PreprintPDF Available

Growth and Inflation Regimes in Greater Tumen Initiative Area

Authors:
  • National Research and Consulting Center (NRCC)
Preprints and early-stage research may not have been peer reviewed yet.

Abstract and Figures

This paper tests for multiple structural breaks in the mean, seasonality, dynamics and conditional volatility of Greater Tumen Initiative Countries' (GTI) growth and inflation, while also accounting for outliers. It finds a drop in the level of Chinese growth rate in the third quarter of 2011 and of inflation rate in 1998. There are more volatility regimes than the growth regimes and most GTI countries are currently enjoying historically low volatility of their growth and inflation. Two exceptions are the increased growth volatility for Japan since 2006 and inflation volatility for Russia since 2012. There is an increased importance of seasonality in GTI and especially in Chinese inflation volatility, constituting at least a half of the total volatility.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Growth and Inflation Regimes in Greater Tumen Initiative Area
Erdenebat Bataa
National University of Mongolia
April 2019
Corresponding author:
Erdenebat Bataa
Department of Economics, School of Social Sciences
Building V, Suite #603
National University of Mongolia
Ikh surguuliin gudamj-1, 14201 Ulaanbaatar, Mongolia
Email: tsors79@yahoo.com
Ph : +976 80343365
Acknowledgements: The author gratefully acknowledges financial assistance from the
Economic Research Institute for Northeast Asia’s Visiting Researcher program, under which
this work was initiated. However, the Institute bears no responsibility for the contents of this
paper. I would like to acknowledge the constructive comments received at the Institute’s
seminar and at University of Niigata Prefecture workshop “International Trade and Innovation
in Global Economization”.
2
Abstract
This paper tests for multiple structural breaks in the mean, seasonality, dynamics and
conditional volatility of Greater Tumen Initiative Countries’ (GTI) growth and inflation, while
also accounting for outliers. It finds a drop in the level of Chinese growth rate in the third quarter
of 2011 and of inflation rate in 1998. There are more volatility regimes than the growth regimes
and most GTI countries are currently enjoying historically low volatility of their growth and
inflation. Two exceptions are the increased growth volatility for Japan since 2006 and inflation
volatility for Russia since 2012. There is an increased importance of seasonality in GTI and
especially in Chinese inflation volatility, constituting at least a half of the total volatility.
Keywords: China slowdown, multiple structural breaks, seasonality, Greater Tumen Initiative,
growth and volatility regimes, growth and inflation.
JEL Classifications: E31, E32, C22, C18
3
1. Introduction
China, Mongolia, Russia and South Korea have agreed to transform the Greater Tumen
Initiative (GTI) into an international organization of economic cooperation in Northeast Asia
during the summit in Yanji, China on Sept. 17, 20141. The Tumen River Area Development
Programme (TRADP) was first formed by the United Nations Development Programme
(UNDP) with the objectives of regional cooperation, economic development, and
environmental management in 1995. In spite of its great potential GTI had been largely inactive
due to several challenges including disharmony of interest among member countries, weak
infrastructure development, and lack of funding to activate the project. However, GTI has
received new stimulus since China adopted it as part of its central economic development plan
in 2009. This paper sheds light on the recent developments in the main macroeconomic
variables of growth and inflation for these four countries and Japan, currently an observer nation
to the initiative.
There are many earlier studies on growth and inflation regimes but none fully focuses
on this important geographical region that produces about a quarter of the World GDP.2 The
moderation in volatility of output has been well documented for the US and other developed
countries, see McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000), and Gadea, Gomez-Loscos and Perez-
Quiros (2018), among others. Coric (2012) studies 98 countries and finds that almost two thirds
experienced GDP growth volatility decline between 1961 and 2007, implying that the so-called
“Great Moderation” took place in economies at all income levels.
On the other hand, Easterly, Kremer, Pritchett and Summers (1993) find that medium
term growth lacked persistence, and countries transitioned between high and low growth
regimes. Ben-David and Papell (1998), Pritchett (2000), Hausmann, Pritchett and Rodrick
(2005), Jones and Olken (2008), Berg, Ostry, Zettelmeyer (2012) show that the growth regimes
are indeed more important phenomena than the long run average growth rate that masks them.
Yet Kar, Pritchett, Raihan and Sen (2013) criticize that the structural break tests that are used
to identify the growth regimes suffer from low power, due to the presence of high volatility in
shorter annual samples, hence miss some of the “true” regimes.
1 See http://www.tumenprogramme.org for details. Such development is extremely important for Mongolia as
imports from China, Russia, Japan and South Korea constitute 41.8%, 36.8%, 11.9% and 5.6% of the total
respectively, while 96% and 1.3% of the total exports go to China and Russia as of 2018.
2 According to the IMF World Economic Outlook-2018, the World, Chinese, Japanese, South Korean, Russian
and Mongolian GDP were 84835462, 13457267, 5070626, 1655608, 1576488, 12724 million USD respectively.
4
Kar et al. (2013) suggest to refrain from using purely statistical test but to marry it with
an ad hoc filter approach that has been used in earlier studies of Hausmann et al. (2005), and
Aizenman and Spiegel (2010), among others. In particular, they propose evaluating the sample
splits derived from Bai and Perron’s (1998, 2003) dynamic programming approach based on a
priori defined filters and find more breaks. In contrast to the earlier works that often use a
simple model with regime dependent intercept (e.g. Jones and Olken, 2008), Jerzmanowski
(2006) and Kerekes (2012) use Markov-switching AR(1) model for the growth rates, whose
intercept, AR coefficient and volatility depend on four different regimes: growth, stagnation,
crisis and miracle growth. But the condition that the intercept, AR coefficient and volatility are
required to change at the same time can be restrictive.
Although the Great moderation and growth regime literatures both address the economic
development, which makes “hard to think about anything else” (Lucas, 1988) due to its
implication for human well-being, the former often uses the growth rates of quarterly real GDP
while the latter relies on that of the annual real GDP per capita. Therefore, the first contribution
of the paper is to use the recently developed iterative structural break testing methodology of
Bataa, Osborn, Sensier and Dijk (2014) and to identify growth regimes in the GTI using the
longest and most up-to-date quarterly data, to increase power of the test.
Blanchard and Simon (2001) show that while the causes of the decline in US output
volatility are complex, this decline can be linked to changes in the properties of inflation and
particularly to a decline in inflation volatility over the period 1952-2001. Similarly,
Eichengreen, Park and Shin (2012) find that policy instability, measured by high and variable
inflation rates, are precursors to growth slowdowns. Therefore, my second contribution is to
search for coincident changes in inflation and growth properties. This is in line with Jones and
Olken (2008) who ask what the breaks actually entail without making statements about the
direction of causality between the variables.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains the data and summarizes the
iterative decomposition method of Bataa et al. (2014) to identify and distinguish between breaks
in mean, seasonality (if any), persistence and (conditional) volatility of the growth and inflation
series, while also accounting for the possible presence of outliers. Section 3 provides the results
and compares with previous studies. Section 4 concludes.
5
2. Data and Methodology
I analyse quarterly real GDP growth and CPI inflation rates for each of the GTI countries. The
sample for China, Russia and Mongolia starts later than the other two countries due to the lack
of quality data. The start dates are therefore the second quarters of 1960 for Japan and South
Korea, of 1993 for China and of 1995 for Mongolia and Russia. All end in the last quarter of
20183. Russian and Mongolian growth rates and all the inflation rates are not seasonally
adjusted.
The series analysed are shown in panel a) in each of Figures 1 to 5. A cursory glance at
these graphs indicates the presence of outliers (see, for example, Japanese inflation after the
first oil shock in Figure 1), changes in mean inflation (such as for Russia, Figure 4) and/or
volatility (apparently present for Chinese, and Korean growth and Mongolian inflation, Figures
3, 2 and 5). In addition, many of the series are seasonal, with this perhaps being clearest for
Russian and Mongolian growth (Figures 4 and 5, respectively).
Bataa et al. (2014) consider decomposing a stationary time series Yt into components
capturing level (Lt), seasonality (St), outliers (Ot) and dynamics (yt), where level and seasonality
are deterministic and only the last component is stochastic and represented by means of an
autoregressive (AR) process (although this could include stationary stochastic seasonality, if
appropriate).
The model they consider allows for structural change in each of the level, seasonal and
dynamic components, where breaks in the latter may occur in the AR coefficients or in the
conditional volatility. A crucial feature of the model is that the numbers of structural breaks in
these components do not have to be the same and nor do their temporal locations, hence might
prove more flexible than the Markov-switching framework used in Jerzmanowski (2006) and
Kerekes (2012). The general model specification is given by
ttttt yOSLY
(1)
1
kt
L
11
111 ,...,1 kk TTt , 1,...,1 11
mk (2)
3 Data for China, Japan, South Korea and Russia are obtained from the OECD (www.oecd.org). Chinese growth
rate prior to the first quarter of 2011 is not available there, hence obtained from Bataa et al. (2018). Russian growth
rate is also not available from the OECD prior to the second quarter of 2003, hence seasonally unadjusted series
is obtained from the Federal State Statistical Office of the Russian Federation (www.gks.ru) and both Mongolian
series are from the National Statistical Office of Mongolia (www.1212.mn).
6
s
lltlkt DS
1
2
22
122 ,...,1 kk TTt ; 1,...,1 22
mk (3)
t
p
iitikt uyy
1
,
3
33
133 ,...,1 kk TTt ; 1,...,1 33
mk (4)
,

44
144 ,...,1 kk TTt ; 1,...,1 44
mk (5)
where mj denotes the number of breaks of type j that occur at observations
(kj = 1, ..., mj),
with
0 and
 (where T denotes the total sample size), and for s seasons per year (s
= 4 for quarterly data), Dlt (l = 1, …, s) are seasonal dummies equal to unity if the observation
at time t falls in season l and zero otherwise. Note that the coefficient lk2
represents the
deviation of the unconditional mean of Yt in the l-th season (month) from the overall mean level
j
and, for identification purposes, we impose the restriction
s
llk
12
= 0 for all seasonality
regimes k2 = 1, …, m2+1.
I can then define the seasonal share in the total volatility as in (6), where ,
and
are simply standard deviations of the fitted values of (2) and (4) respectively:




1,…,
; 1,...,


1 (6)
Although our principal interest is the possibility of breaks in the components (2) to (5),
outliers are corrected to prevent these distorting inferences concerning other components.
Outliers, Ot in (1), are observations that are abnormally distant from the overall level, defined
as 5 times interquartile range from the median and, when detected, are replaced with the median
of the six neighbouring non-outlier observation. The null hypothesis of no break is tested
against an unknown number of breaks up to M using WDMax test and if rejected the exact
number of breaks are identified using sequential tests Seq(i+1|i), starting with i=1 as in Bai and
Perron (1998, 2003). Bataa et al. (2014) employ an iterative approach using Qu and Perron
(2007) test to examine breaks in each of the components of (2)-(5) and the details of their
methodology are relegated to the original study to conserve space.
There is a well-known trade-off between size and power when choosing the maximum
number of breaks (M) and trimming parameter, that is the minimum fraction of the sample
between any two breaks (see Bai and Perron, 1998, 2003). My choice is to allow for a maximum
of three breaks (20% trimming) except for the autoregressive and seasonal parameters for
7
China, Russia and Mongolia. For these I consider up to two breaks (30% trimming). The results
are quite robust to other sensible parameterization.
3. Empirical Results
Figures 1 to 5 show the empirical results of the iterative decomposition in graphical
form. These charts provide: a) the original unadjusted GDP growth and CPI inflation series; b)
the estimated dynamic component yt (constructed by removing outliers, mean and seasonal
components) together with its estimated persistence, defined as the sum of the autoregressive
coefficients in (4) and corresponding 2
standard error bands (in red), and volatility break
dates (vertical green lines); c) the level component Lt with 2
standard error bands; and d) the
estimated seasonal component for each seasonal regime (again with 2
standard error bands)4.
Standard errors are obtained using the HC covariance matrix in the corresponding regression
over the regime defined by the appropriate estimated break dates. Where relevant, the graphs
showing the seasonal components are colour-coded with the first regime (that is, the sub-sample
to the first break date) in blue, the second in red and the third in pink.
Table 1 provides structural break test results for the mean, seasonality (if not already
seasonally adjusted), autoregressive parameters and volatility in its first four panels. The last
panel reports the convergence statistics of the Bataa et al. (2014); the number of iterations for
outer (and inner) loop. Table 2 shows the break dates and the respective component’s regime-
specific estimates based on the breaks and also the estimates ignoring those breaks. 95%
confidence interval for the break dates and heteroskedasticity robust standard errors are also
reported in brackets. There are five country-columns, each split into further growth and inflation
sub-columns. I discuss the results for seasonality first, then dynamics and finally level and
volatility.
The null hypothesis of no structural break in the seasonal pattern of Japanese inflation
against an alternative of unknown number of breaks is rejected soundly as WDmax statistic of
22.34 is significantly higher than the critical value of 14.55 (panel B of table 1). The sequential
test indicates that there are two seasonal breaks, which occur in the first quarter of 1978 and the
4 The procedure detected the following outliers: 74q2 in Japanese inflation, 98q2 in growth, and 63q4, 64q2, 64q4,
74q2 and 80q2 in inflation for Korea, 95q3-96q1 and 98q4-99q2 in inflation for Russia and 95q4 in inflation for
Mongolia. These outliers are associated with well-known historical events such as th e first oil shock, the transition
related shock therapy consequences and Russian debt crisis of 1998.
8
last quarter of 1999 (panel B of table 2)5. As the right-hand side of panel d) in Figure 1 reveals,
the first quarter decline in prices started in 1978. Since then although the overall pattern of
seasonality is largely intact, the magnitude of the seasonal oscillations has reduced in the new
millennia. Bataa et al.’s (2014) study monthly of G7 inflation found that there are also two
seasonality breaks in Japanese inflation; in September 1984 and May 1999, the latter of which
is very close to the one in this study.
I find no statistically significant structural change in Korean, Russian and Mongolian
inflation seasonality; prices peak in the first quarter and drop subsequently throughout the year
for the former two countries (figures 2 and 4) while inflation is highest in the first half of the
year and declines only in the autumn in Mongolia. As for China, there is a marg inally signif icant
structural break in inflation seasonality; after 2009 prices neither drop in the third quarter, nor
increase in the last quarter, as much as they used to before that (figure 3). In terms of the size
of seasonality, measured by their standard deviations, the countries rank from low to high order
as Japan, Korea, China, Russia and then Mongolia.
Remarkably large seasonal fluctuations for Russian and Mongolian growth in figures 4
and 5 contain two structural breaks each with similar timing, perhaps both reflecting their
dependence on fuel and energy products as their main economic growth. In both countries,
growth drops in the first quarter and recovers in the second quarter (and also third quarter for
Russia’s case). The magnitude of the drop in the first quarter has intensified in Russia, first in
the second quarter of 2003 and again in the third quarter of 2011 while the seasonality is overall
declining for Mongolia, although starting from an extremely high level. The magnitude of the
Russian seasonal fluctuations is a drop of 12.92% in the first quarter, and seasonal recoveries
of 3.92%, 8.04% and 0.96% respectively in the remaining quarters of the year before 2003.
Then the pattern changes into a drop of 15.04% in the first quarter and recoveries of 6.66%,
7.47% and 0.91% in the following quarters. After 2010, the drop is 18.55% and the recoveries
are 6.31%, 6.45% and 5.79%. The comparative seasonal drop and recoveries are -43.56%,
47.34%, -8.49%, 4.71% over the quarters before 2003, -42.02%, 40.21%, -5.31%, 7.13%
afterwards and -39.26%, 36.98%, 0.82% and 1.47% after 2011 in Mongolia.
It is also interesting to find no growth persistence break for all the countries (panel C of
Table 1). This is line with the earlier literature that finds low growth persistence (see e.g.
Easterly et al.). The growth persistence is statistically insignificant for Japan and Korea but
5 Note that the growth rates are seasonally adjusted for Japan, Korea and China, thus indicated with N.A. in the
tables; see OECD and Bataa et al. (2018).
9
significant for the other countries (panel C of Table 2). Inflation persistence, measured by the
sum of autoregressive coefficients declines in China in the third quarter of 2011 and is now the
lowest in the GTI area, while that of Mongolia increased after a quarter6.
The null hypothesis of a constant mean is rejected for all series except in Russian growth
and Mongolian growth and inflation. The sequential tests indicate that there are two breaks for
Japan and one break for China in their levels of growth and inflation. The number of breaks in
growth and inflation does not match for Korea and Russia; 1 and 2 for the former and 0 and 2
for Russia. The 95% confidence intervals for the break dates much tighter than the seaonality
breaks.
Japanese growth declines in the second quarter of 1973, after the first oil shock, from
2.31% per quarter to 1.03%, and again in the last quarter of 1990, after the burst of its asset
price bubble. The growth is mere 0.24% after this break, which is at least 3 times lower than
the post-60 average growth of 0.94%, obtained by ignoring the breaks. Interestingly, Korea
maintained its miracle growth rate of 2.21% up until 2001. This is in contrast to Ben-David and
Papell (1998) who found, using annual real per capita GDP, growth slowdowns, in 1967 for
Japan and in 1979 for Korea using data from 1950 to 1990. However their methodology allows
for only one break. Bai and Perron (1998, 2003) show that when there are more than one breaks
such a procedure can be misleading. Jones and Olken (2008) and Kar et al. (2012) found two
down-breaks in 1970 and 1991 for Japan, which are very close to what I find. For South Korea,
Jones and Olken (2008) found an up-break in 1962 using a sample that ends in mid 2000s. Kar
et al. (2012) reported two up-breaks in 1962 and 1982 and two down-breaks, in 1991 and 2002
for South Korea. But as explained in the Introduction they do not consider the statistical
significance of their breaks.
There is some evidence that the growth regimes precede those of inflation for Japan and
Korea, in contrast to Eichengreen et al.’s (2012) claim. The second Japanese growth decline
occurs less than 3 years before the inflation decline, while 2001 growth slowdown of 1.28
percentage point in Korea is followed within a quarter by 0.52 percentage drop in its level of
inflation. Interestingly, Bataa et al. (2014) also found two down-breaks in Japanese inflation;
the first one is in January 1981 and the second one in 1990s. The level of inflation is breaking
down in both China and Russia but remains at stubbornly high level in Mongolia.
6 When the autoregressive lag in panel C of Table 1 is 1, the AR(1) coefficient itself is the persistence.
10
Eichengreen et al. (2012) note that a special anxiety is attached to the question of how
and when Chinese growth might slow. This study finds evidence that the slowdown might have
already occurred and is dated in the third quarter of 2011. If this break is ignored one would
wrongly calculate the average annual growth is 8.8% per annum since 1995, but as Table 2
indicates the growth has declined from 9.56% before the break to 6.9% afterwards. This could
indeed be associated with the increased power of Bataa et al.’s (2014) testing strategy.
Panel Ds of Tables 1 and 2 indicate that volatility regimes are most common. There are
6 and 7 of them in growth and inflation, respectively. While most other countries growth
volatilities are entering more stable regimes, Japanese one is substantially higher in the latest
regime that started in the last quarter of 2006, influenced by the GFC, yet the inflation volatility
is still subdued since 1979. Inflation volatilities are also mostly subdued except in Russia, where
the inflation has become more volatile after the first quarter of 2012, perhaps reflecting the
Western sanctions.
The volatility for inflation first declines in 1981 for South Korea followed by a decline
for its growth in 1989 (panel D, Table 2). The inflation volatility further declines in 2000, which
is again followed by a growth volatility decline after 3 years. Such close relationship applies
for China and to a lesser extent for Russia. Given that inflation volatility is often used as policy
instability (see e.g. Eichengreen, Park and Shin, 2012) it could be that inflation volatility
precedes growth volatility. This hypothesis should be an interesting topic for future research,
perhaps using the multivariate approach as in Bataa et al. (2013).
The share in the total volatility of seasonal origin has increased for all inflation series.
While around a quarter of the total volatility used to be attributed to the seasonality in Japan
and Korea before the 1980s, more than a half is due to such forces in the new millennia. It is
particularly high in otherwise tranquil Chinese inflation where it accounts for 82% of the total
volatility after the third quarter of 2011. As for the Russian and Mongolian growth rates, more
than 80% their volatility is driven by seasonal fluctuations. As the business cycle component
of Russian quarterly growth volatility declines, the seasonal cycle’s share has increased; 92%
of its total volatility is being driven by seasonality since the second quarter of 2013.
11
4. Conclusions
This paper uses a newly developed iterative procedure for the decomposition of GTI growth
and inflation into level, seasonality and dynamic components, together with conditional
volatility, when these components are permitted to exhibit distinct multiple structural breaks
over the sample period and outliers are taken into account. To my knowledge, such a flexible
procedure has not been used previously in the.
The paper delivers evidence that important structural changes occurred not only in the
level (mean) of growth and inflation, but also in their seasonal pattern, and volatility. These
results contribute to the on-going debate (see, for example, Pritchett and Summers, 2014) about
the nature and implication of Chinese growth slowdowns. More specifically, just as did the
growth slow down in the second quarter of 1973 and in the last quarter of 1990 in Japan and
also in the first quarter of 2001 in South Korea, I find a statistically significant growth
slowdown in the third quarter of 2011 for China.
The paper also sheds light on the sources of inflation volatility and documents that
seasonality is emerging as the dominant source of volatility in an era of reduced business cycle
volatility.
12
References
Aizenman, J. and Spiegel, M.M. 2010. Takeoffs. Review of Development Economics 14(2),
177-196
Bai, J.S. and Perron, P., 1998. Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural
changes. Econometrica 66, 47-78.
Bai, J.S. and Perron, P., 2003. Computation and analysis of multiple structural change models.
Journal of Applied Econometrics 18, 1-22.
Bataa, E., Osborn, D.R., Sensier, M. & van Dijk, D. 2013. Structural breaks in the international
dynamics of inflation. Review of Economics and Statistics 95(2), 646-659
Bataa, E., Osborn, D.R., Sensier, M. & van Dijk, D. 2014. Identifying changes in mean,
seasonality, persistence & volatility for G7 & Euro area inflation. Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics 76(3), 360-388,
Bataa, E., Izzeldin, M. & Osborn, D.R. 2016. Changes in the global oil market. Energy
Economics 56, 161-176.
Bataa, E., Osborn, D.R. & Sensier, M. 2018. China's increasing global influence: Changes in
international growth spillovers. Economic Modelling 74, 194-206
Ben-David, D & Papell, D.H. 1998. Slowdowns and meltdowns: Postwar growth evidence from
74 countries. Review of Economics and Statistics 80(4), 561-571
Berg, A., Ostry, J., Zettelmeyer, J., 2012. What makes growth sustained? Journal of
Development Economics 98(2), 149-166.
Blanchard, O. and Simon, J. 2001. The long and large decline in U.S. output volatility.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 135-164.
Coric, B. 2012. The global extent of the Great Moderation. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics 74(4), 493-509.
Easterly, W, Kremer, M., Pritchett, L. and Summers, L.H. 1993. Good policy or good luck?:
Country growth performance and temporary shocks, Journal of Monetary Economics
32(3), 459-483
13
Eichengreen, B., Park, D. and Shin, K. 2012. When Fast Growing Economies Slow Down:
International Evidence and Implications for China. Asian Economic Papers 11(1), 42-87
Gadea, M.D., GómezLoscos, A. and PerezQuiros, G. 2018. Great Moderation and Great
Recession: From plain sailing to stormy seas?, International Economic Review 59(4), 2297-
2321
Jerzmanowski, M. 2006. Empirics of hills, plateaus, mountains and plains: a Markov-switching
approach to growth. Journal of Development Economics 81, 357-385.
Jones, B. and Olken, B. 2008. The anatomy of start-stop growth. Review of Economics and
Statistics 90(3), 582-587.
Hausmann, R., Pritchett, L., and Rodrik, D. 2005. Growth accelerations, Journal of Economic
Growth 10(4), 303-329
Kar, S., Pritchett, L., Raihan, S. and Sen, K. 2013. Looking for a break: identifying transitions
in growth regimes. Journal of Macroeconomics 38, 151-166.
Kerekes, M. 2012. Growth miracles and failures in a Markov switching classification model of
growth. Journal of Development Economics 98, 167-177.
Lucas, R. Jr. 1988. On the mechanics of economic development, Journal of Monetary
Economics 22(1), 3-42
McConnell, M.M. and Perez-Quiros, G. 2000. Output uctuations in the United States: What has
changed since the early 1980s? American Economic Review 90, 1464-1476.
Pritchett, L. 2000. Understanding patterns of economic growth: searching for hills among
mountains, plateaus, and plains. World Bank Economic Review 14(2), 221-250.
Qu, Z.J., and Perron, P. 2007. Estimating and testing structural changes in multivariate
regressions. Econometrica 75, 459-502.
14
Figure 1: Japan Decomposition
Notes: Panels show: a) observed growth and inflation, b) dynamic component, persistence (red line) and
volatility break dates (green vertical lines); c) regime means and d) deterministic seasonal component for
regime 1 in blue, regime 2 in red and regime 3 in pink.
15
Figure 2: South Korea Decomposition
Notes: See Figure 1.
16
Figure 3: China Decomposition
Notes: See Figure 1.
17
Figure 4: Russia Decomposition
Notes: See Figure 1.
18
Figure 5: Mongolia Decomposition
Notes: See Figure 1.
19
TABLE 1. Structural break tests in components of GDP growth and CPI inflation
Japan South Korea China Russia Mongolia
1960q2-2018q3 1960q2-2018q3 1993q2-2018q3 1995q2-2018q3 1995q2-2018q3
growth inflation growth inflation growth inflation growth inflation growth inflation
A. Mean 0
WDmax 102.52* 202.16* 48.19* 110.37* 51.73* 33.60* 8.93 64.31* 7.18 1.50
Seq(2|1) 26.44* 38.04* 2.68 24.84* 0.20 0.19 24.96*
Seq(3|2) 0.45 0.02 0.0 0.0
B. Seasonality
WDmax N.A. 22.34* N.A. 7.04 N.A. 13.29* 87.06* 4.40 41.31* 3.18
Seq(2|1) 19.84* 7.67 18.32* 50.30*
Seq(3|2) 0.0
C. AR lags 0 3 3 4 4 2, 0 1 1 3 0, 4
WDmax 1.83 (9.4) 9.63 (14.6) 13.07 (14.6) 14.04 (16.9) 5.32 (15.5) 14.34*(10.8) 4.4 (8.24) 1.42 (10.8) 10.72 (13.3) 19.8*(13.3)
Seq(2|1) 2.17 (11.70) 4.35 (16.70)
D. Volatility
WDmax 15.68* 64.22* 70.42* 140.29* 58.63* 45.55* 11.44* 23.74* 3.62 24.47*
Seq(2|1) 15.73* 5.98 55.53* 23.40* 2.63 6.78 6.63 21.49* 6.74
Seq(3|2) 4.27 4.65 0.0 1.30
E. # iteration 2 (2) 6 (2) 3 (2) 5 (2) 3 (2) 19 (2) 19 (2) 8 (2) 3 (2) 5 (3)
Notes: Decomposition using the iterative method of Bataa et al. (2014), with breaks detected using Qu and Perron’s (2007) test. * indicates a rejection of the null
hypothesis with 95% confidence. The null hypothesis of WDmax test is no structural break while the alternative is up to M breaks. If the null is rejected then
Seq(i+1|i) test is sequentially applied to determine the exact number of breaks, starting with a null of 1 break against an alternative of 2, until the null is not
rejected. Asymptotic 5% critical values of WDmax, Seq(2|1) and Seq(3|2) tests for the mean and volatility are 9.42, 9.82 and 10.72, respectively with trimming
20% and M = 3. The corresponding values for the seasonality are 14.55, 15.46 and 16.34 respectively, with 20% trimming and M = 3 (13.26 and 14.34 with 30%
trimming and M = 2). Those for the autoregressive parameters (trimming parameter and M are the same with seasonality) are reported next to the test statistics
in brackets in panel C as the lag orders differ across variables. The autoregressive order of the dynamic component is selected by the AIC criterion and is reported
in panel C. Finally, the numbers required to achieve convergence on the main and (sub) loops are shown. If the iteration converges to a two cycle (when 19) it
reports results based on Bataa et al. (2016)’s information criteria.
20
TABLE 2. Regimes in components of GDP growth and CPI inflation and seasonality share in the total volatility
Japan South Korea China Russia Mongolia
growth inflation growth inflation growth inflation growth inflation Growth inflation
A. Mean break dates 73q2 80q4 01q1 81q4 11q3 98q3 01q3
(72q1-74q3) (80q1-81q3) (97q3-04q3) (81q1-82q3) (09q4-13q2) (98q1-99q1) (00q4-02q2)
90q4 93q4 01q2 09q4
(87q3-94q1) (90q1-97q3) (88q3-14q3) (08q1-11q3)
Regime means (s.e.) 2.31 (0.16) 1.70 (0.10) 2.21 (0.16) 3.29 (0.22) 2.39 (0.09) 2.37 (0.31) 4.62 (0.27)
1.03 (0.13) 0.51 (0.05) 0.93 (0.10) 1.13 (0.09) 1.71 (0.03) 0.51 (0.07) 2.81 (0.10)
0.24 (0.09) 0.06 (0.04) 0.61 (0.05) 1.68 (0.18)
[0.94 (0.08)] [0.73 (0.06)] [1.82 (0.12)] [1.77 (0.12)] [2.20 (0.07)] [0.89 (0.11)] [0.69 (0.18)] [2.84 (0.16)] [1.64 (0.42)] [2.55 (0.35)]
B. Seasonality break
dt
N.A. 78q1 N.A. N.A. 09q1 03q2 03q1
(74q1-82q1) (03q3-14q3) (01q2-05q2) (01q1-05q1)
99q4 10q3
11q3
(91q4-07q4) (09q3-11q3) (10q1-13q1)
Seasonal St.Dev. N.A. 0.41 N.A. N.A. 0.90 8.42 34.38
0.52 0.64 9.66 32.19
0.26 11.17
28.00
[0.33] [0.61] [0.76] [9.23] [0.86] [30.10] [2.91]
C. Dynamic break dates 11q3 11q4
(09q3-13q3) (09q4-13q4)
Persistence (s.e.) 0.80 (0.07) 0.46 (0.33)
0.15 (0.24) 0.69 (0.21)
[0.02 (0.09)] [0.63 (0.11)] [-0.15 (0.14)] [0.46 (0.14)] [0.49 (0.19)] [0.78 (0.07)] [0.37 (0.17)] [0.47 (0.13)] [-1.24 (0.25)] [0.46 (0.32)]
Notes: Estimates of the break dates and of the components of (1) in the resulting regimes. 95% confidence intervals for the break dates and
heteroscedasticity robust standard errors are reported in brackets. The quantities that are estimated ignoring the breaks are in square parentheses.
21
TABLE 2. Continued
Japan South Korea China Russia Mongolia
growth inflation growth inflation growth inflation growth inflation Growth inflation
D. Volatility break dates 90q3 79q3 89q2 81q1 11q1 11q1 13q2 00q4 09q3
(84q1-93q3) (65q4-79q4) (80q2-89q4) (67q2-81q2) (07q3-11q2) (07q1-11q2) (01q4-14q1) (96q4-01q1) (05q1-10q1)
07q2 04q1 00q4 12q1
(04q3-11q2) (04q1-05q1) (95q3-03q1) (11q3-16q2)
Regime shock St.Dev 1.09 0.92 2.27 2.06 0.76 0.94 2.01 1.81 4.25
0.66 0.42 1.21 0.80 0.18 0.28 1.07 0.58 1.92
1.24 0.79 0.45 1.31
[1.01] [0.62] [1.73] [1.29] [0.62] [0.78] [1.81] [1.10] [4.09] [3.41]
E. Seasonality share N.A. 0.27 N.A. 0.22 N.A. 0.31 0.80 0.29 0.85 0.40
in total volatility 0.32 0.42 0.38 0.82 0.39 0.87 0.52
0.37 0.55 0.70 0.84 0.56 0.88 0.59
0.54 0.82 0.92
[0.44] [0.56] [0.45] [0.82] [0.51] [0.88] [0.63]
Notes: Estimates of the break dates and of the components of (1) in the resulting regimes. 95% confidence intervals for the break dates and
heteroscedasticity robust standard errors are reported in brackets. The quantities that are estimated ignoring the breaks are in square parentheses.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
Changes in linkages between growth in the USA, Euro area and China are investigated utilising an iterative procedure for detecting structural breaks in VAR coefficients and disturbance covariance matrix. We find dynamics to be unchanged and, accounting for volatility changes, cross-country correlations are constant until the end of 2007. Although largely isolated from the other large economies until 2007, growth in China is subsequently strongly related to that of the US and the Euro area. The effects are illustrated using generalised impulse responses and forecast error variance decompositions. The increased international synchronisation found may be associated with the effects of the Great Recession on the US and Euro area together with China's extraordinary export growth since joining the World Trade Organisation in 2001.
Article
Full-text available
Changes in the parameters of a recursively identified oil market model are examined through an iterative algorithm that tests for possible breaks in coefficients and variances. The analysis detects breaks in the coefficients of the oil production and price equations, together with volatility shifts in all three equations of the model. Coefficient changes imply an enhanced response of production to aggregate demand shocks after 1980; and that the price response to supply shocks is more persistent from the mid-1990s. All variables evidence changes in the relative contributions of individual shocks to their forecast error variances, with coefficient and volatility breaks in the first half of the 1990s being particularly important in this respect. The results show that analysts of this market should eschew constant parameter models estimated over an extended period.
Article
Full-text available
This paper proposes an iterative procedure to discriminate between structural breaks in the coefficients and the disturbance covariance matrix of a system of equations, with recursive procedures then identifying individual coefficient shifts and separating volatility from correlation breaks. Structural breaks in short-term cross-country inflation relations are then examined for major G-7 economies and within the Euro area. There is evidence that the Euro area leads inflation in North America, while changing short-term interactions apply within the Euro area. Co-variability generally increases from the late 1990s, while Euro area countries move from essentially idiosyncratic contemporaneous variation to co-movement in the 1980s.JEL classifications: C32, E31
Article
Many have argued that the Great Recession of 2008 marks the end of the reduction in output volatility known as the Great Moderation. This article shows that this is not the case through an empirical analysis. Output volatility remains subdued despite the output loss of the Great Recession. This finding has important implications for policymaking because we also find that a lower volatility of output is associated with slower recoveries. © (2018) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social and Economic Research Association
Article
Economic growth in developing countries is characterized by frequent shifts in growth regimes. Following Pritchett (2000), there is a large empirical literature that has tried to identify the timing of these shifts in economic growth. Two distinct approaches have been developed by this literature. The first is a ‘filter-based’ approach that identifies growth breaks on the basis of subjectively defined rules, while the second approach is based on statistical structural break tests. The first approach is ‘ad hoc’ and lacks consistency across studies while the Bai–Perron method that is the basis of the statistical approach has low power, not able to discern true breaks in growth. In this paper, we propose a unified approach that combines the filter and statistical approaches, and avoids the limitations of each approach. Applying our approach to comparable GDP per capita data for 125 countries for the period 1950–2010, we are able to identify a much larger number of plausible breaks in GDP per capita than a pure statistical approach. More importantly, our approach is able to identify more breaks from countries with volatile growth paths, and hence has a larger proportion of breaks from developing countries, compared to other studies that use the pure statistical method of Bai–Perron.
Article
In a recent paper, Bai and Perron (1998) considered theoretical issues related to the limiting distribution of estimators and test statistics in the linear model with multiple structural changes. In this companion paper, we consider practical issues for the empirical applications of the procedures. We first address the problem of estimation of the break dates and present an efficient algorithm to obtain global minimizers of the sum of squared residuals. This algorithm is based on the principle of dynamic programming and requires at most least-squares operations of order OOT 2 for any number of breaks. Our method can be applied to both pure and partial structural change models. Second, we consider the problem of forming confidence intervals for the break dates under various hypotheses about the structure of the data and the errors across segments. Third, we address the issue of testing for structural changes under very general conditions on the data and the errors. Fourth, we address the issue of estimating the number of breaks. Finally, a few empirical applications are presented to illustrate the usefulness of the procedures. All methods discussed are implemented in a GAUSS program.
Article
In 2008 the US financial crisis spilled over into a number of other economies causing declines in GDP across the world. Yet the decades preceding the current downturn had been a period of unprecedented stability for the US economy. This paper examines annual data for 98 countries over the period 1961-2007 and finds that lower GDP growth volatility in the period preceding the current crisis was not confined to the US. It is detected in a number of developed and developing countries, suggesting that a reduction in volatility in this period was a more general development.
Article
We identify structural breaks in economic growth in 140 countries and use these to define growth spells: periods of high growth preceded by an upbreak and ending either with a down break or with the end of the sample. Growth spells tend to be shorter in African and Latin American countries than elsewhere. We find that growth duration is positively related to: the degree of equality of the income distribution; democratic institutions; export orientation (with higher propensities to export manufactures, greater openness to FDI, and avoidance of exchange rate overvaluation favorable for duration); and macroeconomic stability (with even moderate instability curtailing growth duration).