brackets.
Income sources are expressed in monthly per capita terms (2008 prices).
© REDI3x3 32 www.REDI3x3.org
Table C-4 Ratios for the decomposition of poverty (Z = 424) by income source
P0
P1
P2
Income Source Income
Share Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio Relative
Ratio Absolute
Ratio
Informal self-
employment 0.03 1.44 1.02 1.37 1.21 1.34 1.25
Informal
regular
wage emp. 0.02 1.64 1.15 1.56 1.37 1.49 1.39
Casual
employment 0.01 2.25 1.59 2.34 2.06 2.38 2.22
Domestic work 0.01 2.72 1.92 2.49 2.19 2.37 2.21
Formal sector
employment
0.63 0.76 0.54 0.56 0.49 0.49 0.45
Agricultural
income 0.00 2.08 1.46 2.87 2.52 3.29 3.07
Other income 0.00 1.72 1.21 1.20 1.06 1.16 1.08
Social grant
income 0.07 2.25 1.59 3.57 3.13 3.88 3.62
Investment
income 0.06 0.43 0.30 0.40 0.35 0.39 0.36
Remittance
income 0.02 1.57 1.11 1.78 1.56 1.81 1.69
Imputed rental
income 0.14 1.12 0.79 1.41 1.24 1.58 1.47
© REDI3x3 33 www.REDI3x3.org
Appendix D:
Income Source
Numbe r of
jobs
Share of
income per
million jobs
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Informal self-
employment
1,462,314 0.018 -0.023 0.79 -0.022 0.73 -0.020 0.67
Informal regular
wage emp.
1,185,124 0.020 -0.028 1.00 -0.028 0.93 -0.026 0.84
Casual
employment
1,358,512 0.009 -0.020 0.71 -0.019 0.64 -0.017 0.57
Domestic work 923,511 0.013 -0.028 0.99 -0.028 0.93 -0.026 0.84
Formal sector
employment
10,400,000 0.061 -0.029 1.00 -0.030 1.00 -0.030 1.00
Agricultural
income
298,937 0.004 -0.011 0.39 -0.010 0.33 -0.009 0.28
Table D-1 Jobs Stuff of the poverty headcount (P
1
) by formal income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
Income Source
Numbe r of
jobs
Share of
income per
million jobs
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Informal self-
employment
1,462,314 0.018 -0.023 0.87 -0.023 0.81 -0.022 0.75
Informal regular
wage emp.
1,185,124 0.020 -0.028 1.07 -0.028 1.01 -0.027 0.94
Casual
employment
1,358,512 0.009 -0.021 0.81 -0.021 0.74 -0.019 0.67
Domestic work 923,511 0.013 -0.028 1.06 -0.028 1.01 -0.027 0.95
Formal sector
employment
10,400,000 0.061 -0.026 1.00 -0.028 1.00 -0.029 1.00
Agricultural
income
298,937 0.004 -0.014 0.51 -0.012 0.44 -0.011 0.37
Table D-2 Jobs Stuff of the poverty headcount (P
2
) by formal income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
© REDI3x3 34 www.REDI3x3.org
Appendix E:
Income Source
Numbe r of
jobs
Share of
income per
million jobs
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Informa l self-
employment
1,504,590 0.021 -0.017 0.49 -0.014 0.42 -0.011 0.37
Informal regular
wage emp.
1,201,757 0.020 -0.026 0.75 -0.022 0.66 -0.017 0.55
Casual
employment
1,474,585 0.015 -0.019 0.54 -0.015 0.46 -0.011 0.35
Domestic work 769,514 0.013 -0.024 0.70 -0.019 0.56 -0.013 0.43
Formal sector
employment
7,788,926 0.073 -0.034 1-0.033 1-0.031 1
Agricultural
income
1,261,647 0.001 -0.001 0.03 -0.001 0.03 -0.001 0.03
Table E-1 Jobs Stuff of the poverty headcount (P
0
) by formal income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
Income Source
Numbe r of
jobs
Share of
income per
million jobs
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Informa l self-
employment
1,504,590 0.021 -0.020 0.63 -0.019 0.58 -0.017 0.52
Informal regular
wage emp.
1,201,757 0.020 -0.030 0.96 -0.028 0.88 -0.026 0.81
Casual
employment
1,474,585 0.015 -0.023 0.74 -0.021 0.67 -0.019 0.59
Domestic work 769,514 0.013 -0.030 0.96 -0.028 0.86 -0.024 0.75
Formal sector
employment
7,788,926 0.073 -0.031 1.00 -0.032 1.00 -0.032 1.00
Agricultural
income
1,261,647 0.001 -0.003 0.08 -0.002 0.07 -0.002 0.06
Table E-2 Jobs Stuff of the poverty headcount (P
1
) by formal income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
© REDI3x3 35 www.REDI3x3.org
Income Source
Numbe r of
jobs
Share of
income per
million jobs
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Change in
poverty per
million jobs
Change in
poverty
relative to
formal job
Informa l self-
employment
1,504,590 0.021 -0.020 0.69 -0.020 0.65 -0.019 0.60
Informal regular
wage emp.
1,201,757 0.020 -0.030 1.02 -0.030 0.97 -0.028 0.90
Casual
employment
1,474,585 0.015 -0.024 0.82 -0.023 0.76 -0.022 0.69
Domestic work 769,514 0.013 -0.030 1.03 -0.030 0.97 -0.028 0.88
Formal sector
employment
7,788,926 0.073 -0.029 1.00 -0.031 1.00 -0.031 1.00
Agricultural
income
1,261,647 0.001 -0.003 0.11 -0.003 0.09 -0.002 0.08
Table E-3 Jobs Stuff of the poverty headcount (P
2
) by formal income source
Z = 307
Z = 424
Z = 594
© REDI3x3 36 www.REDI3x3.org
The Research Project on Employment, Income Distribution and Inclusive Growth
(REDI3x3) is a multi-year collaborative national research initiative. The project seeks to address
South Africa's unemployment, inequality and poverty challenges.
It is aimed at deepening understanding of the dynamics of employment, incomes and economic
growth trends, in particular by focusing on the interconnections between these three areas.
The project is designed to promote dialogue across disciplines and paradigms and to forge a
stronger engagement between research and policy making. By generating an independent, rich
and nuanced knowledge base and expert network, it intends to contribute to integrated and
consistent policies and development strate
gies that will address these three critical problem
areas effectively.
Collaboration with researchers at universities and research entities and fostering engagement
between researchers and policymakers are key objectives of the initiative.
The project is based at SALDRU at the University of Cape Town and supported by the National
Treasury.
Consult the website for further information.
Tel: (021) 650-5715
© REDI3x3 37 www.REDI3x3.org
... All the aforementioned responses clearly show that, according to the interviewees, their involvement contributes to securing their livelihoods. This aligns with the sentiments of Cichello and Rogan (2017), who established that informal traders generate income in Cape Town to sustain livelihoods. ...
... This concurs with literature from various scholars (e.g. ILO, 2002;Williams, 2014;Cichello and Rogan, 2017;Brata, 2010;Hausarbeit, 2018;Oberholster, 2020). These studies all assert that the informal sector contributes to securing livelihoods. ...
... Most of the respondents indicated that they were happy with the income generated from their involvement in informal activities because this income helps in the fight against poverty. This aligns with the sentiments of Cichello and Rogan (2017), who established that informal traders in Cape Town generate income to sustain livelihoods. ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose-This study aims to investigates the contribution of the informal sector towards secure livelihoods. Using a case study design, the study focusses on Mandela park, situated in Khayelitsha Township, Cape Town, in the Western Cape province of South Africa. Khayelitsha is predominantly an old township established by the apartheid government using unjust segregation laws to foster spatial planning that isolated people of colour in areas with insufficient infrastructure and informal economic activities. Therefore, informal trading became a survival strategy in Khayelitsha, attracting an increasing number of informal traders in public spaces within the township in pursuit of livelihoods. Informal activities are generally conducted to generate income and secure sustainable livelihoods. Design/methodology/approach-This study uses a qualitative research design, incorporating structured interviews instrumental in data collection and in-depth thematic analysis. Findings-The study findings reveal that the informal sector positively contributes to the sustainable livelihoods of those involved in the informal sector and the relatives of those through income generation, family support, wealth creation, source of employment, business incubation and innovation and creativity. Originality/value-The study concludes that given the increasing unemployment rate in South Africa, caused by the stagnant economic growth rate, policymakers should rethink their policies on the informal economy, acknowledge the sector's relevance and support the sector.
... In affirmation, Average (2020) describes the sector as "a seedbed for economic development". Cichello and Rogan (2016) affirm the prevalence of the "controversial" view of the IS as a second economy depicted by poverty and lack of development, including being structurally detached from the formal one. They allude to the failure to recognize the importance of the sector in South Africa (SA) as a source of employment, sustenance for livelihoods and poverty reduction. ...
... This under-recognition has led to policy gaps and misguided policies towards the IS as policy responses often overlook this sector or are sometimes hostile (Cichello & Rogan, 2016;Rogan, 2019). Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) allude to the fact that SSA countries hold a negative view towards the informal sector, often to the detriment of policy prescription. ...
... In affirmation, the Bank of Industry points out that sustainable and inclusive economic development, as well as employment creation, cannot afford to overlook the potential, peculiar requirements and constraints of the IS. The debate on the IS rages on with others considering an under-utilized source of employment that must be enabled (Cichello & Rogan, 2016;Fourie, 2015Fourie, , 2018), yet other scholars consider it an inferior source of employment (Potts, 2008). Hassan (2018) asserts that discussions about the role of the IS in the economy and the need to formalize it often ignore the development policy and social interests of the weaker power base of those in the IS. ...
Article
Full-text available
The informal sector remains a permanent feature of all economies. It is a more pronounced component of developing country economies where it is an integral part. Literature on economic development offers diverging viewpoints on the sector’s contribution to economic growth. On the one hand, researchers view the sector with positivity as a resource to be harnessed, capable of growth and innovation and on the other hand with negativity as a pure survivalist strategy and a stumbling block to effective policy formulation and economic development. Therefore as an inconvenience to be extinguished. The ambivalent view is further compounded by the sector’s paltry contribution to national tax revenues and as such, the IS has remained unappreciated and largely on the peripheral of economic reviews and policy responsiveness. The former view suggests that the latter is a misconception and narrow recognition of the sector as merely survivalist and contributing negligibly to employment creation and poverty alleviation efforts. Failure to recognize a coexistence of both street traders and firms with potential for growth, improved productivity and innovation, has consequently resulted in misguided policies. Policymakers pay little or no attention to the potential of informal sector firms, the challenges they face, the vulnerability they are exposed to and the appropriate support they require. This gap motivates this paper, as it seeks to explore the role played by the IS in developing countries with a special focus on Zimbabwe. The study employs a mixed-method research design. The research established that the sector remains unequivocally a major source of employment for many developing countries. It also established that a single-minded focus on formalizing the sector, linked to registration for tax purposes, ignores the other arm to the equation that is the creation of job opportunities, hospitable working conditions, improved productivity and increased profits which are possible with adequate policy support. The research recommends improved policy research and support which is development focused to aid informal firms to grow and be independent institutionally and financially from their owners as well as skills capacitation to improve operational and financial management.
... Even though, there was countless acknowledgement and sanguinity given in the powers' major policy document, the National Development Plan (NDP) in auspicious between 1.2 and 2 million new informal jobs to dropping off poverty [5], presently the policy is still quiet about the conceivable job openings and how it can relate with the formal economy. There is still a perception amongst politicians that the informal sector is regarded as a regressive and inefficient economy while on the other hand it is recognised by the same people as a valuable tool for poverty reduction and the absorption of the unemployed [6]. It also served as a fallback pond of inexpensive labour for both informal and formal institutions. ...
... The informal segment is a very vulnerable area of doing business [6] and should be considered as a standardised sector [8]. Mentioning from StatsSA (2019), the reread showing that 8.9 million people were retained in 1994, with a redundancy proportion of 20 percent (8.112 million of the total population). ...
... Maluleke (2020: 1) found that workers in the informal economy in South Africa are prone to low earnings, unsafe environments, and a lack of protection from exploitation. Furthermore, despite the informal sector in South Africa being recognised as an important mechanism for job creation, its role in job creation has been hampered by unsupportive policies (Cichello and Rogan, 2017;Rogan, 2018). Studies from developing nations have also revealed that women are mainly present in the informal sector, particularly in trade-based employment and as ownaccount workers in family businesses (Chant and Pedwell, 2008). ...
Article
Full-text available
Western-centric studies on opportunity-based entrepreneurship have dominated the literature on female entrepreneurs. Existing research has also tended to focus on the experiences of women in the formal rather than the informal sector. In this article, we examine female necessity entrepreneurs' experiences of learning financial and business skills in the informal street trade in South Africa. The theoretical framework for this research, which was located within a critical feminist paradigm and used a feminist phenomenological design, drew on African feminisms, resilience, and informal learning. Phenomenological, in-depth, face-to-face interviews were conducted with a convenience sample of twelve women in the informal street trade in the Durban area of KwaZulu-Natal, to capture the essence of their experiences of running their businesses. The main findings showed that poor black women, especially those trading without permits in the informal street trade, faced multiple challenges, but were able to learn some of the financial and business skills necessary for survival. However, this learning was reactive, problem-centred, observation based, imitative, and partial. These findings emphasised the need for these entrepreneurs to upgrade their financial and business skills in order for their businesses to remain sustainable. The study recommended various targeted policy initiatives to support female necessity entrepreneurs.
... Kingdon and Knight (2007) posit that the informal sector is a liability to the economy as it is characterised by underdevelopment, failure to generate capital accumulation or economic growth and contributes little to the GDP of the economy and that is a view shared by Millin and Coetzee (2007). The researchers give evidence of the dualist view in explaining the growth of the informal sector in South Africa yet, Cichello and Rogan (2016) (Joshi & Ayee, 2008). Horodnic and Williams (2016) describe this view as the political theory of the economy yet Tendler (2002) posit it as the "Devil's deal". ...
... In 2013, over 2,3 million people were employed in the informal sector, estimated to contribute around 5.9% to South Africa's GDP (StatsSA, 2013), and Fourie (2018) estimate that this had risen to 2.9 million in 2018. Signifi cantly, the share of the workforce in the informal sector is highest in the poorest regions, those most historically undeveloped and with higher levels of poverty and unemployment, as described in Section 4. It is also higher in towns and cities other than the big metropolitan areas, such as Johannesburg, and higher amongst people living in traditional communal rural areas, in townships and informal settlements in urban areas(Fourie 2018).Informal-sector employment has a signifi cant impact on poverty reduction(Cichello and Rogan 2018), because income fl ows primarily to poor ...
Article
Full-text available
Through analysis of the South African case, a country stalled in a middle income trap, the paper aims to add to the literature on catch-up. It uses Albuquerque’s (2019) model of the vicious cycles arising from inequality and income concentration, together with the notion of ‘upgrading coalitions’ (Doner and Schneider 2016) required to challenge these vicious cycles, to analyse the persistence of lock-ins. It then analyses a global astronomy project, a ‘window of opportunity’ building on historically grown capabilities, promoted by ‘upgrading coalitions’ operating in the national interest. In contrast, it proposes a ‘detour’ to build domestic capabilities, driven by an upgrading coalition centred on local economic development and livelihoods in the informal economy. The paper aims to reinforce the evidence on how inequality is both a cause and consequence of a middle income trap, and open debate on how upgrading coalitions may be a critical strategy for breaking lock-ins.
Article
Full-text available
The township economy supports many South Africans by creating employment and reducing the socio-economic challenges facing the country. To ensure sustainable growth of the sector, research is required on key businesses within the informal economy. This study empirically investigated the factors influencing the shopping experience of spaza shop customers in South Africa. Spaza shops, an under-researched South African context, continue to expand in various townships and serves as retail outlet where consumers purchase their daily products and services. The study embraced a quantitative research design. A self-administered questionnaire was employed to collect the data for the study. The target respondents include customers who were older than 18 years and had previously purchased from spaza shops. Respondents were selected using convenience sampling. The questionnaires were distributed to six townships in South Africa. 185 usable questionnaires were included in the data analysis. The empirical results provided evidence that supports the existence of statistically significant positive correlations between five independent experience factors, namely: esthetic, distinctiveness, cognitive, affective and social; with customer experience (dependent variable). Additionally, three of the five experience factors (social, affective and cognitive) are significant predictors of customer experience in the context of this study. Based on the identified factors, several recommendations are made for improving customer experience in a spaza shop context. Recommendations made are expected to enhance the competitiveness of spaza shops thereby enabling them to increase their contribution to employment creation and national Gross Domestic Product.
Article
The literature on urban transport in Ghana focus exclusively on the state of buses, drivers and transport unions, much to the neglect of a group of workers referred to as “shadow men.” Their function is to help fill these buses with passengers. This paper explores the activities of these shadow men, their origin, and their contributions to the growth of urban transport. The researchers selected a total of 47 respondents for the study. The researchers conducted interviews with the Head of Department of Urban Transport of the Kumasi Metropolitan Assembly and the Head of Ghana Private Road Transport Union, and then purposely selected 25 of these shadow men, 4 trotro drivers, 6 trotro mates, and 10 passengers in Kumasi, Ghana’s second largest city. In addition to these interviews, the researchers held two focus group discussions that involved drivers and drivers’ mates (conductors) in one group, and passengers in another group. Thematic analysis was used to analyze the data. The research found that there are two broad categories of shadow men: those engaged in it as a full-time business, and out-of-work drivers and drivers’ mates who rely on it for income until they have a new bus to work with. The findings also underscore the lucrative nature of the work and the city authorities’ indifference to the shadow men. Shadow men are essential to the urban transport sector in Ghana and should therefore be given considerable attention by academics, and included in the plans of city authorities.
Article
Full-text available
The informal sector is an integral part of several sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries and plays a key role in the economic growth of these countries. This article used a comparative systematic review to explore the factors that act as drivers to informality in South Africa (SA) and Nigeria, the challenges that impede the growth dynamics of the informal sector, the dominant subsectors, and policy initiatives targeting informal sector providers. A systematic search of Google Scholar, Scopus, ResearchGate was performed together with secondary data collated from grey literature. Using Boolean string search protocols facilitated the elucidation of research questions (RQs) raised in this study. An inclusion and exclusion criteria became necessary for rigour, comprehensiveness and limitation of publication bias. The data collated from thirty-one (31) primary studies (17 for SA and 14 for Nigeria) revealed that unemployment, income disparity among citizens, excessive tax burdens, excessive bureaucratic hurdles from government, inflationary tendencies, poor corruption control, GDP per capita, and lack of social protection survival tendencies all act as drivers to the informal sector in SA and Nigeria. Several challenges are given for both economies and policy incentives that might help sustain and improve the informal sector in these two countries.