Content uploaded by Joshua R Goodman
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Joshua R Goodman on Jan 05, 2022
Content may be subject to copyright.
Contesting Identities in South Sinai:
Development, Transformation, and the
Articulation of a “Bedouin” Identity
under Egyptian Rule
The Moshe Dayan Center for Middle Eastern and African Studies
seeks to contribute by research, documentation, and publication to the
study and understanding of the modern history and current affairs of the
Middle East and Africa. The Center is part of the School of History and
the Lester and Sally Entin Faculty of Humanities at Tel Aviv University.
Contesting Identities
in South Sinai:
Development, Transformation,
and the Articulation
of a “Bedouin” Identity
under Egyptian Rule
by
Joshua R. Goodman
Tel Aviv University
The Moshe Dayan Center
for Middle Eastern and African Sudies
Copyright © 2013 The Moshe Dayan Center, Tel Aviv University
ISBN: 978-965-224-097-2
Production and cover design: Elena Lesnick, The Moshe Dayan
Center
Printed by: Tel Aviv University Press
5
Table of Contents
Preface
A Personal Account ..............................................................11
Introduction .............................................................................21
Chapter 1
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai .........................................................47
Chapter 2
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin — Emerging
Trends and Continuities .........................................................67
Chapter 3
Economic Competition and Marginalization ............................97
Chapter 4
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks .............................123
Chapter 5
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among
the Aqaba Bedouin .............................................................159
Conclusions ...........................................................................199
Epilogue
July 2011 – June 2012 .......................................................217
Bibliography ..........................................................................223
Acknowledgements
6
Table of Figures
Figure 1: Map of approximate tribal divisions in Sinai ............................. 30
Figure 2: Conducting an interview on film. ............................................. 42
Figure 3: Ongoing construction in Dahab .............................................. 65
Figure 4: The Dahab Corniche .............................................................66
Figure 5: Urban herds .......................................................................... 80
Figure 6: Dried, preserved fish .............................................................. 82
Figure 7: Cannibis farm in South Sinai .................................................. 86
Figure 8: Bedouin girls selling bracelets ................................................. 94
Figure 9: Bedouin ‘arisha competing with Egyptian construction. ........... 103
Figure 10: Bedouin selling handicrafts on the Dahab Corniche .............. 120
Figure 11: Cairene youths strolling in the Khan al-Khalili ...................... 132
Figure 12: New forms of Bedouin dress ............................................... 141
Figure 13: Two photos of ‘Asala Center .............................................. 148
Figures 14 and 15: Wealthy and poor Bedouin homes in ‘Asala ............150
Figure 16: Graffiti on a wall in a Bedouin neighborhood ....................... 210
Figure 17: Graffiti in ‘Asala declaring “No to the Goverment.” .............. 221
Acknowledgements
7
7
Acknowledgements
First and foremost, I would like to recognize and thank Eli Sperling,
my close friend, colleague, and research partner. Without him, it is
very likely this project, born from our collaboration, would never
have happened. I would also like to thank him for his continuing
availability for questions, comments, and continuing debate, as
well as his support. Next, I would like to thank Daniel Cherrin, our
documentarian, for his patience, commitment, and hard work during
the course of this project. Special thanks go to him for documenting
and archiving our primary research, providing a number of photos
that appear throughout this work, as well as facilitating our close
relationship with our subjects.
I would like to recognize my thesis advisors, the late Professor
Joseph Kostiner, and Dr. Yoav Alon, both of Tel Aviv University’s
Department of Middle Eastern and African History, for their continuing
support and advice throughout the course of our research and writing.
Without their close help, this project would not have been conceived,
approved, or successfully executed. In a similar vein, thanks go out
to Tel Aviv University’s Moshe Dayan Center for Middle Eastern and
African Studies for its support in bringing this study to publication.
In addition to my departmental advisors, I would like to extend
my appreciation and thanks to Professor Emanuel Marx of Tel Aviv
University’s Social Sciences Department, who is not only one of the
foremost researchers of the Sinai Bedouin, largely paving the way
for my own work, but who also consistently made himself available
to answer any questions and provide valuable feedback based on his
experiences as well as his area of expertise, anthropology. He was
also kind enough to provide us with some of his own contacts in Sinai
and took valuable time out of his schedule to review a number of
chapters. Additionally, I would like to thank Professor Efrat Ben-Ze’ev
of Hebrew University’s Truman Institute for the Advancement of
Peace, for also agreeing to act as an advisor in an unofficial capacity,
especially in relation to issues of anthropology and field research.
This project is the product of my time at not one but two
institutions, and I must extend my deepest thanks to Yale University
and the MacMillan Center’s Council on Middle Eastern Studies,
Acknowledgements
8
Sociologists Jonathan Wyrtzen and Jeffery C. Alexander, and the
participants of the Middle East Social Sciences workshop for their
comments. Special thanks are due to Ellen Lust, my advisor in the
Political Science Department, for her close assistance and comments
on the final manuscript. I would also like to extend my gratitude to
James C. Scott, whose ideas echo throughout this work. His unique
perspective on agrarian societies and their interaction with states
provided a fascinating looking glass for my work with pastoral groups.
Thanks also to William G. Nomikos, a colleague and fellow graduate
student in the Political Science department. I must also thank the
MacMillan Center for providing a finishing grant for the project,
providing me an unexpected opportunity to return to the field in the
summer of 2012 while I was making my final revisions.
Another important individual to acknowledge is Professor Lila Abu
Lughod of Columbia University, whose work Veiled Sentiments on
identity and the Western Egyptian Awlad ‘Ali Bedouin was a primary
source of inspiration behind this study. Also deserving of recognition
in this regard is Thomas Eriksen, whose anthropological examination
of ethnicity provided valuable insights and direction in my own
examination of Bedouin identity.
On a more personal note, I must express my deep appreciation
to my family and advisors who encouraged me to take the risk and
plunge head first into the experience that was picking up my life and
moving it to another country. They would readily acknowledge that
this was a trying moment in my life, but they gave me the unequivocal
support I needed to make the step into that unknown. To my parents,
who never once questioned my decision and encouraged me to follow
my passions, thank you for your support and encouragement. I must
also recognize and thank two professors at Emory, Benjamin Hary
and Kenneth Stein, who both helped me to understand the decision I
was about to make and the opportunities it would present me. Their
support gave me the confidence I needed to succeed abroad, and
while they have not been my official advisors for many years, I will
never forget the impact they had on me as I transitioned to life in the
Middle East.
My warmest thanks and deepest appreciation go to the Bedouin
of Aqaba, the Egyptian migrants, and all the others who formed the
Acknowledgements
9
basis for the research presented in this paper. To all the inhabitants
of Dahab, I dedicate this work to your uneasy coexistence and your
attempts to make the best of a difficult situation. Furthermore, a
special and eternal thanks to the members of the Mzeina and Jabaliyya
tribes who welcomed us into their lives, homes, and families, who
showed us nothing but warmth and kindness, whose cooperation was
invaluable to this study, and whose friendship will remain with me for
the rest of my days.
Finally, I want to dedicate this work to the memory of Joseph
Kostiner, who passed away shortly after the completion of the first
version of this study and my departure from Tel Aviv. His guidance
and support were instrumental both to this project as well as my early
encounter with academia. He was the closest thing I had to family
during my time at Tel Aviv University. While we did not always agree,
he was a source of unequivocal support and encouraged me to stand
by my claims and pushed me to develop more convincing arguments.
I can undoubtedly say this project would not have succeeded without
his personal support. He was a source not only of guidance, but of
inspiration, and he will be missed dearly.
1111
Preface: A Personal Account
My story begins late one evening in the winter of 2008 when I was
sitting on the beach in Dahab with a young Bedouin shop-owner and
my close friend and classmate, Eli Sperling. Eli and I had come to
Dahab in search of a break from the bustle of life in Tel Aviv, where
we were both pursuing a masters degree in Middle Eastern History.
While the purpose of our trip was purely relaxation, it was typical of
us to wander off of the beaten path and perhaps stumble into a scene
that a run-of-the-mill tourist might not. After looking into a random
shop and being invited to share a shisha with the Bedouin who
ran it, we found ourselves having a heart to heart with a complete
stranger by the beach. The first thing that struck me was the level
of openness he was willing to show us as he began to rant about
his dissatisfaction with Egypt and the Egyptian “farmers” (fellahin),
as he pejoratively referred to residents of the Nile Valley. “Fucking
Egyptians,” he practically spat, “I hate those Egyptian farmers.” Wait,
I thought to myself, were we not sitting on an Egyptian beach? Wasn’t
this Bedouin also Egyptian?
As he launched into a tirade about the feminine qualities of the
“Egyptian man,” my thoughts wandered to Lila Abu Lughod’s work
on the Awlad ‘Ali Bedouin of the Western Egyptian Desert, and the
almost identical way in which she described their dim perceptions
of Egyptian society.1 As I listened along with Eli, we both began
considering the words of our companion and how his expressions
related to the anthropological concepts we were studying in our
Middle Eastern tribalism seminar in Tel Aviv. As though a light had
been turned on in the attic, we realized that our academic experience
allowed us to place this episode in a greater sociological context.
There was a deeper, more significant meaning behind this seemingly
random display of hostility and bravado, perhaps applicable to a much
wider Bedouin culture. This, I felt, was a significant discovery.
Rewind a year and a half, back to my first visit to Dahab in the
summer of 2007, shortly after my graduation from Emory University,
1. Lila Abu Lughod, Veiled Sentiments: Honor and Poetry in a Bedouin
Society (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1999).
Preface
12
where I had received by bachelor’s degree, and my arrival in Tel
Aviv. While I had visited Israel on many occasions, this was my first
time in Egypt, in fact my first time in the Middle East outside of the
predominantly Western-oriented State of Israel. I had been eager to
see something of the “real” Middle East: a convoy of camels carrying
goods across the desert, a fireside evening at a Bedouin camp singing
ancient songs about the “good old days,” really anything that made
me feel like I was actually in the Middle East, a region that, as an
American Jew, had been a personal obsession for as long as I could
remember. Looking back, I will admit, my views of the region were
perhaps overly romanticized and I undoubtedly set myself up for
disappointment. Indeed, upon our arrival in Dahab, I was struck by how
phony the presentation of “Bedouin culture” to tourists appeared to
me, how much its manifestation reminded me of tourist reproductions
of Bedouin culture in Israel. That is not to say that there were no
camel convoys or singing by the campfire, but it still felt artificial.
Due to a certain, albeit limited, understanding of the social history
of the Middle East, it was quite apparent to me then that the tourists
were getting duped, and there was very little in Dahab that constituted
anything resembling “traditional” Bedouin culture of the past in my
limited understanding of the subject. I feared that the presence of
the town and the tourists had caused the Bedouin and their cultural
heritage to disappear, replaced by a manufactured cultural experience
presented as authentic in order to give scuba divers and windsurfers
an “exotic” atmosphere meant to enhance their vacations.
But for the longest time, I had great difficulty explaining exactly
why I felt this way. I knew that something seemed phony to me, but
should this come as such a shock in a space devoted to tourism? It
wasn’t until my arrival at Yale, when during a course on Imperialism
in the Middle East I read Timothy Mitchell’s post-Structuralist account
of British imperialism in Egypt, Colonising Egypt, that it hit me. The
key was in Mitchell’s narrative of European visitors’ first experiences
in the chaotic disorganization of Egyptian cities after their exposure to
sanitized reproductions back home:
They were confused, of course, but perhaps the key to their
confusion was this: although they thought of themselves as
moving from the pictures to the real thing, they went on trying…
A Personal Account
13
to grasp the real thing as a picture. How could they otherwise,
since they took reality itself to be a picture?...Brought up in
what they thought of as a representational world, they took
representation to be a universal condition.2
The problem for these visitors was that they had arrived in Egypt
expecting to find something distinctly familiar, connecting their
experience in the real world to the “world-as-exhibition” they had
experienced back home. I realized my problem had been exactly the
opposite; my disappointment stemmed from the fact that Dahab’s
Bedouin experience did appear to me as “world-as-exhibition,” when
I was distinctly looking for something “authentic” that transcended the
superficiality that I experienced in Orientalized Western perceptions
of the Bedouin. My disappointment, ironically, stemmed from the
unexpected situation in which Dahab met all of my expectations.
But the irony was that while my expectations for the Bedouin were
quite different than most visitors to Dahab, I, too, was guilty of the
same essentialization that had been the source of my disappointment.
Looking back, this was a vitally important experience, as it helped
me understand how the tourists’ expectations and limited knowledge
created demand for certain activities, helping to shape the type of
tourism the Bedouin offered, which in turn shaped the way in which
their culture was articulated.
Returning to that beachside evening conversation: it was then
that I realized that Bedouin culture had not disappeared in Sinai, but
lingered in both altered forms as well as symbolic forms, reflecting
simultaneously an acceptance of development and transformation as
well as an attempt to maintain tradition. Our excitement was palpable.
Eli and I decided to pursue this subject and immerse ourselves in the
Bedouins’ contemporary environment in an attempt to understand
how the Bedouin have changed and what their present condition was.
This was the beginning of our collaboration.
Our new friend invited us back to his home where we shared
tea with his family. From there we were introduced to his cousins
and friends who lived in Dahab. Quickly they came to know us,
2. Timothy Mitchell, Colonising Egypt (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1988), p. 22.
Preface
14
and before long we were seldom able to walk through the streets of
Dahab without being recognized and greeted. Over the course of the
next three years, our relationship with the young Bedouin (in their
teens and twenties) deepened and we came to know the community
through their eyes. This group included our friend the shopkeeper,
his older sister, divorced by the time she was 23, his mother the land
activist, his younger brothers and sisters (full and half-siblings), and
their many cousins and friends who formed the core of their social
group in Dahab. We met Bedouin shopkeepers and drivers, tour
guides, windsurfing and scuba instructors, local drug dealers, hotel
owners, community organizers, and school children, Bedouin with
an incredibly wide array of occupations and responsibilities. Each
had a story to tell, with similar origins but widely different hopes and
goals. With all of these individuals guiding us through the developing
landscape of Dahab, we came to perceive the town (both physically
and symbolically) in a way that we never could have imagined. Instead
of understanding Dahab only as a beachside tourist paradise, we came
to understand it as an economic and social conflict zone in its own
unique way.
Our greatest source of information came from the younger
Bedouin, both because of the nature of our encounter as well as the
linguistic skills that the members of this generation possessed. Despite
our limited Arabic, we found communication to be practically effortless
as our English-speaking Bedouin friends would act as translators when
needed. This group of Bedouin mediated our encounter with the
society of Sinai, and in this way, the research we gathered was most
influenced by this young generation of unmarried Bedouin who grew
up almost exclusively in an urban setting under Egyptian rule.3 The
3. While many people would not recognize a town as small as Dahab to
constitute something truly “urban,” the social and economic distinction
between urban (town) and rural (village) is vital to this study. The town of
Dahab is an important manifestation of early urbanization, and contrasts
between Dahab, loosely conceived as a type of metropole, and the
surrounding villages will be continually invoked. The distinction between
town and village is not based on size, but rather on the fundamentals of
organization.
A Personal Account
15
very nature of our field encounter focused our research in a far more
significant way than the types of questions we asked.
It soon became apparent that the relationships that we forged with
the Bedouin had a significant impact on the direction of our research
agenda. As Lila Abu Lughod explains in the introduction to Veiled
Sentiments, “To ignore the encounter [between researcher and
subject] not only denies the power of factors such as personality, social
location in the community, intimacy of contact and luck to shape
fieldwork and its product, but also perpetuates the conventional fictions
of objectivity and omniscience that mark the ethnographic genre.”4
A fair account of the field research preserves the transparency and
integrity of the research. It does not benefit the writer to underplay
the personal connection that inevitably results from the ethnographic
experience. On the contrary, by acknowledging and embracing the
inevitable, we might come to a better understanding of the impact of
the research on the final work, increasing the accessibility and value
of the research itself. Throughout this book, a number of personal
accounts are given. I attempt to present as personal a picture of the
event as possible while maintaining my focus on the issue at hand for
the very purpose of providing a transparent account of the research
experience.
Our first important discovery was that as much as we were
interested in learning about the Bedouin’s culture, they were equally
fascinated with ours, listening to our tales from home with an intense
curiosity. This was not limited to stories, however, and our Bedouin
friends viewed our return trips with excitement as we would bring
much promised photographs and souvenirs along with our tales. The
Bedouin, trapped in Egypt because of restrictions against their travel
out of the country, are gripped with a perpetual wanderlust that our
tales of New York, Paris, and Tel Aviv could only partially sate. For
them, we were a window to the outside world.
It was no small shock for me to discover the strong similarities
between myself and my Bedouin friends, especially when I was
expecting to be confronted by a very foreign, even unrecognizable
culture. But as I listened to the Bedouin speak about their lives, I heard
4. Abu Lughod, Veiled Sentiments, p. 10.
Preface
16
echoes of my own thoughts, ranging from anxiety about their future
success to their attitudes about women, sexuality, and marriage, and
even their growing interest in music and sports. It was impossible not
to view them as part of a global youth that, in my late 20s at the
time of this publication, I am equally a part of. This connection was
facilitated by the openness that we were shown, the extent to which
the Bedouin were able to understand us from their daily interactions
with tourists, as well as the ease with which we were able to understand
their lives, which were not so starkly different from our own. While the
circumstances of their lives were certainly quite different, it was easy
to understand their worries about securing a good job and starting
a family, and whether they would be able to support themselves in
the future. Instead of focusing on the issues that were unfamiliar to
us, we spent much of our time discussing what we had in common,
deepening the bond that formed between us.
Further blurring the lines between the field and our lives back
in Tel Aviv and beyond has been our ability to maintain contact
with our friends from Dahab, through social media and internet
communications such as Skype. Many of our friends have Facebook
accounts that they access almost daily, allowing us to keep in contact
when we are not in Dahab. They have the ability to follow our lives
over the internet, and we often have the opportunity to speak and
catch up, despite being as many as 5,000 miles away. These Bedouin
were not just research subjects, they were, and still are, close friends;
people who opened my eyes to new but familiar realities and gave me
the opportunity to leave Tel Aviv with a sense of accomplishment and
a greater understanding of the world around me.
My greatest regret is that I cannot be more specific when
discussing them. I cannot tell their individual stories or even write
their names. While we all agreed that it was important to produce a
narrative highlighting the sociopolitical trauma of the Egyptian state’s
development scheme and dismantling the idea that the benefits rain
down evenly on all Egyptians, there is no question that challenging
the regime’s sociopolitical hegemony entails a certain level of risk. But
first and foremost, I believe my responsibility is to my friends, and the
following work is an attempt to shed light on their situation.It should
be fairly clear that this type of subaltern or “bottom-up” analysis
A Personal Account
17
clashes quite strikingly with the “top-down” narratives perpetuated by
state authorities.
Perhaps the most important factors pushing me to focus on the
particular question of identity contestation were the politics that
were unfolding around me during my time in Sinai. While Sinai has
received increasing, and increasingly negative, attention in the media
after the fall of the Mubarak regime in February 2011,the peninsula
has long been considered a hotbed of instability. Narcotics smuggling,
human trafficking, and terrorism are just a few of Sinai’s endemic
problems that have been blamed on the Bedouin. True, Bedouin have
been involved in all of these activities. The problem, which is itself
a core issue treated in this book, is that the activities of a select few
have been generalized as a cultural characteristic afflicting everyone
who considers themselves Bedouin. This is simply not true, and
the underlying circumstances that produce these types of behaviors
have little to do with internal aspects of Bedouin culture. Instead, I
discovered that regional and national factors, as well as basic market
pressures such as supply and demand, pushed certain groups of
Bedouin into certain illicit activities.
The primary distinction to be made among the Sinai Bedouin in
this regard is sub-regional; the social geography of North and South
Sinai are distinct. This has nothing to do with systematic differences in
the nature of the tribes inhabiting each region, but rather the policies
adopted by the Egyptian state and the nature of the Arab-Israeli
conflict. North Sinai, especially the areas bordering Israel and Gaza,
has become rife with the smuggling of weapons and narcotics as well
as of women and refugees across the border, due to the incredibly
high level of demand for these goods and the risk associated with
transport across a national border. Official embargoes on such goods
prevent legal organization of these activities, but the promise of high
profits for those willing to take the risk have pushed some North
Sinai Bedouin to participate, utilizing tightly bound social networks
to facilitate such activities. Their willingness to participate in the black
economy is increased by their marginalization from the legal economy.
Egyptian policies have failed to provide the Bedouin sufficient
economic opportunities in the transforming agricultural and industrial
economy of the North. In the South, production and smuggling of
Preface
18
narcotics is widespread, due not to transnational smuggling pressures,
but to local demand fuelled by the tourist market. The smuggling of
weapons, women, and refugees is entirely absent. Trade routes for
these goods and migrants do not transit the South, and furthermore,
such activities are potentially disruptive to tourism, the primary source
of Bedouin income. The relatively more open access that South Sinai
Bedouin have to the developing economy has led to significantly
different attitudes about the worth of certain types of illicit activities,
as well as economically disruptive violence in general.
The other major issue facing Sinai Bedouin is terrorism. In the
opening decade of the 21st century, South Sinai was targeted three
times by terrorism. In October 2004, the Taba Hilton was attacked
with a car-bomb; in July 2005, a number of explosions rocked
Sharm el-Sheikh, and in April 2006, three bombs exploded in Dahab
itself, leading to multiple deaths and injuries, among both Egyptian
and foreign tourists. In all of these cases, authorities confirmed
Bedouin participation and cracked down on Bedouin throughout
Sinai. However, in targeting Southern Bedouin for early arrests, the
authorities made a serious mistake. While opposition to the Egyptian
state is widespread in Sinai, violent manifestations are generally a
product of circumstances unique to North Sinai, where opposition
ideologies and greater instability have combined to generate violence
on a scale unseen in the South outside of these bombings. In the
South, on the other hand, the political and economic consequences
of terrorism are so devastating that there is absolutely no support for
it among Bedouin in the tourist areas of South Sinai.
Authorities later discovered and acknowledged that the Bedouin
perpetrators were from Northern tribes, just as the economic logic
would suggest.5 Northern tribes resent both the state and Southern
tribes, and the attacks against tourist resorts were as much an outburst
against the latter for their “privileged” economic position as they were
against foreigners or the state. These bombings devastated the tourist
economy in South Sinai, in turn causing severe economic hardship
among Southern tribes involved in tourism. Instead of understanding
that the Southern Bedouin were as much victims of these attacks as
5. Roee Nahmias, “Dahab Bombers Were Sinai Bedouins,” Yediot Ahronot
Online, April 26, 2006.
A Personal Account
19
were the tourists, the Egyptian state undertook efforts to “shield”
tourist centers from Bedouin living nearby. While Southern Bedouin
were entirely innocent of these crimes, they fell victim to the tendency
to assign cultural blame to groups instead of specific blame to
individuals. They were dangerous and subversive simply because they
were “Bedouin”; the actions of a few led to a generalized stereotype
afflicting the entire group.
The Egyptian state made no efforts to prevent the emergence of
such patently false and damaging stereotypes. If anything, their actions
served to reinforce them. The question is why. I believe there are two
answers. First, we all have a tendency to characterize by culture and
judge entire groups based on the actions of some of their members.
Second, it seems intuitive that the Egyptian state would show little
inclination to acknowledge the effects their own policies have played
in the Northern Bedouins’ turn to violent opposition. The state, by
virtue of its existence as the state, rarely accepts responsibility for the
negative effects of its policies. Instead, it seeks to blame others for
reasons that may be entirely spurious, while attempting to guard the
legitimacy of its actions.
Finally, on this note, I would like to insert a bit of a disclaimer
about some of the analytical decisions I have made throughout this
book. Language is a tricky thing when applied normatively. That is
to say, similar actions may be categorized differently depending on
the ideological proclivities of the speaker as well as the identities of
the actor and recipient of such action; people cannot seem to detach
language from the “good” and “bad” connotations that many words
carry. The maxim “One person’s terrorist is another’s freedom
fighter” speaks volumes about the emotional connotations words carry
and the strength of the responses they provoke. It is my strong belief
that similar actions or attributes should carry similar labels, and when
I select a term, I have done so because of the analytical definition
I have attached to it. Thus, when I describe Egyptian state actions
as “neo-colonial,” this is not an accusation nor is it an attempt to
delegitimize the state. Instead, it is the recognition that the actions
of the Egyptian state (or any other state, for that matter) towards its
national periphery is strikingly similar to the manner in which imperial
centers acted towards their imperial peripheries.Joel Migdal presents
Preface
20
an identical conclusion: “Indigenously ruled regimes… often ended up
employing much the same set of policies as the Western powers did
in colonial territories.”6 Similarly, when I describe Bedouin identity as
“ethnic,” I am not making a political argument but an analytical one,
based on a well-established scholarly literature, albeit an argument
that is still somewhat contested. I hope that readers will withhold
their judgments regarding the legitimacy of such labels until after the
evidence has been presented. Legitimacy should come a posteriori,
not from the normative or emotional response to linguistic markers
used to describe events and actions.
6. Joel S. Migdal, Strong Societies and Weak States: State-Society
Relations and State Capabilities in the Third World (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1988), p. 56.
21
Introduction
Tourism development and an increasing state presence along the
Aqaba Coast of the Sinai Peninsula have motivated a number of
transformations among the local Bedouin population. Most notable of
these changes relate to patterns of social and economic organization
as the Bedouin increasingly settle in towns, pursue economic
opportunities provided by Egyptian development, and come into
increasing contact with foreigners in their daily interactions. While
Egyptian development programs have encouraged many Bedouin to
settle in towns such as Dahab and Nuwayba, they appear to be failing
to incorporate the Bedouin into the social fabric of the Egyptian nation.
This study focuses on the relationship between Egyptian development,
socioeconomic change, and the transformation of Bedouin identity
in the Aqaba Coast region of the Sinai Peninsula in the period
since Egypt reoccupied Sinai between 1979 and 1982 (henceforth
“the neo-Egyptian period”). This period has been characterized by
rapid development and attempts at national integration. Egyptian
state-building has instigated an accelerating process of acculturation
among the Bedouin that reflects the major transformations in
their sociopolitical environment. Absent, however, is exchange of
“traditional” identities for “modern, national” identities as envisioned
by Egyptian authorities. Instead, the Bedouin have retained a strong
sense of their heritage and tradition despite the significant social
transformations they have already experienced. They have developed
a unique sense of cultural distinctiveness and articulate their identity in
direct opposition to an “Egyptian” identity.
The Bedouin living in Sinai’s Aqaba (Southeast) region have
reacted to the increasing presence of both state authorities and
unskilled migrant workers from the Nile Valley with hostility, leading
to the emergence of a social boundary between the Aqaba Bedouin
and the Egyptians who constitute the pool of laborers and authority
figures in Sinai. What is surprising, however, is that this boundary
is strengthening even as empirically identifiable cultural differences
between the two groups appear to be in decline. Furthermore,
Introduction
22
and far more interesting, the intensity of this process appears to
be tied directly to the intensity and pace of Egyptian development.
Simultaneously, the Bedouin are forming closer relationships with
foreign visitors and tourists, despite the often significant differences
in their social conventions. These relationships constitute a primary
source of cultural transformation for the Bedouin, and in Dahab many
Bedouin are actively adopting and communicating elements of tourist
culture as their own.
How, then, are the Bedouin maintaining their identity and
heritage in the face of rapid social transformation, and what role, if
any, has the Egyptian government and its policies played in fueling
this process? While the connection between state development and
Bedouin socioeconomic transformation is quite clear, the link between
these processes and Bedouin identity is far less apparent. In order to
more effectively anticipate the sociopolitical outcomes of this type of
development and the resultant relationships formed by different sectors
of Egyptian society, it is important to ascertain the actual effects of
development on processes of integration and identity formation.
The social distance between the Egyptian and Bedouin
communities, reflected by the economic marginalization of the
Bedouin and their self-segregating tendencies, has led to the
reinforcement of the boundary between Bedouin and Egyptian
social categories. This situation has largely been motivated by the
Egyptian authorities’ inaccurate assumptions about Bedouin society
and the social effects of economic development, both of which were
fundamentally challenged by the unanticipated Bedouin reaction to
Egyptian development strategies. This study contends that Bedouin
identity in the Aqaba region of South Sinai, far from disappearing
in the face of new lifestyles, is actually strengthening in reaction to
Egyptian encroachment and development despite processes of social
homogenization caused by integrative development. The structural
integration of the Bedouin into the Egyptian state is not increasing a
sense of “national solidarity” among the Bedouin. On the contrary,
they communicate both a feeling of marginalization by Egyptian
authorities and a lack of national pride and belonging. Instead of
folding the Bedouin into the existing “Egyptian nation,” increasing
contact and transformation is fuelling a conflict between two groups
that see themselves as socially distinct.
Introduction
23
Simultaneously, the Bedouin are clearly recognizing a number of
benefits that tourism development has brought to them, acknowledging
the rise in living standards even while lamenting the marginalization
due to perceived discriminatory policies of the Egyptian government.
This suggests that the Bedouin are not opposed to development, but
to the manner in which the Egyptian government is pursuing it.
Due to the economic and political importance placed on the
peninsula in the latter half of the 20th century, Sinai of the past 60
years has been marked by increasing levels of foreign penetration,
whether from Cairo, Jerusalem, or more recently, the “Lonely
Planet.” As scholars most often focus on the political and “big picture”
consequences of this type of penetration, competition, and conflict,
the micro-level social consequences have been given relatively little
attention and warrant closer study. This has been especially true of
the 30 years since Sinai was reoccupied by Egypt and Israeli social
scientists largely ended their research there. However, it is undeniable
that this perpetual instability, marked by frequently shifting regimes,
the intrigues of interested powers, and the recent arrival of tourism on
a global scale has ensured that change has been a constant feature in
the lives of Sinai’s inhabitants. While some of these changes have been
purely political and rather superficial, others have caused significant
dislocations in the socioeconomic patterns of everyday life.
The Bedouin, once caught between competing powers, an
environment of scarcity, and a territory marked by limited centralized
political control, are now faced with a new reality. The Egyptian
government, which regained Sinai from Israeli occupation per the
1979 Israeli-Egyptian peace treaty, has discarded its previous plan
for Sinai as military buffer to Israel and instead continued the Israeli
strategy of economic development, especially in the tourism sector.
This development has led to the emergence of urban spaces across
Sinai, sites that have supported emerging markets to create local
jobs and attract migrants from the Nile Valley searching for work in a
stagnating national economy. These towns have given the Egyptian
government a foothold in Sinai, allowing the state to bring a measure
of regulation to the peninsula; they have also created a destination for
an expanding foreign population of tourists and ex-pats, mostly from
Europe and America, who have become a common feature in the
transforming socioeconomic landscape of South Sinai.
Introduction
24
A large majority of the indigenous inhabitants of Sinai are
Bedouin, who are often assumed to be disconnected from the realities
of contemporary political life and are usually viewed as traditional
and isolated. On the contrary, it is inevitable that the lives of those
inhabiting Sinai would be dramatically affected by wars, invasions,
peace negotiations, phased withdrawals, urban development, and the
growth of tourism, and not only politically. Economically, these events
have the power to shape markets, and socially, the arrival of new
visitors carrying differing forms of culture has fundamentally altered
the Bedouins’ social space.
The native Bedouin have not ignored the Egyptian-directed
development process; indeed they could not even if they wanted to. On
the most superficial level, significant changes to the economic situation
of Sinai, with the emergence of local markets and a flourishing tourist
economy, have encouraged new types of economic engagement,
while an increasing government presence has limited the ability to
continue a number of traditional activities such as herding and fishing.
Furthermore, with the rapid expansion of available technologies and
increasing contact with Egyptian authority figures, migrants, and
tourists, the Bedouin have been exposed to new forms of culture
that have led them to reconsider their place in society. A notable
consequence is that they have begun to conceive of themselves as
imbedded in a much larger social environment on both a national and
global scale. This has recently become a much greater concern to the
Bedouin, leading to significant changes in cultural conceptions and
self-image.
Analytical Frameworks
A major focus of this study is political identity. A question immediately
arises as to the best way to conceive of Bedouin identity. Is the
lens of tribalism still the best way to understand socioeconomic and
political transformation among the Bedouin? The answer to this
question is an unequivocal no, for the continuing tendency to study
the Bedouin through the lens of “tribalism” does a double disservice.
First, it perpetuates the fiction that there is some fundamental cultural
difference between tribal and non-tribal societies instead of conceiving
Introduction
25
“tribalism” through an organizational idiom. Second, it eliminates
any intersubjectivity with non-tribal populations, complicating any
attempt to apply the study of contemporary political processes to the
Bedouin.
Instead, I propose to utilize a significantly different type of identity
theory to examine the identity politics of the Aqaba Bedouin, that
of “ethnicity.” While the term itself carries a number of political
connotations, my decision to adopt this category is entirely analytical,
defined as “a form of interaction between culture groups operating
within common social [and political] contexts.”7 While this definition
may be unfamiliar to some, who instead perceive ethnicity to be similar
to ideas of race, there is a rich literature on the politics of identities
in interaction, to which scholars, notably social anthropologists, have
attached the label “ethnic.” In this way, I draw an analytical distinction
between tribalism, which aims to regulate relations within Bedouin
society, and ethnicity, which operates between the Bedouin and other
social groups. Tribalism is internally regulating; ethnicity is externally
regulating. At its most parsimonious, ethnicity is defined as a form of
social organization based on an idiom of cultural descent.8
This political interaction of distinct social groups within national
contexts is precisely the focus of this book, and I have found that this
concept of ethnicity has provided high leverage for the analysis of
questions of Bedouin identity in a socially heterogeneous setting such
as Dahab.9 “Ethnicity” in this sense, focuses on issues of sociopolitical
7. Abner Cohen, “Introduction: The Lessons of Ethnicity,” in Abner Cohen
(ed.), Urban Ethnicity (London: Tavistock, 1974), p. xi.
8. Note that this definition implies that traits such as skin color and language
are not the sources of ethnic difference in and of themselves, but
instead are signaling devices for different culture groups, whether real or
imagined. See Donald L. Horowitz, Ethnic Groups in Conflict (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1985), p. 55. Horowitz states, “Ethnic
groups can be placed at various points along the birth-choice continuum.
But there is always a significant element of descent.”
9. J. Clyde Mitchell, “Perceptions of Ethnicity and Ethnic Behavior: An
Empirical Explanation,” in Urban Ethnicity (ed.), Abner Cohen (London:
Tavistock, 1974), pp. 27–28. When reading anthropology that dates
back to the 50s and 60s, as much of Mitchell’s work does, care must
Introduction
26
competition and provides a strong approximation of national identities
and those that develop in reaction to nationalism and nation-building.
In all of these ways, the type of identity that is the focus of this study
reflects many ethnic elements, and ethnicity theory, especially as it is
articulated among social anthropologists, provides a compelling logic
explaining the patterns of transformation and articulation of Bedouin
identity in the urban centers of South Sinai.
While the application of an “ethnic” framework is admittedly quite
rare in the study of the Bedouin, its importance to Middle Eastern
sociopolitical organization has not gone unrecognized. As early as
1984, Itamar Rabinovich and Milton Esman hypothesized that a
greater willingness to explore such theories of ethnicity and issues of
ethnic pluralism in Middle East societies could significantly aid in the
explanation of patterns of conflict that dominate many structurally
weak Middle East states, but noted that ethnicity has not often been
used as a basis for analysis.10 Despite this hesitancy, they identified the
sectarian conflicts in Iraq and Lebanon, as well as the Sunni-Shi‘i rift
in the Gulf and the Muslim-Christian divide in Egypt all as phenomena
that can be studied in an ethnic framework. This contention is accurate
even though the dichotomies themselves may be religious. This has to
do with the field in which identities are deployed. Whether religious or
racial, in contemporary national interactions, all cultural identities are
“ethnic” in this way.
Philip Khoury and Joseph Kostiner make a related claim in their
edited volume Tribes and State Formation in the Middle East, in
their discussion of the developing relationship between tribesmen
and polities. They argue that in conflicts between the state and tribes,
ethnicity is a vehicle that tribesmen, like other social groups, might
adopt in order to oppose government attempts to increase state
be taken to distinguish between the use of the terms ethnicity and
tribalism. However observers will notice that these terms often reflect the
perceptions of “modern” versus “traditional” societies and are thus quite
illuminating.
10. Itamar Rabinovich and Milton Esman, “Introduction,” in Itamar Rabinovich
and Milton Esman (eds.), Ethnicity, Pluralism, and the State in the
Middle East (Cornell: Cornell University Press, 1988).
Introduction
27
control over them.11 This statement in their introduction forms the
basis for this study, which seeks to examine social change and identity
formation in the framework of ethnic organization. The focus shall
be on examining the transformations in the social and economic
forms of organization among the Bedouin and how this relates to
the evolution in the articulation of their identity in an increasingly
“national” context.
Bassam Tibi, in his chapter in Tribes and State Formation,
supports a qualified view of Rabinovich and Essman’s hypothesis
by reconciling it with Khoury and Kostiner’s, drawing important
distinctions between tribalism and ethnicity. He shows that ethnicity
as a theoretical framework for studying tribe-state interactions
assumes importance due to the centrality of ethnic organization to the
modern nation-state (see below). Tibi distinguishes between tribes and
ethnicity in that ethnies are “sub-national divisions in the communities
of the modern nation-states of the Middle East,” while tribalism is
fundamentally non-national.12 He continues by asserting that ethnicity
presupposes the possibility of further tribal division, using the example
of the Alawites in Syria, showing how, despite their Arab heritage
and their tribally-divided society, they should be considered an ethnic
category in Syrian contexts due to the articulation of their Alawite
identity in ethnic terms.13 This is equally applicable to the Amazigh or
Berber tribes of some North African states, notably Morocco, Algeria,
and Libya, who have begun to mobilize politically, not along tribal
lines but along ethno-cultural lines.14
11. Philip S. Khoury and Joseph Kostiner, “Introduction: Tribe and the
Complexities of State Formation in the Middle East,” in Philip S. Khoury
and Joseph Kostiner (eds.), Tribes and State Formation in the Middle
East (London: IB Tauris, 1991), p. 3.
12. Bassam Tibi, “The Simultaneity of the Unsimultaneous: Old Tribes and
Imposed Nation-states in the Modern Middle East,” in Philip S. Khoury
and Joseph Kostiner (eds.), Tribes and State Formation in the Middle
East (London: IB Tauris, 1991), p. 139.
13. Ibid., p. 138.
14. See Jonathan Wyrtzen, “Colonial State Building and the Negotiation
of Arab and Berber Identity in Protectorate Morocco,” International
Journal of Middle East Studies 43 (2011). Wyrtzen demonstrates how
Introduction
28
The state is the primary factor in ethnic identity formation in two
major ways. First, as a territory with established boundaries, it sets
the scope for national sociopolitical interactions, defining the arena or
political field in which ethnic identity is shaped and deployed. Second,
it is a vehicle for the distribution of resources and the pursuit of group
interests, which are manifested in state policies. In the words of
Barkey and Parikh, “it has already become evident that state policies
constituted one of the major determinants of mobilization and shifting
identity patterns.”15 The social group controlling the state drives the
formation of primary national identities and ideologies, and it will
be against this group that other identities form. In these two ways,
the contemporary state is the primary arena for group mobilization
and the articulation of identities. Furthermore, it is not the state that
assumes importance in an examination of ethnic identities, but it is
ethnic identity that assumes importance in the contemporary reality
of the state system and state-society interaction. This, as Mitchell
explains, is because so often “political oppositions are phrased
in ethnic terms and in so doing provide the sentiments in terms of
which social actions may be justified.”16 It is this link between ethnicity
and national context that makes ethnicity theory applicable in an
examination of tribe-state relations in Sinai, as the state has, to a large
extent, created the basis for a Bedouin ethnicity through its policies
towards the group as a whole.
government policies created the basis for an ethnic “Berber” solidarity that
crossed tribal boundaries. This concept of state policy and identity will be
explored later in this paper. Regarding ethnopolitical Berber mobilization
in Morocco and Algeria in more recent years, see Bruce Maddy-Weitzman,
“Contested Identities: Berbers, ‘Berberism’ and the State in North
Africa,” The Journal of North African Studies 6.3 (2001). For a short
discussion of ethnopolitics between Arabs and Berbers in Libya, see Ishra
Soleiman, “Denied Existence: Libyan-Berbers under Gaddafi and Hope
for the Current Revolution,” Muftah, March 24, 2011, <http://muftah.
org/?p=961>.
15. Karen Barkey and Sunita Parikh, “Comparative Perspectives on the
State,” Annual Review of Sociology 17 (1991), p. 542.
16. Mitchell, “Perceptions of Ethnicity and Ethnic Behavior,” p. 30.
Introduction
29
Within this framework, this study aims to analyze the marginal
status of the Aqaba Bedouin as a result of the realities that the
Egyptian state, especially though its development policies, has
created for them, specifically through the link between socioeconomic
transformation, acculturation, and identity formation. This will begin
in chapter one with an examination of Egyptian goals for Sinai.
Chapter two examines the Bedouins’ adaptation of their economic
practices to adapt to the realities of Egyptian development and the
proliferation of tourism in the region. Chapter three examines the
other side of this coin, the increasing economic marginalization of
the Bedouin. Chapter four focuses on the social transformation of the
urbanizing Bedouin. Finally, chapter five examines the transformation
and articulation of a Bedouin identity to determine the relationship
between state policies, socioeconomic transformation, and processes
of Bedouin ethnogenesis, which is defined as the articulation and
emergence of previously non-ethnic identities in an ethnic idiom.17
This study will show that state policies regarding development
and integration in South Sinai are motivating transformations in both
dominant modes of socioeconomic organization as well as Bedouin
identity including expressions of social solidarity. It is simultaneously the
goals of development and the manner in which state policies fuelling
integration have shaped Bedouin-Egyptian interactions that have led
to the emergence of the frameworks necessary for socioeconomic
transformation and the emergence of ethnically-articulated identities
among the Aqaba Bedouin.
Definitions
Before continuing, a few definitions should be presented in order to
clarify the terms and concepts central to this paper. First and foremost,
the subjects of this study are the Bedouin of the Aqaba Coast of the
Sinai Peninsula, and more specifically, the sedentary Bedouin of
Dahab. The focus of the research has been on the younger generation
of Bedouin who did not spend a significant portion of their lives living
17. Horowitz, Ethnic Groups in Conflict, p. 64.
Introduction
30
in the desert or under Israeli rule and whose social experiences have
developed exclusively under expanding Egyptian rule from 1982
onwards. As a trend, these Bedouin are the ones most active in the
urban markets of Dahab, and thus represent the “cutting edge” of
Bedouin transformation. They also embody the core of an emerging
Bedouin elite at the top of distribution networks connected to tourism,
which has become the primary source of revenue for the Bedouin.
Figure 1: Map of approximate tribal divisions in Sinai, reproduced from
Murray, G.W., Sons of Ishmael: A Study of the Egyptian Bedouin
(G Routledge & Sons Ltd. London, 1935)
Introduction
31
As the geographical focus of this study is Dahab, which lies in
the territory of the Mzeina Bedouin (see Map, Figure 1), a majority
of these subjects come from the Mzeina tribe, inhabiting the Sinai
coast along the Aqaba Gulf from Nuwayba to Sharm el-Sheikh, and
inland to Santa Katarina. However, tribal divisions have not mirrored
developments in Egyptian policy and do not constitute a primary
source of differentiation for the purposes of this study. Within Dahab,
Bedouin from other tribes, such as the Jabaliyya and ‘Aleqat, also
seek work. Furthermore, the area north of Nuwayba is the territory
of the Tarabin tribe, whose members also participate in development
and tourism but are not from the same confederational grouping as
the Mzeina and other southern tribes: the Tawara, and therefore
hold a much different tribal identity. For the purposes of analytical
accuracy, then, tribal identities will only be used in specific reference
to tribal issues. In other contexts, the term “Aqaba Bedouin” will be
used to identify them primarily on the basis of their nationally-defined
territory (the Aqaba Coast of Sinai, Egypt) and the activities which are
dominant in the region, notably tourism, as opposed to their tribally-
defined territory. In instances where I am specifically referring to the
sedentarized Bedouin of Dahab, I use the term “Dahab Bedouin.”
Two terms that must be defined are “state-building” and “nation-
building,” considered here to be two distinct but related processes,
both integral to a study of state-sponsored development and
identity transformation. State-building is a process aimed at building
institutions that reflect regime preferences while increasing state
control over its territory and inhabitants. It seeks the integration of
the periphery into the center for this purpose, through the creation
of transportation and communications infrastructure, coercive control
(such as army and police), the application of national laws and
policies and the effective collection of taxes. Nation-building, on the
other hand, is psychologically-oriented. As defined by one political
scientist, nation-building is a process of “weld[ing] disparate elements
of the populace into a congruent whole by forging new identities at
the national [=state] level at the expense of localism or particularistic
identities.”18 In other words, it is the state’s (or other elite groups’)
18. Amitai Etzioni, “A Self-Restrained Approach to Nation-Building by
Foreign Powers,” International Affairs 80.1 (2004).
Introduction
32
dissemination and reification of nationalist ideologies and values
across the whole of its population. The goal of this process is the
standardization of values, ideologies, and identities among a state’s
population to increase national solidarity and specific patterns of
sociopolitical conformity. While state-building seeks to strengthen
the state or the polity, nation-building seeks to forge a unified social
body, the nation, to overcome the inevitable existence of sub-national
social divisions. In blunter terms, nation-building may be thought of as
a process of legitimization of a social and institutional order created
by those controlling the state. Nation-building strategies are pursued
through mandatory education and national media outlets, tourism,
museums and other public spaces, and mandatory national service,
all of which play an important role in the socialization of identity and
values.19 State- and nation-building are the two processes by which the
Egyptian state seeks to increase its authority in Sinai. These processes
will be repeatedly addressed throughout this work.
Finally, a major concept presented in this paper is “modernization.”
Modernization most accurately refers to a cluster of theories seeking
to explain the effects of economic development and the sources of
social and political change. Originally, the founders of modernization
theory sought to locate the sources of participatory government
in contemporary trends of economic development, notably
industrialization and its accompanying social trend, urbanization.
Seymour Martin Lipset, considered one of the formative scholars
of modernization theory, showed a correlation between economic
output and democracy.20 The mechanisms through which this process
supposedly operates were given greater expression in various other
works, notably Daniel Lerner’s The Passing of Traditional Society,
which presents a theory linking economic development to participatory
19. See for example Byron G. Massialas, Education and the Political System
(Reading: Addison-Wesley, 1969); see also Benedict Anderson, Imagined
Communities: Reflections on the Origin and Spread of Nationalism,
2nd ed. (London: Verso, 1991).
20. Seymour Martin Lipset, “Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic
Development and Political Legitimacy,” The American Political Science
Review 53.1 (1959), pp. 69–105; See also Lipset, Political Man: The
Social Bases of Politics (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1960).
Introduction
33
government through processes of social change allegedly caused by
economic growth. For Lerner, industrialization yielded urbanization,
which in turn promoted the emergence of a mass media, which drove
increasing literacy, culminating in greater demands for participatory
government (democracy).21 In a nutshell, the idea is that economic
development drives social development which yields positive political
development, and by implication, all good things go together.
This is not to say that my own analysis in any way relies on the
components of modernization theory. Instead, it recalls a comment
once made by the renowned Middle East scholar Elie Kedourie, who
said, “When…policies… together with the doctrines and principles
which justify them, are considered, then it is realized what a large
part verbal traps and dubious dogmas have had in the construction
of doctrines and the shaping of policies.”22 Modernization theory can
be considered one of Kedourie’s “dubious dogmas,” enjoying little
empirical support at the micro-process level. Samuel Huntington
was more explicit in declaring modernization theory an “erroneous
dogma,” which simply cannot account for the abundance of anomalies
whereby industrialization and economic development have failed to
produce positive social and political developments.23
The abundance of critiques and the persistence of anomalies,
however, have not prevented the emergence of a number of extensions
and inversions of modernization theory. Perhaps the most problematic
have been social variants of modernization focusing on the role of
economic growth and institutional change in the disappearance of
traditionalism and the emergence of national identities. This strand of
modernization theory conceives of ethnic or particularistic identities
as “primordial sentiments … forg[ing] ties of emotion rather than
interests … [that] would be replaced through modernization by loyalties
21. Daniel Lerner, Passing of Traditional Society: Modernizing the Middle
East (New York: Macmillan Publishing, 1958). Moreover, the parallels
between modernization and structural conceptions of nationalism, notably
by Gellner and Anderson, should be apparent and will be addressed later.
22. Elie Kedourie, The Chatham House Version, and Other Middle-Eastern
Studies (London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson, 1970), p. 2.
23. Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New
Haven: Yale University Press, 1968), p. 6.
Introduction
34
to the class and the nation,” loyalties that are labeled rational instead
of emotional.24 In a political sense, “modernization” entails a “marked
redistribution of power within a political system: the breakdown of
local, religious, ethnic, or other power centers and the centralization
in national political institutions [my emphasis].”25 Not only does
the mantra of modernization enshrine the national state as the sole
legitimate authority, but by combining economic and political strands
of the theory, it also casts state development as both benevolent and
efficient when the reality may be much more traumatic for regions
undergoing this development.
The impact of modernization theory on economic ideologies
and development paradigms has had serious consequences for the
direction of national and global development. Since economic growth
is assumed to produce positive social and political outcomes, then by
implication more or faster growth is better than less or slower growth.
This produced a focus on maximizing economic efficiency. Moreover,
since the principal unit of political and economic organization is
assumed to be the state (this is certainly the case if we are interested in
outcomes such as democracy), the primary focus of the modernization
paradigm is not the individual, but the state. Modernization supports
a developmental strategy based on top-down economics singularly
focused on maximizing efficiency and growth through privatization,
reliance on international fiscal institutions, free trade, and foreign
investment and control; it focuses more on national economic interests
than on microeconomic successes and often does little to address the
economic needs of a great portion of the population.26
Simon, in an excellent and critical review of development rhetoric,
argues that defining modernization in terms of economic efficiency has
meant that we no longer predicate modernity on increases in individual
24. Barkey and Parikh, “Comparative Perspectives on the States,” p. 542.
See also Andreas Wimmer, Nationalist Exclusion and Ethnic Conflict:
Shadows of Modernity (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002),
pp. 42–43.
25. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies, p. 142.
26. David Simon, “Development Reconsidered: New Directions in
Development Thinking,” Geografiska Annaler. Series B, Human
Geography 79.4 (Current Development Thinking) (1997), p. 187.
Introduction
35
wellbeing.27 Policies aimed at maximizing economic efficiency have
often ignored questions of whether economic transformations have had
positive or negative impacts on the quality of life of a state’s subjects,
whether it empowers locals to make their own decisions, and whether
this development is socially and environmentally sustainable.28
Regardless of the observed consequences of economic development,
the modernization paradigm’s tendency to privilege the welfare of the
state has rendered it an attractive model for state-building projects
and top-down development. The combination of social and economic
strands of modernization enables the state to dismiss peripheral
concerns and competing interests by casting them as “traditional” or
otherwise irrational. Modernization, as a development paradigm, is
very friendly towards states and national goals by legitimizing them
and delegitimizing regional development concerns that clash with
central interests, which are framed in the rhetoric of the greater
good or the national interest. Further perpetuating the centrality of
the modernization paradigm in global development and post-colonial
state-building has been the dominance of neoliberal policies favored
by USAID, the IMF, and the World Bank.29
In this way, modernization is given an objective existence
as the foundation of the state’s development strategy, guiding
assumptions and expectations for development, and thus has very
real consequences for the Aqaba Bedouin. Borrowing from political
scientist Alexander Wendt’s constructivist approach to objectivity, “If
men define situations as real, they are real in their consequences.”30
27. Ibid., 185. See also a discussion of economic reconstruction of Iraq:
Haytham Bahoora, “Shock-and-Awe Nation Building: Iraq’s Neo-Liberal
Reconstruction,” Jadaliyya.com, Arab Studies Institute, May 14, 2012.
Web. <http://www.jadaliyya.com/pages/index/5522/shock-and-awe-
nation-building_iraqs-neo-liberal-re>. For Lenin, this was the sacrifice that
modernization entailed.
28. Ibid., p. 187.
29. Ibid., p. 185. Simon calls neoliberalism the “contemporary incarnation”
of modernization. See also Hutington, Political Order in Changing
Societies.
30. Alexander Wendt, Social Theory of International Politics (Cambridge,
UK: Cambridge University Press, 1999), p. 330.
Introduction
36
What is important to note here is that I am not claiming that these
development authorities necessarily adopt an explicit modernization
paradigm in their approach to development, that is to say, that
the state does not claim that the modernization of such peripheral
populations is the overarching goal of development.31 However, the
coincidence in the case of Dahab is striking, and the rhetoric of the
state and its developmental agencies appears predicated on many of
the assumptions of economic modernization to justify policies whose
benefits have tended to target a narrow, politically connected group
of officials and entrepreneurs. This issue will be explored in greater
depth in chapter one.
What is important to clarify is that the processes of “modernization,”
notably economic development, urbanization, the construction of
transportation and communications infrastructure and the rise of mass
media, the expansion of education and literacy, and the emergence
of bureaucracies, to name a few, are better defined as “integrating”
processes. These processes lead to the adoption of similar
organizational forms and similar expressions of dependence on state
structures. This encourages cultural homogenization, but is superficial
and not necessarily linked to an adoption of “modern” or “national”
identities as predicted by proponents of social modernization. Samuel
Huntington acknowledges this reality in Political Order in Changing
Societies when he states that in contrast with the above “facts” of
integration, “progress towards many of the other goals which writers
have identified with political modernization [including]… national
integration—often is dubious at best.”32
This study is not interested in distinctions between “modern” and
“primitive” societies, and instead focuses on the relationship and
interactions between various social groups bounded by a state as
levels of “stateness” increases in Sinai. I define stateness, following
Joel Migdal, as the state’s appropriation of forms of social and
economic control from non-state actors.33 In this regard, the state
31. The Development reports, though, do clearly show this to be at the very
least an ancillary objective.
32. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies, p. 35.
33. Migdal, Strong Societies and Weak States. See discussion in Chapter
One: A Model of State-Society Relations, pp. 10–41.
Introduction
37
should be understood as “regime,” one of a number of social actors
competing for sociopolitical influence within its defined territory.
To be “modern,” in the rhetoric of the state system, is to willingly
subordinate non-state forms of sociopolitical control and solidarity to
state interests and organs, a demand that has met much resistance
along the peripheries of the developing world. This is one potential
explanation for the persistence of “traditional” societies within
hegemonic “modernizing” states and suggests a coincidence of
identity and interest. In fact, a basic premise of this argument is that
the modern-traditional dichotomy, far from providing useful analytic
leverage on issues of social change, actually obfuscates the dialectical
and co-produced nature of social transformation. The link between
this structure of competition and identity will be discussed in chapter
five.
The Bedouin are not autarkic, a society able to exist independently
from the rest of Egypt (as in thinking about Egypt as a “modern”
society and the Bedouin as a “traditional” society), but have come to
constitute a unique social category within Egyptian society. It would
be helpful to recall the words of Friedrich Nietzsche when he noted,
“The general imprecise way of observing sees everywhere in nature
opposites (as for example “warm” and “cold” [or in this case “modern”
and “traditional”]) where there are, not opposites, but differences in
degree.”34 Instead of examining a transition from “traditional” to
“modern” modes of living, the focus shall be on increasing levels of
state control and integration and how the Bedouin have responded to
these changes.
Research and Methodological Approaches
While this work is based in large part on ethnographic field
research conducted in Sinai, it draws on a number of other sources
34. Frederich Nietzsche, Der Wanderer und sein Schatten, in R.J.
Hollingdale (ed. and trans.), A Nietzsche Reader (Harmondsworth:
Penguin, 1988). Quoted in Thomas Hylland Eriksen, Ethnicity and
Nationalism—Anthropological Perspectives (Anthropology, Culture
and Society), 2nd ed. (New York: Pluto, 2002), p. 162.
Introduction
38
of information. It will be beneficial to discuss the particulars of the
research as well as the location, Dahab. However, this project relies
on a number of other disciplines and methodological approaches in
addition to ethnography, and some words should be said about my
preference for a multi-disciplinary approach. I have attempted to rely
as evenly as possible on the different disciplines chosen for this study
instead of relying exclusively on one. The primary disciplines engaged
in this study are social anthropology, sociology, and history, though
support was sought further afield, including from political science,
social psychology, and the emerging field of tourism studies. More will
be said about each discipline and their interaction.
The decision to make Dahab the geographical focus of the project
stems from the special attention this part of Sinai has received
for the development of tourism, which has been a primary tool
highlighting and magnifying the identity processes under study. As
the mainstay of the Aqaba Bedouin economy, tourism has led to
a “traditionalization” of Bedouin economic practices, that is, the
communication of these practices through the language of tradition
as a way to make these economically valuable practices symbolically
meaningful to consumers, who search for an “authentic” cultural
experience. Effective symbolism, in this case, legitimizes these
activities as “authentic.” Tourism can, in this way, be considered the
commercialization of culture for economic gain. This culture, however,
far from being a true representation of how the Bedouin live today,
is largely constructed based on perceptions about the Bedouins’
heritage and “traditions,” and is thus economically analogous to other
symbolic identity processes that are the focus of this study. This type
of culture under-communicates aspects of acculturation and focuses
instead on elements preserved from an idealized, distant past. Just
as ethnic identity links contemporary culture to images of the past,
tourism does the same.
Heritage tourism in Dahab has the effect of exaggerating the
communication of culture, allowing for a clearer examination of the
processes involved in the formation and communication of identity.
Furthermore, heritage tourism provided the opportunity to contrast
tourist conceptions of Bedouin culture and the actual progress of
socioeconomic transformation in order to analyze the role of culture
Introduction
39
in identity formation. Tourism as a lens was an invaluable aid in the
study of identity politics, especially the construction of culture and
tradition and the symbolic purposes they serve.35 Special attention
was given to manifestations of identity through tourism, a central
theme in the research. However, tourism so strongly connects culture
and economics that it may be the case that the economic aspect of
social conflict, a well-established but contested theory, is somewhat
overdetermined by the force of particular circumstances.
The field of tourism studies played an important role in studying
the economic and social effects of tourism development. While this
field is still fairly new, tourism as a global, cultural phenomenon
undoubtedly deserves the attention of social scientists, and a number
of works on the subject in general, as well as in the Middle East
specifically, had a profound impact on this analysis, and even played
a role in shaping the direction of the research conducted in the field,
providing for the use of certain aspects of tourism as way points and
bases for further analysis, such as the state’s role in formal versus
informal tourism and how each might approach a single concept,
such as employment. Tourism is an issue that cannot be divorced
from the Aqaba Coast; it was vital to this work to explore the ways
in which tourism affects communities and economies. The volume on
tourism in the Middle East edited by Rami Daher is an excellent and
encompassing look at the various aspects of tourism—combining such
fields as economics, cultural anthropology, sociology, and political
science—and demonstrates how truly dynamic tourism studies can be
as an independent field of inquiry.
Further increasing the value of Dahab as a research site is its
origin not as an administrative center, colonial outpost, or military
base, but as a Bedouin date oasis, a traditional forum for Mzeina
social interaction. Dahab’s origin as a tourist center dates from the
establishment of traveler camps set up by Bedouin to serve Israeli
visitors to Sinai after the 1967 War instead of a tourist resort
35. Rami Farouk Daher, “Reconceptualizing Tourism in the Middle East,”
in Rami Farouk Daher (ed.), Tourism in the Middle East Continuity,
Change, and Transformation (Minneapolis: Channel View Publications,
2006), pp. 16, 19.
Introduction
40
planned and built through government projects.36 Dahab’s Bedouin
neighborhoods around ‘Asala comprise the largest urban Bedouin
settlement on the coast, and they have developed organically from an
exclusively Bedouin space to a bustling commercial and tourist center.
Since Bedouin neighborhoods in Dahab are not the result of an
Egyptian urban plan, the space remains a manifestation of authentic
Bedouin transformation instead of a Bedouin tourist façade reflecting
external assumptions about the Bedouin; the Bedouin presence in
Dahab is more reflective of the Bedouin condition than the spaces
constructed to fuel Egyptian tourism.
The bulk of our field research was conducted in Sinai between
March 2009 and May 2010, in which I, along with my research
partner, Eli Sperling, would take trips to Dahab for about a week
every other month. Additionally, I was able to undertake two longer
periods of research, each consisting of about four weeks, in the
summers of 2011 and 2012. From our base in Dahab, spending the
majority of our time with the Bedouin around town, we were able to
acquire a unique perspective on the effects that development in Sinai
and Egyptian policies have had on the lives of the Bedouin. We had
the opportunity to explore the ties between the Bedouin and foreign
tourists, through the relationship we forged with our subjects, as well
as the relationship between the Bedouin, the authorities, and the
Egyptian migrants. As a town about half-way down the Aqaba Coast,
Dahab provided a perfect base to travel throughout the sub-region.
Our excursions ranged from visits to Sharm el-Sheikh to compare the
economic roles of the Bedouin between the two towns, to trips into
the desert to participate in Mzeina social functions such as weddings
and even a ritual goat slaughter, to Bedouin tourist camps in order to
explore the role of Bedouin culture in Sinai tourism. While we felt that
these excursions did not greatly inform us about the historical practices
or lives of the Bedouin, we were able to construct a broad picture of
how development has affected the lives of the Sinai Bedouin today
36. Interview with a Bedouin Divemaster, July 24, 2009; see also Smadar
Lavie, The Poetics of Military Occupation Mzeina Allegories of
Bedouin Identity Under Israeli and Egyptian Rule (New York: University
of California, 1991), p. 68.
Introduction
41
and were shown how Bedouin notions of tradition were reconciled
with the changes to their world.
The goal of the field component of the research was to construct a
broad picture of the realities of contemporary Bedouin life, especially
in an urbanizing setting, as well as to immerse ourselves in the Bedouin
tourist economy. From this it was possible to draw conclusions about
Bedouin self-identity and image, notably how Bedouin imagine
themselves and their cultural heritage and how they communicate
themselves and their community as separate from Egyptians.
Additionally, we focused on patterns of socioeconomic organization
and attempted to compare these forms to those adopted by other
social groups within the Egyptian state in order to draw conclusions
about the factors motivating certain socioeconomic transformations.
The ultimate goal was to ascertain whether the transformations we
identified within the community were motivated by internal structures
and dynamics or by external pressures.
The field research came from a mix of observational methods
including mapping demographic patterns in the town, charting
types and locations of construction and development, and observing
Bedouin-Egyptian-Tourist interactions through what ethnographers
describe as participant observation as well as formal interviews (See
Figure 2). This raw data was then filtered through intense analytical
sessions between myself and my partner in which we discussed our
observations and used “thick descriptions” to analyze the events we
had witnessed and attach underlying meaning to them.37 While the
number of formal interviews we conducted were quite limited, with
no more than ten individuals being recorded, our method of informal
interviewing, based on the concept of “snowball sampling,” brought
us into contact with dozens of Bedouin holding many different
occupations and social positions. Additionally, we were able to
interview about ten migrant laborers, from Egypt and Sudan, who had
traveled to Sinai in search of employment. Snowball sampling, which
entails the assistance of current subjects to recruit future subjects,
while a non-random sampling process, has the benefit of allowing
us to construct a clear picture of the social networks that exist both
37. Clifford Geertz, “Thick Description, Towards an Interpretive Theory of
Culture,” in The Interpretation of Cultures (New York: Basic, 2000).
Introduction
42
within Dahab itself and how they connect to villages outside of the
town. This non-randomness was an important element in tracing
distribution networks that have emerged through tourism and inter-
familial as well as inter-generational relationships.
The reflections of the previous paragraph raise two major issues
that we confronted over the course of our fieldwork. The first is highly
complicated and had the potential to threaten our ability to collect
data. This has to do with our interview methodology. We quickly found
our attempts at formal interviewing frustrated by the Bedouin, who
appeared to react to our questioning with suspicion. It was important
to find a method of accessing this information while simultaneously
building trust with those we were interviewing. In order to accomplish
this, we were largely required to turn off the cameras and recording
devices and be less direct in our questioning.
We found that the greatest level of success came when we posed
our questions anecdotally and in a largely quid-pro-quo manner. By
this I mean we would exchange stories with our Bedouin interviewees
Figure 2: Conducting an interview on film.
Photo by author, September20, 2009.
Introduction
43
and compared their answers with experiences from our lives, or, more
commonly, attempted to lead the Bedouin to a certain issue by framing
it against the backdrop of our culture. For example, if we wanted to
discuss Bedouin marriage requirements, we might tell the Bedouin
about marriage practices in America, or tell a story of a particular
friend or family member’s marriage, and then ask about their own
experiences. We found that this worked quite well, and often it would
set the Bedouin off on long stories with valuable tangents that gave
us more information than a simple question and answer would have.
Furthermore, this allowed the Bedouin to volunteer information that
they felt was important to the topic, providing an opportunity to study
concepts from their perspective.
The second aspect of our research design was the issue of teamwork
in the field, which, from the anthropological literature guiding our
research, appeared to be quite rare. Nevertheless, working in a team
was invaluable. Not only did this kind of work allow one of us to fill in
gaps the other might have missed, it also encouraged discussion and
debate, fuelling analysis and the consideration of multiple points of
view. While we did not always agree on the meanings behind what
we saw, our differences of opinion more often than not added to
the quality of the material as we attempted to reconcile, convince,
or disprove each other’s concepts. Working as a team allowed us
to support one another, and gave each of us an advisor intimately
familiar with the research. We continually challenged each other’s
ideas, which forced us to carefully construct our theories and raise the
quality of our work. While in the end, each of us authored our own
papers and focused on different aspects of our experience, there is
no doubt that Eli’s ideas are reflected in my own work and mine are
reflected in his.
One final but immensely important issue to mention in a discussion
of fieldwork is the issue of potential bias. While we interacted with a
wide variety of people in Dahab, the focus of our research was the
Bedouin, and thus a large majority of our time was spent interacting
with Bedouin. There was a danger, I was warned, that my feelings for
my new-found friends would affect my ability to analyze the situation
objectively. This concern was voiced through my advisors, who
warned me that my sympathies might lead me to developa narrative
Introduction
44
that is overly critical of the Egyptian government or overly delicate in
regards to the Bedouin. In short, the objectivity of the researcher, and
by implication the integrity of the work, is called into question because
of an emotional connection or a tendency of the subjects to present a
biased view that is accepted and adopted by the researcher.38
In this way, ethnography more often than not is a double-edged
sword necessitating a delicate balancing of two very distinct identities
that may very well be impossible to separate: the first being the friend
and the second the researcher. Without the friend, the researcher’s
job would be impossible. At the same time, it is the friend that
endangers the objectivity of the researcher, who is supposed to be
dispassionate and analytical. Thus, to the researcher, the friend is both
indispensable and a liability, and in the field, not a moment went by
without consideration of the balance that we had to maintain between
them.
Unfortunately, there is no scientific method to counter this
tendency towards sympathizing with one’s subjects. In the words
of John Van Maanen, “Neutrality in fieldwork is an illusion.”39 In
this case, all scholars who conduct this type of work might be
susceptible to accusations of bias, whether personal or ideological;
it is the responsibility of the researcher to navigate this path with
as much attention to avoiding such traps as possible. From my own
experience, to ignore the friend is impossible and only calls attention
to the researcher, generally leading to concerns and suspicion among
the ethnographic “subject.” The Bedouin have little use for formal
data gathering methods such as surveys, and are generally less willing
38. This has been a perpetual concern to ethnographers, both inside and
outside of the field of anthropology. See, for example, Annette Lareau and
Jeffrey J. Shultz, Journeys through Ethnography: Realistic Accounts of
Fieldwork (Boulder: Westview Press, 1996).
39. John Van Maanen, “Playing Back the Tape,” in W.B. Shaffer and R.A.
Stebbins (eds.), Experiencing Fieldwork: An Inside View of Qualitative
Research (Thousand Oaks: Sage, 1991); quoted in Timothy Pachirat,
“The Political in Political Ethnography: Dispatches from the Kill Floor,”
in Edward Schatz (ed.), Political Ethnography: What Immersion
Contributes to the Study of Power (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 2009).
Introduction
45
to participate in these formal environments. The only alternative
is to always maintain self-awareness and to understand that this
emotional response is an inevitable consequence of the experience of
field research. This process, I imagine, is very personal, varying from
researcher to researcher, and it would be difficult, if not impossible, to
draw an accurate picture of the relationship between the researcher
and the subjects just by reading the work without any mention of
the personal experiences of the research. It is my goal to present as
transparent a picture of the research experience as possible, allowing
readers to understand my own ethnographic perspective.
The research we conducted in the field did not present a complete
picture of the historical development of the Bedouin community, only
their present situation. Thus, this type of data was insufficient to address
the types of historical questions that were vital to this study, including
how and why Egyptian development was undertaken, as well as how
this development has transformed the Bedouin socioeconomic order.
History was just as important to this analysis as anthropology, and so
constituted a second, yet equally important methodological approach.
Historical information about Sinai comes from two main sources:
first, the diaries and surveys produced by visitors and colonial officials
during the eighteenth, nineteenth, and early twentieth centuries, and
second, the accounts and analyses of historians and social scientists
who spent time researching in Sinai in the 1970s and 80s, as well
as a number of studies published by their Egyptian successors. Since
the Egyptian reoccupation of Sinai, however, the freedom to conduct
research has been limited and our record for the past 20 years is not
as detailed as it was in the 20 years before that.
Many of the early diaries and surveys of Sinai have already been
digested by historians and social scientists and consequently held little
value for this work, as subsequent analyses published in the 1970s,
80s, and 90s proved significantly more useful. These sources blurred
the lines between anthropology and history, as they were often
social histories or anthropological studies from previous decades
that provided the opportunity to construct a coherent timeline of
events and an encompassing picture of the Bedouin community and
its transformations across the previous decades. Reliance on history
enabled the analysis of the transformative processes that development
Introduction
46
in Sinai has instigated. This is an adaptation of a practice that is gaining
favor among anthropologists, increasingly utilizing historical texts; I
took this practice and reversed it by taking past anthropological studies
and using them as historical texts, providing sufficient information to
compare, for example, employment patterns of the Aqaba Bedouin in
the nineteenth century, the 1970s, and today. In this way, it became
possible to examine not only the shape of the Dahab Bedouins’
current socioeconomic order, but to trace its development over the
past decades to analyze the transformative effects of development.
47
Chapter 1
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
This chapter presents an analysis of the Egyptian development project
in Sinai in order to ascertain why Sinai development was undertaken
and how Egyptian authorities went about setting and attaining their
goals. Additionally, it will examine how a number of specific Egyptian
policies have shaped the direction of socioeconomic development
within the Bedouin community. With this perspective, Egyptian
priorities for development and the role envisioned for the Bedouin in
relation to the Egyptian vision for Sinai will become clear. In a study
of Bedouin reactions to development, an examination of Egyptian
approaches is the key to understanding Bedouin transformational
responses and identity processes.
The Egyptian development project in Sinai is merely a single
aspect of a larger plan for the development and integration of Egypt’s
vast, unsettled territory. In May 1974, faced with serious economic
stagnation and the beginnings of a population crisis, the government
of Egyptian President Anwar Sadat prepared a plan, known as “A New
Map of Egypt,” that aimed at extending Egyptian central authority to
territories far from the Nile Valley and developing them so as to make
them productive contributors to the Egyptian economy.40 As Sinai
at this time was still under Israeli control, the Egyptian development
plan focused on areas such as the Western Desert, the Mediterranean
coast, the Red Sea coast, and the Lake Nasser region. The project
had the broadly-stated goal of relieving social and economic pressures
on the population, and by implication, on the central government.41
40. Dames and Moore International, Sinai Development Study, Phase I:
Final Report (Washington, D.C.: United States Agency for International
Aid, 1985) Vol. 1, “A Strategy for the Settlement of Sinai,” 3.1 “National
Goals,” p. 47.
41. Lavie, The Poetics of Military Occupation, p. 75.
Chapter 1
48
The plan eventually adopted to oversee the development of
the Sinai Peninsula, as a piece of this greater strategy to increase
industrial and agricultural development in Egypt, was aimed at fulfilling
goals identified by the government to address central problems; the
primary concerns were not the wellbeing or interests of peripheral
populations, but those of the central state. One of the stated aims of
the Sinai Development Study (SDS-I), published in 1985 by Dames
and Moore, Inc. in conjunction with USAID, was to “ensure social
justice for the residents of these regions [under development],” to aid
in the reduction of “regional disparities.”42 However, this would only
be the case inasmuch as the goals and interests of these residents
aligned with those of the state. In fact, in the research and planning
stages of the project, the Bedouin were treated only superficially and
were never actually consulted on potential courses of development
or Bedouin-Egyptian cooperation. Central Egyptian planners viewed
the Bedouin as a marginal population that did not need to be directly
included in Sinai development, but would react to development by
assimilating into Egyptian society.
In their attempt to impose “legibility” on the Bedouin, the Egyptian
state made a number of incorrect assumptions about the fundamental
nature of Bedouin society and the natural consequences of economic
development.43 Egyptian development strategies ultimately resulted
in the socioeconomic marginalization of the Sinai Bedouin. These
assumptions, compounded with their “modernization”-oriented
approach, facilitated the emergence of a number of obstacles
frustrating Bedouin participation in budding tourism industries in the
Aqaba region. Many of these assumptions or miscalculations were
based on Egypt’s focus on the critical crises that the regime faced
in central Egypt, for example the need to maximize tax revenue,
provide jobs, and spread the population. In focusing on these goals,
the Egyptians neglected to consider a situation whereby specifically
Bedouin interests might clash with Egyptian development goals. Not
42. Dames and Moore, Sinai Development Study, Vol. 1, p. 48.
43. James C. Scott, Seeing like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve
the Human Condition Have Failed (New Haven: Yale University Press,
1998). Scott refers to legibility as the manner in which a state categorizes
and defines a concept so that the state may interact with it.
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
49
only did they not make an effort to ensure the Bedouin a dominant or
even a protected place in the developing tourist economy, they failed
even to undertake a comprehensive study of the Bedouin and their
standards of living in order to determine how best to harmonize their
plan with existing conditions on the ground; the Bedouins’ customary
socioeconomic order and recent transformations were not examined
or considered in the scope of development.
Egyptian National Crises and the Need for
Development and Integration
In the early 1970s, Egypt faced a number of social and economic
crises stemming from major demographic shifts, destructive economic
policies, and President Gamal Abd al-Nasser’s fixation on the conflict
with Israel. Egypt’s economy, which Nasser had based on the socialist
model of import-substitution and nationalization, was on the verge
of collapse. Compounding a lack of productivity, a rapid population
increase created a shortage of employment. While Nasser promised
jobs to all university graduates, stagnant economic growth and rampant
corruption meant that there were not nearly enough opportunities to
satisfy Egypt’s population.
Making matters worse, the urban centers of Egypt experienced
rapid population increases due to the dual processes of urbanization
and accelerating population growth. Cairo, which in 1960 had a
population of three and a half million,44 and in 1989 of 14 million,45
today has an estimated population of 20-25 million inhabitants.46 As
Cairo’s population expands, the conditions in the city have deteriorated
44. Janet Abu Lughod, “Migrant Adjustment to City Life: The Egyptian
Case,” The American Journal of Sociology 67 (1962), p. 22.
45. Thomas W. Lippman, Egypt After Nasser: Sadat, Peace, and the
Mirage of Prosperity (New York: Paragon House, 1989), p. 166.
46. André Raymond, Cairo, trans. Willard Wood (Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 2000), p. 13. In 2000 Raymond supports the lower
figure of 18 to 20 million. The higher estimate of 25 million comes from
a consideration of the potential contribution of the unofficial residents of
Cairo as well as the figure stated by everyone in Egypt.
Chapter 1
50
for its inhabitants. Overcrowding is now a fact of life and living
conditions for many have become less than sanitary. Additionally, the
huge population has put an incredible strain on Cairo’s aging urban
infrastructure, which is in severe need of renovation and replacement
and has barely been able to support a city of 20 million inhabitants.
Population growth and urbanization have had a devastating impact
on Egypt’s ability to maintain food self-sufficiency.47 Processes of
urbanization, concentrated heavily in the Nile Valley, have created a
situation whereby land suitable for agriculture is being converted into
residential zones to accommodate an increasing number of citizens.48
While Egypt’s population has grown rapidly in the Nile Valley, the
amount of cultivable land has not increased despite Nasser’s massive
land reclamation scheme, which aimed at converting unproductive
desert into cultivable land suitable for agriculture. As settlements
expand, they continuously encroach on the limited amount of arable
land. Egypt, once a major exporter of agricultural products, has
become dependent on massive food imports to supply the needs of
the population.49
When Anwar Sadat became president of Egypt in 1970,
overpopulation, under-employment, food shortages, and economic
stagnation were the major socioeconomic crises facing the Egyptian
state. In order to address these crises, the Egyptian government
enacted a number of policies aimed at bringing economic as well as
social relief to Egypt. Perhaps the most well-known of these policies
was Sadat’s program of Infitah, or “Open Door” economics, aimed
at attracting private and foreign investment, and bringing an end
47. While World Bank figures show that the rate of population growth
is slowing, it is still well above rates in Europe and North America.
Moreover, this has done little to relieve pressures on the state to continue
supplying sufficient food to urban populations. Source: Google Public
Data from World Bank, updated Jan 17, 2013. <https://www.google.
com/publicdata/explore?ds=d5bncppjof8f9_&met_y=sp_pop_grow&idi
m=country:EGY&dl=en&hl=en&q=population%20growth%20rate%20
egypt>.
48. Dina F. Ali, “Case Study of Development of the Peripheral Coastal
Area of South Sinai in Relation to its Bedouin Community” (MA Thesis,
Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, 1998), p. 13.
49. Lippman, Egypt After Nasser, p. 128.
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
51
to the state-dominated economic policies of Nasser.50 As a clear
rejection of the Nasserite economic model based on etatism, Sadat’s
freer-market Infitah was a highly visible concept. It was not, however,
the only plan developed to address Egypt’s ills. Another of Sadat’s
programs, geared simultaneously at relieving both the population and
food crises, was the “Green Revolution.” This “revolution” strove to
tame the Egyptian frontier, extract valuable natural resources, convert
deserts into farmland, and relieve the immense population pressures
in Egypt’s cities and along the Nile River.51
With this “Green Revolution,” Sadat envisioned a massive
population shift out of Egypt’s urban areas along the Nile into the
desert, namely the Western Desert around the oases of Siwa and
Bahariyya, the Eastern Desert along the Red Sea Coast, and later,
the Sinai Peninsula. It was the government’s hope that relieving
overcrowding would increase economic productivity, bringing added
relief to the economy in addition to alleviating urban congestion. It
additionally hoped to convert the desert into cultivable land, bringing
Egypt back to food self-sufficiency.
The goals of the Sinai Development Project, as outlined in the
development reports published in the 1980s and 90s, are consistent
with the crises mentioned above. As stated in the SDS-I study prepared
in 1985, the national goals were the following:
Social1.
Slower population growth in Cairo and the cities of the •
Delta
Reversal of Brain Drain, in part by creating well-paid, high •
tech, modern economic activities within Egypt
Economic2.
Expanded private sector•
Foreign aid reduced, later eliminated•
Strategic3.
Food self-sufficiency, improved yields and land reclamation •
50. P.J. Vatikiotis, The History of Modern Egypt, 4th ed. (London:
Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1991), p. 430; see also Raymond Hinnebusch,
“The Politics of Economic Reform in Egypt,” Third World Quarterly
14.1 (1993).
51. Lippman, Egypt After Nasser, p. 126.
Chapter 1
52
Integration of remote areas into the mainstream of Egyptian •
civilization.52
The final goal, the integration of remote areas into “Egyptian
civilization,” suggests an added aim of increasing state control over its
territory and simultaneously working for the socialization of peripheral
populations and regions to integrate them into the Egyptian nation.
These goals, far from striving to protect the unique characteristics
of Egypt’s peripheral populations, suggest that a major aim of the
Egyptian government is to transform the character of these territories
to reflect Egyptian national values and characteristics. This is a major
element in the process of nation-building. Economic development in
Sinai aimed both to increase Egyptian state presence and control in
Sinai and to socialize peripheral populations into Egypt’s national
society.
It is clear from even this superficial examination of the crises Egypt
faced and the goals the government set that regional integration and
development in Egypt was undertaken to serve the center instead
of the peripheries. Despite claims about the importance of regional
equality, Egyptian development was less about extending the amenities
and services available in central Egypt to the various peripheries as it
was about the development of these peripheries in order to solve the
problems of central Egypt.
From the “Green Revolution” to the
National Project for the Development of
Sinai — A Plan for 2017
Between 1979 and 1982, when Egypt re-gained Sinai after the Camp
David Accords and the Israeli-Egyptian peace treaty, the concept
of developing the deserts was extended to the Sinai Peninsula. The
values and goals of the Green Revolution were reproduced in the Sinai
Development Studies and played a primary role in shaping Egyptian
goals for Sinai. Soon after the Egyptian reoccupation, planning
for Sinai development began. The SDS-I Sinai Development Study
was commissioned by USAID in order to survey Sinai and present
52. Dames and Moore, Sinai Development Study, Vol. 1, p. 48.
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
53
its recommendations for the best development strategies. This plan
eventually yielded the Egyptian Ministry of Planning’s National Project
for the Development of Sinai (NPDS), which was adopted by Egyptian
authorities as the official strategy to develop Sinai between the years
1994 and 2017. These plans hoped to transform Sinai into a multi-
sector economy through large-scale foreign investment and the
settlement of over a million Egyptians in the peninsula.53
There is remarkable similarity between the two development
reports, and the NPDS can easily be considered a continuation of
the development strategies recommended in the 1985 SDS-I report.
The major difference between the two is in the scale of development.
The SDS-I had for its goal one million Egyptian settlers in Sinai while
the NPDS hoped to attract over three million,54 reflecting an ever-
increasing need to relieve Nile Valley population pressures by both
enticing urban Egyptians to seek better working conditions in Sinai
as well as convincing rural Egyptians to seek employment in Sinai
instead of in the urban centers of the Nile Valley.
The development reports identify tourism as a huge potential
market in Sinai, suggesting that Sinai could compete with international
tropical vacation destinations; the Aqaba Coast was recommended
as particularly suitable for international tourism development.55
They further suggest that basing tourism on large-scale private
and foreign investment could potentially fund other development
projects, highlighting the economic importance of tourism and tourist
development to the Egyptian authorities in their endeavor to create
industry and infrastructure in Sinai. The SDS-I study, and later the
NPDS, proposed to expand the Aqaba Coast’s tourist capacity by
attracting “major international beach tourist resorts along the Gulf of
Aqaba,” as this would be the most direct way to maximize both growth
and (taxable) profit.56 The plan foresaw continuous development along
53. David B. Ottaway, “Egypt Tries Hard to Lure Settlers to Sinai Region,”
The Washington Post, April 25, 1983.
54. David Homa, “Touristic Development in Sinai,” in Tourism in the Middle
East Continuity, Change, and Transformation, ed. Rami Farouk Daher
(Minneapolis: Channel View Publications, 2006), p. 239.
55. Dames and Moore, Sinai Development Study, Vol. 3, “An Economic
Development and Investment Plan, 1983 to 2000,” p. 80.
56. Ibid., p. 77.
Chapter 1
54
the Aqaba Coast and the eventual growth of Dahab’s population from
just over 2,000 to over 90,000 inhabitants between 1994 and 2017,
and the growth of Sharm el-Sheikh’s population from just over 2,000
to over 130,000 in the same time frame, almost all of whom would
be Egyptian families enticed to move from the Nile Valley.57
While an in-depth analysis of the two development plans is beyond
the scope of this study, there are two major aspects that must be
discussed in relation to how the Egyptian government chose to relate
to the Bedouin in their development scheme. The first is to what
extent the reports consider the needs and probable reactions of the
Bedouin; the second deals with the issue of the formalization of tourist
economies.
The Bedouin and Development
The SDS-I report purports to have conducted an in-depth study of
the population of Sinai, and volume six of the report deals exclusively
with Sinai’s social development. However, the study focuses
overwhelmingly on migrant social development and questions of how
to attract and maintain such a high number of Nile Valley migrants
in Sinai. There is little said in this report about the Bedouin outside
of population estimations, and even less is said about the proposed
integration of this population into development strategies beyond the
need to provide “opportunities for employment.” While the SDS-I
does not contain a sufficient treatment of Sinai’s Bedouin populations,
the NPDS contains even less.
The SDS-I report predicted that increasing service- and
construction-sector jobs would induce the Bedouin the shift away from
“traditional employment” which, according to their understanding,
was “livestock grazing,” and attract the Bedouin populations to settle
closer to the coasts.58 In this, the report identified and described the
57. “Distribution of the Existing and Target Population in South Sinai,”
Final Report on the National Project for the Development of Sinai,
translated in Ali, “Development of the Peripheral Coastal Area of South
Sinai,” p. 24.
58. Dames and Moore, Sinai Development Study, Vol. 6, “Settlement and
Social Development,” p. 17.
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
55
major transformation in Bedouin economics experienced during the
Israeli occupation, the shift of Bedouin populations to coastal centers
for purposes of employment. It failed, however, to recognize the fact
that this process had already begun and that by the 1980s, herding
and “livestock grazing” were not these Bedouins’ primary sources
of subsistence. The authors were unable to see the link between
increasing sedentarization and the growth of urban economies and
employment opportunities. They failed to recognize the effects of
development and increasing state control on the declining access
of the Bedouin to pastures and wells needed to maintain a pastoral
economy. There was no discussion of how jobs would be allocated
between the local Bedouin and unskilled migrants from the Nile Valley
seeking the same service and construction sector jobs mentioned
above. Finally, there was no provision or discussion regarding the
potential recognition of Bedouin claims according to their customary
laws, specifically regarding certain rights of access, for example to
valuable stretches of shoreline for fishing or tribal gatherings. Nor was
there any discussion as to the proposed legal status of the Bedouin or
their land claims, nor any discussion of compensation for developing
on Bedouin land or of providing housing and other services to the
community.
This is the extent to which the SDS-I treated the Bedouin.
Conspicuously absent are any recommendations regarding the
integration of Bedouin populations into the developing economies of
Sinai, or visions of how the Bedouin would function in close proximity
to these estimated one million migrants. Additionally, in the section
dealing with tourist development, the authors mention a number of
possible types of tourism, ranging from beach and resort tourism to
religious and cultural tourism. This discussion, however, makes no
mention of the possible role the Bedouin might play in this industry,
notably in the culture tourism sector. Culture tourism, according to the
SDS-I, would focus on incorporating Sinai into the existing “Cairo,
Luxor, Giza circuit,” integrating Sinai into Egyptian heritage instead
of focusing on its own unique culture.59
The goals for the NPDS focus even more heavily on the issues
facing central Egypt, and the previously mentioned desire to ensure
59. Dames and Moore, Sinai Development Study, Vol. 3, p. 82.
Chapter 1
56
social justice for peripheral populations is absent from this version.
Not once in the section outlining objectives for Sinai development
are the Bedouin even mentioned, and instead the report focuses
on its goal of “building new societies” to vary the lifestyles available
to Egyptians.60 Thus the role ascribed to the Bedouin by those
responsible for development has been peripheral at best.
The report does, on the other hand, set the goal of appropriating
over 90 percent of Bedouin land for development, allowing Bedouin
to retain a mere seven percent of the territory they once exploited.61
While the Bedouin had previously used this land for fishing, holding
tribal gatherings, and more recently, running tourist camps, Egyptian
authorities hoped to utilize this land for the development of large
multinational resorts that had the potential to yield large tourism
revenues for the central government.
Egyptian development authorities, in conjunction with USAID,
based this land appropriation goal on the assumption that Bedouin
do not value land the same way that the development agency would
due to their “nomadic lifestyle,” and believed this appropriation would
be accepted by the Bedouin. The report went even further, stating
that “the NPDS works for the urbanization of the tribal population
and at the same time [for] maintain[ing] their tribal cultures as it is
part of Sinai heritage.”62 How, then, did the Egyptians propose to
reconcile the confiscation of Bedouin territory for development with a
desire to preserve the cultural heritage of the Bedouin? Furthermore,
how did they expect to achieve the urbanization of the Bedouin
while neglecting to envision a formal role for them in the developing
tourism-based urban economy? Finally, assuming that there were
more migrants at any given time than available jobs, how would
employment be allocated between migrants and local Bedouin? These
are questions that Egyptian planners and developers, as well as their
American counterparts representing USAID, failed to address.63 The
60. David Homa, “Touristic Development in Sinai,” p. 241.
61. Ibid., p. 252.
62. Ibid., p. 241. Quote taken from Sinai report titled “Sinai: Location and
Natural Resources,” Government publication (1995).
63. While many defend organizations such as USAID for their good
intentions, Joel Migdal rightly points out that there is a huge disparity
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
57
fact that the Bedouin have intended to participate in the development
and future economies of Sinai, notably the tourist sector, has all but
ensured that the vision the central government created for Sinai would
be complicated by a clash between local Bedouin and central Egyptian
interests.
Tourist Development along the Aqaba
Coast — Egyptian Preferences
The Egyptian development strategy is best examined through a lens
of “modernization.” While as an academic theory, modernization has
been the subject of ongoing debate, and the mechanisms through
which the process supposedly operates produce questionable
outcomes, modernization continues to hold relevance for developing
states as a popular paradigm for third-world development.64 This is not
to argue that Egyptian authorities adopted an explicit “modernization”
approach to Sinai development, which would assume that a primary
goal was social development of the periphery instead of revenue
maximization. In fact, the state appears little concerned with the
Bedouin outside of the implications for maintaining a tight security
presence in the Peninsula. Instead, both written and anecdotal
evidence strongly supports the revenue maximization approach. The
positive externalities anticipated by the modernization paradigm, such
between declarations of intent by state leaders and the actual execution
of policy on the ground. Furthermore, good intentions and the desire
for macro-level transformation say nothing about their knowledge of
micro-level social and economic dynamics. Migdal, in 1988, argued that
scholars need to examine the impact of social policies from a bottom-up
perspective. Ten years later, Simon suggested that while “sustainability”
had become an ostensible goal of development agencies, the addition of
the label “sustainable” was accompanied by few policy changes and no
greater sensitivity to the micro-level impact of development. Today, while
progress has been made on the scholarly side, aid agencies have not
changed significantly. Migdal, Strong Societies, Weak States, pp. 260-1.
Simon, “Development Reconsidered.”
64. Simon, “Development Reconsidered,” p. 185.
Chapter 1
58
as social integration, economic rationalization, and increasing state
control of its territory, are often assumed to be associated with the
type of neo-liberal development policies in play in Sinai. The failure
of these policies to yield the assumed benefits warrants the same
type of criticism that has underpinned the modernization debate for
decades. Furthermore, it would be hard to deny that the promises of
“modernization,” notably rationalization of the economy and political
stabilization, are themselves attractive goals for state authorities,
and it is quite probable that both neo-liberal goals and sociopolitical
“modernization” arguments work together in this regard.
The course of tourism development in South Sinai was shaped by
the requirements that the Egyptian government needed this sector to
fulfill and reflect the basic assumptions stated above. As one of the
earliest established sectors of the developing Sinai economy, tourism
has become the primary economic activity along the Aqaba cost (as
opposed to industry, concentrated on the West coast, and agriculture,
concentrated in the North). The authorities have favored courses of
tourism development guaranteeing high returns for the government.
This has led them to place major emphasis on formalized tourism
development, focusing on large, multinational resort chains which
invest large sums into development, and from which high taxes and
fees can be extracted.65 In one extreme example, a recent report states
that one of the major casinos in Sharm el-Sheikh pays $24 million in
royalties to the government each year, in addition to its annual taxes.66
While the major resorts undoubtedly pay less, international companies
must maintain the proper permits to operate their businesses, and
these companies have no trouble paying the high fees. This focus
has maximized revenue for the state; however, it has ensured the
marginalization of local inhabitants by channeling revenue flows out of
the local economy and to national projects and foreign shareholders.
The formalization of tourism has made it harder for the Bedouin to
participate in and benefit from Aqaba tourism.
65. Homa, “Touristic Development in Sinai,” p. 252.
66. Adel Abdellah, “Even Tourists and Tourism Operators Say Yes to the
MB,” EgyptVotes.org, Jan. 4, 2012. <http://www.egyptvotes.org/en/
politics/item/400.html>.
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
59
Smaller hotels have been discouraged due to the perception that
these will not generate the same level of revenue and channel it back
into further development. In a similar fashion, tourism advertising has
focused on expensive resorts and vacation packages aimed at families
and wealthier tourists rather than at backpackers and young travelers.
The government has reasoned that focusing on wealthier tourists will
generate the most revenue per visitor.
This focus on development of formal tourism in Sinai has two
major implications for the Bedouin. The first has to do with revenue
leakage, a consequence of the preference for large, foreign-owned
hotel chains. While these chains build resorts that have the potential
to generate significant revenues, a majority of these profits flow out of
the locality where they are generated. For example, the Hilton, one of
the largest and most expensive resorts in Dahab, channels most of the
revenue it generates out of Sinai, into the accounts of the company and
its owners and as payments to the Egyptian government for permits
and as taxes, translating into high leakage out of the local economy.67
Formal tourism development, while favored by Egyptian authorities
for its potential to generate high returns, is actually an obstacle to the
Bedouins’ ability to access locally generated tourist revenue.
This is in direct contrast to smaller hotels and local operations,
which guarantee relatively low leakages as they are prone to be
owned, operated, and staffed by locals instead of foreign investors
and migrants. Small-scale tourism is therefore “capable of higher
integration into the local economic structure; it is capable of producing
a higher multiplier effect on the local economy than the formal
tourism sector,” whereas the formal sector relies heavily on foreign
or external elements.68 For the Bedouin, smaller hotels and locally-run
tour companies would ensure a significant amount of revenue would
remain in the community, allowing the Bedouin to realize more profit
from economic activities within their territory. However, Egyptian
preferences to work with foreign tourism agencies and international
hotel chains make it harder for the Bedouin to access their share of
the profits being collected. Additionally, the regulations have made it
67. Daher, “Reconceptualizing Tourism in the Middle East,” p. 22.
68. Ibid., p. 24; see also Martin Opperman, “Tourism Space in Developing
Countries,” Annals of Tourism Research 20 (1953).
Chapter 1
60
significantly harder for the Bedouin to build and own their own hotels,
which the Egyptians have attempted to replace with larger chains,
using the justification that the Bedouin do not meet the safety and
quality standards of the large resorts, and that Egyptian regulations
are for the safety and benefit of its tourists.69
The second implication for the Bedouin is their marginalization
from the tourist spaces in general. As one of Egypt’s main national
goals has been the creation of jobs for Nile Valley Egyptians, migrants
from those areas, not the Bedouin, are considered to have first
priority when it comes to access to employment. Additionally, the
Bedouin are considered to be less reliable because they do not have
the professional levels of education favored by the modernization
paradigm; many businesses avoid hiring Bedouin altogether, due to
conceptions of the Bedouin as stupid, lazy, or something more sinister
(see chapter four). For the Aqaba Bedouin, this limits their ability to
engage the formal tourist sectors in any manner more substantial than
as menial employees in the large resort hotels, leaving them searching
for ways to protect their livelihood by ensuring the continuation of
informal economies.70 Primary ways in which they establish informal
economic connections are through hiring out jeeps and pickup
trucks to carry travelers between locations, by organizing Bedouin
cultural events such as camel treks and oasis visits independently of
the resorts, and through the operation of illicit economies such as
drug dealing or smuggling. All of these issues, and how the Bedouin
cope with them, will be discussed in greater depth in the following
chapters. It is important, in any event, to highlight that the nature of
Egyptian development policies have had profound effects on courses
of socioeconomic transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin by
creating obstacles to Bedouin participation in Aqaba tourism.
69. Ben Beasley-Murray, “The Tourism Development Agency uses
environmental rhetoric to justify demolishing Bedouin-owned camps in
favor of big hotels,” Cairo Times, September 30, 1999.
70. Heba Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin Community: The Case of the
Town of Dahab in South Sinai,” Nomadic Peoples 4.2 (2000), p. 32.
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
61
Dahab and Development
Dahab has been affected by formalization to a significantly lesser
extent than the other major Sinai tourist center, Sharm el-Sheikh,
which is dominated by international resorts. This only serves to
increase Dahab’s significance as a center of Bedouin life, as their
access to economic opportunities in Dahab is freer than in Aqaba’s
other tourist centers. This has to do with the origins of tourism in
Dahab, which was pioneered by the Bedouin themselves, as opposed
to state-directed tourism in the resort city of Sharm el-Sheikh.
During the Israeli occupation in the 1960s and 70s, Dahab became
a popular coastal location for Israeli travelers and backpackers. The
Aqaba Bedouin quickly seized upon this concept and began building
campgrounds for the backpackers to stay. As recently as the mid-
1990s, Dahab continued to be dominated by Bedouin-owned
campgrounds.71 As Dahab’s popularity increased among these
low-budget travelers, the number of campsites increased, soon to
be complimented by restaurants, and later, hotels, dive shops, and
surf clubs, increasingly owned by Egyptian businessmen and some
foreigners. Dahab, over the past 20 years, has transformed from
a backpacker destination into a major center for water sports such
as scuba, sailing, and surfing, but it continues to be defined by its
laid-back, Bedouin/backpacker character, reflecting the informal or
grassroots origins of Dahab tourism.
Large-scale development in Dahab did not truly begin until the
mid-1990s, more than a decade after the Egyptian reoccupation. At
this point, Egyptian authorities began focusing development in Dahab
on formal tourism, and a number of large multinational resorts have
sprung up by the beach, including a Hilton, a Le Meridien, and a Sofitel,
in addition to others. However, the smaller-scale tourist establishments
have remained a permanent fixture in Dahab proper, as they were
well established by the time the Egyptian development project began.72
These cater to middle- and lower-budget travelers, such as young
backpackers, and involve the Bedouin to a much greater extent than
resorts such as the Hilton. This has allowed the Bedouin a significant
71. Conversation with a Dahab business owner, February 12, 2010.
72. Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin Community,” p. 32.
Chapter 1
62
role in the economy of Dahab by encouraging the establishment of
informal economic ties directly with tourists, cutting out the state or
its foreign representatives, with limited success.73
Recently, however, state-supported resort tourism development
has begun to expand, and discriminatory Egyptian policies have led
to land appropriation and even the demolition of Bedouin-owned
businesses.74 The number of remaining Bedouin camps has begun to
decline as land is being purchased or claimed for three- and four-star
hotels. With its large Bedouin presence and ever-increasing Egyptian
attempts to force the town to conform to Egyptian ideals, Dahab has
become a primary arena for competition between the Aqaba Bedouin,
attempting to preserve their livelihood, and Egyptian authorities,
attempting to utilize Sinai’s resources to pursue national goals.
The Emergent Reality of Dahab
Development
While development in Sinai has been largely successful, and tourism
along the Aqaba Coast has boomed in the past two decades, one aspect
of the NPDS has been a resounding failure. While initially, Egyptian
authorities were optimistic that Egyptian families could be enticed out
of the cities to settle in Sinai, this rarely occurred; the Egyptians failed
to devise a strategy to settle Sinai with Nile Valley migrant families
and create a new Egyptian society in the peninsula. Very few families
agreed to move to Sinai (most are the families of the few doctors,
teachers, and businessmen working in Sinai, but not of those involved
73. Laleh Behbehanian, “Policing the Illicit Peripheries of Egypt’s Tourism
Industry,” Middle East Report 216 (2000), p. 33.
74. Personal observations from multiple trips to Dahab, combined with
repeated statements from the Bedouin asserting that the discriminatory
treatment of the Bedouin regarding land and economics is getting worse.
See also Beasley-Murray, “The Tourism Development Agency uses
environmental rhetoric to justify demolishing Bedouin-owned camps in
favor of big hotels.”
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
63
in tourism or other menial labor).75 This has rendered Dahab, similarly
to other tourism towns along the Aqaba Coast, unviable as an Egyptian
community or an Egyptian society as envisioned by early Egyptian
and American planners. Instead, a majority of Egyptian migrants in
Sinai are young, unmarried men traveling in search of work so that
they can make the money necessary to start a family according to
Egyptian social custom.76 A secondary source of Egyptian migrants is
the pool of married, but underemployed, Egyptian males who pursue
migratory labor in Sinai. Egyptian development plans have, to a large
extent, already compensated for this by adjusting their population
goals down and altering the course of development in Sinai’s towns
from residential construction for families to residential construction for
male workers, resulting in dormitory-style living in the town centers.
Egyptian migrants have decided to relate to Sinai employment
in a similar manner to other forms of Egyptian migrant labor, as a
means of making money to send back to support the family at home
in the form of remittances. Egyptian migrants in Sinai interviewed
for this study had stories of migratory remittances, and admitted
that their only interest in living in Sinai was to make money to send
home to support their families, who remain either in rural villages or
in the cities of central Egypt. Sinai, specifically through tourism, has
become a source of foreign capital for Egyptians. In this way, Sinai
is emerging as an alternative to migratory employment in Gulf oil
industries or education, which, since the 1960s, has been the primary
means to bring foreign capital into Egypt.77 The major difference is
that in Sinai, Nile Valley migrants are favored by authorities, while
those seeking employment in Gulf states are often denied civil rights
and are subject to many other restrictions on their movement and
employment. Egyptian migrants in Sinai say that working there is
preferable to traveling to the Gulf because it is significantly closer
75. Conversations and home visits with Egyptian migrant laborers in Dahab,
March 2009–February 2010.
76. Personal observations of Dahab’s demographic structure, multiple trips to
Dahab, March 2009–February 2010.
77. Nazih N. Ayubi, The State and Public Policies in Egypt Since Sadat,
Political Studies of the Middle East Series (Reading, U.K.; Ithaca Press,
1991).
Chapter 1
64
to home and migrants in Sinai are subjected to less discriminatory
treatment from Egyptian authorities. For these reasons, there is
an increasing desire for Egyptians to seek migratory labor in Sinai
than abroad.78 This trend is a clear result of the relative benefits of
Egyptians seeking employment within their own borders.
Many Egyptians come to Sinai from the cities and the villages
of the Delta and Upper Egypt in search of work, and follow their
acquaintances and kin. Jobs are most frequently allocated along kinship
lines or among friends. A majority of laborers interviewed in Dahab
acknowledged that their job came from an opportunity given to them
by an older brother or cousin, who acts as a host to new migrants.
Thus patterns of development and employment in Sinai suggest that
to central Egyptians, Sinai is not a place to settle and raise a family,
but to make money to support the rest of the family at home. This
concept of remittances will appear occasionally throughout this work,
showing the types of employment and settlement patterns resulting
from Sinai development.
Development in Sinai has been closely controlled by the Egyptian
state in order to reflect the goals of the Egyptian state as opposed to
the interests and developmental concerns of any periphery. In this,
attempts to increase state presence and instruments of control in the
Egyptian periphery are clearly visible. Egyptian security forces exercise
tight control over the main transportation routes across and around
Sinai, able to regulate or restrict the movement of all but the Bedouin.
Furthermore, Egyptian utilities and services have given the Egyptian
government the role of primary caretaker and distributor of goods
78. None of the Egyptian laborers in Sinai interviewed for this study
challenged this statement; they all declared their preference to remain in
Egypt to pursue work, and many stated that Sinai was their only viable
option, as there were no jobs in the cities of central Egypt. A majority of
migrants from urban Egypt indicated that their desire to move to Sinai
was to seek better paying jobs and escape the crowded conditions of the
city. When asked about the possibility of seeking employment outside of
Egypt, not a single respondent declared a preference to give up their
Sinai jobs for foreign employment. It is clear from their responses that
there is a certain feeling of entitlement among Sinai laborers, that they
feel more comfortable there than in a foreign country.
Egypt’s Vision for Sinai
65
and services in Sinai’s growing towns. Elements increasing Egyptian
control in urban spaces include utilities such as water and electricity,
which have been made widely available, as well as services, notably
health, security, and education, all of which, however, suffer from
under investment, resulting in poor quality public goods. Through
development, Egypt has been able to extend these services to the
towns of South Sinai, increasing the reliance of Sinai’s residents
on Egyptian goods and services. This dependence has developed
unevenly, however, and the Bedouin have, to differing extents, been
able to avoid relying on the outcomes of Egyptian development. As
a trend, the Bedouin living in desert villages enjoy relatively greater
independence than those in the towns. The following chapters
examine a number of consequences of increasing Egyptian control
and increasing reliance on Egyptian goods and services.
While the Egyptian authorities have invested a great deal of time
and effort into determining how best to utilize the available resources
to maximize the benefit to the central state, they did not adequately
prepare themselves to deal with an Egyptian population that was not
ready to commit to national life in Sinai or a Bedouin population that
would attempt to participate in the Egyptian project according to their
own interests. Egyptian goals have clashed with the interests of the
Bedouin and their vision for the future.
Figure 3: Ongoing construction in Dahab.
Photo taken by author, February 10, 2010.
Chapter 1
66
Figure 4: The Dahab Corniche. Photo taken by author,
February 20, 2009.
67
Chapter 2
The Evolving Economies of
the Dahab Bedouin —
Emerging Trends and
Continuities
The development of urban centers along the Aqaba Coast is a new
phenomenon for the Bedouin. Whereas historically, these Bedouin
had to travel long distances to access towns and their markets and
practiced subsistence economics within their tribal territory, Israeli
and Egyptian development has led to the emergence of local towns
with their own markets. This has had a noticeable impact on Bedouin
economic practices by encouraging the Bedouin to participate in the
opportunities these towns generate, producing a perceptible shift
towards greater reliance on the market economy and a simultaneous
decline in the productivity of their subsistence economies. Far from
leading to a rejection of pastoral economies in favor of those in the
towns (a shift from “traditional” to “modern” economies), the Bedouin
have adapted their economic practices to the changing situation by
increasing their presence in tourist centers and altering their lifestyles
to help them access new sources of income while attempting to
preserve the security their subsistence economies provide. These two
economies do not operate independently of one another; rather, each
system is shaped by the limitations of the other, and elements of one
may be applicable in the other. The Aqaba Bedouins’ contemporary
subsistence economy can only be understood in relation to the
prevailing conditions of the expanding market economy.79 A stylized
ideal-type model would view these economies as mutually dependent
79. Emanuel Marx, “Changing Employment Patterns of Bedouin in South
Sinai,” in Emanuel Marx and Avshalom Shmueli (eds.), The Changing
Bedouin (New Brunswick: Transaction Books, 1984), p. 185.
Chapter 2
68
but separate; however, it would be more useful to understand Bedouin
economic practices as existing on a continuum of “market” on one
extreme and “subsistence” on the other. In practice, all Bedouin
economics fall somewhere in between the two poles, and Bedouin
economic practices simultaneously rely on and benefit from the rules
of both.
The Bedouin have never subsisted from a single-sector economy,
despite popular images that they focus solely on pastoralism. While
a major focus on Bedouin economic practices deals with nomadic
pastoralism, the husbandry of camels, goats, and sheep, the Bedouin
could not possibly subsist off of animal products alone, and the sparse
resources of the Sinai desert render pastoralism unfeasible as a single-
sector economy.80 They have instead engaged in a practice described
by Philip Salzman as “multi-resource nomadism,” which includes not
only animal husbandry, but also some combination of agriculture,
trade, smuggling and raiding, as well as wage labor.81 While Salzman
discusses this phenomenon regarding Baluch nomads, his ideas have
been applied, almost wholesale, to the Arab Bedouin. Of Salzman’s
notion of “multi-resource nomadism,” Emanuel Marx states, “All
Bedouin, except a small number of highly-specialized camel-breeding
groups, engage in a ‘multi-resource economy,’ combining pastoralism
with a variety of other occupations.”82 Similarly, as various studies of
Sinai Bedouin economic practices have revealed, these Bedouin have
80. Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin Community,” p. 33; cf. Emanuel Marx,
“Economic Change among Pastoral Nomads in the Middle East,” in
Emanuel Marx and Avshalom Shmueli (eds.), The Changing Bedouin,
ed. (New Brunswick: Transaction Books, 1984).
81. Philip C. Salzman, “Multi-Resource Nomadism in Iranian Baluchistan,” in
William Irons (ed.), Perspectives on Nomadism (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1972).
Salzman specifically refers to “multi-resource Nomadism,” however
subsequent studies of the Bedouin, notably by Marx, have qualified this
concept by demonstrating that these Bedouin need not maintain nomadic
lifestyles to continue pastoral or multi-resource modes of living. Thus when
considering this ‘multi-resource’ economy of the Bedouin, we should not
assume that it is only applicable to groups that remain nomads.
82. Ann Gardner and Emanuel Marx, “Employment and Unemployment
Among Bedouin,” Nomadic Peoples 4.2 (2000), p. 22.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
69
never maintained an autarkic economy, and interaction with centers
of trade and labor has always played a role in their subsistence.83
Reliance on towns and markets, while variable to some extent, has
been a fixture of Bedouin economic practice.
In this way, the economy of the Aqaba Bedouin is varied, and
different aspects of their economy have occasionally assumed more
or less importance due to the sociopolitical circumstances they have
faced. It is not a case where “traditional” aspects of the economy
are in permanent decline, and even with the presence of the town
and its markets, “traditional” or subsistence-based economic practices
continue to hold economic importance for the Bedouin, especially as
a source of economic security.
The major transformation of the Aqaba Bedouin over the past
40 years has undoubtedly been a result of the proliferation of wage-
labor employment in the towns along the coast. While income from
this type of labor has become the primary source of income for the
Bedouin, they have not abandoned other economic practices. Non-
income generating economic practices, such as the preservation of
flocks and orchards, have either been adapted to take advantages of
new economic opportunities or stem from perceptions of political or
ecological instability, not cultural factors demanding the maintenance
of “traditional practices.” While some of these practices have been
preserved, their relative importance to the subsistence of the Bedouin
has changed. Cash-income labor is now the mainstay of the Aqaba
Bedouin economy.
83. See various studies on Bedouin economies, notably in South Sinai: e.g.,
Dan Rabinowitz, “Themes in the Economies of the Bedouin of South
Sinai in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries, “International Journal
of Middle East Studies 17.2 (1985); Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin
Community”; Marx, “Changing Employment Patterns of Bedouin in
South Sinai.” See also Marx, “Economic Change Among Pastoral
Nomads in the Middle East” for a more general discussion of the Bedouin
and “multi-resource” economies.
Chapter 2
70
Wage Labor and Employment
among the Mzeina
Wage labor is not a new practice among the Aqaba Bedouin. In fact,
they have known migrant employment since the mid-1800s, when
it played a supplemental role to Bedouin subsistence. Since then,
wage labor has transformed from a source of supplemental income
into a primary source of Bedouin livelihood; it has risen and declined
in cycles reflecting periods of political instability in Sinai, when
employment tends to become insecure and subsistence economies
allow the Bedouin to weather the turbulence. Wage labor is actually
complimentary to the Bedouin economy, and furthermore, is not
a radical new innovation but an increasingly important source of
income.
Before wage labor, the Bedouin of South Sinai relied on a number
of practices to supplement their subsistence economy. While the
Bedouin did operate a pastoral economy, in reality, most of their
food was imported from markets like Cairo and Gaza and had to be
purchased.84 Before the accession to power of Muhammad ‘Ali in
the early 19th century, the Sinai Bedouin, like many other Bedouin
tribes, derived this income from raiding, the extortion of khuwa or
protection money from towns, and the transportation and protection
of people and goods across their tribal territories.85 The income from
these practices would be used to purchase the agricultural products
that the Bedouin relied on but could not produce themselves including
cereals, grain, tea, and sugar, as well as other necessities such as
clothing and weapons. In the 1810s, however, Muhammad ‘Ali began
to pacify the Bedouin in the Egyptian deserts and Sinai.86 Despite
vigorous attempts to resist ‘Ali’s advances, the Tawara Bedouins’ free
reign in the towns of Egypt and their ability to raid caravans traveling
through Sinai was substantially curbed.
84. Emanuel Marx, “Oases in South Sinai,” Human Ecology 27.2 (1999).
85. Rabinowitz, “Themes in the Economies of the Bedouin of South Sinai,”
p. 219.
86. See Gabriel Baer, “Some Aspects of Bedouin Sedentarization in 19th
Century Egypt,” Die Welt des Islams 5.1/2 (1957).
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
71
Due to the limitations of a pastoral economy, particularly when
relying on territory that is underproductive and undependable, the
supplementation of animal husbandry with some kind of income-
earning practice is necessary.87 Various studies (e.g., Salzman, Marx,
Sweet88) have shown that pastoral nomads must supplement their
animal-based economy. In the past, additional income was largely
derived from raiding and trading; however, the profitability of these
practices has declined as states have used their military might to pacify
the tribes and increase security along trade routes. In response, some
tribesmen began selling their labor to Egyptian industry, including the
manganese mines at Umm Bogmah and the petroleum fields of Abu
Rudeis on the west coast of Sinai. More substantially, young men
began traveling to Egyptian cities such as Suez and Cairo in search
of employment as migrant laborers.89 Although this work was largely
supplemental, many Aqaba Bedouin did engage in wage labor at some
point in their lives starting from the mid-19th century.
Until the Israeli occupation of the Sinai in 1967, wage labor
functioned as a supplement to the subsistence economy of the
Aqaba Bedouin. A number of factors encouraged a shift towards
greater reliance on a cash economy after the Israeli occupation. First,
increasing Israeli security and policing, as well as the imposition of
an international border at the Suez Canal, brought activities such as
smuggling—an offshoot of raiding that developed independently of
wage labor—to a halt. The Israeli preference to employ the Bedouin
in Sinai development increased both the number and proximity of
jobs, allowing the Bedouin to seek employment significantly closer
to home. The Aqaba Bedouin began working in infrastructure and
construction within Sinai, operating motor vehicles, and participating
87. Salzman, “Multi-Resource Nomadism in Iranian Baluchistan,” p. 66.
88. Louise E. Sweet, “Camel Raiding of the North Arabian Bedouin: A
Mechanism of Ecological Adaptation,” in Louise E. Sweet (ed.), Peoples
and Cultures of the Middle East, vol. 1 (New York: The Natural History
Press, 1970). This study demonstrates that the most specialized Bedouin
groups, the Arabian camel-rearing Bedouin, are equally dependent on
markets to accrue their food supplies.
89. Marx, “Changing Employment Patterns of the Bedouin of South Sinai,”
p. 178.
Chapter 2
72
in the budding tourist economy, from setting up camps and coffee
shops to guiding desert safaris to selling drugs to young backpackers.90
After the 1973 War, the Israeli authorities increased their
employment of the Bedouin by giving them free access to towns and
cities in Israel, and the Bedouin began pouring into Eilat and Be’er
Sheva in addition to Sharm el-Sheikh; in the mid-1970s, almost all
working-age Bedouin males were employed in a wage-paying job.91
This had two major consequences. First, the economic opportunities
available to the Bedouin both increased and diversified, resulting in
a decline in the relative significance of pastoralism to the Bedouin
as it comprised a smaller and smaller share of Bedouin economics.
This additionally shifted the foundations of the Aqaba Bedouin
economy from multi-resource nomadism to wage labor, fully realized
in the 1970s. Despite this shift, the animal producing economy of
the Bedouin has been maintained, and at times has even been in
resurgence. Increasing reliance on employment opportunities closer to
home is also leading to a decline in nomadic movement and increased
sedentarization. This has to do both with increasingly secure access to
water and fodder for flocks as well as increasing reliance on the towns
for livelihood instead of the natural environment.
Employment trends among the Bedouin in
Dahab under Egyptian Rule
A consistent and continuing trend under Egyptian rule has been
the increasing localization of employment. While before the 1960s,
employment was limited to Egyptian cities, and during the Israeli
occupation was extended to the large urban centers of Sharm el-
Sheikh, Eilat, and Be’er Sheva, during the neo-Egyptian period, from
1982 onward, there has been accelerating growth of employment
centers even more locally, with the emergence of market towns in
Taba, Nuwayba, and Dahab. The number of jobs is increasing, as is
their proximity to the homes of the Aqaba Bedouin.
90. Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin Community,” p. 34.
91. Marx, “Changing Employment Patterns of the Bedouin of South Sinai,”
p. 181.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
73
Tourism continues to be the primary source of income for the
Aqaba Bedouin under Egyptian rule, but the market has undergone
a significant change in transition from Israeli control back to Egyptian
sovereignty. While the Bedouin did not have to compete with Israelis
for jobs, as the Bedouin monopolized the unskilled labor pool and the
tourism industry, under Egyptian rule, competition for employment
between the Bedouin and unskilled migrant laborers has been intense.
These unskilled workers have come to Sinai from both Egypt and the
Sudan to take advantage of the jobs that Egyptian development has
promised them.
In Dahab, patterns of employment in the tourist industry have
experienced a major transformation. In the years of the Israeli
occupation, tourism in Dahab was largely run by the Bedouin
themselves. They set up campsites and restaurants and employed
other tribesmen. Non-Bedouin businesses during this period had
to purchase land directly from the Bedouin. Even after Dahab was
reoccupied by Egypt, development remained slow in the 1980s and
early 1990s, giving the Bedouin a large degree of freedom. This early
period of low-budget tourism development cemented for the Bedouin a
place in the Dahab economy. At the turn of the millennium, however,
the Egyptian government placed higher priority on economic growth
in Dahab, and began implementing large-scale tourism development
along the beaches according to the goals outlined in the NPDS.92 This
gave the Egyptian government the primary responsibility of regulating
Dahab’s tourist economy and deprived the Bedouin of a great deal
of their economic freedom, increasingly forcing them to rely on the
goodwill of the state to maintain Bedouin employment and ownership
opportunities.
Consumerism is a relatively new concept for the Bedouin, but a
major issue when examining social attitudes towards employment. In
a pastoral economy, there are a number of ways to display wealth,
notably through practices of granting hospitality, as the ability to host
others is a sure sign of prosperity, as well as through the production
of luxury items instead of subsistence items, for example raising
92. Interview with owner of a dive shop in Dahab, video archives, May 14,
2009.
Chapter 2
74
horses in Arabia.93 The Western conception of consumption, based
on the concept of saving money to accrue luxury items, appears to
have been imported into Sinai only through the arrival of Israeli and
European tourists, who introduced the Bedouin to consumer goods.94
The availability of these items close to home, coinciding with the rise
of local markets, has been the major factor encouraging the adoption
of consumer lifestyles, which has, in turn, encouraged more and more
Bedouin to pursue wage-paying jobs with the goal of accumulating
capital. This process, however, is incomplete and is supplemented by
a common trend of gift-giving, whereby the Bedouin accrue consumer
items through the relationships they have formed with foreigners. In
this way, the maintenance of close relationships with foreigners is as
important to patterns of Bedouin consumerism as employment, and
wage labor is not the only path to consumerist lifestyles. Furthermore,
these consumer goods are not always kept by the Bedouin; they are
occasionally sold for cash, and should be considered a form of savings
or investment that can be converted into currency when necessary. In
this way, the turn towards a consumerist economic orientation is also
a product of the rising cost of living.
For the Bedouin, employment does not differ significantly from
other forms of subsistence: it is a means to provide basic necessities
such as food, shelter, and security, and secondarily for purposes of
consumption. An implication of this approach is that Bedouin attitudes
towards employment differ from those in Western, industrialized
nations: maintaining oneself in a job to ensure a continuous flow
of income is unnecessary, and perhaps even wasteful, taking away
from other activities that contribute equally to the subsistence of
the family or the maintenance of relationships with foreigners. The
Bedouin work to earn the money they require to purchase items the
family needs, mostly food, clothing, and locally available consumer
goods. Bedouin concepts of saving place a higher value on preserving
and storing necessities for times of emergency than on cash, which
has no real utility except in the short term. While the adoption of
93. William C. Young, “The Bedouin: Discursive Identity or Sociological
Category? A Case Study from Jordan,” Journal of Mediterranean
Studies 9.2 (1999). p. 289.
94. Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin Community,” p. 34.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
75
consumerist tendencies is accelerating and wage labor is increasingly
viewed through a lens of consumerism, many of the Aqaba Bedouin
continue to view employment as one of a number of practices geared
towards subsistence.
This being the case, many Bedouin seek temporary employment
in Dahab. This means that a Bedouin will work for a limited period of
time, perhaps one to two weeks, make some money, and then take
an equal or longer period off. A Bedouin working as a waiter at one of
the restaurants on the Dahab corniche explained that he only worked
when he needed the money, whether it was to provide food for the
family or buy a new bathing suit, and that he might work a week or
two to make what he needed and then stop until he needed more.95
This tendency, not uncommon today among the Dahab Bedouin,
has encouraged a view of the Bedouin as lazy and unreliable, leading
to accusations that the Bedouin despise work and prefer poverty.96
Such attitudes, however, reflect the values of a capitalist society that
favors steady employment, the accumulation of capital, and saving,
which are necessary to drive a consumerism-based society; they do
not accurately reflect the values of the Bedouin. A pastoral economy
simply cannot be maintained by sloth, and claims that it is are entirely
divorced from the reality of life in the desert.
Another Bedouin described his employment history as one of
low duration and high mobility. He changed jobs according to where
the tourists were concentrated and when. His first job, as a Bedouin
tour guide, was only successful during the cool winter months, so he
would limit his time working as a guide, and in the summer he worked
as a waiter at his brother’s beachside restaurant before becoming a
Divemaster.97 He explained that he maintained both a summer and
a winter job, not because he needed the constant flow of money for
himself, but so that he would be able to send continuous money home
to his mother and sisters who live in a desert village. Dahab is a source
95. Conversation with a Bedouin employee, September 22, 2009.
96. Proof of the existence of these attitudes needs no citation as it is recounted
in almost every traveler’s journal and official recollection regarding the
Bedouin. These attitudes continue to be held by many Egyptian migrants
working in Dahab. This topic will be addressed in greater detail in chapter
4 of this study.
97. Interview with a Bedouin Divemaster, July 24, 2009.
Chapter 2
76
of remittances for the Bedouin as much as it is for Egyptian migrant
workers. All of the Bedouin living in Dahab have family in Sinai’s
desert villages, and their sedentarization has created permanent
channels for the flow of tourist revenue to the Bedouin not living in
Dahab or other urban centers. Many more Bedouin rely on tourist
revenue than live in Dahab.
Furthermore, these Bedouin have grown accustomed to labor
insecurity, because in addition to political instability having the
potential to undermine their access to employment, they also know
that they can be dismissed by their employers without any notice. This
being the case, the Bedouin value the ability to work in a number
of different occupations and quickly change from one occupation to
another. This allows them to pursue a wide variety of job opportunities
whenever they might be available in order to mitigate the insecurity
of the job market or the potential fickleness of Egyptian employers.
While providing a measure of flexibility for the Bedouin, this practice
has also limited their vertical mobility in the tourist economy because
it has created a lack of specialization among Bedouin workers. This
lack of specialization is caused by reluctance to make risky, expensive
investments in a single skill. This, according to Dan Rabinowitz, “in
turn, limits the Bedouins’ incorporation into the wider economics
on which they are dependent. They tend to perpetuate themselves
as pools of unskilled laborers, available for hire by the economies of
Egypt… at any time.”98 This allows the Bedouin to pursue a wide
range of jobs, but prevents them from progressing beyond the level
of menial employment and generates negative perceptions regarding
their work ethic.
The major exception to the above discussion has been the
increasing employment of young Bedouin, in their early twenties, in
the windsurfing clubs attached to the multinational resorts along the
Dahab Lagoon, as well as in a few scuba shops that employ Bedouin
as Divemasters in addition to drivers and gear carriers.99 Many of
these Bedouin began windsurfing and diving as a hobby during their
98. Rabinowitz, “Themes in the Economies of the Bedouin of South Sinai,”
p. 225.
99. Divemaster being a high-skilled job and drivers and gear carriers being
low-skilled.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
77
teenage years, and have become natural candidates for employment
in these sectors of the tourist economy. More will be said in the next
chapter about the willingness of some foreign employers to work with
the Bedouin, but for now it is important to note that these Bedouin,
who have turned their hobbies into steady careers, represent a small
minority of Bedouin employees in Dahab.
Bedouin employment, for the most part, is limited to the peripheries
of the Dahab tourist economy. Since Egyptians prefer to hire other
Egyptians, there is little Bedouin presence at the larger resorts or the
Egyptian-owned hotels, with a few exceptions. Instead, the Bedouin
occupy jobs that can be considered self-employment such as driving a
jeep or selling handicrafts, working for other Bedouin, or working as
menial laborers in shops and restaurants. These occupations allow the
Bedouin more freedom, both to pursue a wide variety of jobs and to
decide when to work and when not to. While wage labor has become
the primary source of income for the Bedouin, its insecure nature and
reliance on a single sector of the developed economy, tourism, has
led the Aqaba Bedouin to maintain other economic practices as well.
The Maintenance and Adaptation of
Subsistence Economies
The maintenance of Bedouin subsistence economies in the urban
environment, as shown by the previous generation of Sinai researchers,
is a type of economic insurance against political and economic
instability. The Bedouin have experienced this instability in the past
and know that these periods often lead to increased unemployment
or shocks to the tourist market. In times like these, the Bedouin fall
back on their subsistence economy and the social patterns comprising
it.100 These structures help prevent food shortages, deprivation, and
starvation among the Bedouin in times of crisis or instability. The
strength and vitality of the subsistence economy is directly dependent
on the state of the market economy.
A number of events that occurred in the Sinai over the past
century have reinforced the need for the Bedouin to maintain these
100. Marx, “Oases in South Sinai,” p. 343.
Chapter 2
78
modes of subsistence. Most notable were the wars fought in Egypt
and the Sinai: World War I and the Arab-Israeli wars of 1948, 1956,
June 1967, and October 1973, a number of which, most notably
the October War, froze the economies of the Sinai and led to full
unemployment. More recently, the waves of unrest and terrorism
that struck the Aqaba Coast in the early 2000s in Dahab, Taba, and
Sharm el-Sheikh, discussed in the preface, as well as in the aftermath
of the national uprising in January 2011 that I detail in the epilogue,
brought an immediate halt to the flow of tourists, leading to a spike
in unemployment in a depressed tourist economy.101 Through these
events, which had devastating economic consequences in South Sinai,
the Bedouin have learned that they cannot rely on governments to
provide and maintain stable economies and that in times of crisis, the
Bedouin must be able to rely on themselves. Additionally, they have
discovered the fragile nature of international tourism and the danger
of having to rely on a single sector for a majority of their income.
By maintaining a subsistence economy in times of prosperity and
activating it in times of need, the Bedouin have largely avoided major
food and financial crises.
Perhaps more importantly, while this alternate economy has often
been viewed as economically unproductive, especially compared
to the wage labor opportunities available in the towns, it has great
contemporary relevance to the Bedouin as they integrate into Dahab’s
tourist market.102 Despite this lack of productivity, these practices have
not been abandoned, nor have the tribal social structures that support
them. Largely based on pastoralism and agriculture and grounded in
tribal social structures, the subsistence system is often viewed as the
remnant of the Bedouins’ “traditional” modes of living. However, they
have been largely adapted to fit the developing reality in Sinai and
are more reflective of contemporary conditions, such as the political
101. I had the opportunity to visit Dahab in July 2011, four months after
the end of the January Revolution; tourism had only slightly begun to
recover. Despite the absence of instability in the Aqaba region itself,
the protests led to a virtual disappearance of tourists from all of Egypt
immediately following the uprisings.
102. Marx, “Changing Employment Patterns of Bedouin in South Sinai,”
p. 173.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
79
situation and the availability of market opportunities, than of conditions
of the past. Many economic practices have been maintained, such as
herding, fishing, and smuggling, but the form that they have taken is
significantly different today, as old practices have been adapted to fit
new circumstances born from processes of urbanization and tourism
development. In fact, a number of these “traditional” practices have
only recently become quite lucrative and have given the Bedouin a
competitive edge in the market economy.
Herding
Perhaps most central to the study of the Bedouin is the role of herding
and pastoralism. One of the most popular images of the Bedouin is
as herders of goats and camels, and it has even been suggested that
herding is the major criterion defining the Bedouin. For the Aqaba
Bedouin, however, pastoralism has always been a limited-value
practice.103
In the subsistence territory, flocks are taken to pasture by the
young girls and camps would move in order to ensure the flocks would
get sufficient food and water.104 Today among the Aqaba Bedouin,
the picture is significantly different. The label “nomadic pastoralism”
suggests that camps move in order to ensure the provision of food
and water to their flocks, the source of the nomad’s livelihood. In the
subsistence territory, technological development, notably pumps and
generators, have largely mitigated the need for nomadic movement.
In Dahab, this necessity is further mitigated by the overabundance
of organic waste left around Bedouin neighborhoods. Instead of
having to bring the flocks out to pasture, they are let loose in the
streets of ‘Asala to graze on the heaps of trash available to them (see
Figure 5). As water is also readily available from government-sunk
wells and urban plumbing, the Bedouin do not need to move their
103. Emanuel Marx, “Tribal Pilgrimages to Saints’ Tombs in South Sinai,” in
Ernest Gellner (ed.), Islamic Dilemmas: Reformers, Nationalists, and
Industrialization: The Southern Shore of the Mediterranean (New
York: Mouton, 1985), p. 113.
104. Gardner, “At Home in South Sinai,” p. 53.
Chapter 2
80
flocks in pursuit of water and pasture. Urbanization and technological
development have negated the need for nomadic movement.
While many Bedouin families living in Dahab own goats and sheep,
very few own enough animals from which to subsist. The Aqaba
Bedouin seem to agree that 50 to 60 goats are needed for subsistence.105
In the 1980s, Ann Gardner estimated the average flock size to number
fewer than 20 goats, with a large herd consisting of 40.106 Flock sizes
began to further decline in the 1970s as increasing opportunities for
employment rendered herding less financially attractive.107 Today, the
average size of goat flocks is somewhere between six and ten animals,
and their function has not changed. These herds are not for subsistence
purposes; it would be very hard to maintain larger, subsistence flocks
due to the sparse vegetation available for grazing, which needs to be
supplemented by expensive food purchases. Furthermore, the urban
dietary staples of these flocks, consisting mostly of garbage and poor
quality fodder, have undermined the quality of the products derived
105. Marx, “Tribal Pilgrimages to Saints’ Tombs in South Sinai,” p. 113.
106. Gardner, “At Home in South Sinai,” p. 52.
107. Rabinowitz, “Themes in the Economies of the Bedouin of South Sinai,”
p. 223.
Figure 5: Urban herds.
Photo by Eli Sperling, May 15, 2009.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
81
from them. The quality of the meat has suffered significantly and the
Bedouin have claimed that the milk from urban goats is essentially
useless unless the goats are maintained inside and fed with purchased
grains or vegetables, which quickly become financially prohibitive. In a
day-to-day context, these flocks are at best unproductive and at worst
a drain on Bedouin resources. Instead of considering these flocks as
the economic mainstay for the Bedouin, they should be seen as a
nucleus for reactivating the pastoral economy in times of crisis and as
tools for the maintenance of tribal solidarities. Outside of these two
situations, these animals are rarely consumed; their use is primarily
geared towards modes of tribal maintenance, such as slaughtering for
tribal feasts or celebrations aimed at strengthening kinship ties.
According to historical research done by Dan Rabinowitz, this
attitude towards pastoralism is not new, but appears to have been the
modus operandi for the Aqaba Bedouin even in the 19th century.108
Thus, pastoralism has not been the primary mode of subsistence for
the urbanized Aqaba Bedouin, merely a source of food security in
times of crisis. Clearly, herding was never the sole occupation of the
Bedouin.
Fishing
The Mzeina have fished the waters of Aqaba for as long as they
have lived next to the Gulf, and they have used their catch for both
subsistence and trade. Today, fishing remains a valued economic
pursuit among the Mzeina, who continue to supplement their diets
with dried fish, but who also have found new markets in which to
sell their catches. Fishing can be considered a traditional economic
activity that they have both maintained and adapted to new sources of
demand in the developing market-based economy.
Fishing was (and remains) a popular summer activity for the Mzeina,
who in the past organized expeditions to spend a number of weeks
fishing from temporary villages by the sea and then would preserve
their catch by salting the fish to last many months.109 The benefits
108. Ibid.
109. Lavie, The Poetics of Military Occupation, pp. 20–21.
Chapter 2
82
of this practice were twofold. First, the fish caught in the summer
could be stored by the Bedouin for long periods of time, and could
comprise a significant portion of their diet if necessary, even into the
winter. Second, the preservation of the fish allowed the Bedouin to
bring them to distant markets such as Cairo. In such a market these
Bedouin products were rare, and the Bedouin were able to trade
relatively small amounts of fish for the grains and other agricultural
products they needed. In this way, the Bedouin did not have to rely
solely on the products they derived from their flocks.
For the Aqaba Bedouin who live in the desert villages, drying and
preserving fish continues to be an important source of subsistence.
Fishing as an economic activity has been preserved by the Bedouin
and continues to function for subsistence purposes. Simultaneously,
tourism development in Dahab brought a fundamental transformation
in the potential role of fishing for the Bedouin. Along the Dahab
corniche, dozens of restaurants specializing in seafood have opened
and created strong local demand for fresh fish. Bedouin in Dahab and
Figure 6: Dried, preserved fish.
Photo by author, September 23, 2009.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
83
other tourist centers no longer preserve the fish for transport and
trade in faraway markets, quite often requiring many days of travel
and hardship, and have instead turned to the local market. Tourism
has created market demand for a number of Bedouin products. The
successful operation of these practices in local contexts has allowed
the Bedouin to cut their reliance on transitory trade and integrate
themselves more fully into local economies using their subsistence
skills.
At the end of a successful fishing trip, the Bedouin can sell their
catch in the Bedouin fish market in ‘Asala.110 While a majority of the
fish consumed in Dahab does not come from the Gulf of Aqaba, a
number of restaurants have begun buying their fish from the Bedouin
market, for it is both cheaper and fresher than the fish imported from
Suez. Furthermore, while much of the fish consumed in Dahab is
frozen and shipped in from Suez, every restaurant in Dahab claims the
fish is freshly caught locally. Tourists seek fresh, local produce, and if
it were not for the manipulation of information by the restaurants, it
is clear that those restaurants selling local, Bedouin-caught fish would
be favored over those restaurants who import frozen fish from outside
the region due to the perceived difference in quality.
Additionally, the Egyptian government has declared commercial
fishing in the Gulf of Aqaba illegal, both on an industrial scale, but
also for the Bedouin, essentially rendering a main income-earning
activity of the Bedouin criminal and simultaneously ensuring a role
in Sinai tourism for commercial Egyptian food suppliers. Despite
this restriction, the practice of selling Aqaba fish to local restaurants
continues and it appears as if the state has decided to look the
other way as a number of seaside restaurants continue purchasing
their stocks from the Bedouin. Despite the legal ramifications of this
relationship, market forces, notably regarding price and quality, have
induced these businesses and some Bedouin fishermen to assume any
legal risk. Furthermore, with the state’s lack of regulation of Bedouin
fishing practices, the current system of enforcement actually allows
the Bedouin to monopolize fishing in the Gulf of Aqaba. The success
of Bedouin fishing activities in the Dahab market suggests the large
scale financial success that some previously-subsistence practices
110. Interview conducted September 18, 2009.
Chapter 2
84
could have for the Aqaba Bedouin in the developing tourist economy
under prevailing market conditions.
Smuggling and Narcotics
The narcotics trade in South Sinai is both a new phenomenon and a
continuation of a traditional practice. Smuggling was an occupation
adopted after the armies of Muhammad ‘Ali suppressed raiding.
Similar to raiding, successful smuggling activities require extensive
knowledge of the geography of the desert and an ability to move
where government forces cannot. As the ability to raid caravans
and towns declined as a result of greater state control over main
transportation routes, the Bedouin of South Sinai turned increasingly
to smuggling, which focused on transporting goods across territories
inaccessible to government forces, especially after the criminalization
of hashish in Egypt led to a price spike in 1862.111 This practice took
off in the 1930s, and by the Israeli occupation it was a major source
of income for the Aqaba Bedouin, perhaps as much as 30 percent.112
In the period before Israeli rule, the major products being smuggled
were hashish and opium; the Bedouin would convey the drugs from
their points of arrival into the Nile Valley, which has historically been
a major center for the sale and consumption of these two drugs.113
Today, a number of developments have transformed the smuggling
trade in South Sinai.114 Tourism in Sinai has once again provided local
outlets for the distribution and sale of these drugs. Whereas in the
past, most of the drugs transiting through Sinai would exit, now local
111. Emanuel Marx, “Hashish Smuggling by Bedouin in South Sinai,” in Dina
Siegel and Hans Nelen (eds.), Organized Crime Culture, Markets and
Policies (Studies of Organized Crime) (New York: Springer, 2007),
p. 31.
112. Ibid., p. 29.
113. For a history of opium in Egypt, see Joseph Hobbs, “Troubling Fields:
The Opium Poppy in Egypt,” Geographical Review 88.1 (1998), p.
68.
114. I do not detail issues of human and weapons trafficking and international
smuggling practiced by Northern tribes here.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
85
demand has shifted the flow of drugs into tourist centers, especially
in Dahab and to the smaller Bedouin-run tourist camps along the
Aqaba Coast such as those in Ras al-Shatayn and Bir Sweir, located
between Taba and Nuwayba.115 These locations have received the
infamous label as centers of narco-tourism, and Dahab has often
been compared to other vacation destinations known for drug use
such as Goa and Phuket.116 Paralleling this has been a rise in Bedouin
consumption and the beginnings of drug cultivation inside Sinai,
which began in the 1980s when Lebanese cultivators, fleeing the civil
war, relocated to Sinai and began teaching the Bedouin cultivation
techniques. No longer just a corridor for the transit of drugs between
major cities, Sinai has become an outlet for the sale of these drugs,
and more recently, the desert has become a haven for cultivation;
many smugglers have made the transition to producers.117 This was
made possible by the rise in local demand stemming from budget-
and backpacker-tourism on the Aqaba Coast and the illicit reputation
circulated in the media and travel guides, which might be considered
“The Lonely Planet effect.”118
The sale of hashish, marijuana, and opium in Dahab is well
established and quite lucrative for the Bedouin. These drugs are not
just sold to tourists, however, and migrant workers as well as other
Bedouin have become equal consumers, maintaining constant levels
of demand. The Bedouin control every stage of local production and
distribution, and just like the smuggling activities from the past, the
current market employs many Bedouin at a number of stages. These
115. The more universal name for Ras el-Shatayn is Ras el-Shaytan (Head
of the Devil), which is an Israeli corruption that stuck. I have preserved
the name conveyed to me by the Bedouin. Ras el-Shatayn is so named
because it is the location of two beaches that meet in a peak, “Shatayn”
being Arabic for “two beaches.”
116. Behbehanian, “Policing the Illicit Peripheries of Egypt’s Tourism
Industry,” p. 33.
117. Hobbs, “Troubling Fields: The Opium Poppy in Egypt,” p. 69.
118. Which is to say that when all the tour guides include a note to travelers
that these places are known as centers of drug consumption, then it is
only natural that the ones convinced to go will be the ones hoping to
participate.
Chapter 2
86
activities can be grouped in two separate categories: the hashish trade,
which continues to rely on previously-established smuggling networks
since hashish is not produced locally but smuggled into Sinai from
places such as Morocco, and the cultivation of marijuana (see figure
7), locally referred to as treina, and opium.
Regarding the networks of production and distribution, at the top
there are the cultivators, who hide their fields in the mountainous
desert to avoid detection, as well as smugglers, who bring the hashish
in from Mediterranean ports such as Port Said and transport them
across the peninsula. In both cases, they sell bulk units to local
Bedouin suppliers who convey them into the towns, avoiding Egyptian
checkpoints and other methods of state control, to supply the local
Bedouin dealers. Egyptian migrants do occasionally attempt to enter
the trade; however, the Bedouin cultivators and distributors refuse
to include the Egyptians due to a lack of trust. Besides attempts by
Egyptian migrants to sell fake or marked-up hashish to tourists, the
Figure 7: Cannibis farm in South Sinai.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
87
Bedouin monopolize the drug trade in South Sinai.119 This is another
example of Bedouin labor specialization, where their subsistence skill
set, tribal social structure, and geographical knowledge make them
the only ones able to successfully operate the drug trade in Sinai.
It would be complicated to argue that drug cultivation and smuggling
are part of the Bedouins’ subsistence economy due to the reliance on
the tourism market and the rules of demand and supply. In the past,
the Bedouin received the drugs from international sources and merely
conveyed them across their territories; in return they would get cash.
Thus, smuggling was not based on subsistence but supplement as well
as contact with settled society, just as raiding and trading had been
in the past. The infrastructure supporting this network, however, is
very much part of the Bedouins’ subsistence economy; smuggling and
cultivation are supported and maintained by the same structures that
help maintain the pastoral economy. The movement (but not the sale)
of drugs is based on the same rules as pasturing flocks: all Bedouin
have equal access to territories of other tribesmen.120 Bedouin oases
and gardens, sources of Bedouin agriculture, are also meticulously
maintained as safe havens for smugglers as they move across the
Sinai. Finally, and most importantly, smuggling and cultivation are
supported and reinforced by the kinship bonds that comprise tribal
structure. Tribal social gatherings support smuggling and distribution
activities by maintaining networks and helping to establish new social
ties. The social patterns at the heart of the Bedouin subsistence
economy also regulate Bedouin smuggling. In this way, smuggling is a
practice relying on both market and subsistence economies. Demand
and distribution are based on the rules of the market economy, while
production and supply are made possible by the structures supporting
the subsistence economy. Drug cultivation and distribution, a non-
traditional activity, has been incorporated into the subsistence structure
of the Bedouin. Furthermore, as Dahab lies in the territory of the
Mzeina Bedouin, they enjoy the exclusive right to distribute narcotics
in the town. Similarly, the Jabaliyya Bedouin monopolize the drug
market in the Santa Katerina region, which includes Mt. Sinai, while
the Terabin control the market north of Nuwayba, in the beachside
119. Interview with a Dahab hashish dealer, May 14, 2009.
120. Marx, “Hashish Smuggling by Bedouin in South Sinai,” p. 31.
Chapter 2
88
campgrounds of Bir Sweir and Ras al-Shatayn. This further reflects
the importance of tribal structures and boundaries in the operation of
the drug trade in South Sinai.
In contrast to fishing, a traditional activity adapted to the market
environment, smuggling and drug cultivation are external practices
adopted by the Bedouin and incorporated into their subsistence
system, further showing a lack of distinction between “traditional” and
“modern” economic practices. Instead, Bedouin economies should be
viewed as being grounded in two simultaneous systems, one based on
subsistence and one based on market forces. The subsistence economy
is regulated by tribal social structures and patterns. These support
structures have allowed the Bedouin to establish economic networks
to monopolize certain aspects of the developing market economy.
Furthermore, this economy forms the basis for food security in case
the more lucrative market economy is disrupted by factors outside
their control. These two systems are not maintained independently
but overlap in certain areas, even to the extent that a single practice,
such as smuggling, may rely simultaneously on both systems to ensure
its smooth operation. The Bedouin have not abandoned old economic
practices for new, but instead have adapted their old practices to new
conditions and taken advantage of emerging opportunities.
The Role of the Camel to the Sinai
Bedouin: “Traditionalization” of Past
Practices
In practically every state with a Bedouin population, tourism advertising
agencies play heavily on the image of the Bedouin and his camel,
and popular representations envision an intensely close relationship
between the two. This is the case in Egypt, Jordan, the Gulf states,
and even Israel. It is true that the raising and reliance on camels was
a major aspect of Bedouin economies in Arabia. Khazanov explains,
however, that the species composition of nomads’ herds is based more
on geographic and environmental conditions than any social fixation
on a particular animal. He explains that the camel is ideally suited to
the deserts of Arabia and the Sahara, which is the reason the camel
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
89
and the Bedouin are associated as strongly as they are.121 Bedouin are
not limited to these territories, however, and also inhabit the deserts of
Sinai, the Israeli Negev, Syria, and Iraq. In a number of these settings,
notably Sinai, parts of the Israeli Negev, and the Iraqi cultivable zone,
Saharan conditions favoring camel-breeding do not apply, especially
in the rugged and mountainous terrain of Sinai, which is a desert but
one of radically different topography. In the mountains, sheep and
goats are better suited than camels, which are adapted to range across
great, flat expanses.
This fact has not prevented the image of the Bedouin and the
camel from being applied to the Aqaba Bedouin according to
perpetuated stereotypes, and through this mechanism the camel has
actually come to play a more important economic role for the Aqaba
Bedouin in the age of tourism. Many tourists come to Sinai expecting
to see camels and hope for an opportunity to ride them. While a
number of Bedouin in Dahab own camels, the number of camels
located a significant distance from Dahab remains lower, because the
value of the camel is directly related to its proximity to tourist centers,
notably Dahab, Sharm el-Sheikh, and Santa Katarina. Whereas in the
past, the camel was of limited economic value to the Sinai Bedouin,
who did not generate their income directly from the camel but used it
to facilitate other activities, it has today become an important source
of tourism revenue, not for any specific utility it provides, but for its
symbolism.
In the past, families generally only owned one or two camels,
for use as beasts of burden and transportation, facilitating travel and
transport between home and distant markets or for the conveyance
of travelers and goods across tribal territories.122 While these camels
were, to a limited extent, kept for subsistence purposes, animal
products such as milk and wool more often came from goats and
sheep than camels. This is in stark contrast to the way camels have
been utilized in Arabia, described by Louise Sweet:
121. Anatoly M. Khazanov, Nomads and the Outside World (Madison:
University of Wisconsin, 1994), p. 26.
122. Gardener, “At Home in South Sinai,” p. 53.
Chapter 2
90
As a resource of food, wool, leather, and other products, and
as a means of freight and personal transport, the camel, in one
species, provides all these for the Bedouin on a scale that no
other domestic animal or combination of animals in this area
can rival. As highly specialized a desert animal as the camel
is, it is a multipurpose and generalized beast in the Bedouin
economy. It is a primary source of nutrients for the Bedouin,
both directly and indirectly…123
Furthermore, with the advent of motorized transportation, the
camel’s utility as a beast of burden has largely come to an end, with
the exception of certain routes through the mountains that are too
rugged for jeeps and pick-ups. Today, despite this decline in the utility
of the camel to the Aqaba Bedouin for subsistence and transportation
purposes, a number of Bedouin near tourist centers have begun
keeping camels in larger herds for tourist use. In the tourist market,
the method of acquiring camels is completely different from that of
camel-breeding Bedouin; they are purchased, not bred and raised,
which requires years of investment, and thus the camel is not a part
of the Bedouins’ pastoral economy, with the exception of a few select
desert villages who have begun breeding camels.124
Instead, a number of families in ‘Asala keep a small number of
camels, generally only one or two due largely to the expense of their
upkeep, which points to an economic continuity with past practices.
The Bedouin “rent” these camels for the day to other Bedouin who
are active in camel tourism, thus generating cash directly from the
camel without consuming it.125 In this way, there is an economic
discontinuity with past practices. This camel tourism may be
formal, with the existence of agreements to work with specific tour
123. Sweet, “Camel Raiding of the North Arabian Bedouin,” p. 274.
124. Interview conducted at Wadi Ginea with Bedouin camel guide,
September 18, 2009. Observation and discussion with camel breeding
Bedouin, June 10, 2012—these villages benefit from ideal topographical
conditions that support camel breeding. For a discussion of camel
breeding versus purchase, see Sweet, “Camel Raiding of North Arabian
Bedouin,” p. 274.
125. A Demographic survey of ‘Asala, conducted on February 12, 2010.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
91
companies, or informal, with the Bedouin offering to work directly
with the tourists.
Bedouin engaged in informal camel tourism gather their rented
camels in the morning and congregate with these herds near popular
beaches and dive sites around Dahab. These sites are visited daily by
many tourists, often brought on excursions organized by resort hotels
and “safari” operators as well as dive shops; when they are dropped
at the site, Bedouin vendors are there waiting to offer their services.
During my travels, I observed that as the distance from tourist
centers increased, the number of camels kept by tribesmen appeared
to decrease, and furthermore, camels were not kept in herds as they
were closer to Dahab. This is because, outside of tourism, the camel
has greatly declined in value for the Aqaba Bedouin. Their role as
a pack animal was indispensable in the past, but today, the camel
has largely been replaced by jeeps and pickup trucks, which not only
convey people and goods, but also have the ability to carry goats
and sheep. Cars require less maintenance than camels, and across
the Middle East, trucks are replacing camels as primary means of
transportation. Trucks and paved roads have rendered the camel
obsolete in this sense. They have thus been relegated to the realm of
tourism as a Bedouin “tradition.”
In one respect, the significance of the camel has diminished. In
another, with the emergence of tourism, the camel has achieved a
newfound significance and an economic viability that the environment
of Sinai had previously prevented the camel from attaining. For
these Bedouin, the economic function of the camel has undergone
a process of “traditionalization” to reflect a link to these Bedouins’
idealized past. It is this “traditionalization” that has transformed the
camel into a cultural artifact, which gives the camel significance to
tourists in pursuit of Bedouin culture and gives the camel a new type
of economic value.
It would be reductionist to attribute the link between Bedouin
and camels to cultural proclivities, especially considering that camels
are not considered luxury goods to the Bedouin; they are not raised
and maintained, at considerable expense, as mere pets. Instead it is
important to examine the economic utility provided by camels, which
varies according to geographical region. From an examination of
where and how camels are kept in the Aqaba region, it is clear that
Chapter 2
92
the camel does not play a significant role in the contemporary, non-
tourist economy of the Bedouin. As a source of subsistence, they
have always come second to goats and sheep in Sinai, and as beasts
of burden, they have been replaced by newer forms of technology,
notably motorized transportation, which is both more practical and
more comfortable than transport by camel. This reality, however, has
not in any way impacted the stereotype of the Bedouin and the camel,
and it is precisely through this stereotype that the camel has found an
entirely new type of economic utility for the Aqaba Bedouin.
Externally held understandings of Bedouin culture, in this case made
significant through the dialectics of tourism, have the power to affect
the way in which the Bedouin communicate their culture to outsiders.
It is clear from even this short examination of the camel’s role to
the Aqaba Bedouin that they continue to be relevant to the Bedouin
due to the revenues tourism brings to the community. However, due
to the need to legitimize tourist activities as “authentic,” the Bedouin
have had to manipulate the symbolism of the camel to keep it relevant
in a tourist setting. In an article published in the quasi-official Egyptian
newspaper al-Ahram entitled “Of Camels and Bedouin,” Samir Sobi
appears to reflect the wholesale acceptance of this manipulation
of the symbol of the camel, even suggesting that “the camel is an
inseparable part of any family unit.”126 This claim is certainly untrue
and borderline absurd, especially considering that many of the Aqaba
Bedouin do not even possess camels. Furthermore, it is unclear
how any society would approach the concept of eating or otherwise
consuming “indispensable” members of the family. In any case, the
wholesale acceptance of the manipulated symbol demonstrates the
effectiveness of the “traditionalization” of such a commodity. It further
shows what kind of role culture plays in the economics of tourism,
and how activities seen as “traditional” play an important role in the
contemporary economy of the Aqaba Bedouin.
126. Samir Sobi, “Of Camels and Bedouin,” Al-Ahram Weekly, English
Edition, Issue No. 1055, July 7–13, 2011.<http://weekly.ahram.org.
eg/2011/1055/special.htm>.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
93
Case Study: Friendship Bracelets and the
Adoption of New Economic Roles
Walking along the corniche in Dahab, one phenomenon impossible
to miss is the droves of Bedouin children, usually girls, selling weaved
bracelets to tourists who are shopping or eating. This is a prime
example of the adoption of new roles by various members of the
family, and bracelet-weaving has become a popular activity among
young Bedouin girls only since their presence on the corniche
became a permanent feature of Dahab. While historical evidence and
observations from the Aqaba Bedouins’ subsistence territory has shown
that herding and caring for the flocks were the primary economic roles
of these girls, increasing sedentarization and contact with strangers
has limited these girls’ ability to travel with their animals.127 This had
the twofold consequence of limiting the usefulness of pastoralism and
necessitating the adoption of a new role for the girls. The weaving
and selling of friendship bracelets was the replacement. However, the
adoption of this practice is motivated not merely by economic factors,
but by social necessities as well.
Bracelet weaving as an economic activity has established a
flow of revenue independent of the men of the family, the primary
income generators. It provides the girls with a bit of money to be self-
reliant, which, in turn, has increased its value among the girls, and
consequently among Bedouin boys as well. A number of our Bedouin
interviewees, both male and female, know the skill, having picked it
up during their childhood on the corniche. While past subsistence
roles of boys and girls have been different, in the tourist economy,
both have gravitated towards the bracelets.128 However, boys seem to
affirm Western perceptions of bracelet weaving as a feminine activity,
and this has limited the extent to which they have engaged in bracelet
weaving and selling. Instead, the boys appear more interested in
engaging in drug dealing.
The sale of bracelets to tourists does not hold merely an economic
benefit, but plays a vital social role in the growth of the Bedouin into
127. Gardener, “At Home in South Sinai,” p. 55.
128. Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin Community,” p. 39.
Chapter 2
94
adults. Bedouin interviewed in this study tended not to hold formal
education in very high esteem; many seemed to believe that the
time they spent on the corniche was more important. This is the
forum through which the Bedouin learn English and business skills,
where they learn how to interact with tourists to prepare for a life
surrounded by the tourism industry and establish personal contacts
with restaurants, vendors, and authority figures (such as police) that
will allow them to be successful later in life.129 Thus, bracelet weaving
is also a type of investment in skills that will be vital for the future
livelihood of young Bedouin.
A number of Bedouin youths, both boys and girls, have told us that
their English ability comes exclusively from growing up in the streets
of Dahab, and that it is a more important skill than anything learned
in school.130 In this regard, these activities may eventually assume
greater importance for the boys than the girls as it is the boys who
are expected to maintain their presence in town through adulthood.
129. Interview with young Bedouin adults, conducted on video, February 15,
2010.
130. Interview with Bedouin female youths, May 13, 2009.
Figure 8: Bedouin girls selling bracelets.
Photo by Eli Sperling, February 9, 2010.
The Evolving Economies of the Dahab Bedouin—Emerging Trends and Continuities
95
But for Bedouin women in Dahab, bracelets allow daughters to act
as messengers and interlocuters for the mothers, who as adults are
confined closer to home in an urban setting, indicating this activity
plays a second, equally important social function for the Bedouin.131
Young girls have the freedom to move between male and female
spaces, and Bedouin mothers have taken advantage of their children
to mitigate the limitations that maintaining modesty in a tourist center
has required.
The adoption of bracelet weaving is thus a further adaptation
of the Bedouin to urbanization and tourism development; it did not
develop in a vacuum. The Bedouin have used it both to participate
in the economics of the town and to mitigate the social restrictions
of urbanization to maintain the flow of information and contacts
between households, as well as aid in the socialization of Bedouin
children into the environment of the developing market. It is both
an income-earning activity and an educational investment in the skills
they will need to be successful in Dahab’s tourist economy.
Concluding Remarks
It is clear from an examination of a variety of Bedouin economic
practices that the Aqaba Bedouin maintain a broad economy
comprised of multiple sectors. Today, wage labor is the primary source
of income for the Bedouin community, and along the Aqaba Coast a
heavy majority of this is concentrated in the tourism sector. Due to the
instability of tourism experienced by the Aqaba Bedouin over the past
twenty years, coupled with a much longer history of war and conflict
in Sinai, they have realized that they must maintain economic systems
independent of tourism that they can operate in times of crisis.
The Bedouin are not permanently shifting away from subsistence
economics in favor of wage labor, but continue to balance the two,
challenging the unilinearity of economic modernization assumptions.
From an examination of the subsistence economy, it becomes clear
that this is not an outdated system in permanent decline, but a survival
mechanism to cope with a sparse environment and an unstable
131. Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin Community,” p. 37.
Chapter 2
96
political situation, as well as a source of economic utility in the tourism
market. In this way, the two economies are complimentary, with their
primary wage economy focusing on supplying the main needs of the
community, allowing for a certain leakage of “pastoral economics”
into the tourist market, and the other being a backup to cope with
external crises that cut them off from the first, either in times of war
or due to other external factors, such as government policies, which
are out of the Bedouins’ control.
The Aqaba Bedouin are not rejecting development to maintain
“traditional nomadism,” which, in any case, was never the Bedouin
condition, but neither are they embracing developing economies at
the expense of their previously-accepted economic system. Instead,
the Bedouin have consistently relied on a balanced approach based
on adaptation, where old practices are adjusted to new opportunities,
and the adoption of new practices, which are incorporated into the
Bedouins’ economic order. As Rabinowitz has shown, the Bedouin
have consistently sought to balance income-earning practices with
subsistence, and Bedouin subsistence has been a core of Bedouin
economic practice only inasmuch as it has historically constituted
their last line of defense against economic insecurity. Furthermore,
the concept of economic “rationalization,” which is a major theme
in the literature on economic development, should not be understood
as a rejection of subsistence economics.132 Consumerism and
revenue maximization do not define economic rationality. Thus,
it is not accurate to discuss development and “modernization” of
Bedouin economies, or the transition of the Bedouin from completely
“traditional” subsistence economies to completely “modern” market
economies. An examination of economic transformation among
the Bedouin instead demonstrates that the Bedouin instead merely
hold different notions of economic success that have led them to
participate in the emerging market economy according to their own
socioeconomic patterns and interests. As we will see, this has posed
a direct challenge to Egyptian goals for tourism development in Sinai.
132. James C. Scott, The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion
and Subsistence in Southeast Asia (New Haven: Yale University
Press, 1976); see also Samuel L. Popkin, The Rational Peasant: The
Political Economy of Rural Society in Vietnam (Berkeley: University
of California Press, 1979).
97
Chapter 3
Economic Competition and
Marginalization
The thing that makes the Bedouin very angry in Dahab is that there
is no economic equality. And there are some people who don’t
even have a license, a guarantee for his home, and [his family] lived
here 300 years ago.
Bedouin community organizer, May 30, 2012.
Tourism development along the Aqaba Coast has raised the standards
of living for the Bedouin, giving them access to both utilities and
services (water, electricity, education, healthcare, etc.) on the one hand
and economic opportunities on the other. The Bedouin, however, have
not perceived these developments to be purely positive. In fact, despite
objective material gains attained through development, many Aqaba
Bedouin have come to view development as a form of exploitation
and marginalization, notably as Sinai shifted back to Egyptian rule
and Bedouin monopolization of the tourism industry came to an end.
Far from generating gratitude amongst the Bedouin and accelerating
their integration, Egyptian development strategies have actually led
to increasing resentment of Egyptians, whom the Bedouin came to
consider outsiders. These Egyptians, coming to the Sinai as migrant
laborers in search of work, have placed increasing economic pressure
on the Bedouin community as in many cases jobs are being given to
migrants at the expense of the local population. While state policies
and employment preferences largely exclude the Aqaba Bedouin in
favor of Egyptian migrant workers, Bedouin economic activities are
largely closed to Egyptians due to the exclusivity of Bedouin economic
networks stressing solidarity, creating the framework for competition
between the two communities. Egypt’s development policies, while
creating greater returns for the Bedouin, are actually restricting the
Bedouins’ employment opportunities.
Chapter 3
98
Many Egyptians and Sudanese come to Sinai in search of the
same opportunities available to the Bedouin, and Egyptian policies,
favoring the employment of Egyptian migrants, have made it easier
for a newly arrived migrant to secure employment than a Bedouin
who has lived in Dahab his whole life. The Bedouin are forced to
compete with unskilled migrants who enjoy the support of the state
regarding the allocation of jobs and other resources, who have
experience dealing with Egyptian bureaucracy, and who appear to be
more qualified due to higher levels of formal education. The Bedouin
are at a disadvantage for all of these reasons.
As tourism development proceeds along the Aqaba Coast, Egyptian
and foreign-owned companies have increasingly come to control all
major elements of the tourist economy in Sinai, including hotels, sport
clubs, restaurants, and shops.133 This is partially a consequence of
better access and more experience in development among Egyptian
businessmen, but is to some extent ensured by Egyptian authorities,
who clearly assist Egyptian and foreign employers in establishing
the permanence of their business, even at the expense of Bedouin
businesses that are occasionally shut down to make way for Egyptian
or foreign development. Recently, Egyptian policy has related to the
Bedouin as more of a nuisance or a problem than as a group entitled
to equitable government treatment. The state has treated certain
attempts to establish businesses or assert claims to certain pieces of
land as criminal activity instead of a legitimate claim to certain rights
or privileges. Government treatment of the Bedouin in the sphere of
economics and development has largely shaped their perception of
marginalization.
Egyptian policies regarding two issues in particular have combined
to create an atmosphere of dispossession: land tenure and business
ownership/employment. In both these categories, the Bedouin
see official support for giving to the Egyptians what belongs to the
Bedouin according to their customary rights, and the Bedouin have
been unable to effectively confront this problem. While each Bedouin
household uses less land now than in the past, and many took up
permanently settled residence when they moved to Dahab, the
133. Homa, “Touristic Development in Sinai, Egypt,” p. 239.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
99
Bedouin believe the Egyptians are gaining the most valuable pieces
of land, those pieces that the Bedouin can use to establish their own
businesses, and fear that the loss of this land will equate to the loss of
income and security.
Land Tenure, the Bedouin, and the State
Generally, tribal notions of land tenure support the corporate claim
of a tribe to the entirety of the land it controls. Within this territory,
individual tribesmen have the right to claim and develop plots of
land according to an accepted formula based on customary right,
not purchase. For the Mzeina, both of these statements hold true.
The territory of the Mzeina, stretching between Nuwayba and Sharm
el-Sheikh along the east coast of the peninsula, is available for any
Mzeina to exploit or develop.
According to Mzeina customary law, there are three ways an
individual can stake a personal claim to tribal land. First, the family
can plant fruit trees.134 The recognition of control over a piece of land
in return for agricultural development is incentive for the Bedouin
to plant trees and create orchards. A second method for claiming a
piece of land is by building a permanent house on it. While in South
Sinai, temporary shelters such as tents or palm huts (‘arishas) may
be established anywhere, even in the territories of other tribes, a
permanent structure, such as a brick house, is a sign of ownership.
Thus, if a member of the tribe builds a permanent structure on a
plot of land, customary law recognizes that land as his (or hers for
that matter, as women, as family matriarchs, can also “own” land).135
Finally, it is possible to claim a piece of land by digging a well, another
sign of development. A plot of land containing any of these three
developments is considered owned by an individual or family according
to Bedouin customary law, and it is not surprising that most Bedouin
homes clearly display these three features.
134. Interview with Bedouin homeowners about land tenure and housing,
September 18, 2009.
135. Interview about Bedouin land ownership in Dahab, July 22, 2009.
Chapter 3
100
What does the term “ownership” mean regarding corporate land?
Common notions of tribal land tenure recognize the usufructory
rights of tribesmen, as well as their right to pass the land to their kin.136
They would not, however, have the ultimate right of alienation, such
as the ability to sell the land to someone outside the tribe. However,
with processes of urbanization and development, Bedouin have begun
settling permanently and staking claims to available pieces of land,
especially in Dahab and other tourist centers. This land, while claimed
according to the tenets of tribal law, is presently conceived of by the
Aqaba Bedouin in terms of pure ownership instead of corporate
ownership. The Aqaba Bedouin, therefore, consider land they have
claimed to be available for them to develop or sell.137 When tourism
development began in Dahab, but before the Egyptians had formalized
their own system to grant land permits, many Bedouin claimed
valuable pieces of land in order to sell them to Egyptian and foreign
developers. This land was sold at greatly deflated prices for individual
tribesmen to earn quick cash, and in this way, much of the prime
land along the Dahab bay passed out of the hands of the Mzeina into
the ownership of Egyptian and foreign businessmen. By the time the
problem became clear to the Bedouin, it was too late to reclaim these
valuable plots. In game theory parlance, this is a classic example of
the “social dilemma” where the rational pursuit of individual interests
produces suboptimal outcomes for the entire group.138
Egyptian policy regarding Bedouin land in Dahab has been to
aggressively dispute their remaining claims to valuable pieces of
property and encourage the sale of tribal land to developers. The
Egyptians have developed two major avenues to gain control of tribal
land from the Aqaba Bedouin in and around Dahab. The first has been
an offer of compensation; in return for land the government wants,
they offer to reimburse the claimant with a plot of 200 square meters
somewhere in the desert away from development.139 The government
136. Austin Kennett, Bedouin Justice: Law and Customs Among the
Egyptian Bedouin (London: Kegan Paul Int’l Ltd., 2000), p. 89.
137. Interview with Bedouin Land activists about land and land sales, May
14, 2009.
138. Peter Kollock, “Social Dilemmas: The Anatomy of Cooperation,” Annual
Review of Sociology 24.1 (1998), pp. 183–214.
139. Ibid.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
101
thereby hopes to move the Bedouin away from areas targeted for
economic development, physically removing them from sources of
tourist income. This program has largely been a failure. According to
the Bedouin, there is no need to be compensated because both the
land by the coast and the land in the interior belong to the Bedouin,
and furthermore, the Bedouin do not wish to trade a claim on an
economically valuable piece of land near the coast for a plot far from
tourist centers. Finally, and perhaps most importantly, the Bedouin
who have already agreed to this deal with government authorities
claim that they were ultimately never compensated. The Bedouin
have been hesitant to make agreements with the Egyptian authorities
because they do not trust that the authorities will fulfill their promises.
The second avenue the state has used to dispute a Bedouin claim
to a plot of land is to merely not recognize its legality and maintain the
claim that all land is state land. This is possible due to the ideology of
the state system that the state should have ultimate sovereignty over its
territory, as well as the fact that it does not recognize the legitimacy of
any of the customary signs of Bedouin land ownership; the Egyptians
only recognize ownership based on possession of legal papers, which
generally only wealthier Bedouin possess due to their expense. The
concept of state-ownership of land dates to the Ottoman Land Code
of 1858, a piece of land legislation whose main principles have been
maintained by many post-colonial Middle East governments. Thus,
the Egyptian state, since it governs the Sinai Peninsula, has ultimate
control and ownership of the land there, and has the “legitimate”
right to claim plots of land considered by the Mzeina to be part of
their tribal territory. The Egyptian state further argues that since the
Bedouin cannot show proof of having purchased this land according
to legal standards, the possession of the aforementioned permit, the
government does not have to recognize tribal claims.
One Bedouin interviewee described his attempts to build a
house before getting married. He had tried to settle on a piece of
undeveloped property claimed by his family to build a house, a
common requirement to be considered ready for marriage. The
police, however, prevented him from settling on this land, claiming
that since he could not present legal proof of ownership, he had no
right to develop it. The only way to get this proof was to purchase a
permit from the authorities at el-Tor, the main center for Bedouin-
Chapter 3
102
government contact in the South Sinai Governate. He said that the
permits were quite expensive, perhaps 200 LE for a single square
meter.140 While traditionally, the Bedouin could simply claim a piece
of tribal land to build a house by developing it, the Egyptian system
has made it very costly and stressful for Bedouin to acquire official
permission to build.
This land, now claimed by the Egyptian government, had been
under the control of the same family since the Israeli occupation. Our
interviewee, who remembers the Israeli occupation, highlighted the
dilemma when he said, “The Egyptians want to see our papers proving
we own the land. What can we show them, I asked, a contract with
the Israeli government?”141 The state’s legal claim to all land in the
Sinai is contested by the Bedouin, who reject the principle of eminent
domain and assert their own legitimacy due to customary notions of
duration, occupation, and development. They cannot, in any case,
confront the powerful Egyptian authorities directly; they believe their
choices are to leave the land or be thrown off by Egyptian forces.142
The main avenue to contest Egyptian claims to Bedouin land has
been the organization of sit-ins by Bedouin women at plots of land
claimed by their families, especially in the aftermath of the uprisings
that toppled President Husni Mubarak. While at first this was a largely
symbolic struggle, as the women did not presume that they would be
able to prevent Egyptian occupation through force, after the collapse
of the Egyptian government, the Bedouin have been more successful
in developing land previously denied to them. Bedouin development
has expanded dramatically since February 2011.
Before 2011, women tended to occupy the land instead of men
because they believed that the authorities would be less willing to
interfere with Bedouin women. Yet there were a number of instances
reported to us in which Bedouin women had been arrested and even
assaulted by Egyptian police officers, who then removed them from
the land forcibly.143 This, however, was a last resort for the Egyptian
140. Interview with a Bedouin Divemaster, July 24, 2009.
141. Ibid.
142. Interview with Bedouin land activists about land and land sales, May 14,
2009.
143. Conversation about Bedouin land tenure in Sinai, July 22, 2009.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
103
authorities, who preferred to ignore the Bedouin presence for as
long as possible. In one instance, two Bedouin ‘arishas (palm huts)
occupied a plot of land in the path of Egyptian residential development
on what was then the fringe of Dahab (see Figure 9). The Egyptians
continued to build apartment blocks without waiting for the Bedouin
to vacate their lot. Finally, the women were presented with the fait
accompli that their ‘arishas were blocking the last construction lot
and were interfering with the building process, since there was only
one apartment left to be built. In this way, the women were forced
to vacate this plot of land without compensation.144 Across Dahab,
a number of Bedouin women maintain claims to plots of land in this
manner. The Egyptians have taken to ignoring them until the moment
they need the disputed land or else using force to displace the Bedouin
“squatters.” Once the state stakes a claim to the land, it is very difficult
for the women to maintain their own claim.
144. Personal observations from multiple trips to Dahab, March, May, and
July 2009. The pace of construction is so quick that over a period of
three to five months, this entire scenario conducted itself from start to
finish. While in March, the ‘arishas were the only structures on the strip
of land, by July, the apartments had been completed and tenants had
begun to move in. The ‘arishas have all disappeared.
Figure 9: Bedouin ‘arisha competing with Egyptian construction.
Photo by Eli Sperling, May 14, 2009.
Chapter 3
104
During one of our research trips, we were woken early in the
morning by one of our friends who told us that at sunrise, the Egyptian
authorities had entered his family plot and set fire to the ‘arishas after
plundering them for valuables such as blankets and propane tanks.145
This had been the first night in over a week that the women did
not spend the night at their plot, and they were convinced that the
authorities had been watching them to determine when they could
enter the land and attempt to clear it of signs of Bedouin possession.
When asked why the government tried to burn the ‘arishas, the
women responded that the Egyptians wanted to take this land and sell
it to Egyptians in order to build hotels, villas, and even a golf course.146
While this practice is being carried out on empty land, for which
the government is preparing purchase permits for commercial and
residential construction, the Bedouin are convinced that the Egyptians
are equally interested in clearing the Bedouin off their plots in order to
sell this land as well. This event caused great anguish among the two
Bedouin women. They accused the Egyptians of taking everything
from the Bedouin, such that soon there would be nowhere left for
them to go. They were quite explicit when they said they believed
the government was alienating Bedouin property and rights for the
benefit of the “outsider” Egyptians.147
Since the uprisings in 2011, however, the Bedouin claim that
state presence in Dahab, as regards the land disputes, has practically
disappeared. While my trips to Dahab in the post-Mubarak era have
indicated a continued expansion of state-directed construction, this has
largely focused on areas where the Bedouin have not staked claims to
pieces of land. Additionally, it appears that more and more Bedouin
have begun staking claims to new pieces of land around Dahab and
have begun their own development, leading to the emergence of new
Bedouin neighborhoods around Dahab that did not exist before the
fall of the Mubarak regime. In keeping with the traditional notions of
ownership mentioned above, this development began with very modest
permanent dwellings, constructed from cinderblocks, as well as large
145. Interview with Bedouin land activists, on film, February 16, 2010.
146. This claim is not as outlandish as it might seem—there are golf courses
in both Sharm el-Sheikh and Taba.
147. Interview with Bedouin land activists, February 9, 2010.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
105
gardens, which were often completed before the houses themselves.
Thus far, the state has avoided any confrontation with the Bedouin
over these lands. However, when I asked about the construction, a
number of Bedouin told me that they were unhappy with the current
state of things, that the houses were “ugly” and underdeveloped. When
pushed on the subject, they admitted that this was not due to a lack
of taste or aesthetics, but to a concern that the state would eventually
decide to demolish them, discouraging the Bedouin from investing
more resources and energy into their buildings.148 This conforms to
anecdotal evidence from the Bedouin of the Israeli Negev, who also
report that the constant threat of home demolitions is the primary
factor discouraging them from constructing more permanent homes.
The dispossession of land is a primary concern for the Aqaba
Bedouin. Not only have they not been able to buy back land that
has been sold, due to sharply rising prices, but they have been
increasingly helpless to retain economically profitable plots, such
as those along the beach, and this is infringing on their ability to
maintain ties with the tourist economy. The value of property is in its
proximity to tourist centers, and the Bedouin are seeking the same
land that the government has claimed for development. The NPDS
(National Project for the Development of Sinai, discussed in section
1.2) allocated a large percentage of this land for development under
the assumption that a tribal (read: nomadic) society would place the
same value on this land as would the development authorities. The
Bedouin have, however, sought to participate actively in the tourist
economy, but have had trouble retaining land on which to establish
their own hotels and businesses due to official development strategies
adopted by the Egyptian state. Only the wealthiest Bedouin families
have successfully retained plots on the beach to develop campgrounds
and hotels. For the most part, this wealth came from selling other
plots of land for cash.
148. Day in a new Bedouin neighborhood, June 4, 2012.
Chapter 3
106
Ownership and Employment in Dahab
A majority of smaller tourist businesses are owned by Egyptians, and
the large ones are primarily owned by multinational resort chains
such as Hilton and Accor. This, combined with the proliferation of
resort-package tourism, has affected the ability of the Bedouin to seek
employment and especially to establish their own businesses. Lack of
education is certainly an issue, but it is not the only factor blocking
Bedouin access to employment and ownership. Equally important
are the development policies favored by the state, the negative
stereotypes that Egyptians hold regarding the Bedouins’ work ethic,
and the convoluted bureaucracy regulating tourism development.
These factors, coupled with the relative growth of the formal resort-
tourism sector, have led to a decrease in employment and ownership
opportunities for the Aqaba Bedouin.
Lack of formal education is a major reason that Egyptian business
owners claim they avoid hiring Bedouin workers. Even a Bedouin
owner of one of the medium-sized hotels in Dahab, a member of the
‘Aleqat tribe, admits that he prefers to hire Egyptians because they
are better educated. Despite the fact that both migrants and Bedouin
go into the unskilled labor pool (Egyptian professionals such as
teachers, doctors, and lawyers are not considered here), the Egyptians
have better formal academic qualifications. Instead, the Bedouin have
largely maintained their traditional employment patterns as unskilled
laborers, notably drivers and menial laborers, focusing on skills they
can acquire directly in the marketplace and using them in the informal
tourist sector.149 However, there are a number of unskilled sectors of
the Dahab economy where the Bedouin face stiff competition, notably
the service-sector and construction. Many migrants come to Dahab
from Upper Egypt and seek menial labor jobs, such as driving taxis
or carrying equipment for scuba divers, in the same manner as the
Bedouin. As for construction, a majority of laborers hail from Upper
Egypt and Sudan, and there is little Bedouin presence in the booming
construction industry.
The Bedouin can certainly be considered “unskilled labor” because
of a lack of schooling, but this does not mean that the Bedouin have
149. Aziz, “Employment in a Bedouin Community,” p. 33.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
107
no skills that development authorities and tourism operators would
consider useful, such as mechanical abilities, the knowledge of multiple
languages (often as advanced than their Egyptian counterparts if not
more so), and intimate familiarity with the desert. Despite these very
real skills uniquely suited to the Sinai, negative perceptions regarding
the Bedouin and their education have led Egyptians to avoid hiring
them.150
The formalization of tourism and the preference to develop
package- or resort-tourism has further limited the ability of the Aqaba
Bedouin to participate in the Dahab economy. Increasingly, resort
tourism aims to present an entire vacation package to the tourist, and
the hotels in Sinai are ever more able to address a tourist’s every
need, tempering the desire to leave the confines of the experience
provided by the hotel. This is true not only regarding food, but also
recreation, desert excursions, and souvenirs. These offerings are
arranged through the hotel, which either operates its own excursion
company or establishes a formal business arrangement with one
that is often run by Egyptian or foreign operators. The availability of
these goods and services through the resort, coupled with the resort’s
unwillingness to hire Bedouin, has led to a decline in the ability of
the Bedouin to engage the tourist economy. Bedouin run their own
desert safaris in town and make and sell their own handicrafts, but as
tourists are encouraged more and more to stay within the confines
of the resort, where there is no Bedouin presence, the Bedouin are
separated from sources of revenue.
Resorts in Dahab and Sharm el-Sheikh organize excursions for
their guests to popular beaches as well as dive trips. In the morning,
these tourists are loaded into jeeps run by Egyptian operators, who
convey them to their destination. In many cases, this includes a stop
in the shopping center of Dahab. Many Bedouin vendors claim that
these tourists are brought directly to the Egyptian-owned shops. A
Bedouin community organizer, who is also quite active politically,
unsuccessfully tried to confront this problem. He began to encourage
shops who hired and purchased from the local community to mark their
products and hang signs indicating that their shops worked with the
Bedouin in order to encourage tourists to direct their money to these
150. Ibid.
Chapter 3
108
establishments. However, after a short while, he was approached by
the police who demanded that these signs be removed and threatened
action over it. The signs did not last more than a few days.151 He
could not come to any other conclusion except that the authorities did
not want to draw tourists’ attention to the fact that many shops did
not engage the local community, which might decrease their income
as tourists may prefer to “buy local.”
Another example of the conflict between the formal and informal
tourism sectors was explained to me by an older Bedouin guide. He
had been offering his services as a sea-guide (he described himself
as a Divemaster but holds no formal certification) since the Israeli
occupation, operating a boat to take divers to sites around Dahab.
As we spoke, he turned my attention to the better known dive sites in
Dahab and, knowing that I am an avid scuba diver, asked my opinion.
My reply was that the diving in Dahab was incredible, but… “There
are too many people!” he jumped in and finished my thought for me.
This was exactly the problem with the dive shops, he complained, and
he said that the value in the services that he offered was his ability
to take divers to secluded and pristine dive sites uncluttered by the
shops, restaurants, and other divers that have become permanent
features of the popular dive sites around Dahab. And for twenty
years, he claimed, his business was excellent, and those who engaged
his services were quite satisfied. However, during the past decade he
had been subjected to increasing harassment by the authorities, who
told him that he was no longer allowed to take divers out unless he
was employed directly through a dive shop. He claimed he had been
threatened by the police to shut down his service, because it was
taking business away from the established dive shops.152
The Egyptian government has consistently sided against the
Bedouin in business conflicts to ensure Egyptian dominance in the
fields of ownership and operation. This has allowed Egyptian business
owners to break contracts and leases with Bedouin to ensure they
151. Interview with a Bedouin community organizer, May 30, 2012.
152. Interview with a Bedouin guide, June 5, 2012. Of course, as a scuba
instructor myself, I am always sensitive to issues of risk assumption and
liability, so this story is not so cut and dried. Still, this is but one example
of the trend to favor businesses paying taxes to the state.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
109
would continue to control certain establishments on Bedouin land;
it has also allowed Egyptian authorities to disassemble Bedouin-
run establishments to make room for Egyptian-run businesses. Two
notable examples made the Cairo Times in 1999 when a number
of Bedouin-owned camps in Dahab were demolished by Egyptian
authorities to clear space for a foreign-owned resort.153 While the
Bedouin had legitimate claim to the land, Egyptian authorities used
the excuse that these camps did not meet the international health and
safety standards of the resorts. The Bedouin camps were completely
demolished to make room for Egyptian-owned hotels and the Bedouin
were never compensated for the damage or the land they were
required to vacate.
Another example of this policy was related to us by a Bedouin
interviewee in Dahab. He told us of an Egyptian businessman who
had leased a plot of land on the coast from his father in order to
build a hotel. This land was given to the Egyptian to operate for a
period of ten years, and according to the agreement, at the end of
the term the land could either be re-leased or would revert back to
his father’s control. The Egyptian had leased this land for a small
sum, certainly less than it was worth, and ten years later its value had
increased tremendously. At the end of the lease, the Bedouin refused
to renew because of the significant increase in the land’s value. When
approached by the Bedouin, the Egyptian businessman refused to
recognize the legitimacy of his claim to the property or that his lease
had expired. Instead, he claimed that he had rightfully purchased the
land, and he refused to renegotiate the terms of his occupancy. When
the Bedouin approached the government, Egyptian authorities upheld
the businessman’s claim, siding against the Bedouin, and allowed the
businessman to retain both the land and his business.154 The Egyptian
government has not expressed any willingness to disrupt Egyptian jobs
153. “Green Lines: The Tourist Development Agency Uses Environmental
Rhetoric to Justify Demolishing Bedouin-Owned Camps in Favor of Big
Hotels,” The Cairo Times, September 30, 1999; see also “Bedouin
Camps Demolished: The Claims of Sinai’s Indigenous Tribes Are Swept
Away by the Tidal Wave of Development,” The Cairo Times, July 22,
1999.
154. Interview with a Bedouin waiter, April 10, 2009.
Chapter 3
110
or businesses for the benefit of the Bedouin. On the contrary, they
have repeatedly intervened against the Bedouin on behalf of Egyptian
businesses and business owners.
However, it is entirely possible that the contract signed by this
particular landowner was a bill of sale instead of a lease. I have heard
such a claim repeated a number of times by various Bedouin in
Dahab, as Bedouin appear to be at a disadvantage when it comes to
negotiating land deals because of their unfamiliarity with contemporary
contract practices. They claim that this lack of experience is being
taken advantage of by the state and development authorities in order
to acquire land from the Bedouin at deflated prices, further contributing
to their marginalization from the tourist industry.155
Due to their status as unskilled laborers, combined with the
prioritization of resort tourism, the Bedouin have found it increasingly
difficult to own businesses, and even to seek employment in tourism
along the Aqaba Coast. While it would be significantly easier for
the Bedouin to seek employment with other Bedouin, Egyptian
preferences have made it difficult for the Bedouin to establish and
retain their own hotels and restaurants due to the high standards and
costs mandated by multinational resort chains and supported by the
Egyptian government. These standards have been used both to deny
building permits to the Bedouin as well as to shut down Bedouin
camps that already exist on pieces of land desired by the government
and resorts.
The exceptions to this rule are non-resort foreign-owned hotels
and businesses, notably the dive operators and surf clubs mentioned
in the previous chapter, which have shown a willingness to work with
Bedouin in a number of professional capacities such as divemasters
and windsurfing instructors. These Bedouin consider themselves
extremely privileged to have acquired these jobs and acknowledge
that it is very difficult for Bedouin to access this type of employment,
especially due to the prevalence of Egyptian ownership over foreign
ownership.156 In addition to the relatively warmer social relations
between foreigners and the Bedouin, there is an element of economic
cooperation that benefits both parties. This has allowed Bedouin
155. Interview with a Bedouin community organizer, May 30, 2012.
156. Conversation with a Bedouin windsurfing instructor, February 13,
2010.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
111
youths to pursue permanent careers doing something they love to do.
These are the only Bedouin who I have ever heard say “I love my job
and I love my boss.” For the owners, hiring the Bedouin is quite cost
effective, for while these Bedouin are making more money than they
would in menial jobs, at the same time, owners have the ability to
pay the Bedouin somewhat less than might be demanded by foreign
windsurfing and dive instructors.
Bedouin have maintained their ability to earn income mainly
through maintaining their contacts with budget tourism via informal
economic interaction, which is maintained in and mediated by the
town, not the resort. Examples include selling drugs, operating taxis,
offering services as guides, and selling hand-made goods to tourists.
This is the main difference between the formal resort sector and
the informal budget tourism sector: the town is subject to fewer
rules and regulations than the resort, enabling increased freedom to
pursue employment or income, while undermining the ability of the
government to extract revenue from these types of activities.
The Turn to Illicit Economies
As the Bedouin have been actively excluded from formal sectors of the
Sinai economy, many have turned to illicit economies to supplement
their income. While the previous chapter focused on the “how” of
Bedouin smuggling and drug dealing, this section examines why this
sector is so important to Bedouin economics in South Sinai. The drug
trade, as an illegal and unregulated activity, is completely open to
the Bedouin and has recently been a lucrative source of income for
Aqaba Bedouin, who find it more difficult to access jobs considered
“legitimate” and regulated by the authorities. While Egyptian
authorities view these types of activities as criminal, the Bedouin do
not. They see the cultivation and sale of cannabis or opium to be
just as legitimate as any other economic enterprise, reflected by the
level of social acceptability among Egyptians and the many tourists
who form the basis of the market, as well as the rise in Bedouin drug
consumption.157 Furthermore, it has been estimated that the narcotics
sector in South Sinai, comprised mainly of opium and cannabis, has
157. Marx, “Hashish smuggling,” p. 30.
Chapter 3
112
at times provided up to 30 percent of the income for the Bedouin
community, and therefore the Bedouin consider it a vital part of their
economy.158
The adoption and growth of this activity appears to be a response
to the economic opportunities available to the Bedouin. When
questioned as to the reason he turned to opium cultivation, one
Bedouin replied in the mid-1990s, “Twenty years ago [under Israeli
rule], every able-bodied man had a job. Now there is no work,” but
that working in drug cultivation was reliable as there was little worry of
a drop in demand.159 However, when presented with safer alternatives
to drug cultivation, such as owning hotels and running tourism
activities, many of the Bedouin cultivators declared their willingness
to abandon narcotics production.160 This is due to the labor-intensive
nature of cultivating drugs and the relative risk of being caught. While
the cultivators and dealers have assumed the risk because the margins
are better than pastoral or urban alternatives, drug cultivation is not
compatible with the concept of “multi-resource economics”; it is a
single-source activity within an immediate territory due to its illegal
nature and the risk the fields pose to other activities in close proximity,
notably tourism.161 The cultivation of drugs is a limited value activity
that, if replaced with a legal alternative, might be abandoned in favor
of less risky jobs. The present trend of marginalization, however, has
meant the Bedouin have continued to occupy this illicit niche.
As in other parts of the world, there has been a perception among
the Egyptian authorities that the criminalization of these drugs would
discourage the practice, but this has not been the case. While in other
countries, illegal activities, especially the drug trade, have been coopted
by organized crime, in South Sinai the Bedouin have monopolized
this sector on their own, and the trade is largely non-violent. This
is somewhat of a double edged sword as well, and it appears that to
some extent, and depending on political conditions, the authorities
may turn a blind eye to Bedouin narcotics distribution as they have
158. Ibid., p. 29.
159. Hobbs, “The Opium Poppy in Egypt,” p. 71.
160. Joseph J. Hobbs, “Speaking with People in Egypt’s St. Katherine’s
National Park,” Geographical Review 86.1 (1996), p. 15.
161. Hobbs, “The Opium Poppy in Egypt,” p. 78.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
113
come to realize what an important part of Dahab’s economy it truly
is. This claim should not be overstated, however, and anti-narcotics
operations in Sinai continue apace.
As clearly stated in the Global Commission on Drugs report
published in June 2011, more active forms of government repression
of the drug trade often instigate violent responses and the establishment
of organized crime.162 Although Bedouin cultivators are armed, violent
confrontations between the Bedouin and Egyptian anti-narcotics
enforcement in South Sinai seem to be quite rare according to the
Bedouin themselves, despite the fact that the Egyptian authorities
attempt to use Bedouins’ involvement in the narcotics trade as proof of
their criminal or violent behavior. In fact, there have been a number of
instances of violent clashes between Bedouin and Egyptian authorities
in direct response to anti-narcotics operations. This hit home for me
personally during my most recent stay in Dahab during the summer
of 2012, when two American tourists were captured and held by
members of the Tarabin tribe in retaliation for the arrest of a fellow
tribesmen who had been caught carrying a large quantity of cannabis
through a checkpoint.163 While Bedouin in Dahab acknowledged
the importance of the narcotics trade for their economy, they were
furious that the smugglers had resorted to kidnapping because of the
damage inflicted on the rest of the tourism sector, highlighting the
complicated relationship between tourism and the drug trade. After
162. See War on Drugs: Report of the Global Commission on Drug Policy.
Rep. Global Commission on Drug Policy, June 2011. Web. <http://
globalcommissionondrugs.org>. While receiving little fanfare, this
commission, launched at the behest of the UN, was composed of some
of the most influential politicians and businessmen in the world including
EU Foreign Policy Chief Javier Solana, ex-Mexican President Ernesto
Zedillo, former Greek Prime Minister George Papandreou, former US
Secretary of State George Shultz, former chairman of the FED Richard
Volker, and magnate Sir Richard Branson. This short list hardly does the
commission justice. The study examined cross-national data on narcotics
prevention, enforcement, and treatment.
163. “U.S. Tourists Freed Unharmed in Sinai,” Reuters, May 31, 2012.
<http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/05/31/us-egypt-sinai-
kidnapping-idUSBRE84U0DL20120531>.
Chapter 3
114
less than 24 hours of negotiations, both the tourists and the arrested
smuggler were freed; both parties hoped to avoid incurring the ire
of the US in the event that anything happened to the two American
tourists. In any case, this event appears to support the previously-
mentioned Commission Report’s conclusions that harsher methods of
anti-narcotics enforcement often leads to outbreaks of violence. In this
setting, the impact on tourism may explain why conflicts are relatively
rare.
While engagement in the narcotics trade is not necessarily
connected to a cultural tendency towards violence and criminality,
the Sinai Bedouin have come to be associated with drugs, especially
hashish and heroin. This has contributed to the conflict between the
Sinai Bedouin and the Egyptians (and even created tensions within
the Bedouin community itself), and reinforced a reputation of the
Bedouin as dangerous criminals. Many Egyptians blame the Sinai
Bedouin for being a major cause of the drug problem in Egypt, and
the authorities and the media are doing what they can to reinforce
this perception.164 Involvement in the drug trade has cast a shadow
over the Sinai Bedouin, over the relationships between the Bedouin
and young backpackers, often accused of being addicted to drugs, and
over Dahab as a whole, which has received the reputation as an illicit
drug den in both regional and international news, in guide books, and
in the attitudes of Egyptian officials in their treatment of both Bedouin
and backpackers.165
164. “Six arrested, drugs seized in south Sinai bust,” Agence France-Presse,
February 27, 1997; see also “Four Foreigners Sentenced for Drugs,”
Middle East Times, 2001, issue 41; see also Hobbs, “The Opium
Poppy in Egypt,” p. 79. Hobbs discussed the government’s exaggeration
of the Sinai drug problem and the attitudes these reports have generated
within mainstream Egyptian society.
165. Behbehanian, “Policing the Illicit Peripheries of Egypt’s Tourism
Industry”; I further base this claim on personal observations of treatment
at the hands of Egyptian authority figures. The fact that we, as tourists,
were consistently stopped and questioned only in the presence of our
Bedouin friends is a clear indication that these attitudes are associated
with the Bedouin.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
115
During one of our field trips, we organized a day excursion from
Dahab to Sharm el-Sheikh to explore Bedouin economic participation
in the tourist center of Na‘ama Bay. As we approached the city, we
were stopped by Egyptian officials at the outermost military checkpoint
and told to get out of the car. We were made to stand next to a group
of Egyptian soldiers with automatic rifles while another group began
tearing through the vehicle, clearly searching for something. After
a few minutes, the officer approached one of our Bedouin friends
and demanded to know where the hashish was; he had assumed that
two Bedouin youths and two American youths would naturally have
drugs with them. Upon hearing our adamant denials, they continued
searching the car, evidently not believing us, but were unable to find
anything illegal with which to hold us. There had never been hashish
in the car. Far from catching a lucky break, we were instead the victims
of the illicit reputation of Dahab, the Bedouin, and backpackers in
general. Over the course of our field research, we became accustomed
to this attitude toward us and our Bedouin companions on the part of
Egyptian authorities; it has become an institutional part of the system
that regulates social dynamics in South Sinai. Without fail, every time I
traveled with more than one Bedouin, we encountered this suspicious
treatment.
While some Bedouin have adopted drug cultivation and distribution
as a consequence of their marginalization from more central forms
of employment, the Egyptian authorities’ reaction has reflected a
perception that Bedouin participation is a result of certain cultural
traits. As a consequence, the Egyptian response has been to target
the Bedouin rather than the market factors and policies responsible
for increasing demand and relative profitability for the Bedouin.
The publicity that Dahab has received as a center for illicit activities
including sex and drugs has only served to increase its popularity for
narco-tourism, fuelling demand among young budget travelers and
ensuring the Bedouin will continue to supply. The unequal distribution
and availability of urban employment has made some Bedouin turn to
other methods of interacting with the tourist economy.
Chapter 3
116
Bedouin Niches and Egyptian Attempts
to Occupy Them166
As previously mentioned, the Bedouin heritage has given them a
special role in Sinai tourism. While a major goal of the NPDS for this
sub-region was the creation of a “Red Sea Riviera,” resort and beach
tourism are not the only strengths of the Aqaba Coast. Heritage and
culture tourism also play a major role. This tourism has two major
sources. The first is the monastery of Santa Katarina at Mt. Sinai,
the namesake of the Santa Katarina region mentioned earlier as the
territory of the Jabaliyya Bedouin, which has drawn religious visitors
for hundreds of years and has recently become an UNESCO World
Heritage site. The second is Bedouin culture tourism. The Bedouin
discovered that they could profit from sharing their culture with
tourists in the 1960s and 70s, especially from what have come to be
known as “Bedouin hospitality” events. Since then, Bedouin culture
has been a major tourist theme, especially in Dahab, which attempts
to attract tourists to its “authentic Bedouin atmosphere.”167 While
the Bedouin are in a natural position to provide these services to the
tourists, non-Bedouin Egyptians (migrant workers), have also come to
understand the profitability of Bedouin cultural activities, and they have
increasingly attempted to occupy this niche, partially marginalizing
the Bedouin from an activity that is uniquely theirs.
In Dahab, Bedouin culture has been linked to the atmosphere of
relaxation permeating the “Riviera.” The beachside restaurants offer
“authentic” Bedouin tea, hotels offer evenings at Bedouin camps, and
guides offer camel rides as an “authentic” Bedouin activity. The town
and its experiences are thus unique, as they have a special “Bedouin”
character which has become a major draw for tourists. The important
role that Bedouin culture plays in Sinai tourism has given the Bedouin
a unique niche in the tourism sector, which has allowed the Bedouin to
profit by sharing their culture with outsiders. In its own way, this niche
166. The theme of this section was frequently stressed by the Bedouin
themselves, who asked me to discuss the issue. They appear to consider
it a larger problem than I was able to witness personally.
167. Interview with a Bedouin Divemaster, July 24, 2009.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
117
could have been a consolation for the marginalization of the Bedouin
from resort tourism, and the two sectors might have complimented
one another, which to an important extent they do.
While a discussion on the merits of these activities as “authentic” is
beyond the scope of this chapter, the importance is that these activities
are increasingly being offered by non-Bedouin in an attempt to
increase their market share of the cultural tourism sector.168 A majority
of tourists do not understand the difference between an “Egyptian”
and a “Bedouin,” and this has allowed Egyptians to pass themselves
off as Bedouin as well as to appropriate elements of Bedouin culture
as “Egyptian” in order to gain a foothold in the Bedouin culture
market.169 For example, a number of Egyptian-owned restaurants on
the Dahab and Sharm el-Sheikh corniches have Bedouin names and
attempt to convince the customers that eating there will constitute a
“Bedouin experience,” offering such selections as Bedouin calamari
and Bedouin tea. A prominent example of such a restaurant is the
Egyptian-owned “Bedouin Bar” in Sharm el-Sheikh, where employees
dress up in Bedouin garb.
Competition between Bedouin and Egyptian migrants in the field
of Bedouin culture tourism has had two notable consequences. First
is the expected marginalization of Bedouin from their own economic
niches. This has only served to increase the economic competition
between the Bedouin and the Egyptians, as the Bedouin cannot rely
on culture tourism as a protected Bedouin-only activity, but cannot
themselves break into a number of Egyptian activities. The second
consequence has perhaps even greater implications. By occupying
Bedouin economic niches and profiting from Bedouin culture, the
Egyptians, as the Bedouin perceive them, are attempting to deprive
the Bedouin of the features that make them culturally distinctive. The
Egyptians have accomplished this by coopting symbols of Bedouin
culture and communicating them, not as Bedouin, but as broadly
Egyptian. The Bedouin are very concerned with maintaining their
cultural distinctiveness and see Egyptian encroachment as part of a
larger attempt to impose Egyptian uniformity on the Bedouin, first by
168. See Hobbs, “Speaking with People in Egypt’s St. Katherine’s National
Park,” p. 14.
169. Interview with a Bedouin Divemaster, June 11, 2012.
Chapter 3
118
denying them their cultural uniqueness and second by the imposition
of Egyptian cultural symbols and values on the Bedouin community.
As such, defense of their economic livelihood is also a defense of their
cultural distinctiveness.
Case Study:
Dahab versus Sharm el-Sheikh
Dahab and Sharm el-Sheikh are the two most popular tourist
destinations along Sinai’s Aqaba Coast. While both have been
subjected to accelerating tourism development over the past twenty
years of Egyptian rule, these towns differ from each other significantly,
due to differing origins and development trajectories. Dahab began its
development as a Bedouin oasis, a space where Bedouin would spend
their summers harvesting, fishing, and strengthening social contacts.
Tourism development began with Bedouin setting up tourist camps
for Israeli backpackers. Sharm el-Sheikh was chosen for its strategic
position, beginning its life as an Egyptian, and later Israeli, military
outpost. Development here was always controlled by forces of the
state, and tourism has always been a large-scale development project.
While Dahab has retained a fair share of its small scale, low-budget
character, Sharm el-Sheikh has grown to become a huge tourism
city replete with five-star resorts, multinational restaurant chains, and
bustling beach-side nightclubs. If Dahab, with its illicit reputation and
budget character, has been a disappointment for Egyptian tourist
development, Sharm is undoubtedly Sinai’s greatest success. Dahab
has been targeted by the Egyptian government for development
aimed at bringing it more in line with Sharm el-Sheikh.
While the Bedouin presence in Dahab allowed them to be the first
to set up their own tourist camps and restaurants, the lack of a similar
Bedouin presence in Sharm el-Sheikh made it significantly easier for
developers to acquire land there. Additionally, the absence of anything
but resort tourism in Sharm el-Sheikh has translated into very few
employment opportunities for the Bedouin; few Bedouin work in the
town. The Bedouin see the situation in Sharm as a likely outcome
for Dahab if the appropriation of tribal land on behalf of developers
Economic Competition and Marginalization
119
and multinational resorts continues, highlighting the importance of
protecting what land they still control in Dahab.
For the Aqaba Bedouin, Sharm el-Sheikh and Dahab represent
two fundamentally different possible outcomes of development.
Dahab, as a Bedouin social space and a center for budget tourism,
has allowed the Bedouin to maintain informal economic networks and
has become a center for urban Bedouin employment and trade. Even
though the volume of tourism in Dahab is lower than in Sharm el-
Sheikh, the Bedouin have been able to generate significantly higher
income in Dahab. Egyptian development has had to contend with this
legacy and has been unable to effectively replace it. Sharm el-Sheikh,
on the other hand, has, to a large extent, succeeded in excluding
the Bedouin from the economic life of the city. There are very few
Bedouin-owned shops, restaurants, or hotels, and furthermore, no
Bedouin are allowed to work in Sharm el-Sheikh unless employed
directly by one of the resorts or businesses. As a consequence, the
number of Bedouin profiting in Sharm el-Sheikh is quite small. The
Bedouin feel less attachment to Sharm el-Sheikh than they do to
Dahab, and they correctly see that for the Egyptians, Sharm el-Sheikh
is an ideal model for tourism development. For the Bedouin, Sharm
el-Sheikh as a concept generates high levels of discomfort. In it, they
see the authoritarian policies of the central government as well as
their own vulnerability.
While the Aqaba Bedouin have the freedom to live and seek
employment in Dahab, the rules for the Bedouin in Sharm el-
Sheikh are quite restrictive. In fact, the state has devised a system
to physically exclude them from the economies of the city and have
kept the Bedouin on the economic margins of Sharm. We had
a chance to see the limitations imposed on the Bedouin on one of
our excursions to Sharm el-Sheikh. While our primary goal was to
examine social interactions in the city center, we had the opportunity
to spend time with two of our Bedouin friends who were in Sharm
for the week selling handicrafts. We drove along the main road until
we found ourselves leaving the developed part of the city. Parking by
an abandoned construction site, we exited the car and began walking
toward the ocean, where we found the women sitting in an ‘arisha
next to a half-completed building about 200 meters outside the limit
of Na‘ama Bay, the tourist center of the city. The limit was delineated
Chapter 3
120
by a chain-link fence with a gate guarded by members of the Egyptian
tourist police. On the near side of the fence lay the public beach and
a number of ongoing construction sites, on the far side, the resorts,
restaurants, and shopping that constituted Na‘ama Bay. Tourists
have the freedom to move at will through the gate in order to access
the public beaches; however, Bedouin vendors are prohibited from
passing through the gate into the town.
In Dahab, many Bedouin, both men and women, sit on the
corniche in the center of town selling handicrafts, competing with the
industrially manufactured goods sold in the shops, while children sell
bracelets to tourists (See Figure 10). In Sharm, the authorities have
legally prohibited these practices and forced Bedouin vendors out of
the town. In this way, Egyptian authorities have maintained Sharm as
an exclusively Egyptian commercial space.170 The Bedouin are allowed
to sell their goods outside the fence, but are not allowed in unless
formally employed by a business in town, forcing their conformity to
formal employment preferences instead of allowing them to freely
pursue economic opportunities. This policy highlights the perception
of discrimination among the Bedouin and demonstrates how the
government creates policies to limit the informal tourism industry.
170. Personal observations, Sharm el-Sheikh, April 12, 2009.
Figure 10: Bedouin selling handicrafts on the Dahab Corniche.
Photo by author, February 20, 2009.
Economic Competition and Marginalization
121
The marginalization of the Aqaba Bedouin from Sharm el-Sheikh
is a consequence of the type of tourism development undertaken by
the Egyptian authorities. The successful acquisition of tribal land and
the supremacy of resort tourism have allowed authorities to prevent
the Bedouin from participating in the booming economy of Sharm
by giving primacy to large multinationals and wealthy Egyptian
businessmen. The Bedouin recognize this as a possible future for
Dahab, and equate government support for Egyptian development as
an attempt to seize control of Dahab in order to transform it into
a new Sharm el-Sheikh. This comparison highlights the inability of
the Bedouin to penetrate the resort sector of the tourist economy.
Egyptian development schemes have encouraged this trend and the
authorities see tourism in Sharm el-Sheikh as a major success of Sinai
development.
While marginalization of the Bedouin may not be explicitly linked
to this success, it does show that Egyptian development goals aim to
grant the government sweeping control of tourist centers, making it
easier for them to implement their preferences for development and
employment. In fact, in the spaces where the Bedouin have been
able to maintain contact with the tourism industry through informal
economic ties, Egypt has perceived a failure to implement its vision
for tourism development. Dahab is a manifestation of this trend;
Sharm el-Sheikh is the opposite. The Egyptian authorities do not
explicitly blame this failure on the presence of the Bedouin, but the
same factors preserving Bedouin participation have acted as obstacles
to the crystallization of resort tourism in a town such as Dahab. This
has necessarily linked Bedouin presence to Egyptian disappointment,
further helping to shape official attitudes towards the Bedouin. Thus
the Bedouin have come to be associated with the illicit reputations of
a town such as Dahab, and the Egyptians have treated them as more
of an obstacle than as potential partners.
Concluding Remarks
The Bedouin are at a distinct disadvantage vis-à-vis Egyptian migrants
due to Egyptian development preferences and bureaucratic norms,
Chapter 3
122
which have led to their increasing marginalization through the
imposition of legal barriers frustrating the equitable participation
of the Bedouin in certain sectors of the economy. Moreover, as
development proceeds, the Egyptian government is claiming more
territory and using more of Sinai’s scarce natural resources while
excluding the Bedouin from a protected role in emerging economies.
The Egyptian state’s claim to the best pieces of property along the
shore for tourism development, as well as their enactment of a number
of legal restrictions on Bedouin activities, have further limited the
Bedouins’ access to business opportunities as well as fishing sites and
coastal date oases. Development is replacing the Bedouins’ traditional
social space, but Egyptian policies have attempted to block Bedouin
incorporation into the emerging market.
The Bedouin, excluded from the formal tourist economy and
exceedingly pushed from their land, have viewed this marginalization
as an attempt by the central Egyptian authorities to grab territory
and resources from the Bedouin for themselves, and even more
drastically, to destroy their cultural uniqueness and heritage in the
Sinai. Economically, they have coped with this marginalization by
turning to illicit economic activities to supplement their dwindling
informal contacts. This has led to official perceptions of the Bedouin
as dangerous, dishonest, and even criminal, which has helped shape
the adversarial nature of the relationship between Egyptian officials
and Aqaba Bedouin.
While original Egyptian goals for tourism development created a
system whereby the native Bedouin population could be excluded from
the developing economy, tourism development in Dahab has ensured
a Bedouin role in the future economies of the town. The Bedouin
are well established in Dahab and are well connected within Dahab’s
tourist economy, but they have nevertheless had to compete with
Egyptian migrants to acquire jobs. This competition has shaped the
social patterns of Dahab, involving the Bedouin, Egyptian migrants,
and foreign tourists. The economic roles assumed by each group and
the competition between them have largely shaped the social patterns
regulating the town.
123
Chapter 4
Evolving Social Contacts
and Frameworks
Sinai development has fundamentally changed the nature of the
Aqaba Coast Bedouins’ social space. In addition to an accelerating
influx of foreign tourists and Egyptian migrant workers, new sources
of income and access to services concentrated in tourist towns have
facilitated a process of sedentarization, leading Bedouin populations
to seek permanent settlement in urban neighborhoods such as ‘Asala
in Dahab. Furthermore, participation in the developing economy
and the increased presence of state authorities have necessitated
the establishment of individual contacts between the authorities
and tribesmen, undermining the persistence of tribal corporatism.
Additionally, the continuing expansion of tourism has created for the
Bedouin a reality of daily contact with foreign social groups, leading
to a self-perception embedded in a much wider social space than
merely Sinai or even Egypt. The institutionalization of the relationship
between the Bedouin and these different groups has played a major
role in the processes of cultural change and identity transformation.
The very nature of Bedouin contact with Egyptian officials
and migrants is playing a differentiating role in reinforcing identity
boundaries. While the Aqaba Bedouin and Nile Valley Egyptians share
an increasing number of cultural similarities, including the adoption
of similar patterns of urban settlement, acculturation and increasing
contact are not leading to an erosion of a particularistic identity for
the Bedouin. Instead, uneven Egyptian development policies and
the resulting economic competition have been the primary factors
defining the Bedouin-Egyptian relationship, which is marked by mutual
exclusion and hostility. In examining the nature of the social ties that
have formed between the Aqaba Bedouin and the Egyptians, as well
as the sources of cultural change favored by the Bedouin, it is clear
that there is a link between the economic and social relationships that
have formed between these groups. Egyptian development policies,
Chapter 4
124
which played a primary role in shaping the economic contacts between
the Bedouin and the Egyptians, have also assumed an important role
in the evolving social relationship that has formed between these
Bedouin and central Egypt.
Bedouin contact with foreign tourists has had a significantly
different effect than contact with Egyptians. While the conflict-ridden
relationship between Egyptians and Bedouin stems from a competitive,
adversarial relationship, the economic complementarity between
foreigners and the Bedouin has led to the establishment of relationships
of a different nature. A major element of the Bedouin-foreigner
relationship is its quid pro quo character. While many travelers seek
out the Bedouin to learn about their culture and experience it as part of
their vacation, the Bedouin have in turn actively absorbed many values
and interests of the tourists. Bedouin attitudes towards consumerism,
entertainment, social mobility, and even to some extent sexuality in
South Sinai have all been affected by the relationship with visitors
from the cosmopolitan global North. Slowly but surely, the Bedouin
are becoming increasingly familiar with a global, cosmopolitan society,
incorporating and communicating various elements of Northern culture
into their own cultural frameworks. Furthermore, the articulation of
current forms of Bedouin self-identity, especially among the youth,
cannot be understood without referring to cultural symbols that might
be considered foreign to the Bedouin.
Transforming Patterns of Social
Organization — A Decline in “Tribalism”
Perhaps the most fundamental transformation among the Bedouin
in response to development in Sinai has been the start of a process
of sedentarization and urbanization, with Bedouin families moving
into neighborhoods in expanding urban centers such as Dahab. It is
equally clear that the previously-mentioned economic consequences of
sedentarization, for example the decline in the importance of pastoral
migrations and the maintenance of subsistence economies, have been
accompanied by analogous social consequences. The major social
effect of these processes has been a weakening of patterns of “tribal”
organization; in the transition to life in the town, reliance on tribal
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
125
social structures and sources of authority has decreased. While this
type of transformation has often been identified as a transition away
from “traditional” societies, it should instead be primarily understood
as the social manifestation of economic adaptation to urban markets.
Emanuel Marx has theorized that the tribe functions as a unit of
subsistence whose members work together to exploit the resources
of a given territory. He further shows how tribal divisions and
genealogies, based on the dual concepts of agnation and kinship, play
the vital role of establishing position and membership (belonging) in
this unit and how they regulate the way in which tribesmen cooperate
to exploit their territories and resources.171 In light of this approach,
tribal structure may be understood as an organizational system geared
towards regulating the subsistence economies of the Bedouin, aimed
at solving problems of resource distribution. From this perspective,
we may hypothesize that tribal structures and ties of solidarity will
be at their strongest when tribesmen must activate and rely on their
subsistence economies and kinship networks, and they will be at
their weakest when non-subsistence or socially diverse opportunities
are widely available. As it turns out, both of these predictions hold
true. Various researchers have demonstrated that tribal maintenance
activities intensify in times of economic uncertainly, such as in the
wake of the October War of 1973, when tribesmen had to fall back
on their subsistence economies to mitigate the effects of conflict.
I have also observed a decline in tribal solidarity in the wake of
sedentarization and participation in the urban economy, for example,
in various expressions of economic individualism that have come at
the expense of tribal strength and cohesion, the younger generation’s
shaky knowledge of their genealogies and kinship ties, as well as the
declining influence of tribal shaykhs among urbanized Bedouin.
For the young, urban Bedouin, tribal social structures have not
played a vital role in governing emerging forms of social organization
because they are not needed to regulate their economic patterns
within the town. Furthermore, when asked about tribal genealogies
or the structure of their tribe, the Bedouin who were born and grew
171. See Emanuel Marx, “The Tribe as a Unit of Subsistence: Nomadic
Pastoralism in the Middle East,” American Anthropologist 79.2
(1977).
Chapter 4
126
up exclusively in an urban setting were unable to discuss these topics
in any specific manner. On the other hand, among the Bedouin who
have had the experience of living outside of an urban, market-driven
setting, knowledge of tribal structures and their genealogies has
remained intact. These two processes, urbanization on the one hand
and a relative weakening in tribal social organization on the other, are
linked. However, they are not unidirectional, meaning that it is not
valid to express this as a one-time process of “sedentarization” leading
to the rejection of tribal patterns of organization. Instead, social
reorganization among the urbanizing Bedouin should be conceived
in a manner similar to their economic transformation, an attempt to
balance opportunity with security and self-reliance. Thus, in addition
to a certain level of social reorganization within the town, a number
of social practices that could be considered traditionally tribal have
been maintained, such as the respect for Bedouin customary law,
gender and generational relations within the Bedouin community, as
well as broader tribal loyalties. Notably, however, non-tribal Egyptian
populations tend to reflect similar values, suggesting there is nothing
inherently “tribal” about many of these cultural practices.
As Marx points out, “Where secure employment is found outside
the pastoral field, the maintenance of boundaries and control over
access to territory becomes less important, and this may lead to a
reorganization of tribesmen in other frameworks.”172 This is exactly
what is happening in the urban centers of the Aqaba region, but
it has not led to a fundamental change in the social identity of the
Bedouin, merely the adaptation of certain social structures to help
the Bedouin integrate into a sedentary, urban, and market-driven
environment. Tribal membership has been maintained, but the social
organization of the urban Bedouin community has changed to reflect
the necessities of urban life. Similar conclusions have been presented
by Lila Abu Lughod, who showed that urbanization, notably in the
Egyptian coastal city of Marsa Matruh, often led to weakening kin
structures, which were in many cases replaced with forms of urban
solidarity, sometimes described as “ethnic” mobilization.173
172. Ibid., p. 344.
173. Abu Lughod, Veiled Sentiments, p. 77.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
127
The Bedouin and the Egyptians
The Egyptian is sick from ful and tamiyyah. It makes him act crazy.
174
I do not like Egyptian people, whatever they tell you, don’t trust them.
175
The Bedouin, they are a stupid people. Not like the Egyptian people.
176
The Bedouin have tried to avoid Egyptian migrants on a social level;
there is very little contact between the two groups outside of necessary
economic exchanges and the limited instances of Bedouin employment
in Egyptian businesses. While the Bedouin and the Egyptian migrants
in Dahab compete in town for economic opportunities, the two
communities are socially self-segregating. As Bedouin prefer to work
with other Bedouin, and Egyptians prefer to hire other Egyptians,
Dahab as a market is not a forum for the establishment of extensive
economic ties between the two groups, and cooperation is limited.
This has translated into little social interaction.177
Additionally, there exists a physical social divide in Dahab. The
southern areas of Masbat and Mashraba are dominated by Egyptians
and the northern areas, known as the Lighthouse, Eel Garden, and
‘Asala, as well as the few scattered bars and nightclubs, are centers
of Bedouin-tourist social interaction. While during the day there is
a fairly high level of overlap, after business hours, each community
confines itself to its respective area. By night, Mashraba has come
to resemble a small neighborhood in Cairo, dotted with cafes where
migrant workers smoke shisha, watch football or the news, and
play checkers or backgammon with other migrants. The restaurants
claim to serve “real Egyptian food,” which from their menus, is often
koshary, kofta, and ta‘amiyya (Egyptian falafel).178 It is quite rare for
any Bedouin to be seen in this area in the evenings, just as it is rare to
174. Statement by Bedouin in conversation, May 14, 2009.
175. Statement by Bedouin in conversation, April 12, 2009.
176. Interview with Egyptian shop owner, February 10, 2010.
177. This is not categorical; there are many Bedouin in Dahab who have
formed friendships with migrants from Egypt. It should also not be taken
as a claim that there is a lack of civility between the two communities.
178. Koshary and Kofta are two foods commonly found in central Egypt.
Kofta is a type of kebab made from ground beef, while koshary, often
Chapter 4
128
see Egyptian migrants in Bedouin neighborhoods or in the bars and
clubs frequented by Bedouin youths.
While the Bedouin continue to honor hospitality, a number of
Bedouin have told us that they would never invite an Egyptian back
to their homes.179 In fact, there is practically no Egyptian presence in
the Bedouin neighborhoods outside of business and the few Egyptian
families that have permanently settled there; Egyptian migrants
avoid entering them. I have noticed that a number of Egyptians have
purchased “vacation homes” in these areas, much to the dismay of
their Bedouin neighbors, who complain about their bad habits, which
generally involve some type of behavior that disrupts the tranquility
of the neighborhood.180 The Bedouin claim that Egyptians are not
welcome, and a number of our Bedouin acquaintances have even
declared a willingness to confront any Egyptian who is found near
their homes after dark, asserting that Bedouin spaces would be
dangerous for Egyptians to enter. This attitude does not appear to
reflect a fear that the Egyptians would harm the Bedouin or pose
any kind of threat, for the Bedouin do not communicate any sense of
fear regarding potential Egyptian actions in Bedouin neighborhoods.
Instead, it merely highlights the high level of hostility many Bedouin
hold against Egyptians. Bravado or not, this constitutes yet another
manifestation of their view of Egyptians as outsiders and reveals
the great social distance that exists between the Bedouin and the
Egyptians in Dahab.
The stories that are told of Bedouin-Egyptian interactions generally
involve confrontation and violence. I occasionally hear stories of
groups of Egyptians entering Bedouin neighborhoods. The response,
according to these stories, is a mobilization of Bedouin to confront the
Egyptians, generally leading to some kind of argument or even clash
between the two groups. This trend of action and reaction is fairly
normative in Bedouin accounts. A Bedouin interviewee described one
such encounter, which ended in an outbreak of hostilities necessitating
police intervention. He explained that the conflict had started when a
attributed to military innovation, is a combination of rice, lentils, and
pasta covered in tomato sauce with various toppings.
179. Interview with a Bedouin resident of ‘Asala, April 10, 2009.
180. Conversation with Bedouin residents, July 5, 2011; May 26, 2012.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
129
group of Egyptians confronted a Bedouin one evening near his home
regarding a contract dispute between two individuals; the conflict
soon escalated beyond simple words. When news of the arrival of this
group of Egyptians spread around the neighborhood, many Bedouin
went to support their co-ethnics, leading to an outbreak of violence
in the streets of ‘Asala. He went on to explain that this is a typical
reaction from the Bedouin in such a situation, because hostility and
confrontation were an expected part of Bedouin-Egyptian social
encounters.181 He further explained that these conflicts were most
frequently centered on some type of economic dispute, often over
land or money, reflecting the economic motivation behind much of
the Bedouin-Egyptian social tension.
During my time in Dahab, I witnessed a number of Bedouin-
Egyptian disputes over land or money, but have never personally
witnessed an escalation of this type; I cannot discount the possibility
that these stories may be displays of bravado aimed to impress. In
either case, they demonstrate popular perceptions and attitudes held
by many Bedouin towards Egyptian migrants. Such a story may even
be more revealing of Bedouin attitudes if the event did not actually
take place but rather was imagined, due to its scripted nature.
The Egyptian government has not given the Bedouin a significant
voice in determining development policies in Sinai; they instead
proceed according to their needs and force the Bedouin to cope with
changes without any support or acknowledgement of their hardships.
In a number of related ways, this has led to the categorization of the
Bedouin as an “indigenous people” in Sinai. As an indigenous people,
the Bedouin, a non-state group, have been forced into conflict with
the central state; the state seeks to impose the values and identities
of dominant society while the group seeks official recognition of
their cultural and territorial rights.182 This is not an inherent conflict
between two competing social groups, but a consequence of trends
in development and integration policies as the state aims to increase
its level of control over the full extent of its territory and population.
Territorial disputes and heritage defense in the face of radical
181. Interview with Bedouin about Egyptians, February 11, 2010.
182. Anthony D. Smith, The Ethnic Revival (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1981), p. 6.
Chapter 4
130
transformation and marginalization spurred by the state are major
elements of the conflict between indigenous peoples and the state,
instigated by hegemonic state policies.
One notable consequence of this situation is the inability of those
controlling the central government—i.e., the hegemonic social group
within the state—to extend their identity to the indigenous periphery.
Instead, the Bedouin believe that state policies, whether intentional
or not, pose a danger to the continued existence and wellbeing of the
Bedouin as an autonomous social group. This has led the Bedouin
to mount a defense of their cultural distinctiveness and distance
themselves from dominant national identities while claiming privileged
access to local territory. This process is directly linked to the clash of
economic interests described in the previous chapter. Like the basic
incompatibility between Bedouin and Egyptian goals of economic
development, the divergence between the Egyptians and the Bedouin
in terms of social values plays a role in defining and regulating the
identity boundary between them.
Both the Bedouin and the Egyptians have created negative
stereotypes of the other, and the attitudes of each group regarding
the other can be found in their statements and characterizations.
These images and stereotypes provide valuable insight into how the
Bedouin perceive the Egyptians as well as themselves and vice versa.
An examination of these attitudes is a necessary step to illuminate the
social boundary and decipher the processes of identity transformation
among the Bedouin.
The attitudes of the Aqaba Bedouin towards Egyptians reflect
the statements of other Bedouin groups regarding settled Egyptian
society, notably the Awlad ‘Ali Bedouin studied by Lila Abu Lughod.
First and foremost, the Bedouin perceive an incompatibility between
an Egyptian and an Arab identity. The Bedouin interviewed in this
study did not conceive of themselves as Egyptians; the statement “I
am not Egyptian, I am Bedouin” was common.183 The Bedouin claim
origins in the Arabian Desert, and consider themselves to be true
Arabs. Egyptians, on the other hand, originate in the Nile Valley and,
183. Personal observations and conversations with the Bedouin about their
legacy and identity; see also Gardner, “At Home in South Sinai,” p.
49.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
131
according to the Bedouin, are not true Arabs. In a conversation with a
group of Bedouin on the beach in Dahab, an Egyptian was pointed out
to me. One of my Bedouin friends leaned over and in a conspiratorial
tone whispered “Hatha pharown” (he is Pharaonic), to which I replied
“Mish ‘Arabi?” (not Arab?). Smiling, he responded “Aywah, mish
‘Arabi” (yes, not Arab), clearly pleased that I was able to distinguish
between their conception of Arabs and Egyptians.184 For the Bedouin,
there is a fundamental incompatibility between the images of Egypt’s
Arab character and its pre-Islamic history linked to the legacy of the
Pharaonic and Coptic periods; in the eyes of the Bedouin, Egypt’s
pre-Islamic heritage has undermined its Arab and Muslim legitimacy.
This presents a fundamental challenge to notions of common descent
despite the Arab Muslim character claimed by both populations.
The Bedouin conceive of the Egyptians as descended from a pagan
riverain (Nilotic) past, which they contrast with their noble Arabian
desert origins.
In a similar manner to the Western Desert Bedouin, the Sinai
Bedouin disparage Nile Valley Egyptians as “farmers” (fellahin),185
a label to which many negative qualities have been attributed. At
the most basic level, the Bedouin portray the fellahin as dishonest
thieves. In contrast, the fellahin attribute to themselves the quality of
karama’ (nobility or generosity). The Bedouin vigorously contest this
claim by attaching pejorative qualities to them such as lack of honesty,
honor, and intelligence. This can be directly related to Abu Lughod’s
discussion of Awlad ‘Ali attitudes towards Egyptians, in which she
shows that the Bedouin consider the fellah to lack sharaf (honor),
sadag (honesty), and karama (generosity).186
Abu Lughod has further shown that the Western Desert Bedouin
perceive Egyptian behavior to be feminine and dishonorable. I have
heard similar comments from the Aqaba Bedouin, who also view
Egyptian men as feminine and Egyptian women as manly; in general,
184. Day at the Laguna, April 11, 2009.
185. The literal translation of the Arabic fellah is ‘peasant,’ however, the
Aqaba Bedouin use the English term ‘farmer’ instead when referring to
fellahin. This translation has been reproduced by the author to reflect
Bedouin statements.
186. Abu Lughod, Veiled Sentiments, p. 45.
Chapter 4
132
Egyptian behavior is often described in feminine terms. One notable
example is the dim view they take of Nile Valley male bonding
habits, including men hugging and kissing each other in greeting and
holding hands while walking together down the street (see Figure 11).
According to our interviewees, Bedouin men would never behave
in this way, as such behavior is only an activity for women.187 They
furthermore criticize Egyptian men for being subordinate to their
women, for following behind them in the street and for doting on
them. The Bedouin agree that true masculine behavior means the
man must set the boundaries and control his wife.
As the greatest source of competition between the Bedouin and
the Egyptians has been in the economic sphere, the Aqaba Bedouins’
greatest criticism of the Egyptians revolves around business practices.
The Bedouin accuse Egyptian migrants of constantly hassling tourists,
187. Interview with Bedouin (men and women) about Egyptian male bonding,
May 15, 2009.
Figure 11: Cairene youths strolling in the Khan al-Khalili.
Photo by author, September21, 2009.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
133
trying to convince them to spend money, and claim that this has given
both the Egyptians and the Bedouin a bad image in the eyes of the
tourists. A number of Bedouin complained that Egyptian migrants
traveled to Sinai solely to make money from the tourists, but that their
business practices were dishonorable and their tendencies to lie and
cheat their customers have given tourists bad impressions of the people
who work in town. This has created a situation in which the Bedouin
communicate a belief that poor Egyptian behavior will alienate the
tourists from the towns of South Sinai, which will have devastating
economic consequences for the Bedouin.188 In their view, the Bedouin
are not merely victims of aggressive Egyptian economic policies, but
have also fallen victim to dishonorable Egyptian behavior.189 These
types of statements support the argument that social perceptions are
closely linked to economic conditions.
In turn, negative stereotypes of the Bedouin are perpetuated among
Egyptian migrants and officials in Sinai.190 Some of these attitudes
were described earlier, but here it becomes important to examine the
deeper significance behind them. First of all, the Egyptians believe the
Bedouin are lazy, that they prefer poverty to manual labor, and that
furthermore, they are primitive and will retain primitive economies
because they are incapable of integrating into “modern” economic
systems without radical transformation. Reinforcing this stereotype is
the perception of the Bedouin as unskilled and uneducated, leading
to frequent descriptions of the Bedouin as stupid, as expressed
in the quotation at the beginning of this section. This attitude was
reflected in the 1985 Sinai Development Study, and appears to have
remained the basic assumption regarding Bedouin behavior on the
part of the Egyptian authorities to this day despite visible signs of
Bedouin integration into the urban economy. Despite this focus on
transformation, Egyptians continue to “see” the Bedouin through an
188. Conversation with Bedouin about Egyptians, April 12, 2009.
189. Conversation about trip to Cairo, September 22, 2009.
190. During interviews in Cairo, I found that those who have had little
exposure to the Bedouin in reality tended to take a more ambivalent
attitude towards the Bedouin and speak in the abstract. They reflected
the media’s negative portrayal, but often added that the Qur’an refers to
the tribes as “noble.”
Chapter 4
134
essentialist lens, where the label “Bedouin” automatically implies the
above social characteristics. And despite clear signs of integration,
many Egyptians believe that to be “Bedouin” means to remain
traditional and nomadic, and there is a powerful tendency to view
them as such.
A second but related stereotype is of the Bedouin as dangerous
and untrustworthy. This is a stereotype perpetuated by Egyptian
authorities, who have come to associate the Sinai Bedouin with
activities such as drug cultivation, smuggling, human trafficking,
and even terrorism and espionage along with a number of smaller
vices frequently mentioned in the Egyptian media. Reinforcing this
stereotype is the hostility the Bedouin hold against the government
and Egyptian migrant workers. Egyptians perceive the hostility to
them as a general tendency to be hostile to all outsiders, and they
have attempted to present the Bedouin as dangerous.191 In the event
that Bedouin and backpackers are seen traveling together, there is
an immediate suspicion that they are participating in some kind of
illegal activity. In one such event, I was detained for over four hours in
el-Tor, evidently due to a suspicion that my traveling companion and
I, who were in el-Tor with three Bedouin friends, were Israeli spies
sent to gather information on Egyptian elections. This is the level of
mistrust and suspicion in which the authorities hold the Bedouin and
their associates. While the incident was largely a misunderstanding,
one major question posed to us was why we felt we had to travel with
three Bedouin. In the future, the authorities suggested, it would be
better to hire an official taxi.
How can these attitudes be analyzed? Anthropology conceives of
stereotypes as a method for members of social groups to “fit their
neighbors and acquaintances into categories which determine the mode
of behavior towards them.”192 In this way, stereotyping is a method
191. “Six arrested, drugs seized in south Sinai bust,” Agence France-Presse,
February 27, 1997; see also Hobbs, “The Opium Poppy in Egypt,” 79-
80. See also the volumes of news articles tying the Bedouin to the terror
attacks of the 2000s in Southeastern Sinai and the reports of Bedouin
violence and agitation against Egyptian authorities.
192. J. Clyde Mitchell, The Kalela Dance (Manchester: Manchester
University Press, 1956), 32. While this quote was written in the 1950s,
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
135
of ordering the social world, delineating categories of people based
on generalized concepts of who they are and what they do. A similar
definition, put forth by a social psychologist, conceives of stereotyping
as “a means whereby kinds of objects (people) are classified on the
basis of perceived properties, thus facilitating a meaningful response
to those objects.”193 Along these lines, stereotypes do not need to
reflect reality, but they must be generally accepted by others in order
to have social meaning.194 While there are a number of possible uses
for stereotypes, the Bedouin and Egyptian examples represent two
distinct cases.
First is the case of Bedouin stereotypes of Egyptians. These
stereotypes focus heavily on putting down Egyptians by attaching
pejorative qualities to them to which Bedouin qualities can be
positively contrasted, notably regarding attributes considered to be
honorable. Thus, while the Bedouin see themselves as noble and
generous, they label the Egyptians as dishonest and greedy, focusing
their stereotypes on perceptions of invasion and aggression. This sets
and hardens boundaries between social groups. These stereotypes
“inform the individual of the virtues of his or her own group and the
vices of the other, and thereby serve to justify thinking that ‘I am an
X and not a Y.’”195 In this way, negative stereotypes of Egyptians
are one form of defending one’s own culture from an encroaching,
foreign culture. In terms of identity boundaries, these stereotypes are
tools to communicate fundamental cultural incompatibilities between
two social groups, reinforcing the perception that members of group
Y (Egyptians) do not share the same basic values as members of
group X (Bedouin), undermining the value and legitimacy of Egyptian
identity in the eyes of the Bedouin.
In the case of Egyptian stereotypes of the Bedouin, these attitudes
shape the way in which Egyptians interact with the Bedouin,
contemporary social anthropologists, especially those focusing on
ethnicity and ethnic relations, agree that this function of stereotyping
continues to have social relevance today.
193. John C. Brigham, “Ethnic Stereotypes,” Psychological Bulletin 76.1
(1971), p. 18.
194. Eriksen, Ethnicity and Nationalism, p. 25.
195. Ibid.
Chapter 4
136
providing justification for their unbalanced policies. By labeling the
Bedouin primitive and unskilled, there is ex ante motivation and ex
post validation for the marginalization of the Bedouin from the fruits
of economic development. Furthermore, by labeling the Bedouin as
dangerous or criminal, authorities justify maintaining tighter control
over the population and distancing the Bedouin from tourists, although
the true reason may be a desire to limit Bedouin-tourist interaction
for the benefit of Egyptian migrants. In terms of Bedouin identity,
these stereotypes are prescriptive and constraining. Such stereotypes,
created and perpetuated by dominant social groups, enable those
controlling the state to place certain restrictions on the Bedouin
and perpetuate negative attitudes while also having the function of
ascribing “acceptable” roles and relationships the Bedouin may adopt
in their national context. The main difference between stereotypes
created by hegemonic groups and those created by peripheral groups
is the power—coercive, constitutive, and institutional—that lies behind
hegemonic stereotypes.196 While it may appear that the Bedouin and
the Egyptians use these stereotypes in different manners, in fact both
employ stereotypes to regulate inter-group interaction. And while
such stereotypes may be entirely false at the outset, in time such
groups may come to internalize some of their images, leading to a
cycle of ascription and reflection known as altercasting, a subject that
will arise again in the next chapter.197
This is a consequence of the uneven power relations that exist
between the hegemonic social group and the periphery; the state
has the capability of reifying its perceptions of other social groups
through its official policies and enforcement mechanisms. Returning
to Wendt’s maxim “If men define situations as real, they are real
in their consequences,” I suggest a refinement of this statement to
include a consideration of power: If men define situations as real,
and have the power to reify those definitions, then they generate real
196. For a discussion of different types of power, see Michael N. Barnett and
Raymond D. Duvall, “Power in International Politics,” International
Organization 591 (2005), pp. 39–75.
197. Eugene A. Weinstein and Paul Deutschberger, “Some Dimensions of
Altercasting,” Sociometry 26.4 (1963).
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
137
consequences.198 This power is why the state has the ability to ascribe
acceptable roles and relationships, whereas the Bedouin can merely
contest these definitions. Furthermore, this explains why state law
consistently dominates Bedouin customary law except in zones the
state is unable to penetrate. The importance of this type of social
interaction for identity formation is not merely in the conception of
“who we are,” but of “who we are in relation to everyone else,” which
focuses on roles and relationships “acceptable” (as defined by the
dominant power) within heterogeneous social contexts.
Stereotyping is a method in which social groups define
boundaries and membership and give order to a heterogeneous social
arena. This order is manifested by patterns of social interaction that
reflect concepts of social distance, such as barring Egyptians from
Bedouin neighborhoods, and value incompatibility, reflected in the
competition between Egyptian goals and Bedouin interests for Sinai
development. It is a primary way of dealing with the institutionalization
of social relations between distinct groups and of coping with
processes of integration. Importantly, cultural stereotypes develop in
situations of close contact between social groups. The presence of
stereotypes is one indicator of the presence of boundaries between
distinct social groups, and they contribute to the ordering of relations
between them.
The Bedouin and Tourists
As opposed to the hostility that developed between the Aqaba
Bedouin and Egyptian migrants, relations between the Bedouin and
foreign tourists are often marked by warmth and a high degree of
cross-cultural exchange. While the Bedouin perceive the Egyptians as
a threat to their livelihood and heritage, tourists play the opposite role.
Not only do tourists not pose a threat to Bedouin social distinctiveness,
they actually provide an outlet for the Bedouin to communicate and
profit from their culture. Conversely, while the Bedouin have openly
rejected Egyptian cultural symbols and values, they consume tourist
198. Wendt, Social Theory of International Politics, p. 330.
Chapter 4
138
culture, representative of the global North, with fascination. Tourism
has provided the primary medium through which the Aqaba Bedouin
adopt new values and symbols. While for the purposes of tourism,
Bedouin culture reflects a high level of traditionalization (the defense
of concepts of tradition and an attempt to maintain them), there is
no denying that the culture of the tourists has had a profound effect
on the social patterns of the Dahab Bedouin. This not only includes
the adoption of new tastes in music and dress, but also changing
perceptions of modesty and social mobility.
Many among the younger generation of Bedouin in Dahab are
genuinely interested in forming close relationships with foreign tourists
and experiencing their culture. They describe these relationships as
free, as opposed to the social conventions regulating relationships
between the Bedouin, or the hostility regulating Egyptian-Bedouin
relations. A number of Bedouin have even confided that they feel they
relate to foreigners better than they do to older Bedouin, indicating
the emergence of a rather wide generational gap in the Bedouin
community.199 These relationships are forged in Dahab and are
maintained through visits and the establishment of permanent lines of
communication between the Bedouin and their friends. Most recently,
this has been accomplished through the internet and social networking
sites such as Facebook, which has become the forum for Bedouin youth
to maintain relationships with foreigners. Through these connections,
the Bedouin are able to maintain their links outside of Sinai and
achieve a greater understanding of foreign culture, increasingly able
to place themselves in a global context instead of merely an Egyptian
one. Foreign cultural symbols have become a daily part of Bedouin
life through interaction with tourists, exposure to foreign television
such as MTV and BBC, as well as the internet. For their part, the
Bedouin are actively absorbing these cultural symbols and taking pride
in being able to show the impact of foreign culture on their own lives.
199. Conversation with Bedouin women about relationships with foreigners,
April 12, 2009. I also had the opportunity to witness a rather rude
interaction between a group of urban Bedouin youth and their elders at
a wedding to which the youth brought alcohol and tourist women who
were considered inappropriately dressed. Their response was that their
elders are behind the times.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
139
Furthermore, these Bedouin have begun to understand their existence
in a global context and begun to express themselves as part of a global
youth culture that connects them to the foreigners visiting Dahab. In a
number of cases, they have begun deploying adopted foreign symbols
to express evolving Bedouin values.
Pop Culture and Dress
The popular culture preferences of the Aqaba Bedouin are largely
informed by processes of media globalization through television and
internet, which are now widely available in Bedouin homes in Dahab,
and by their social interactions with tourists. Through these channels,
the Bedouin have begun to embrace certain symbols of Northern
culture, adapting them to reflect both local values and values they see
as shared with foreign youth.
MTV has become a popular station among the Bedouin youth,
and their exposure to international media has allowed them to follow
Northern popular culture. Among the Aqaba Bedouin, Hip Hop and
R&B are two genres of music that have become immensely popular.
One Bedouin, just a few years younger than myself, has even organized
a Bedouin break-dancing troupe consisting of himself and four of his
friends, performing to the songs of artists such as Akon and 50 Cent,
icons of the American Hip Hop scene. The Bedouin see this music as
a reflection of a romantic life of freedom and prosperity (associated
with the images contained in their music videos), and have begun to
identify with this genre of music. They have furthermore begun to
identify with HipHop as a form of counter-culture expression, seeing
themselves in a similar context to oppressed groups in other states,
such as African Americans or French Muslims, for whom Hip Hop is
also a popular form of expression.
The Bedouin have adopted these symbols and have begun to
reflect them as an organic part of their own culture.200 To an extent,
Bedouin youth identify with African-American expression due to their
perception that they, like the African-American community, have
200. These Bedouin occasionally brag that it was the Arabs who first invented
Hip Hop through their tradition of extemporaneous poetry.
Chapter 4
140
been the victims of discrimination by their government. As a result,
a number of Bedouin have adopted African-American social symbols,
such as “bling” (large chain necklaces), wide-brimmed baseball caps,
and as mentioned above, Hip Hop. These adopted symbols have not
been adapted to reflect traditional Bedouin values, but reveal that the
Bedouin are identifying with and adopting foreign values that reflect
similar a sociopolitical contexts and status. It is important to note that
they still express a strong sense of Bedouin identity despite these
transformations. This type of social change does not undermine their
“Bedouin” identity, which is communicated as entirely complimentary,
but is deployed as a challenge to “Egyptian” identities and Egyptian
processes of nation-building. This relation to the political condition
of social groups in other states, as opposed to the acceptance of
national (Egyptian) solidarities, clearly proves the extent to which
the Bedouin are aware of their role in Egyptian society as well as
in expanding global culture. It further indicates the possibility that
similar government policies, irrespective of national borders, have the
potential to elicit similar identity processes that transcend nationalism
or national identities.
The standard dress for Bedouin males has been the jalabiyya, the
robe worn by the Bedouin as well as many Egyptians. This dress is
the only style among many older Bedouin, but among the younger
generation, the jalabiyya is beginning to lose its popularity. For many
Bedouin youth, it has become a traditional dress, worn only on special
occasions when participating in tribal activities. In Dahab, on the other
hand, many Bedouin have adopted what they might consider the
“traditional dress” of the tourists, which is frequently a flashy t-shirt
and a pair of board shorts or jeans. This uniform is common among
younger Bedouin males, as are items such as European football
jerseys and baseball caps. Notable sports clubs, such as FC Barcelona,
Manchester United, and the New York Yankees, have become popular
among the Bedouin, who now follow their favorite European sports
teams on television and the internet. In this way the Bedouin are able
to present themselves as socially similar to the tourists, with patterns
of dress and popular culture communicating familiarity.
Among young Bedouin women, there is alimited trend towards
decreasing personal modesty in the presence of foreigners. In the
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
141
presence of elder Bedouin, Bedouin women maintain a high level of
modesty, continuing to cover their head and body with a black abaya.
In the presence of their foreign friends, however, these girls often
uncover their faces, and even occasionally remove the hijab (headscarf)
altogether. Bedouin concepts of modesty have been tempered when
interacting with foreign friends. One female Bedouin, 26 years
old, said that she felt uncomfortable in the black abaya because it
drew attention to the fact that she was different among her foreign
friends.201 While inter-Bedouin relations, notably between genders and
generations, continue to be regulated by social convention, increasing
contact with foreigners has induced a number of Bedouin to embrace
external cultural values.
Clearly one of the ways the Bedouin are attempting to maintain
ties with foreigners is the adoption of foreign cultural symbols, which
increases familiarity and comfort among both Bedouin and tourists
201. Conversation with Bedouin female about relationships with foreigners,
February 12, 2010.
Figure 12: New forms of Bedouin dress.
Photo by author, February 11, 2010.
Chapter 4
142
in their interactions. In this way, the adoption of tourist culture is an
expression of tourist-Bedouin social compatibility. While empirical
cultural markers between the Bedouin and tourists can occasionally be
quite significant, warm relations reflect a perception of social proximity
or compatibility, based on the economic and social relationship that
has emerged between them.
Sexuality and Gender Relations
Perhaps the most radical social transformation among the young
Aqaba Bedouin has been their changing attitudes towards romance,
marriage, and relationships, especially as relates to the formation
of relationships between Bedouin and foreigners. Many Bedouin
youths maintain romantic relationships with foreigners. While this
phenomenon has been reported among Bedouin (and occasionally
Egyptian) men in Dahab, I was surprised to discover a limited number
of Bedouin girls, in their late teens and twenties, who confided that
they, too, occasionally maintained relationships with foreign men, but
that they had to be kept secret from their elders.202
For the young Bedouin men, notably those who work closely with
foreign tourists, social interactions, especially at bars and nightclubs,
are opportunities for engaging in sexual relationships with female
tourists.203 Simply put, many young women come to places like Dahab
hoping to have an “exotic” sexual experience.204 One woman I met in
Dahab even went as far as to proudly explain that she was traveling
the world having sex with as many “locals” as possible because she
was planning on writing a book about her “exotic” experiences. Due
to the high turnover rate of tourists, who often stay for a week or
less, there is a constantly replenished pool of women in Dahab, and
moreover, relationships tend to be fleeting. It should not come as a
202. Ibid. and various other discussions.
203. Multiple evenings at a Dahab nightclub, May-June 2012.
204. Much work has been done on this subject. For a local example, see
Jessica Jacobs, “Have Sex Will Travel: Romantic ‘Sex Tourism’
and Women Negotiating Modernity in the Sinai,” Gender, Place &
Culture 16.1 (2009).
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
143
surprise that sexual prowess is a status symbol among young Bedouin
men, who frequently discuss their sexual exploits with others. This is
not to link these attitudes to tribal culture in any way, but instead to
acknowledge that this is a fact of youth culture throughout the North,
in places such as America and Europe. It appears to be expressed
even more strongly in vacation destinations such as Dahab, where
tourists tend to be a bit more hedonistic than they might otherwise
be. In a similar vein, the Bedouin tend to be more hedonistic with the
tourists than with members of their own community.
Among both men and women, relationships with foreigners are
preferable to relationships with other Bedouin because they are less
regulated by social convention and are, in an important way, less
demanding. The availability of foreigners for platonic and romantic
relationships has undermined the value of endogamy among the
Bedouin. This has spurred some Bedouin men to seek marriage
outside of their own community (women have not attained this
freedom). Furthermore, the Bedouin have come to greatly appreciate
the freedom that surrounds these relationships, as opposed to the
regulations regarding modesty and respect that exist both within
Egyptian and Bedouin society regulating cross-gender relations.
Whereas in the past, marriage was restricted to fellow tribesmen, often
agnatic kin (such as a paternal cousin), and many would never have
considered marrying outside their tribe, let alone marrying someone
from a settled, non-Muslim population, today, many Bedouin youths in
Dahab say they would prefer to date and marry a foreigner, perceiving
that these relationships grant them greater social freedom. On the
other hand, such relationships and potential marriages carry the risk
of social insecurity. If they become public, the result is often social
ostracization by fellow tribesmen, and if they should fail, it is quite
hard to regain the “face” already lost. Bedouin that rely on the social
security provided by the tribe, even in urban settings, are constrained
in their ability to pursue relationships with foreigners. The ones with
the greatest freedoms are those who are economically self-reliant and
socially closer with the foreign tourists, which once again means those
employed in windsurfing and scuba clubs.
When asked about this preference to carry on relationships and
eventually marry outside the Bedouin community, one interviewee
Chapter 4
144
described how marrying a Bedouin would limit his opportunities
later in life for two primary reasons. First, a foreigner is a symbol of
social mobility for the Bedouin, who are, to an extent, a suppressed
group. Bedouin have limited access to certain areas and are treated
as second-class citizens by the Egyptian authorities. A foreign spouse
would allow the Bedouin to overcome this restriction and escape the
limitations of being Bedouin in Egypt. Prominent examples of the
benefits of marrying a non-Bedouin include the ability to leave Egypt
and get citizenship in another country, the ability to travel around
Egypt on vacation to visit places like Sharm el-Sheikh without being
confronted by Egyptian authorities, and finally, freedom from the
marriage responsibilities of tribal life, such as the necessity to provide a
home and a flock for his future wife.205 Another interviewee described
the desirability of marrying a foreign girl simply: “The European
women, they don’t need goats.” For Dahab’s Bedouin youth, the
requirement to have already provided for a wife has made marriage
almost prohibitive due to Egyptian laws and regulations.
Case Study:
‘Asala — A Developing Bedouin Center
Egyptian, German, Russian, English—everyone comes to Dahab.
Dahab now is an international city. Everybody lives in one land,
with Egyptians, Bedouin, everybody together. We are neighbors
now. My neighbor is Russian. But the city mentality is too much
for many people here. There are many people who aren’t ready for
city life—and nobody trains them or gives them education about
the city, how to live and make business, how to deal with life in the
city. It’s different.
Bedouin community organizer, May 30, 2012.
The neighborhood of ‘Asala is the focus of Bedouin urban
sedentarization in Dahab. The patterns of Bedouin settlement,
social organization, and dependence stemming from processes of
205. Various conversations with Bedouin males regarding marriage, July 22,
2009; September 17, 2009.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
145
development can best be studied within this social space. Not only are
we interested in how the Bedouin have adapted their social patterns
within an urban environment, but we are also interested in the extent
to which patterns of Bedouin settlement mirror patterns of Egyptian
migrant settlement in their goals and structures. This will allow us to
draw conclusions about the main factors encouraging specific types of
social change, notably whether this transformation is fuelled by culture
and tradition, or by certain factors within the process of development
itself.
The most basic examination of ‘Asala involves mapping
demographic patterns of Bedouin settlement within the town stemming
from natural growth as well as migration from desert villages. Looking
at basic demographics, the major difference between the social space
of the town and the village becomes clear. Bedouin villages in Sinai
are frequently based on kinship ties, and each village has the freedom
to regulate its social organization. The town, on the other hand, does
not permit the same kind of freedom due to restrictions on physical
space, which generally leads to clustering and vertical construction as
towns and cities continue to expand. For the sedentarizing Bedouin,
there is a clear preference to reproduce village structures within the
town, that is, to keep kin units in close physical proximity. Where
space is available, brothers and cousins frequently live in neighboring
houses. This not only provides a certain bubble of familiarity and
comfort within the urban space, it also provides natural avenues of
migration for villagers looking to move to the town. It is frequently
the case that young Bedouin from the desert villages of Sinai move
into urban spaces with older kin, giving them a support structure in an
unfamiliar environment.
In these patterns of settlement, there is remarkable similarity to
trends of rural-to-urban migration within central Egypt as shown by
Janet Abu Lughod, notably regarding attempts to reproduce village
structures in urban settings to provide a system of support for new
migrants.206 These settlement patterns create a channel between the
town and the villages to allocate and distribute resources. A number
of Bedouin describe their relationships with their villages of origin and
206. For more on rural urbanization in Cairo, see Abu Lughod, “Migrant
Adjustment to City Life: The Egyptian Case.”
Chapter 4
146
their reasons for moving into Dahab in a manner identical to Egyptian
migrants, as a means to earn a living and to send money back to
their families that have remained in the village. Thus, the model of
migration and remittance is also applicable to the Bedouin. Dahab,
then, has become a source of external income that is sought by
individuals from different social groups for the purpose of supporting
both themselves as well as their villages of origin, which have come
to depend on ties established with urban economies for maintenance.
In this way, Bedouin villages in South Sinai have become dependent
on income from tourism even though they are not directly involved in
tourist activities.
Unlike the social freedom of village organization, however, the
urban environment has a major limitation, that of space. In many
instances, kin are prevented from living in close proximity due to a lack
of available space. This has necessarily forced some Bedouin in ‘Asala
into situations in which they find themselves living next to complete
strangers, unable to ensure their privacy, as well as situations in which
a young Bedouin may have to select a location for his marriage-home
that is quite far from the rest of his kin.
Urbanization, then, has had a major effect on issues such as
familiarity and modesty, and has led to a transformation in the social
space of the Bedouin. The greatest effect has been on women, who
have been forced to spend more of their time indoors in order to
avoid interactions with strangers. The urban space is highly restrictive
due to issues of unfamiliarity. In the Bedouin neighborhoods of ‘Asala
this problem was clearly visible; women and children would vacate
the streets as we walked through them, obviously uncomfortable
with being seen in public by strangers.207 This is not only a Bedouin
207. While this might seem to contradict my earlier statement regarding
decreasing personal modesty around foreign friends and a desire to
form relationships with foreigners, the major issue here is familiarity,
not a general sense of openness. The formation of relationships
between Bedouin women and foreign men is fundamentally connected
to the issue of increasing familiarity, and modesty must continue to be
maintained between strangers. This is not a prohibition against seeking
to increase familiarity, but one against immodesty in close contact with
strange men.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
147
condition, but one applicable to Egyptian women from rural villages,
who, as Janet Abu Lughod aptly explains, have increasingly been
forced indoors and into a life of solitude due to the social restrictions
of unfamiliar contact in an urban environment. Lila Abu Lughod
presents a similar discussion regarding changing social restrictions on
Awlad ‘Ali women in the Western Egyptian Desert as a consequence
of sedentarization and the proximity of unfamiliar neighbors and
visitors.208 Social patterns within urban spaces continue to be regulated
by social convention, even to a greater extent than in villages, despite
changing social realities. Urbanization has inherently undermined the
ability to maintain public modesty, leading to greater restrictions over
women’s freedom and necessitating greater segregation between men
and women.
In Dahab, ‘Asala has grown well beyond its original status as a
loose cluster of Bedouin settlement. As more and more Bedouin
are moving to Dahab, Bedouin neighborhoods are becoming more
crowded. Additionally, the Egyptian and foreign populations of
‘Asala have grown significantly in recent years. While ‘Asala began
as a Bedouin space, the Bedouin have not been able to shape the
demographic patterns of the town to prevent strangers from settling
in close proximity. Egyptian development in ‘Asala has begun to hem
the Bedouin into a limited pale, as the building of Egyptian residences
have created a boundary on the north and west edges of the town,
bounding the Bedouin neighborhoods by Egyptian neighborhoods on
two sides, the sea on a third, and the resorts and hotels of tourist
Dahab on the forth. The Bedouin currently have a bit of room to
continue expanding, but will soon have to decide between living in
close proximity to the Egyptians and beginning to build vertically to
maintain connections with their kin. These challenges will inevitably
lead to issues such as poor construction and overcrowding, which
plague other urban centers in Egypt.
Perhaps the most significant transformation visible in ‘Asala has
come from the proliferation of commercial centers in the town square.
‘Asala is now complete as an urban space, providing for all the needs
of the Bedouin as well as making available consumer and luxury items.
208. Abu Lughod, Veiled Sentiments, pp. 73–74.
Chapter 4
148
Figure 13: Two photos of ‘Asala Center.
Photos by author, February 12, 2010.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
149
This includes a number of supermarkets, pharmacies, and clothing
stores, as well as electronics and computer stores, hardware stores,
furniture stores, and even a liquor store. The availability of these
services and goods has led to a major transformation of Bedouin social
and economic patterns. For example, the presence of supermarkets
mitigates the necessity to maintain a nomadic lifestyle. It has allowed
the Bedouin to become sedentary without having to worry about
feeding themselves and their flocks. Clothing and luxury items are
now available significantly closer to home, rendering transitory trade
obsolete. Finally, the concentration of consumer stores as well as
hardware stores has allowed the Bedouin to invest significantly more
into their houses, which no longer need to be movable, leading to
an increase in consumer items and amenities within Bedouin homes.
For example, most Bedouin houses are now wired for electricity and
running water and contain a number of amenities such as refrigerators,
televisions, and even air conditioners and the internet. A number of
Dahab Bedouin admit that they have become quite used to these
luxuries, and could not picture returning to life in the desert without
them.209
Furthermore, due to the growth of the urban setting and the
proliferation of luxury items and consumer goods, wealthy and poor
neighborhoods are beginning to emerge in ‘Asala, betraying an
increasing gap between rich Bedouin, who live in neighborhoods
closer to the sea, and poor Bedouin, who live further west. This
situation is becoming plainly visible in ‘Asala by the size and amenities
of the houses. Close to the sea, houses have tall, picturesque fences
and extensive garden courtyards. These houses might have garages
or large gates, as well as their own water pump, all signs of wealth
expressed through Bedouin home construction. More modest homes
continue to be constructed from cinderblocks and corrugated metal,
and do not contain extensive gardens like the wealthier Bedouin. One
notable consequence of urbanization has been declining perceptions
and expressions of Bedouin egalitarianism and an increasing wealth
gap within the community (see Figures14 and 15).
209. Statement by Bedouin Youth in Dahab, February 15, 2010. Video
Archives.
Chapter 4
150
From this short examination of patterns of Bedouin settlement, it is
clear that urbanization has led to similar transformations in the social
patterns of both the Bedouin and migrant Egyptians. Urbanization,
then, is a process leading to cultural convergence due to the availability
of similar services and amenities and entrance into similar markets. A
Figure 14: Wealthy Bedouin home, showing a cobblestone outer wall and an
extensive garden.
Figure 15: Poorer Bedouin home.
Photos by author, February12, 2010.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
151
notable consequence is the reorganization of certain economic and
social frameworks, allowing the Bedouin to integrate into an urban
setting. Furthermore, urbanization has led to demographic patterns
significantly different from Bedouin villages and subjected the Bedouin
to a heterogenous social setting where the Bedouin inevitably
encounter Egyptians, who own a majority of the shops in ‘Asala
center, and foreign visitors, many of whom prefer to stay in ‘Asala.
Thus, it is no surprise that the Bedouin have had to adapt their social
patterns to urban conditions. These social adaptations are bringing the
social patterns of the sedentarizing Bedouin in closer alignment with
those of other Egyptian groups. This transformation is a consequence
of urbanization processes instead of specific cultural notions regarding
“proper” forms of social organization.
The Sources and Extent of Social Change
The above discussion should not be taken as a claim that the entire
Bedouin community of Dahab reflects a homogenous degree of social
transformation. To the contrary, the balancing of opportunities in the
market economy with the security of the subsistence economy, as
discussed in chapters two and three on Bedouin economic change,
can be directly applied here. The social order of the Bedouin reflects
a continuum of transition between individuals remaining in their
subsistence territory and continuing to reflect values more closely
associated with tribal social structures, and those who have settled
in Dahab, found steady employment, and formed close social ties to
foreign tourists. Naturally, this variation has caused tension within the
community, a not uncommon occurrence within groups undergoing
extensive social transformation.
What, then, accounts for this variation and what can be said
about the mechanisms through which social transformation occurs?
At the macro level, there is striking coincidence between social
transformation and tourism. The emergence and differentiation of the
tourist economy closely correlates to the spectrum of social change
visible within the Bedouin community, implying some important link
between economic and social transformation. Styles of dress and new
tastes in music correlate to trends in European and American popular
Chapter 4
152
culture brought to Dahab by tourists, and relationships between the
Bedouin and these tourists are the avenue through which the Bedouin
absorb this culture. To some extent, certain sub-cultures are even
emerging, notably between those engaging with the windsurfers,
who reflect a bit more of a “hippie” demeanor and carefree attitude,
and those who engage with the scuba divers, who tend to be a bit
more professional. In turn, particular relationships tend to map onto
employment trends. Bedouin engaged in windsurfing are generally
friends with the windsurfing tourists, while the Bedouin engaged in
diving are generally friends with the divers, even to the extent that
Bedouin in one group occasionally disparage members of the other.
Taken together, these observations strongly suggest that tourism is the
factor to which the Bedouin are reacting. This is not, however, to claim
that tourism, in and of itself, is the causal factor driving specific patterns
of social transformation. Instead, tourism should be understood as a
phenomenon that entails the disintegration of barriers of isolation,
leading to increasing contact between culturally different groups and,
consequently, new forms of social differentiation. The importance of
isolation and contact, linked to patterns of self-conception and identity
articulation, will be discussed in the next chapter. What is important to
distinguish here is that tourism has been the channel through which
new social symbols have entered the Bedouin community and thus
constitutes a ready “pool of availability” that accounts for specific
manifestations of socialization in Dahab.
As a general observation it is a minority of younger Bedouin
who have undergone the most extreme social changes. Many of
the younger Bedouin, while certainly affected by their transforming
social environment, do continue to wear “traditional” forms of dress,
pray five times a day, and avoid alcohol and the nightlife of Dahab
to various extents. Upon closer inspection, the particular extent of
social change undergone by individual Bedouin appears to be quite
closely connected to the job he holds. Those working very closely with
foreign tourists reflect the most extreme social changes, while those
who have very little contact with the tourist market may reflect very
little social transformation. Finally, there are those in the middle.
One clear example of an intermediate stage of social transformation
is that oft hose involved in the hashish and opium trade. Since they
are required to exist both in the pastoral economy and the tourist
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
153
economy (see chapter two), they appear to have struck a balance
between social transformation and social conservatism, often speaking
excellent English and being able to carry on conversations with foreign
tourists about their own culture (especially drug culture), while at the
same time continuing to reflect more conservative patterns of dress
and social conduct (such as refraining from drinking). Drivers also
exhibit an intermediate state of social transformation, not because
they necessarily exist in both economies, but because while they work
in the tourist economy, they have significantly less face-to-face social
contact with tourists, instead merely conveying them from one point
to the next; other Bedouin act as brokers, insulating drivers from direct
contact with the tourists. In this way, the aforementioned balance of
the Bedouins’ “dual economies” can be applied to their triangulation
of social transformation. These two processes work together. But once
again, the evidence demonstrates that this is not a case of “either/or”;
it instead exists along a continuum, blending cultural conservatism and
transformation, with a major correlate being the extent of contact
with foreign groups.
While this might lead to the conclusion that the particular form
of employment is the causal factor determining the extent of social
change, we should not be so quick to draw causal inferences from
these observations. The micro-level mechanisms that are driving
these transformations and mediating the relationship between
tourism and social transformation are a bit harder to identify.210 Issues
such as reverse causality and circular causation must be considered
seriously. Upon closer examination, powerful selection effects can be
readily identified.211 It is not the case that all Bedouin behave in a
homogenous manner until they acquire jobs, and furthermore, they
are not randomly assigned to employment, but rather self-select into
jobs depending on their own tastes. Finally, connections between
family and friends mean that there is no “unit-independence” among
the Bedouin, and this has a strong influence on social development.
These issues undermine an easy ability to draw neat, strong causal
inferences linking employment to social change.
210. Henry E. Brady and David Collier (eds.), Rethinking Social Inquiry:
Diverse Tools, Shared Standards, 2nd ed. (Lanham: Rowman &
Littlefield, 2010).
211. Ibid. See especially, “Introduction to the Second Edition.”
Chapter 4
154
Many Bedouin youths spend their evenings in Dahab’sbars and
nightclubs, interacting with tourists and other Bedouin. However, it
is not just the Bedouin “of age” who frequent these establishments,
and there is often a large group of younger Bedouin, in their early
teens, who remain on the sidelines.212 While they are too young to
be drinking and pursuing women, they come anyway; this appears
to be an important avenue of socialization for younger Bedouin, who
absorb this tourist culture and learn proper modes of behavior from
their “elders,” Bedouin in their twenties. Eventually, when they get
old enough, they self-select into peer- and employment-groups. These
younger Bedouin are often siblings or friends of older Bedouin, and
family ties to particular groups of older Bedouin appear to have an
equally important effect in determining the extent of social change
as well as the employment decisions that come a bit later in life.
Thus, while there is a very high correlation between employment and
social transformation, the above process observation suggests that
employment alone is not the primary causal factor determining the
extent of social change; family environment and youth experiences
are also important elements of the story. This should be unsurprising
considering what we know about youth socialization in other settings.
While I have often heard arguments claiming that the Bedouin are a
socially closed off community hostile to outside culture, it is clear from
this discussion that avenues of Bedouin socialization differ little from
those of youth living in Brooklyn, London, or Lagos. What might make
this surprising are assumptions that Bedouin society is less developed
than others, rendering the Bedouin a case of “least likely.” This issue
will be discussed in greater depth in the following chapter.
As in any community experiencing rapid social transformation,
a debate has emerged among the Dahab Bedouin regarding the
appropriate extent of transformation vis-à-vis tradition. I often hear
criticism directed at the most transformed Bedouin youth from their
more conservative elders and peers. Again, these opinions exist on a
continuum, where some Bedouin who criticize the most transformed
youth for their laziness or carefree manner (usually in regards to
the windsurfers) are in turn criticized by their more conservative
peers for their own employment and life decisions, for example the
212. Notes on an evening at a Dahab nightclub, May 25, 2012.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
155
decision to open a hotel. Social transformation clearly has its limits,
and this process continues to be negotiated. However, the ability of
the Bedouin youths to make their own living has undermined their
reliance on more conservative members of their community as well as
any sanctioning mechanisms that might be used to bring these youths
back into line.213 This has naturally caused a high level of tension
between groups within the Bedouin community in Dahab, and further
highlights the nature and limits of social transformation, as well as the
friction associated with processes of social and economic change.
In light of the obstacles to drawing valid inferences, can a causal
argument still be made for sources of social change? Shifting the
argument around to account for endogeneity, it is possible to
claim that the socialization process strongly influences the career
decisions made later in life. Taken alone, this is neither surprising nor
particularly interesting. Yet this raises a question as to what extent
these preconceived social attitudes may change with changes in
employment. That is to say, the problem of endogeneity can be found
when examining whether a change in employment predicts a change
in social attitudes; however, if it can be shown that the employment
decision is exogenous and that social attitudes were subsequently
affected, this increases the plausibility of a causal argument. A specific
example is illustrative:
One of my earliest Bedouin acquaintances in Dahab owned a shop
selling handmade Bedouin souvenirs to tourists. Socially, he fit into
what I would call the progressive side of the Bedouin order: he drank
alcohol and spent his evenings in nightclubs chasing girls with his
foreign friends. He spoke frequently of marrying a foreign girl so he
could leave Egypt and settle elsewhere. He listened to American music
and seldom prayed. Furthermore, perhaps linked to the fact he worked
213. James P. Habyarimana, Macartan Humphreys, Daniel N. Posner,
and Jeremy M. Weinstein, Coethnicity: Diversity and the Dilemmas
of Collective Action (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2009);
see also James D. Fearon and David D. Laitin, “Explaining Ethnic
Cooperation,” American Political Science Review 90.4 (1996).
Significant work in Political Science focuses on sanctioning mechanisms
for pressuring interethnic conformity. Habyarimana et.al. point to
sanctioning to explain intra-ethnic cooperation; Fearon and Laitin focus
on sanctioning to explain inter-ethnic cooperation.
Chapter 4
156
closely with Bedouin culture tourism, he was quite chauvinistic when
it came to his identity. He constantly spoke with pride about Bedouin
culture and slandered Egypt and Egyptians. Two years after I made
his acquaintance, his shop was suddenly closed; the Egyptian-owned
resort from whom he rented the space apparently wanted it back,
depriving him of an outlet through which to sell his goods. Unable to
find another source of steady employment, he subsequently turned to
drug dealing.214 Initially, his change in occupation was accompanied
by little social change; he still spent much of his time at nightclubs
with foreigners and continued to drink and listen to foreign music.
However, as time passed, I began noticing clear changes in his
behavior. He began to refuse alcohol and eventually started spending
less time at nightclubs, until the point at which he categorically
refused to attend bars or parties where there might be alcohol. He
also began to pray consistently and regularly wear a jalabiyya, which
he once claimed he hated. Currently, he is attempting to secure a plot
of land so that he can marry a Bedouin girl. As these changes were
happening, the gap between him and his friends began to widen until
he selected out of his peer group and into another that was clearly
more socially conservative. His former friends now refer to him as
“boring,” while he refers to them as “not good people.” Finally, as
a significant portion of his clientele is now Egyptian, I find that he is
much less hostile to Egyptians than he once was.
While I cannot categorically say that it was the switch from
one employment position to another that caused these social
transformations, the timing is suggestive and I cannot identify any
other factor unique to him that can account for these transformations.
For example, the intuitive link between increasing contact with
Egyptian clients and attenuated hostility suggests the influence that
the change in employment has wrought. An alternative explanation,
that the passage of time account for his change (a maturity argument),
can be rejected on the grounds that this passage of time is constant
for everyone, and within his peer group he was the only one who
214. This should not be understood as in any way accusatory or disparaging.
While this statement might carry connotations of stigmatization and
illegitimacy in other parts of the world, it is considered a legitimate form
of self-employment within the Bedouin community.
Evolving Social Contacts and Frameworks
157
underwent this process; he was simultaneously the only one who
switched jobs in this manner. As for an increase in religious sentiment
potentially being the cause, it appeared to me that his increase in
religiosity was itself an outcome of his change in job. Moreover, while
he prays, he does not speak often about his religious beliefs to the
same extent as I have heard from other religious Muslims.
While I would not argue that tourism or employment is mono-
causal, I argue that employment does exert social influence which
shapes attitudes and values. So in what sense is this causal? Tourism
is a mechanism that generates face-to-face contact between culturally
different individuals. It is precisely this interaction which creates
moments of social and identity change. In this way, tourism is one of
a number of mechanisms that increase the breadth of social contact,
in a manner similar to industrializing urbanization in the Copperbelt
of Africa studied by Mitchell and Epstein.215 Additionally, the specific
sites for current trends in Bedouin socialization are closely related to
the tourist market: resorts, nightclubs, restaurants, popular beaches.
Employment determines, to a significant degree, the type of social
contacts that an individual will develop, which explains why pre-
existing social preferences are such an important factor determining
employment selection. On the other hand, in situations in which
employment is not a matter of self-selection, it clearly creates
somewhat of a path-dependent channel that encourages the adoption
of certain social values. These two factors explain the correlation, in a
loosely deterministic and dialectic manner, between employment and
social transformation. This has important implications for patterns of
identity transformation, to be discussed in the final chapter.
Concluding Remarks
The changes in the Bedouins’ social space are consequences of
economic development and transformation. Among the Bedouin, social
patterns are, to a large extent, predicated on modes of subsistence
215. Mitchell, The Kalela Dance. See also A. L. Epstein, Politics in an
Urban African Community (Manchester: Published on Behalf of the
Rhodes-Livingstone Institute by Manchester University Press, 1958).
Chapter 4
158
and economic organization. The stability of tribal structures has
fluctuated inversely with political stability and economic opportunity
in Sinai development. With the beginnings of sedentarization and
integration, the tribal structures and sources of authority prevalent in
a Bedouin subsistence economy have declined in relevance, reflecting
the social needs of the urban population. Fluctuations in the strength
of tribal structures, in a manner similar to the extent of social change
undergone by individuals, reflects the balancing of the Bedouins’ dual
economies, suggesting that social organization is to a large extent
predicated on patterns of economic organization.
Increasing contact with Egyptians and foreigners is driving social
transformation among the Bedouin, leading to changes in how the
Bedouin perceive themselves and their role in the state. Egyptian
development policies were the major factor in shaping social relations
between Bedouin and Egyptian migrants, and the social patterns
pursued in Dahab mirror the economic competition that developed
between the Bedouin and the migrants, as well as the economic
relationship established between the Bedouin and foreign tourists.
One conclusion that can be readily drawn from this discussion is
that the Bedouins’ social frameworks are evolving; increasing contact
with outsiders has transformed the Bedouins’ social space as well
as their conception of self. Economic competition and government
policies marginalizing the Bedouin have reinforced negative
perceptions of Egyptians and the boundary between the Bedouin and
Egyptian social groups. Simultaneously, the presence of foreigners is
causing high leakage of Northern symbols and values into many parts
of urban Bedouin society. The Bedouin are consciously orienting
themselves away from Egyptian symbols and society by incorporating
cultural symbols brought by foreigners and communicating them as
part of “Bedouin” culture. In this way, the Bedouin have reacted
to economic development by orienting themselves towards a social
order that is noticeably cosmopolitan and barely Egyptian as a way to
maintain themselves as a distinct social group within Egyptian society.
While this new culture is significantly different from what is considered
Bedouin “tradition,” it has allowed the Bedouin to retain a unique
and differentiating identity from other Egyptian groups and reflect
values that some Bedouin have come to embrace as a response to the
direction of development.
159
Chapter 5
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and
Identity Transformation
among the Aqaba Bedouin
Economic development in Sinai is increasing Egyptian state control
over a territory previously characterized by the state’s limited presence.
As we have seen throughout this study, the major consequences of
increasing state presence and economic development for the Aqaba
Bedouin have been processes of economic transformation and
social reorganization spurred by a number of integrative processes
including urbanization, sedentarization, expanded communications
and transportation infrastructure, and the emergence of local but
integrated markets. As the Egyptian state seeks to establish its
authority, it is simultaneously working to disseminate and standardize
national ideologies and identities. But it must be stressed that these
processes, instead of leading to the homogenization of identities, are
actualizing reactive processes of identity formation that are dependent
on a number of external pressures. And it must further be stressed
that there is a difference between these identities themselves and the
“politics of difference” in which these identities form the bases of
sociopolitical categorization and interaction. This chapter focuses on
the latter: the nature of the social politics, or identity politics, of South
Sinai and how this is connected to a broader sense of “Bedouin”
identity.
As my experiences in Sinai strongly suggested, Bedouin identity
is an extremely complicated topic that cannot be addressed without
due consideration of the academic and political debates surrounding
identity and ethnicity. A holistic understanding of contemporary
political identity is impossible without appealing simultaneously to
essentialist, instrumentalist, and constructivist traditions, each of
which defines a different aspect of identity. While it is undeniable that
Chapter 5
160
identity as a badge is quite “sticky,” this does not imply that the roles
and significations of identity are necessarily fixed and unchanging
across varying political contexts.216 And as we will see, identity
formation often occurs below the national level. In Sinai, and even
just in Aqaba, Bedouin cultural identity is in certain ways distinct from
other Bedouin cultures, even within Egypt. For example, comparative
studies of Bedouin groups in other settings would probably challenge
the claim that something like Hip Hop, discussed in the previous
chapter, constitutes an important element in the expression of
Bedouin identity. This variability in expressions of identity suggests
the situational nature of certain aspects of identity.
In the modern state system, defined by discrete, territorially-bounded
polities (states) comprised of socially heterogeneous populations,
identity politics are closely linked to the spread of national interests
and ideologies and a clash with particularist, sub-national ones that
for one reason or another have not been absorbed through nation-
building strategies. The particular local form this identity assumes is
encouraged by the contemporary sociopolitical needs of the group
and its elites and is largely articulated as a foil to nationalism, defined
here slightly differently than those understandings adopted by scholars
such as Gellner, for whom nationalism was “primarily a political
principle, which holds that the political and the national unit should be
congruent.”217 Instead, I define nationalism as the ideology that both
legitimizes the authority of the territorially-bounded national state and
shapes its social programs.218
Nationalism provides the ideological basis for dominant national
identities, which seek to assert their universal applicability in an
attempt to cover social divisions within state borders. As it is this
territorial state that has been identified as the basic arena for group
competition, it is against these national identities that alternative
216. Horowitz, Ethnic Groups in Conflict, p. 66.
217. Ernest Gellner, Nations and Nationalism, 2nd ed. (Oxford: Blackwell,
2006), p. 1.
218. Thomas H. Eriksen, “Ethnicity Versus Nationalism,” Journal of Peace
Research 28.3 (1991), p. 263. In the words of Benedict Anderson,
“nation-ness is the most universally legitimate value in the political life of
our time.” Anderson, Imagined Communities, p. 3.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
161
identities, or expressions of collective solidarity, form. This solidarity
is structured on “certain qualitatively distinct characteristics,” which
form the basis for familiarity and group feeling and constitute the
elements of identity.219 This sense of solidarity is vital to the social
being (symbolic existence) as well as the political organization (practical
existence) of groups. This produces a conclusion identical to that of
Abner Cohen in his work Two Dimensional Man, that identities play
two primary roles, a symbolic legitimizing role and a practical political
role.220 These dual functions will be repeatedly addressed. Once
again, the distinction must be made between the identity itself and the
contemporary political role that these identities play.
What, then, is the role of “ethnicity” in the politicization of identity
and how does any of this apply to a discussion of the Bedouin?
Scholars from all ideological streams have come to recognize that
“nations have a historical core” that is based on certain primordial
culture elements of the core (dominant) social group.221 In this way,
national identities and the legitimacy of the nation-state are quite often
articulated in the language of “ethnicity,” based on notions of social
continuity, common descent, and shared cultural symbols and values.
Instead of attempting to claim “ethnic status” for the Bedouin, my
preference to use ethnicity theory stems from the analytical leverage
that this scholarship lends to the question at hand. The wholesale
219. Jeffrey C. Alexander, “Core Solidarity, Ethnic Outgroup, and Social
Differentiation: A Multidimensional Model of Inclusion in Modern
Societies,” in Jaques Dofny and Akinsola Akiwowo (eds.), National and
Ethnic Movements (Beverley Hills: Sage Publications Ltd, 1980), p. 6.
220. Abner Cohen, Two-dimensional Man: An Essay on the Anthropology
of Power and Symbolism in Complex Society (Berkeley: University
of California, 1974). See chapter 4 “The Political Man, the Symbolist
Man.” See also Migdal, Strong Societies and Weak States, p. 80. Joel
Migdal links these aspects of identity to patterns of “social control” in
the politics of contemporary states: “Effective social control depends
first on the regulation of resources and services. Beyond that, it entails
the effective use of symbols to give meaning to social relations.”
221. Alexander, “Core Solidarity, Ethnic Outgroup, and Social
Differentiation,” p. 10; see also Smith, The Ethnic Origins of Nations,
p. 14. In the words of Anthony Smith, identity mainly relates to a sense
of community based on history and culture.
Chapter 5
162
acceptance of ethno-nationalism as a dominant ideology regulating
the state system has simultaneously legitimized the politicization of
culture and identity as an effective basis for contemporary political
solidarities in national contexts. From an instrumentalist point of view,
all political identities can be considered “ethnic,” whether based on
race, religion, or even country of origin.
Since ethnicity is a primary source of identity and solidarity in
nationally defined situations, as the Aqaba Bedouin become integrated
into the fabric of Egyptian society, they have increasingly begun to
express their collective identity in an ethnic idiom, a process scholars
refer to as ethnogenesis. This chapter will explore issues of identity
transformation and articulation among the Aqaba Bedouin in response
to Egyptian development as well as other state- and nation-building
strategies explored in previous chapters. First, I will discuss what is
meant by ethnicity, especially as it operates in contemporary contexts;
we must arrive at a satisfactory analytical definition of ethnicity for
it to be useful. Next, issues of identity and ethno-nationalism in
the contemporary Egyptian state will be explored. This will lead to
a discussion regarding the specific shape and circumstance of the
identity communicated by the Aqaba Bedouin. By way of conclusion, I
will discuss the lessons that the case of the Aqaba Bedouin present for
questions of political identity more broadly.
What Is Ethnicity?
Among partisans of identity, there remains disagreement over what,
precisely, ethnicity is. This debate has led to the emergence of two
main camps. First are the primordialist-essentialists, who assert that
ethnicity is a product of highly identifiable and measurable culture
traits that can be traced into the past and which are objective “givens”
for analysis. Second are the instrumentalists and constructivists,
who claim that ethnicity is a specifically modern phenomenon that
is adaptable as circumstances require.222 However, instead of seeing
222. For discussions on the primordialist-modernist debate, see Anthony D.
Smith, Myths and Memories of the Nation (Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 2000), p. 98; see also Rabinovich and Esman, Ethnicity,
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
163
these arguments as rigid definitions for ethnicity, they should instead
be understood as two sides of the same coin: ethnicity, in fact, relies
on contemporary and primordial elements to give it both relevance
and legitimacy.
By understanding ethnicity as simultaneously grounded in both
primordial structures and contemporary contexts, we arrive at a
definition of ethnicity quite similar to that of Anthony Smith, who
acknowledges the importance of both essentialist and instrumentalist
elements but agrees that neither, on their own, sufficiently explains
ethnicity.223 Ethnic categories are defined as “populations distinguished
by outsiders as possessing the attributes of a common name or
emblem, a shared cultural element, and a link with a particular
territory.”224 Overall, Smith identifies six major components that
comprise ethnicity: an identifying name, a myth of common descent,
shared historical memories, one or more elements of a common
culture, and a link to a territorial homeland. Questions regarding the
origins and symbols of ethnic identity, and additionally their sources
of legitimacy, can only be answered by primordial elements. While
Smith grounds his definition of ethnicity in these primordial elements,
he agrees with the instrumentalists on the contemporary functions of
these identities, if not their origins.
According to instrumentalist arguments, ethnicity is the
categorization of individuals in a heterogeneous society for the purposes
of interaction and identification, allowing a person to categorize a
complex social world and achieve self-definition.225 Ethnicity, in this
Pluralism, and the State in the Middle East, p.12. I am not attempting
to conflate Instrumentalism and Constructivism; they are not equivalent.
However, the contingent and constructed nature of ethnicity according to
these schools of thought establishes a useful distinction from essentialist
understandings.
223. Anthony D. Smith, The Ethnic Revival (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1981).
224. Smith, Myths and Memories of the Nation, p. 12.
225. Fredrik Barth, “Introduction,” in Fredrik Barth (ed.), Ethnic Groups and
Boundaries: The Social Organization of Culture Difference (Boston:
Little, Brown, and Company, 1969), 13; see also Cohen, “Introduction:
The Lessons of Ethnicity” in Urban Ethnicity.
Chapter 5
164
sense, is a product of the interaction of social groups who consider
themselves distinct, informing the normative patterns of interaction
between these groups in a collective environment.226 Thomas Eriksen,
another instrumentalist, qualifies this definition: “Ethnicity is the
property of a social formation and an aspect of interaction; both
systemic levels must be understood simultaneously.”227 Ethnicity, as
he understands it, is simultaneously a property of a group formation
(essentialism) as well as a co-constituted property of sociopolitical
forces (instrumentalism).
Ethnicity, as it emerges from contact between distinct groups,
cannot, then, be based merely on objective cultural markers of a group,
which can be measured in a vacuum. It instead uses “culture” as a
symbolic way of regulating contact between distinct groups operating
within a bounded system. This definition identifies the contemporary
political role that ethnic identity plays but fails to identify the sources
of ethnicity. Smith provides the missing link: myths of common
descent provide legitimacy for the identity and its special interests, and
cultural symbols play a vital unifying role where values, memories, and
customs form the basis for group solidarity in addition to markers of a
boundary.228 Ethnicity is necessarily grounded both in primordial and
contemporary elements. Primordial elements serve to legitimize the
identity, both internally, as these cultural elements form the basis for
group feeling, as well as externally, where the recognition of historical
continuity and cultural unity form the basis for external groups to
understand and recognize the legitimacy of the group:
It is this sense of history and the perception of cultural
uniqueness… which differentiates populations from each other
and which endows a given population with a definite identity,
both in their own eyes and in the eyes of outsiders.229
226. Barth, Ethnic Groups and Boundaries, p. 12.
227. Thomas H. Eriksen, “The Cultural Contexts of Ethnic Differences,”
Man, New Series 26.1 (1991), p. 132.
228. Smith, Myths and Memories of the Nation, pp. 14, 61–62.
229. Quote by Smith, The Ethnic Origins of Nations, p. 22; see also Barkey
and Parikh, “Comparative Perspectives on the State,” p. 531.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
165
The more grounded in recognized historical realities, the greater
the basis for the legitimacy of the group. Identities are more easily
contested if they are not grounded in primordial elements, which
provide the visible basis for their “objective” existence.
Contemporary elements, on the other hand, function to give this
identity political relevance. Instrumentalists have shown that cultural
variation between ethnicities is not fixed, but is constructed and
communicated to reflect tension between ethnic categories and is
exploited to serve political ends. In other words, while the essentialists
clearly demonstrate that identities and their symbols must have
historical basis to be considered universally legitimate, thus contributing
to the subjective “strength” of a given identity, the meanings that
are associated with these identities can be highly contingent, based
on sociopolitical relations and power asymmetries operating in a
particular field of interaction. Smith is in full agreement:
Such [an objectively existent ethnic] ‘reality’ as we shall impute
to an ethnie is essentially social and cultural: the generic
features of ethnie are derived less from ‘objective’ indicators…
than from the meanings conferred… on certain cultural, spatial,
and temporal properties of their interactions and shared
experience.230
This explains why ethnic boundaries may shift depending on situational
circumstances and ethnic patterns that regulate society in a particular
state will not be equally applicable to societies in other states.231 The
focus of this discussion should be understood as the transformation
of existing identities as they are mobilized politically, not the formation
or emergence of new ones.
As many societies once considered “traditional” are undergoing
major social transformations as responses to processes of national
integration, ethnic identity is strengthening instead of weakening.232
While ethnic identity relies on the communication of culture, often
through primordial symbols, “heritage” becomes a tool for the
legitimation of group identity in the contemporary arena. I define
230. Smith, The Ethnic Origins of Nations, p. 22.
231. Mitchell, “Perceptions of Ethnicity and Ethnic Behavior,” p. 23.
232. Cohen, Two-dimensional Man.
Chapter 5
166
tradition along similar lines, as sets of normative behaviors from
the past that are no longer utilitarian in contemporary contexts but
continue to be deployed because of their symbolic value. These shared
practices point to common ancestral pasts and suggest common
descent, and have the purpose of strengthening group solidarity as
well as distinguishing social groups from one another.
The above discussion suggests that both essentialist and
instrumentalist accounts are vital to a broader understanding of
what ethnicity is. On the other hand, it is clear that each school of
thought addresses a fairly specific set of questions regarding this type
of identity in a contemporary setting. Essentialism is necessary to
address questions of where, when, and what, relating to the origins of
ethnic identity as well as the symbols that comprise relevant cultural
forms. Furthermore, this aspect of ethnic identity helps explain
questions of legitimacy that plague identity contestation. Overly
“modernist” and “post-modernist” approaches to identity have been
unable to address such issues appropriately. On the other hand,
overly essentialist accounts of ethnicity tend to focus too strongly on
the past, making broad assumptions about “process” or lack thereof,
especially as it relates to transform ability of social groups and the
mutability of identity. They may wrongly assume that such groups are
unchanging and that myths of common descent are socio-historical
“facts” when the reality may be quite different.233 There is little use in
studying identity without focusing on the contemporary role that these
identities play, which has been the focus of instrumentalist accounts
and theories of identity. These accounts focus on questions of why
and how, especially relating to issues of identity politics and group
mobilization. As contemporary identity politics can undoubtedly be
characterized as the “politics of difference,” instrumentalist theories
of identity boundaries and intergroup relations may assume greater
analytical relevance than essentialist characterizations of the sources
of identity. Due to the primary focus of this analysis on Bedouin
identity in contemporary interactions with the national state, such
instrumentalist approaches have been the most valuable in my analysis
of Bedouin identity in transformation. My analysis does not focus on
233. Horowitz, Ethnic Groups in Conflict, p. 66. Horowitz discusses the
mutability of antecedent historical conditions, malleable “within limits.”
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
167
“what is ethnicity?” but rather “how is identity used in contemporary
political interactions?”
An effective way to further understand the difference between
essentialist and instrumentalist focuses of ethnic identity would be to
consider the differences between symbol and stereotype. Symbols of
cultural identity are closely related to concepts of tradition and arise
from within a culture group. Stereotypes, on the other hand, relate
to identity boundaries and relations between distinct social groups,
and in this way arise from the interaction of culture groups that see
themselves as distinct. Symbols fall into the realm of essentialism;
stereotypes are instrumental.
Symbols play a cognitive and emotional role. Like “tradition,”
symbols are objects or practices imbued with social and historical
meaning that, through the “politics of similarity,” form the basis
for social solidarities by eliciting similar cognitive and emotional
responses from those identifying with them. The purpose of cultural
symbols is to homogenize cultural production within a given social
community. The goal is to create a situation whereby all of the
members of an ethnic community infer the same meanings from a
given symbol, creating a shared response which reinforces the idea of
group membership and in-group solidarity. Symbols derive from the
collective experiences of an ethnic group and thus exist regardless of
the particular constellation of social groups interacting in the broader
political system. That is to say that the historical symbols of Bedouin
communities are largely uniform whether those communities are
located in Egypt, Israel, or Saudi Arabia. That is not to say, however,
that the precise repertoire of symbols defining specific communities
of Bedouin must be uniform across borders, but that specific, shared
symbols must generally have the same subjective meanings if they are
going to successfully generate group feeling. These meanings arise
from the shared historical experience of the broader ethnic category.
Symbols can only be exogenously forced on a community through
the mediation of history –such as the symbolism of the antique key or
the olive grove for Palestinians, signifying dispossession at the hands
of another. Symbolic differences are not always invoked, but always
remain available to define a boundary between the two social groups.
Similarly, while “Egyptians” and “Bedouin” share many cultural
Chapter 5
168
similarities, the lack of tribal affiliation is one of the examples cited by
Bedouin showing that Egyptians are not part of their culture group. In
this way, tribal affiliation has acquired an important social symbolism
for the Bedouin as a means of distinguishing themselves as a distinct
social group.234
Stereotypes are also cognitive and emotional, but play a very
different function. Instead of structuring solidarities within a given
community, they structure relations between different social groups.
Another important difference between symbols and stereotypes
is that while primordial cultural symbols are largely uniform across
borders, stereotypes can be highly contingent, based on the interests
and perceptions of other groups with which the ethnic community
must interact. This statement receives additional empirical evidence
through a number of studies, notably by Daniel Posner, whose work
with dyads of ethnic groups on either side of the Malawi-Zambia
border shows that the remarkable consistency in individuals’ abilities
to identify cultural symbols of the other group does not extend to
stereotypes, which differed significantly. Attitudes of social distance
were based, not on differences between the communities’ symbols, but
on the stereotypes that emerged on either side of the border, reflecting
political relations between the groups.235 While internal conceptions
of identity may be fairly well established through the strength of
cultural symbols and traditions, acceptable roles and relationships can
be ascribed through the standardization and reification of stereotypes
imposed on the community by politically powerful groups. Symbols
may display their own consistency, but stereotypes generally indicate
the presence of a social boundary.
234. Horowitz, Ethnic Groups in Conflict, p. 71. This is a process Horowitz
refers to as “Differentiation”—the invocation of a cultural difference in
order to define a boundary.
235. Daniel Posner, “The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why
Chewas and Tumbakas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in
Malawi,” American Political Science Review 98 (2004), p. 533. I
remain agnostic as to the causal mechanisms posed by Posner; however,
the evidence from the surveys is unambiguous. Posner finds in a series
of logit regressions that there is no significant correlation between social
distance and the number of cultural “differences” between groups as
identified by survey respondents.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
169
Despite similar cultural symbols, the sociopolitical implications
of a Bedouin identity in Egypt are quite different than they are in a
state such as Saudi Arabia. As a more globally familiar example, an
Arab or Muslim identity in Egypt has significantly different political
implications than it does in the United States, even more so after
September 11, 2001 than before. The relationships and constraints
ascribed to identity categories through processes such as stereotyping
are products of sociopolitical forces interacting at the national (system)
level, notably the particular constellation of ethnic groups in the
system and the alliances forged between them, as well as the ideology
and material interests of the hegemonic or ruling social group. When
discussing identity categories, scholars and politicians alike must take
care to distinguish between the questions “what does it mean to be an
X?” and “what does it mean to be an X in this particular context?” It
is almost always the case that the answer to these two questions will
differ.
Ethnicity in a Modern State System
As ethnicity is grounded to a certain extent in primordial elements,
ethnies, according to Smith’s definition of ethnicity, have been
identified in pre-modern and even ancient periods. While ethnies are
not unique to the system of territorial states, the form and function
that ethnic identities have assumed in contemporary contexts have
differed significantly from those of the pre-modern period. One of
the reasons I have shown such favoritism for Smith’s definition
of ethnicity is that he clearly identifies the political role of ethnic
identities in contemporary, national contexts, and he does not
attempt to isolate ethnicity from its role in the construction of national
identities. This study is interested in contemporary expressions of
ethnic identity along the lines articulated above, specifically how and
why they are deployed in contemporary, nationally-defined situations,
i.e. in the politics of contemporary states. Notably, ethnic identities
frequently form at odds with dominant nationalist ideologies.236 This
is because in many cases, national identities attach themselves to
236. Eriksen, “Ethnicity Versus Nationalism,” p. 263.
Chapter 5
170
ethnic identities, rendering most nationalist conflicts a type of ethnic
conflict, for example in Yugoslavia, Northern Ireland, and Israel.
This phenomenon is well recognized by scholars of nationalism, as
evidenced by the myriad of works entitled Ethnicity and Nationalism
or some variation that have proliferated over the years.
The territorially-defined nation-state, as it is the primary source of
sovereignty in the contemporary international system, is the primary
arena for the activation of social conflict, especially in an inter-ethnic
sense.237 It is important to recognize the centrality of nationalism to
this argument, as it has provided the context against which other
identities mobilize. Nationalism is expressed through cultural symbols
and traditions, based on myths of common descent and historical
continuity, and is thus articulated in the language of ethnicity.238 Most
nationalisms are, in fact, entho-nationalisms. The concept of language
games and competition explains why ethnicity has become a powerful
and effective means of contesting nationalism, forming the basis for
the social articulation of politics. Language games, first described by
Wittgenstein, implies that all interactions must be conducted in the
same “language” or an “intersubjective field tied to a particular context,
which is reproduced by the individuals [or groups] interacting.”239 This
means that any type of interaction can only be meaningful if conducted
using compatible, mutually agreed-upon frameworks or perceptions
of the “particular context” in question.
Nationalism, in this sense, may be considered the strategy
adopted by central states and dominant social groups in their national
interactions to pursue their interests and promote their legitimacy. In
other words, it is useful to think of nationalism “as a political activity
contesting or upholding a particular type of political order… In this
sense, nationalism is not simply about imagined communities; it is
much more fundamentally about a struggle for control over defining
communities [my emphasis].”240 As a social ideology, nationalism
237. Rabinovich and Essman, Ethnicity, Pluralism, and the State in the
Middle East, p. 4.
238. Smith, Myths and Memories of the Nation, p. 9.
239. Eriksen, “The Cultural Contexts of Ethnic Differences,” p. 132.
240. Mark R. Beissinger, Nationalist Mobilization and the Collapse of the
Soviet State (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2002),
p. 18.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
171
stresses conformity to the values and identity of the central state, which
may or may not be egalitarian across the wider spectrum of society,
especially in post-colonial states and states dominated by single social
groups.241 In this sense, nationalism is necessarily hegemonic, seeking
to delegitimize and under communicate social differences within the
state and instead claim social uniformity based on the identities and
interests of the core. In the words of Ernest Gellner, nationalism
“insists on imposing homogeneity on the populations unfortunate
enough to fall under the sway of authorities possessed by the
nationalist ideology.”242 This is an attempt to assert that the goals and
ideologies of the center are equally applicable across the population,
legitimizing the core’s pursuit of its own interests as national interests;
nationalism always legitimizes the interests of the hegemonic social
group. Contemporary identities cannot be studied or understood
divorced from issues of national interests, goals, and values, for their
formation is linked. In order to contest nationalism then, peripheral
social groups have increasingly adopted the language of ethnicity,
which becomes the most effective basis to contest ethnically grounded
nationalist ideologies on the basis of the previously-mentioned
common intersubjective framework structured around historical and
cultural legitimacy.
While these identities are articulated in the language of ethnicity,
they are not assumed as mere foils to national identities, but
increasingly to national ideologies.243 In other words, if the state
attempts to treat all of its constituent social groups equally, then these
groups will generally be less likely to react against dominant values
and identities, which are seen as distributive and inclusive instead of
potentially restrictive or exclusionary.244 This further suggests that the
241. Eriksen, “Ethnicity Versus Nationalism,” p. 263.
242. Gellner, Nations and Nationalism, p. 44.
243. Smith, The Ethnic Revival, p. 6. “It is tautologically true,” wrote
Smith, “that if the nation-state and its agencies can satisfy the perceived
needs in ways acknowledged by its citizens, then its inhabitants become
nationalists,” implying a direct link between coincidence of interest and
the acceptance of identities.
244. Migdal, Strong Societies and Weak States, p. 27. Joel Migdal
wrote, “Social control rests on the organizational ability to deliver key
components for individuals’ strategies of survival.”
Chapter 5
172
mobilization of identities for political purposes is often a reaction to
material and psychological conditions that state policies create for
social groups.
Perceptions of unequal treatment and discrimination on the part
of central authorities often lead to a reaction away from national
identities, through the development of both distinct social identities
and distribution networks. Which identity will be mobilized, however,
is not entirely up to social groups and their elites. In many cases, state
policies use pre-existing social categories as a basis for organizing
distribution and exclusion. As will be demonstrated below, it is often
the case that systemic political conditions “pre-select” and activate
specific identities.
A state’s legitimacy among its population rests on its ability to act
as an equitable distributor. In contrast, social groups may continue
to favor non-state modes of organization which are structurally
incompatible with organizational forms favored by the state. These
forms will often appear threatening to state interests and will be
labeled “subversive”—for example, the Bedouins’ desire to pursue
their own forms of employment and labor in Dahab’s tourist economy
rather than be subordinated to state development.When presented
with this choice, social groups will generally follow the path of greatest
utility, further contesting the state’s claim to universally represent the
identities and interests of its population.245 In the event that these
ideologies and values are not deemed universally applicable to the
state’s heterogeneous population, national identities are more likely to
be rejected by peripheral groups who will instead turn to particularistic
identities.
This form of ethnic expression is primarily a symbolic way to
assert a separate existence from hegemonic forms of nationalism,
which simultaneously seek to impose a particular set of interests and
values that operate alongside distinguishing forms of culture. Once
again, identity simultaneously plays two roles, one symbolic, in the
form of cultural identities, and the other political, in the form of group
interests. Elements of ethnicity, then, constitute the primary tools of
identity transformation and resource competition in national contexts.
245. Smith, The Ethnic Revival, p. 6.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
173
Ethnicity is viewed as an organic form of solidarity as well as an
effective means of mobilization to contest national ideologies.
Within the Arab world, nation-building strategies in Morocco
and Algeria represent perfect cases of hegemonic forms of cultural
national identity clashing with particularist sub-national identities.
Bruce Maddy-Weitzman, in a study of the Amazigh cultural awakening
in these two states, shows how state policies supporting a program
of Arabization and Islamo-Arabic supremacy were instrumental in
motivating reactions from these states’ Amazigh populations, who
mobilized to defend their sociolinguistic heritage. Maddy-Weitzman
continues: “No less important [to the Amazigh cultural awakening]
was the poor performance of the state in satisfying both material and
social-psychological needs, leaving an ideological vacuum,” which
was a primary factor cementing a formal social boundary between
Arab and Berber social groups and mobilizing the Berbers.246 This
reflects both the material and symbolic needs of the community.
Such a cultural awakening was largely absent in the period before
the state’s program of Arabization began to systematically marginalize
the Amazigh language and legacy, suggesting this movement was a
reaction to specific state policies.Mobilization occurred despite the
existence of tribal divisions within the Berber ethnie, showing that
multiple forms of identity may exist simultaneously and tribal divisions
do not preclude the possibility of a broader sense of ethnic solidarity.
In national contexts, these tribal groups have turned to an ethnically-
articulated identity that generally de-emphasizes tribal divisions in
favor of a pan-tribal culture group.
Expressions of National Identity in Egypt
and Their Implications for National
Solidarities
Egypt provides a perfect example of a strongly-rooted ethno-
nationalism based on links to the ancient civilization of the Nile River,
246. Maddy-Weitzman, “Contested Identities: Berbers, ‘Berberism’ and the
state in North Africa,” p. 24.
Chapter 5
174
that in the words of Israel Gershoni and James Jankowski, “generat[es]
a particularist and exclusivist Egyptian national identity.”247 National
identities and forms of expression in Egypt strongly reflect the
historical continuity of the Nile Valley from Pharaonic through Islamic
times.248 Thus, Egyptian national identity is based on two historical-
cultural elements: Pharaonism and Islamism. While this identity is
very strongly tied to the essence of Egypt’s territorial history, it is a
particularistic legitimacy that has created a strong national core but
has created problems for peripheral nation-building.
Expressions of Egyptian national identity are identifiable in
three main arenas: art and literature, tourism, and Egypt’s national
institutions and symbols. The articulation of Egyptian national identity
emerged in the writings of early Egyptian nationalists in the 1920s
and 30s, coinciding with the rise of Pharaonic and Hellenistic imagery
in art and literature.249 This national literature aimed at focusing
Egyptian mass culture on the uniqueness of Egyptian history and
heritage. In these expressions of Pharaonism there was an attempt
to present the idea that Egypt has been more or less preserved since
Pharaonic times as a natural entity. In the period after World War II,
many more Egyptian writers focused on the particularist history of
Egypt, including Taha Hussein and Tawfik al-Hakim.250 Gershoni and
Jankowski provide examples of nationalist expression in numerous
247. Israel Gershoni and James P. Jankowski, Commemorating the Nation:
Collective Memory, Public Commemoration, and National Identity
in Twentieth-century Egypt (Chicago: Middle East Documentation
Center, 2004), p. 52.
248. Donald M. Reid, “Nationalizing the Pharaonic Past: Egyptology,
Imperialism and Egyptian Nationalism, 1922–1952,” in Israel Gershoni
and James Jankowski (eds.), Rethinking Nationalism in the Arab
Middle East (New York: Columbia University Press, 1997), p. 149.
Despite more recent trends toward Arabism and Islamism, Reid
states, “A current identification with Ancient Egypt … seems to have
become an independent and self-sustaining element of modern Egyptian
identity.”
249. Vatikiotis, The History of Modern Egypt, p. 494.
250. Mahmud Ismail, Nationalism in Egypt before Nasser’s Revolution
(PhD Dissertation, University of Pittsburgh, 1966) (Ann Arbor, MI:
University Microfilms International, 1978), pp. 171–176.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
175
forms of art, notably in the expressions of Nahdat Misr (The Egyptian
Renaissance), showing how Egypt’s particularist national identity is
enshrined in its art and architecture in addition to its literature.
At that time, the future of the field of Egyptology became a focal
point for the Egyptian national struggle against the British, and the
political struggle for independence incorporated a strong element
of reclaiming and defending cultural and historical legacies.251 This
observation helps to explain why Pharaonism played such an important
role in cultural and even political expression during the 1920s and
30s, forming a major basis for the anti-colonial struggle: Egyptian
nationalists attempted to “reclaim” their history from the Europeans.
In addition to the aforementioned nationalist authors, Pharaonic
symbolism was adopted by many of the nationalist political parties
including the Wafd, the Umma party, and the Watani party, as well
as a number of political newspapers, notably al-Siyasa operated by
Muhammad Husayn Haykal. Despite the relative decline of Pharaonism
and the later rise of Islamism and Arabism, Reid incisively points out
that “territorial patriotism, Arabism, and Islamism are incompatible
only in the abstract and unreal world of ideal types.”252 Even at the
height of Egypt’s pan-Arabism, Nasser did not attempt to erase the
legacy of ancient Egypt from the memory of the Egyptian nation, he
continued to strive for the nationalization of the field of Egyptology,
and he worked for the preservation of Egypt’s ancient archaeological
spaces.253 Instead of interpreting the relative decline of Pharaonism
in the 1940s and beyond as a turn away from this historical legacy, it
could instead be seen as an attempt to harmonize this theme with the
others to create an identity with broader appeal. Today, the symbols
of Egypt’s Pharaonic past coexist alongside expressions of Arabism
and Islamism in Egypt’s nationalist spaces.
251. Reid, “Nationalizing the Pharaonic Past.”
252. Ibid., p. 149.
253. Ibid., p. 147. See also James P. Jankowski, “Arab Nationalism in
‘Nasserism’ and Egyptian State Policy, 1952–1958,” in James P.
Jankowski and Israel Gershoni (eds.), Rethinking Nationalism in
the Arab Middle East (New York: Columbia University Press, 1997),
pp. 150–167.
Chapter 5
176
The second arena for the expression of Egyptian national identity is
tourism, which has become a primary avenue for the communication
of national heritage and culture to insiders as well as outsiders.254 In
Egypt, as previously identified, tourism is predicated primarily on
the history of ancient Egypt, in showcases such as the pyramids, the
Egyptian museum’s focus on its ancient civilization, the Temple of
Karnak and the Valley of the Kings in Luxor. In an internet Google
image search for “Tourism in Egypt,” by far the most popular image
returned was of the Sphinx and the pyramids, followed by pictures of
Karnak, the Nile, Abu Simbel, and mummies. A secondary source of
heritage tourism, notably in Cairo, derives from the legacy of Islam
and the Arab conquests. Tourist spaces supporting this aspect of
Egyptian history include the many mosques frequented by visitors, as
well as the walls of medieval Cairo and the medieval Khan al-Khalili.
All of these spaces focus on links to two epochs of Egypt’s history:
Pharaonism and Islam.
This serves to disseminate Egyptian national identity to a non-
Egyptian audience and further reinforce the pride Egyptians take in
their identity. Tourism plays a role in reinforcing the cultural symbols
of a nation in the minds of the lower classes, as opposed to merely
upper-class elites frequently associated with discussions of nationalism
and literacy, because it is the masses that are quite often involved in
the economics of cultural transmission as touts, guides, and vendors.
As their economic livelihood relies on their internalization of the
myths of this idealized past, these symbols leave a lasting imprint on
the consciousness of all those engaged in tourism. The discussion
of the past few paragraphs cannot be overstated, as these issues of
political struggle with a “colonial power” as well as the impact of
cultural tourism on identity can be applied directly to the Bedouin case
that is the focus of this study. These Bedouin are engaged in a form
of tourism that reproduces their particularist culture, as opposed to a
national “Egyptian” culture.
The museum, a fundamental element of tourism, is constructed to
reflect historical continuity between the past and the present.255 This
is applicable to culture museums as well as archeology museums.
254. Daher, Tourism in the Middle East, p. 4.
255. Anderson, Imagined Communities, p. 181.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
177
Museums not only allow the state to construct spaces fuelling identity,
but also allow states to attach their own meanings to such artifacts and
draw their own historical connections which serve to legitimize the
state’s sociopolitical program. The display of such artifacts also aids
the state in a process Benedict Anderson refers to as “logoization,” or
the forging of past images into contemporary symbols.256
Furthermore, the museum is a tool that allows the state to draw
identity boundaries and establish historical narratives. In the Egyptian
case, there are a number of important cultural and archeological
museums, including the so-called “Egyptian Museum” (in fact the
Pharaonic Museum of Egyptian Antiquities), the Nubian Museum,
and the Coptic Museum. That the Copts and Nubians have separate
museums expresses an underlying political meaning. Nubian and
Coptic history have been deliberately left out of the “Egyptian
Museum,” as they are considered to be minority or peripheral
groups and do not carry the same type of “Egyptian” identity. While
the Nubians (non-Pharaonic, and indeed non-Arab) and the Copts
(non-Muslim) are excluded from the core Egyptian identity, their
representation through these museums reflects an official recognition
of their collective existence as minorities and their categorization as
such.The Bedouin, on the other hand, have no museum and are not
considered an officially recognized minority.
Reid presents another interpretation, one organized temporally
instead of culturally but which leads to the same conclusion. The
official narrative of Egyptian identity is enshrined in the dedication
of four major museums in Cairo to one major historical era: the
Pharaonic, the Greco-Roman, the Coptic, and the Islamic.257 Again,
this progression reflects the historical continuity of the Nile and
diverges from Bedouin perceptions of their historical narrative. In
this way, the Bedouin’s existence as an autonomous social group in
a socio-historical sense is contested by the state, further fuelling their
preoccupation with heritage defense and their desire to communicate
themselves as culturally different from “Egyptians.” This has led the
Bedouin to perceive that they have been “left out” of the Egyptian
narrative, further alienating them from a sense of Egyptian solidarity.
256. Ibid., p. 182.
257. Reid, “Nationalizing the Pharaonic Past,” p. 146.
Chapter 5
178
This feeling of sociopolitical marginalization parallels their economic
marginalization. As opposed to Copts and Nubians, who are merely
marginalized by the state, the Bedouin are denied by the state,
meaning the very existence of their collective identity is contested.
Finally, national institutions and bureaucracies are important
sources of socialization and transmit Egyptian national identity,
reflecting the coexistence of Islamic and pre-Islamic history. This
takes on a number of forms. At the most basic level of symbolism
is Egyptian money, which is designed to reflect the two sources of
Egyptian identity. On all denominations of Egyptian paper currency,
the basic design is to place a Pharaonic symbol on one side and an
Islamic symbol on the other. For example, the 100 LE note displays
a picture of the Sphinx on one side and the Mosque of Sultan Hassan
on the other, while the 20 LE note displays images of Egyptian
hieroglyphs on one side and the Muhammad ‘Ali Mosque on the
other. In addition to currency, there are other outlets for the display
of national symbols such as postage stamps, the architecture of public
spaces (such as parks, malls, and public squares), and street names.
These symbols, taken from archeological and historical spaces, have
been forged into reproducible logos that have come to represent Egypt
and are designed to evoke a sense of national identification and pride
around which group feeling is structured. In this way, certain aspects
of Egyptian history have become symbols of collective identity, easily
recognized and reproduced, around which Egyptians have come to
structure their cultural self-image. While these symbols appear wholly
organic to many Egyptians, certain groups, the Bedouin included, see
them as alien.
Institutions with more active socializing functions include education
and the media. In his first edition of Imagined Communities,
Benedict Anderson stated, “so often in the nation building policies of
the new states, one sees… a systematic, even Machiavellian, instilling
of nationalist ideology through the mass media, the educational
system, administrative regulations, and so forth.”258 While Anderson
subsequently backed away from this statement in his second edition,
it is clear that in many single party states with tight control over
258. Anderson, Imagined Communities, pp. 113–114, 1st edition.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
179
education and the media, these organs have been used to instill a
nationalist ideology supportive of state-disseminated histories and
identities. In the Middle East, the life’s work of Sati al-Husri and his
impact on nationalist education in Syria and Iraq is illustrative of this
claim.259 Not without substantiation is the suggestion that “liberal” or
“democratic” states do the same.
Images of Egyptian identity are reproduced in the national press
as well as public education. The Egyptian press “provides numerous
examples of the widespread effort to link contemporary Egypt with its
Pharaonic past.”260 Even the names of major Egyptian media outlets
reflect this endeavor. Two notable examples are the radio station el-
Nil (the Nile) and the newspaper al-Ahram (the pyramids). Public
education focuses on the Pharaonic origins of the Egyptian nation.261
In Sinai, Bedouin school children are confronted with stories glorifying
ancient Egypt in their school books, full of tales of the pyramids and
the Pharaohs, which they consider to be quite alien to their own
cultural narrative. These socializing institutions are avenues through
which central authorities disseminate symbols of national identity and
nationalist ideologies (national values), and strive towards national
integration by inculcating society with a singular set of symbols,
values, and a uniform world view around which social solidarities are
structured.262
Egyptian national identity is clearly particularistic, reflecting the
uniqueness of Egypt’s core, increasing its legitimacy for national
existence. However, the acceptability of this identity among non-core
elements of Egypt’s population has been problematic, further showing
that Egyptian national identity is not considered universal among all
segments of Egypt’s population; instead it is only applicable to the
core of Egyptian society, identified as Nile Valley Sunni Muslims (the
intersection of the legacies of the Nile and of Islam). Among other
259. William L. Cleveland, The Making of an Arab Nationalist: Ottomanism
and Arabism in the Life and Thought of Sati al-Husri (Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 1971).
260. Gershoni and Jankowski, Commemorating the Nation, p. 52.
261. Ibid., p. 53.
262. James Turner, “Universal Education and Nation Building in Africa,”
Journal of Black Studies 2.1 (1971), pp. 3–13.
Chapter 5
180
social groups in Egypt, such as the Coptic Christians, the Nubians,
and the Arabic-speaking Muslim Bedouin unconnected to the legacy
of the Nile, this identity has been perceived as exclusionary.
This leads to the problem of minority formation within states.
Minorities form in precisely this situation where social boundaries
have been drawn to exclude certain social groups from national
membership.263 This may potentially occur when the state disseminates
very narrow ethnic identities, if it discriminates against specific social
groups, or in situations where equally applied laws inherently favor
one group over another, for example, by supporting inequitable
status-quo situations such as land and employment allocation in
South Sinai. Smith links the formation of minorities to expressions
of ethno-nationalism, where “only people of a presumed descent can
be members of the ethnic nation.”264 While nationalism constitutes
a drive towards homogenization and the implementation of cultural
uniformity, it is simultaneously exclusionary, “creating outsiders
within,” by placing rigid constraints on national membership.265
The formation of minorities relates not only to national sentiment,
but also to greater issues of political and economic inequality and
discrimination. This is because members of the national core, or
those ascribing to dominant identities and ideologies, are generally
privileged by the state when it comes to allocation of resources. The
case of the Bedouin and the Egyptian migrant workers in Sinai is a
powerful example of this phenomenon, where the distributive role of
the Egyptian state gives priority to the migrants and sets the stage
for the competition between them and the Bedouin, leading to the
simultaneous emergence of an identity boundary between the Bedouin
and the Egyptians. Smith elucidates this issue and deserves to be
quoted in full:
Not only are jobs and houses reserved for members of the
dominant ethnie… aliens within become politically suspect or
vulnerable. In these circumstances they may be discriminated
263. Eriksen, Ethnicity and Nationalism, p. 108.
264. Smith, Myths and Memories of the Nation, pp. 187–192.
265. Ibid., p. 197.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
181
against, harassed, segregated, and finally expelled or even
exterminated…
More often, ethnic nationalism does not involve a specifically
racist component, but manages to exclude non-members within
and deny them their rights while preserving their essential
humanity.266
These groups are seen as a threat to national solidarity and
nationalist goals, and will often be the subject of attempts at forceful
transformation or suppression. Yet again there is a strong link
between identity and ideology. In the context of contemporary states
and nationalism, ethnicity is a powerful method of contesting the
legitimacy of nationalism and national ideologies.
Identity Transformation and the Aqaba
Bedouin
What, then, is driving the observed patterns of identity transformation
among the Aqaba Bedouin and how is this identity manifested? First
and foremost, we have seen that identity transformation occurs in
periods of increasing economic and political integration stemming
from processes of state- and nation-building. Smith identifies two
particular instances where ethnogenesis is most likely to occur. First
is what he refers to as “incipient secularization,” or “the nub of a
wider clash of cultures, usually between a technologically superior…
civilization and a more traditional, backwater one.”267 Second is
“incipient commercialization… breaking down the community’s
isolation and involving it in an external economic network based on a
superior material culture and technology.”268 Rabinovich and Esman,
in their look at ethnicity, come to a similar conclusion: “Conditions
that give rise to ethnic [mobilization] are (1) control by the modern
state of the political and economic resources that are vital to the
security and wellbeing of its inhabitants and (2) tensions between the
266. Ibid.
267. Ibid., p. 84.
268. Ibid.
Chapter 5
182
pluralism of society and the claims of the state to regulate the lives of
all who live within its territorial boundaries.”269
Both of these definitions suggest that ethnic mobilization is most
likely to occur in reaction to processes of state- and nation-building and
periods of accelerating integration, especially when the interests of the
core clash with the interests of the periphery. In Sinai, it is clear that
Egyptian preferences for development have not been wholeheartedly
accepted by the Bedouin, who fear attempts to suppress their
heritage (symbolic) and deprive them of their resources (political).
In concurrence with this rejection of Egyptian goals and ideologies,
seen as threatening, the Bedouin have also rejected Egyptian national
identities, seen as particularistic and exclusive. They have chosen an
ethnically-articulated “Bedouin” identity as a preferred alternative.
The strength of the Bedouin reaction appears to be directly related
to the intensity of the attempt to forcefully disseminate an “Egyptian”
identity and pursue national programs, just as the strength of the
previously mentioned Amazigh revival was directly related to the
intensity of Morocco’s Arabization program.
The Aqaba Bedouin, as a social category, fulfill Smith’s basic
requirements to constitute an ethnic category: they have a collective
name, they believe in a myth of common descent, they see a relatively
shared history based on their shared culture, and they lay claim to
a specific territorial component (or type) within Egypt. It should be
kept in mind, however, that it is not merely the successful attainment
of these elements that give these groups ethnic legitimacy, but the
extent to which they can claim these elements and to which these
elements are externally recognizable. It is not, then, legitimate to
reject a Bedouin ethnic category because of the existence of an Arab
ethnicity, which, incidentally, also does not conform exactly to Smith’s
notion of ethnie because of issues of weak solidarity, contestations of
common descent, and specific notions of shared culture. Additionally,
as Gershoni and Jankowski identify in the Egyptian case, “Nationalists
rediscover, reconstruct, and in some cases invent narratives of
a glorious past,” showing that national identities can be socially
269. Esman and Rabinovich, Ethnicity, Pluralism, and the State in the
Middle East, p. 3.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
183
constructed and the clash of identities is largely a political struggle.270
Identity is necessarily an abstraction from reality, not a claim that
individuals within a group are identical in all ways. This leaves open
the possibility for contestation of different identities based on different
types of abstraction.
Thus, the existence of the Egyptian nation is no more objective
than the existence of a Bedouin ethnie; the primary existence of each
construct is in the minds and expressions of its partisans.271 Instead,
“Egyptian nation” and “Bedouin ethnie” should be understood as
competing sources of primary solidarity whose relative legitimacy is
not objective, but is the source of competition between the identities.
Once again, the identity that will be favored is the one that holds
the most utility for its proponents. There is little sense in working
to mobilize an identity with zero contemporary relevance just as
there is little sense in working to mobilize an invented identity with
zero historical legitimacy. This is not, however, an attempt to assert
that the Bedouin constitute a “nation” or an incorporated ethnic
community. Instead, Bedouin ethnogenesis is a rejection of attempts
to make the Bedouin into “Egyptians,” which rigid Egyptian policies
have rendered practically impossible anyway, or otherwise force them
into conformity with Egyptian goals.
Major elements of Bedouin cultural identity have evolved to
legitimize the separate existence of the Bedouin as an ethnic category
by focusing on elements of a shared, distinct culture, claims to a
territory, and myths of common descent. Most important of these
elements are those that highlight the major cultural differences between
the Bedouin and central Egyptians, and that present Bedouin values as
superior. These elements have become the primary characteristics in
defining a Bedouin identity. For example, the Bedouin communicate
themselves as generous and hospitable while they assert that the
Egyptians, because of their authoritarian development policies, are
greedy and subjugating. The Bedouin also stress their attachment to
the desert, contrasted to Egyptian dependence on the Nile and urban
spaces. For the Bedouin, the desert symbolizes freedom and nobility
while the river and the city symbolize dependence and subjugation.
270. Gershoni and Jankowski, Commemorating the Nation, p. 8.
271. Daher, Tourism in the Middle East, p. 19.
Chapter 5
184
To this they add conceptions of honor and masculinity, casting
Egyptian social behavior as feminine and dishonorable. Key elements
of Bedouin identity, then, have been articulated to contrast with their
perceptions of Egyptian identity: that the Bedouin are noble and free
while the Egyptians are slaves. This dichotomization serves to establish
a boundary between “self” and “other,” as well as an uneven power
dynamic where “self” identity is a source of pride in direct contrast
to the identity of the “other,” which is portrayed as inferior. This
maintains distinct boundaries between the two social groups as well as
aids in the formation of value-system bases for group solidarity.
The primary factors encouraging the transformation of
identity among the Bedouin are those processes identified by the
instrumentalists, notably Barth, Cohen, and Eriksen. These identities
provide the basis for effective group mobilization and solidarity, seen
as preferable to dominant, hegemonic core identities, as well as a way
to regulate resource competition. They emerge in reaction to uneven
political and economic development between core and peripheral
social groups. An important aspect of these identities is that they are
assumed in reaction to certain shortcomings of nationalist ideology—
primarily the falsehood that nationalism is universal and egalitarian.
In actuality, nationalism is either too particularistic and cannot apply
to all the social groups inhabiting a socially heterogeneous state (as
in issues of Egyptian core national identity), or it is too universal and
does not give individuals clear placement in their social environment,
generating the need to add an additional element of identity, for
example, hyphenated ethnicities in America.
In both of these situations, ethnicity remains a powerful source
of mobilization and is often adopted as an alternative to dominant
national identities. This is not to say that groups will turn to pre-
existing ethnic identities, but that, just as nationalism is legitimized
by history, culture, and descent, these alternative identities have been
articulated in the same way. An identity previously unrecognized as
“ethnic” may begin to adopt ethnic elements as national integration
accelerates and the contest between groups becomes political. The
Aqaba Bedouins’ increasing integration into the urban environment of
Dahab and Egyptian society has motivated a turn towards a political
form of identity and solidarity designed to contest expressions of
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
185
Egyptian national identity. Their place within the Egyptian state and
its society is the primary concern for the Bedouin.
This, further, does not require the forging of extensive ties of
solidarity across the entirety of the group, especially in situations
of limited contact. For better or worse, it is often the case that a
sense of ethnic identity means loyalty to an identity as a badge or
imagined community, not necessarily to the individual members
of that community. In tribal contexts, a number of studies of North
African Berbers and Native Americans show that ethnogenesis can be
motivated in divided tribal societies based on state policies that relate
to them as a single category.
In North Africa, ethnically articulated tensions between Arab
and Berber groups have peaked in times of intense nation-building,
when authorities have attempted to promote one cultural identity
over another or, in the case of Libya, attempted to forcefully
repress certain expressions of alternate cultural identities.272 This
systematic categorization was the primary factor establishing the
basis for collective Berber mobilization that crossed tribal boundaries.
While there was, to a certain extent, a transnational element to this
cultural movement, Maddy-Weitzman clearly demonstrates that the
movements themselves focused on national politics in both the
Moroccan and Algerian cases, even though this identity may have
crossed national borders.273 Jonathan Wyrtzen, in his study on Berber
identity formation in interwar Morocco, comes to a similar conclusion
for a previous era, that French colonial attempts at state building
provided a framework for a “Berber” ethnicity by institutionalizing the
category across from an “Arab” ethnicity through policies of divide
and rule.274
Similarly, Eugene Roosens identified the emergence of what he
called “pan-Indian culture” in Canada that encompassed all Native
American tribes by conforming to general, positive stereotypes
272. Soleiman, “Denied Existence: Libyan-Berbers under Gaddafi and Hope
for the Current Revolution.”
273. Maddy-Weitzman, “Contested Identities: Berbers, ‘Berberism’ and the
state in North Africa.”
274. Wyrtzen, “Colonial State Building and the Negotiation of Arab and
Berber Identity in Protectorate Morocco,” p. 229.
Chapter 5
186
held within Canadian society. Despite historical enmities between
individual tribes, pan-Indian mobilization “unites all Indians against all
outsiders.”275 This type of mobilization was made possible due to the
singular approach the Canadian government took regarding all Native
American tribes. By conceiving of them as a single society, even in
a case where there were significant internal linguistic and cultural
divisions, the Canadian government created the basis for shared
interest and group mobilization. In a number of different states, tribal
groups have proven equally vulnerable to the social consequences of
national politics by reacting to state policies through forging inter-tribal
solidarities in the cases where tribally divided groups are conceived of
as a single and relatively homogenous society.
The Aqaba Bedouin have been subject to similar treatment by
Egyptian authorities, who see the Bedouin as constituting a singular
type of “traditional society.” The legitimacy of the separate existence
of these Bedouin, however, is more easily contested and has been
suppressed to a much larger extent than those of the Berber and
Native American tribal groups. This is primarily because the Bedouin
share the same religion and language as dominant national society and
thus appear culturally similar, as opposed to the Amazigh and Native
Americans, who clearly constitute a separate sociolinguistic category
in their respective states. Ironically, this has created somewhat
of a paradox of identity for the Aqaba Bedouin: while Egyptians
conceive of them as “Bedouin,” characterized as a particular type
of “traditional” society distinctly separate from their own “modern,”
national society, they contest the existence of a Bedouin identity
category. Simultaneously the state categorizes the Bedouin and denies
them.
However, these claims about sociolinguistic uniformity are also
largely political. For while it is easy to claim that all Egyptians speak
“Arabic,” this covers deep linguistic divisions within the Arabic
language. This is by no means limited to a discussion of “national
dialects,” which merely serve to reinforce the fiction of social
homogeneity within national borders. In my discussions with the
Bedouin, a number have told me that they have encountered major
275. Eugene Roosens, Creating Ethnicity (London: Sage, 1989). See also
Eriksen, Ethnicity and Nationalism, p. 70.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
187
linguistic obstacles when trying to communicate with Egyptians in
Cairo.276 One even remarked that he was forced to resort to English
because no one in Cairo could understand his dialect. Furthermore,
several Bedouin reported that during trips to central Egypt, they were
often considered foreigners, with “Saudi” being the most common
categorization, based not merely on language, but also on dress and
even skin color and body-type:
One time I was in Tahrir Square during the revolution, and I
was there with my Jalabiyya. Some people came to me and
said, “You are Saudi Arabian, you support the government [of
Mubarak].” And I said, “I am not Saudi, I am Egyptian.” And
no one believed. I showed them my ID card and they told me
that it was fake. And I said, “No man, I am Egyptian. I come
from Sinai, I am Bedouin.” And one old guy came over and
said, “It’s good, it’s ok, the Bedouin.” And the people left, but
they had wanted to fight with me.277
These Egyptians are clearly conflating “Saudi” and Bedouin, which
further demonstrates the way in which ethnicity and nationalism
are tied together as well as how ethnic identity often presupposes
cultural and ideological characteristics and relations between people.
More importantly for this argument, despite political claims to social
uniformity—as a “category of practice” instead of merely an abstract
“category of analysis”—distinctions are often drawn between Egyptian
and Bedouin social groups, even to the extent that Egyptian Bedouin
are occasionally “informed” that they are not Egyptian.
But in any event, as this examination of ethnicity has demonstrated,
identity is not necessarily grounded in a concrete number or type of
cultural structures such as language or religion, and in the case of the
Aqaba Bedouin, their distinctive identity is based, not on language
or religion, but on a more general type of culture based on origins
and descent, elements that can define a boundary between Bedouin
and Egyptian categories. In the Egyptian context, the Arabic language
276. Interview with Land activists, May 14, 2009; Interview with Bedouin
Divemaster, July 24, 2009; Interview with Community Organizer, May
30, 2012.
277. Interview with a Community Organizer, May 30, 2012.
Chapter 5
188
and the Islamic religion do not constitute major aspects of Bedouin
identity used in their heritage defense, as this would undermine their
claims to social uniqueness. Instead, the Aqaba Bedouin focus on
those things that they do not share with “Egyptians,” such as their
tribal affiliations and nomadic descent. While these aspects of Bedouin
culture undoubtedly form legitimate bases for ethnic mobilization,
the conventional wisdom on ethnicity does not often hold these
characteristics in the same regard as language, religion, or certain
“racial” qualities such as skin color. Such an identity might therefore
be considered “less legitimate” and thus more easily contestable by
essentialists and state authorities.
Despite this legitimacy dilemma, these major aspects of Bedouin
culture have formed the basis for group interests and inter-tribal
solidarities. While tribally-based divisions continue to exist, there is
now a clearly identifiable “Bedouin culture” and singular government
policies are setting the stage for group mobilization.278 In this way, tribal
divisions may continue to limit the type of ties that might be formed
between members of different tribes, but in national contexts, an
ethnically-articulated Bedouin identity is presented as an alternative to
Egyptian identity, not an identity grounded in specific tribal affiliations,
which form a different type of solidarity that operates in different
contexts. Furthermore, the Bedouin are increasingly articulating an
emerging “Bedouin culture” in their expressions, and recognize that
it is forming the basis of shared interests. Now, when discussing their
traditions with outsiders such as tourists, they do not say “We, the
Mzeina, do X,” instead they increasingly say “We, the Bedouin, do
X,” where “Bedouin” is a socio-cultural category operating in national
political contexts.
As the Sinai increasingly becomes “state space,” defined as territory
under effective control of state forces, the Egyptian authorities are
more and more able to apply laws and regulations that institutionalize
278. Barkey and Parikh, “Comparative Perspectives on the State.” This
supports their claim, “it has already become evident that state policies
constituted one of the major determinants of mobilization and shifting
identity patterns.”
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
189
this social boundary.279 While it is clear that the Egyptian authorities
are not undertaking a concerted effort to create any institutional
antagonism between the Bedouin and the Egyptian migrant workers,
as French colonial policy of divide and rule often did in North Africa,
the outcomes have not differed significantly due to the prioritization of
central Egyptian interests over local Bedouin interests. Furthermore,
as it becomes clear that the authorities conceive of the Bedouin as
a separate category, they are providing a pre-determined avenue
for political mobilization by the Bedouin, even if this mobilization
is suppressed in a non-democratic environment. Thus, the basis
for a cross-tribal solidarity emerges, one that includes all tribes that
consider themselves “Bedouin” and are seen that way by the Egyptian
government, often conceiving of the Bedouin as tribal and Egyptians
as non-tribal. In this case, perhaps ironically, it is the very fact that
Bedouin individuals in Egypt hold tribal identities that constitutes the
basis for cross-tribal ethnic solidarities.
We have seen instances of cross-tribal Bedouin solidarities in
Dahab, where members of the Mzeina tribe prefer to work or associate
with members of the Aleqat or Jabaliyya tribes instead of mainland
Egyptians.280 We have also seen more removed expressions of this
solidarity as well, in interactions between the Mzeina and a visiting
Jordanian Bedouin, who was welcomed by the Sinai Bedouin as one
of their own despite having different national and tribal origins.281 As
we were walking along the Dahab corniche, we were invited into a
Bedouin tent that had been erected on a hotel construction site owned
by a local Bedouin. As we spoke with the group, they referred to one
of the men and informed us that he was not from Sinai, that he was
279. James C.Scott, The Art of Not Being Governed: An Anarchist
History of Upland Southeast Asia (New Haven: Yale University Press,
2009). See especially chapter two, “State space: Zones of Governance
and Appropriation.” See also Wyrtzen, “Colonial State Building and
the Negotiation of Arab and Berber Identity in Protectorate Morocco,”
p. 230.
280. Observations from Bedouin-Bedouin and Bedouin-Egyptian encounters
in Dahab.
281. Observations from an afternoon with an Anize Bedouin from Jordan in
Dahab, February 11, 2010.
Chapter 5
190
a member of an Anize tribe from Jordan, in Egypt on business but
in Sinai for a short vacation.Despite different national origins, they
referred to this Bedouin as a cousin due to similar ethnic origins. It
did not matter that he was Jordanian, not Egyptian, or even that he
was Anize, not Mzeini, all that mattered is that they considered him
to be a “Bedouin,” which provided the basis for their feelings that
this visitor was part of their core solidarity group.This identification
involved a certain amount of triangulation, leading to the selection
of this particular identity as opposed to wider (national) or narrower
(tribal) possibilities, which could have increased their perceived social
distance if selected. Furthermore, in our conversation, the Anize
Bedouin stated that he very much enjoyed his time in Sinai and always
visited Dahab after his business in Cairo was concluded. He felt very
comfortable in Dahab because there were many Bedouin, to which he
contrasted his feelings of discomfort in “Misr” (Egypt proper), which
he described as loud, crowded, and inhospitable.
The ability of a “Bedouin” identity to trump tribal divisions in
these cases has to do with arenas in which identities are deployed. All
individuals hold multiple identities including religion, nationality, tribe,
gender, etc. These is often referred to as “levels of identity”; however,
I prefer not to use the term “levels” as I do not view these multiple
identities in a strict hierarchy where one is necessarily overshadowed
by another. Instead, it is preferable to identify the arenas in which
each identity operates; the primary identity deployed is contextual,
not strictly segmentary.282 In tribal contexts, or in the absence of state
authority in Sinai, tribal identities might be best suited to regulate
intergroup dynamics between different tribes, which would create
meaningful divisions between solidarity groups. However, in the
context of state interactions, which have increased dramatically over
the last half century, these tribal identities no longer have the same
practical function, as the Egyptian state does not treat individual tribes
differently and conceives of all as simply “Bedouin.” Furthermore,
continued inter-tribal competition would render this group less
282. Identity selection is not, however, an individual choice. It should instead
be understood as shaped by collective decision-making processes and
power-relations within the arenas in question. This is one aspect of
identity formation that Posner does not address.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
191
able to compete in national interactions. Categorization creates a
natural avenue for collective mobilization based on shared interests
that develop in reaction to policies targeting the group. It further
shows the extent to which identities can be imposed externally and
how categorization can create the basis for solidarity through these
aforementioned shared interests. As a hypothetical counter factual,
if Egyptian policies differentiated between tribes or tribal groupings,
for example, between the Tawara (South Sinai) and the Tiyaha
(Central and North Sinai), it is probable that these identities would
be deployed and developed as state policies would have given them
political significance, and they might thus form the basis for group
mobilization and competition. While this statement is impossible to
test within this study, it is the case that in other Arab states—notably
Saudi Arabia and several other Gulf states, as well as Saddam’s Iraq
after the Gulf War—tribal identities have proven quite significant as
avenues for definition and resource distribution and, consequently,
competition.283
In Sinai, this is not the case and it does not make political sense
for the Bedouin to mobilize along tribal lines in interactions with the
state.Similarly, it does not make practical sense to mobilize along
religious lines, even though the Bedouin hold an Islamic identity.
While in Egypt, there is an element of Muslim-Christian conflict, in
the Bedouins’ sociopolitical space this conflict is largely absent, and
further, Islam is not a source of distinction between the Bedouin and
the groups with which they are in conflict. Thus, there would be little
utility in adopting and communicating an Islamic element as a primary
indicator of group distinctiveness.This is why “Bedouin,” and not
some other source of collective identification, has become the primary
source of identity for the Aqaba Bedouin in this context.
In the aftermath of the national uprisings of January-February
2011 that drove President Husni Mubarak from power, the Egyptian
283. For example, see Joseph Kostiner, “Transforming Dualities: Tribe and
State Formation in Saudi Arabia,” in Philip S. Khoury and Joseph
Kostiner (eds.), Tribes and State Formation in the Middle East
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990). On Iraq, see Amatzia
Baram, “Neo-Tribalism in Iraq: Saddam Hussein’s Tribal Policies 1991–
96,” International Journal of Middle East Studies 29.1 (1997).
Chapter 5
192
state cannot be considered any less “authoritarian.” Yet the temporary
power vacuum and state of disorganization have created an opening
for Bedouin political mobilization. In Sinai in March 2011, Bedouin
across Sinai laid the groundwork for a number of ethnically-oriented
structures, including an all-Bedouin television station as well as an
inter-tribal Bedouin council to interact with the Egyptian military
regime.284 On a more local level, a Bedouin business owner in Dahab
has been trying to organize a Bedouin community center in Dahab
for the express purpose of allocating resources such as employment
as well as providing a center for cultural activities in the town, once
again reflecting Cohen’s dual roles of ethnic identity. Regarding the
previous lack of Bedouin political mobilization, a Bedouin journalist
from Sinai stated, “We [the Bedouin] have been neglected for a long
time and prevented from expressing ourselves,” suggesting that the
lack of ethnically-articulated Bedouin institutions stemmed not from a
lack of solidarity or will, but from the active suppression of civil society
by the Egyptian regime.285 Even this journalist’s statement is reflective
of the recognition of both a shared culture and political interests. The
early attempts at ethnic mobilization following the collapse of the
Egyptian regime reinforce his claim.
It is clear from the Bedouins’ own expressions of their cultural
self-image that they are conforming closer to concepts of ethnic
“Bedouin” identities over other, notably tribal, forms of identity. As
this ethnic identity is less objectively distinctive than the other tribal
examples cited earlier, notably the Amazigh and Native Americans,
the legitimacy of a Bedouin identity is far more easily contestable.
However, this does not in any way mean that the processes involved
are not having significant impacts on Bedouin identity. In fact, this
contestation of a Bedouin identity can be seen as a fundamental
element of social conflict.
One last point must be made about identity formation and the
Bedouin, which is that this phenomenon is clearly not unique to this
group, and these patterns of socioeconomic change and identity
transformation in response to state building are phenomena that
284. Amirah Ibrahim, “Push and Pull,” Al-Ahram Weekly, March 3–9,
2011. <http://weekly.ahram.org.eg/2011/1037/eg41.htm>.
285. Ibid.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
193
can be found in practically all developing countries, for example the
adoption of certain tastes of sports and music. Why, then, are these
Bedouin an interesting case study? I believe it has to do with the
distinction between what some scholars have labeled the third and
fourth worlds, where the third world, now that the Cold War is over, is
a term that refers to developing states, and the fourth world is a term
that nominally refers to indigenous people or what are conceived of
as “traditional societies,” often seen as autarkic and static.286 This is
clearly not the case, and the idea of the “unchanging Bedouin” is as
inaccurate as the idea, once quite popular, of the “unchanging East”
that motivated past Orientalist discourse. What was once perceived as
a conflict between the Developed and the Developing Worlds during
the Age of Imperialism has shifted to one between the Developing and
the Indigenous Worlds in the Age of States. In this way, socioeconomic
transformation and identity formation are directly linked; both are
reactions to state development policies geared at state- and nation-
building. Furthermore, under these conditions, the most likely type of
identity to develop is ethnic in nature, articulated along cultural lines
to maintain a distinctive group identity.
Towards an Environmental Theory of
Identity Transformation
From the discussion above, focused on the question “What can
ethnicity theory tell us about Bedouin identity?,” we inevitably arrive
at the opposite question: What, if anything, can the Bedouin and
their increasing interaction with the state tell us about identity and
its transformation? I believe the answer is quite a bit, especially in
comparison with the other examples discussed in this chapter. Taken
together, an interesting pattern begins to emerge, one based on the
role of external forces. While often marginalized in the study of identity,
286. See George Manuel and Michael Posluns, The Fourth World: An Indian
Reality (Collier: MacMillan Canada, 1974). For another definition of
Fourth World, see “International Day of the World’s Indigenous People,”
Asian Center for the Progress of Peoples.
Chapter 5
194
it should be evident from this analysis that external perceptions and
sustained interactions appear to have a powerful influence in shaping
identities and their articulation. Theories of constructivism already
acknowledge the importance of processes of interaction in shaping
and sustaining certain identities.287 This observation simultaneously
provides an explanation for the primordial elements of identity,
represented by the cultural symbols and labels attached to certain
identities, as well as the contingent nature of identities, or more
specifically their contextual definitions, which hinge on interactions
with particular sociopolitical groups whose own identities and interests
vary from state to state.
A number of the empirical and theoretical works cited above
seem to support this claim, as their own analyses acknowledge the
importance of outsider perceptions in their discussions of legitimacy
and meaning. For example, Smith’s definition of ethnic legitimacy
hinges on the recognition of history and cultural distinctiveness “in the
eyes of outsiders,” and even his definition of ethnicity hinges on the
recognition of traits “by outsiders.” Furthermore, as Maddy-Weitzman
and Wyrtzen demonstrate, periods of heightened cultural mobilization
in North Africa appear to be responses to attempts at suppression
by politically powerful others. My own observations support these
claims. Reid, in his discussion of Egyptian national identity, suggests
that Pharaonism became a key element of Egyptian identity as a result
of British and French attempts to monopolize and appropriate the
field of Egyptology.Too, anthropologists such as Cohen and Mitchell
discuss the activation of identity conflict, which is what Eriksen means
when he analyzes ethnic identities as a product of interaction.
But again, these claims should not be taken to mean that identities
themselves do not exist independent of interactions with others.288 I
once again appeal to the distinction between stereotype and symbol
to clarify the distinction between the constructivist elements of identity
and the “primordial.”
287. Alexander Wendt, “Anarchy Is What States Make of It: The Social
Construction of Power Politics,” International Organization 46.2
(1992), p. 421.
288. Or otherwise stated, that these identities cannot be sustained outside of
the initial interaction that produced them.
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
195
The psychological concept of altercasting has the potential to
contribute a great deal to our understanding of identity transformation
through interaction. While this concept has been studied in the fields
of social psychology, marketing, and to a limited extent, international
relations, it has rarely been applied to theories of ethnicity and identity
formation. However, with slight modifications it may provide valuable
insight into the manner in which hegemonic political actors define
social groups and project roles onto them. Altercasting is defined as
“a technique of interactor control where ego [self] uses tactics of self-
presentation and stage management in an attempt to frame alter’s
[other] definitions of social situations in ways that create the roles in
which ego desires alter to play.”289 In this way, definitions assumed by
the state and reified through the formation of policies are projected
onto social groups with the expectation that these groups will behave
in the manner described. It should be clear that attempts to impose
“legibility” represent less active (at least in their articulation) attempts
to align state expectations with the behavioral patterns of the social
groups in question.290
In the application of the concept of altercasting, a major input in
the transformation of identity is the state, whose policies provide a
set of constraints that crystallize a structural reality for social groups
within that field. This structure should be considered both economic
and social, ascribing both acceptable economic roles as well as
“official” social definitions to particular groups. The marginalization of
the Bedouin stems not merely from uneven economic policies favored
by state authorities, but also from the suspicious attitudes projected
towards the Bedouin, which shape the manner in which authorities
treat them, a quintessential example of altercasting. In turn, these
projected attitudes shape the manner in which the Bedouin conceive
of their role in Egyptian society as well as their relationship to state
authorities and other social groups within the state.
Another element of altercasting is the role that political power plays
in the direction of this projection. It has been clearly demonstrated that
both the state and the Bedouin have perceptions of the other that are
quite different from their own self-perceptions. In a situation where
289. Wendt, “Anarchy is what states make of it,” p. 421.
290. Scott, Seeing Like a State.
Chapter 5
196
both groups try and cast the other, what can be said about which
side prevails? There is little doubt that power asymmetries play a
significant role in determining the outcome of this interaction, and the
definitions perpetuated by the state have penetrated further than the
definitions perpetuated by the Bedouin. Returning to the modification
of Wendt’s maxim, “If [powerful] men define situations as real, they
are real in their consequences,” we might conclude that power is
what gives state authorities the ability to impose their interests and
social definitions on other social groups.
Of course, this does not necessarily say anything about where and
when identity conflict will break out, since it is not necessarily the case
that an incorrect essentialization of a social group will activate conflict;
groups may accept the stereotypes and roles ascribed to them and
comply with their subordination. In fact, for our current purposes, let
us assume that the state is always incorrect in its essentialization of
social groups (this may not be categorically true but is unproblematic
for this argument). In this situation, identity conflict is activated when
the essentialized social group refuses to accept the roles ascribed
to them and instead continues to pursue its own interests through
other paths. I label this process “assertion” which can be constructed
diametrically against “subordination.” When expectation diverges
significantly from self-presentation, especially in situations where ego/
self is not interested in updating its expectations but instead desires to
force its expectations onto alter/other, this will create friction between
the two groups manifested in sociopolitical conflict.291 One possible
explanation for an ability to resist is relative capacity: if the social
group has the power to contest roles of subjugation, and it is the case
that the utility of resistance minus the resulting sanctions is higher
than the utility of subjugation, it is probable that they will do so.292 In
Aqaba, despite the state’s moral claims to legitimacy of power, their
291. On expectation versus self-presentation, see Weinstein and
Deutschberger, “Some Dimensions of Altercasting,” p. 456.
292. Formally resistance comes when Ua – P > Us where U is the utility
function for assertion (a) and subordination (s) and P represents the
sanction from attempts to resist. For an excellent formalization of the
political economy of identity, see Moses Shayo, “A Model of Social
Identity with an Application to Political Economy: Nation, Class, and
Redistribution,” American Political Science Review 103 (2009).
Ethnicity, Nationalism, and Identity Transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
197
capacity is relatively weak. This levels the playing field for the Bedouin
and undermines the state’s ability to sanction the Bedouin for failing
to conform to “acceptable” identities projected by the state. The state
has paid the price for their attempt to over-cast the Bedouin in a
situation where their repressive apparatus is too weak to back it up
with appropriate coercion.
Consequently, the emergence of a particular identity in a particular
context should be an equilibrium in which the identity adhered to
yields the greatest utility contingent on the decisions of all the other
actors in the arena and the structures that define it.293 This approach
is undeniably instrumental; however, it does not claim that individuals
may simply choose any identity they desire, a common accusation
directed against instrumentalist accounts of identity formation. Instead,
it suggests that we should be able to predict which identities will be
chosen as long as we know the institutions and actors within an arena
of contestation.
By creating policies that institutionalize a boundary between
national identities and “others,” the state has created a predetermined
avenue for identity mobilization. From a rational perspective, the state
has already done much of the “start-up” work for identity mobilization,
providing a set of shared interests and, on a psychological level,
reinforcing the idea that individuals are already members of that
group.294 This lowers the cost of mobilization for elites, increasing
the potential payoffs. This also provides a plausible mechanism that
explains the centrality of state policies in shifting identity patterns.
And alongside a discussion of the cognitive power of cultural symbols,
this further explains why identities are contingent as well as quite
persistent, external perceptions and structural conditions “pre-select”
and activate certain identities. Groups do not necessarily have the
ability to impose self-definitions of their own identity as sociopolitical
facts. This can be considered an “environmental” theory of identity
transformation.
293. This brings us to the type of equilibrium defined by John Nash in
1951. This is one of the central concepts of game theory. John Nash,
“Non-Cooperative Games,” The Annals of Mathematics 54.2 (1951),
pp. 286–295.
294. Weinstein and Deutschberger, “Some Dimensions of Altercasting,”
p. 456.
199
Conclusions
Tourism development along the Aqaba Coast by the Egyptian state
has instigated major socioeconomic transformations among the
Aqaba Bedouin. Through processes such as sedentarization and
urbanization, these Bedouin are becoming increasingly integrated
into emerging and developing urban structures in Sinai. The identity
processes that the Bedouin are currently undergoing are reflective of
these transformations and highlight processes of integration and state
building along a national periphery. The shape of this integration, as
well as the specific reaction of the Bedouin, is driven not by Bedouin
cultural peculiarities but by their reactions to the approach Egyptian
authorities have taken regarding Egypt’s Bedouin population and
Sinai development. Socioeconomic transformation among the
Bedouin in Dahab is a reaction to the shape of state development
schemes; increasing integration has resulted in increasing vulnerability
to, and reliance on, the institutions of the state. Simultaneously, as
the integration of the Bedouin accelerates, the identity processes that
have helped the Bedouin distinguish themselves from the population
of central Egypt have also accelerated. These identity processes are
not a cause of Bedouin attempts to increase their autonomy; they
are instead reactions to homogenizing processes of integration and
acculturation, leading social groups to become more concerned with
the expression of cultural continuity and group cohesion. In the face
of acculturation and social homogenization, the Bedouin are fighting
to maintain a distinctive and distinguishing identity.
Egyptian development in Sinai has produced two major
transformative reactions among the Aqaba Bedouin. The first is
a process of economic transformation as Bedouin economies have
been reorganized to take advantage of emerging opportunities.
This has frustrated Egyptian development policies, based on the
prioritization of core national interests at the expense of peripheral
interests. The Egyptians did not prepare to share the Sinai with the
Bedouin. Instead, development reports indicate an expectation that
the Bedouin would essentially “become Egyptian,” discarding their
Conclusions
200
traditional values and modes of socioeconomic organization in a
manner similar to the assumptions of modernization theory. This has
been the primary factor encouraging the emergence of a competitive
economic relationship between the Egyptians and the Bedouin in
Dahab. We may conclude from the clear empirical evidence that the
assumptions regarding the effects of the modernization paradigm for
development—notably that the homogenization of identities would
follow economic development—have proven unfounded.295
The second reaction has been social, as the Bedouin settling in
Dahab have adopted new social patterns to regulate their transforming
lives. The presence of foreigners has, perhaps, had the greatest social
effect on the Bedouin, leading to the adoption of many aspects of
Northern, globalized culture including dress, music, and the increasing
adoption of consumerist tendencies. The foreign symbols adopted
by the Aqaba Bedouin reflect increasing awareness of globalizing
culture as well as identification with foreign groups subjected to similar
state policies as opposed to greater identification with the values of
dominant social groups within their own state. This is a clear rejection
of nationalist ideology among the Bedouin, or more specifically, a
rejection of national interests and ideologies of the Egyptian state.
The Bedouin do not consider themselves Egyptian despite being
de jure citizens of the Egyptian state. This is because Egyptian policies
favoring the core interests of the central state have created an unequal
relationship benefiting Nile Valley Egyptians over the Bedouin; the
Bedouin are not granted the same rights or privileges. These issues of
Egyptian national interest, expressed through Egyptian development
policies and integration processes in Sinai, have resulted in reactive
identity processes that have led the Bedouin to reject Egyptian identity
due to an incompatibility with the Bedouins’ interest in defending their
resources and heritage. The Bedouin have instead sought to express
their identity through other avenues. Their orientation towards the
symbols and values of the tourists is one of the methods the Bedouin
have chosen to distinguish themselves from the rest of Egypt. A turn
towards an ethnically-articulated “Bedouin” identity has been another.
This identity focuses on symbols of Bedouin culture that differ from
295. Daher, “Reconceptualizing Tourism in the Middle East,” p. 21. See also
Huntington, Political Order in Changing Society.
Conclusions
201
Egyptian symbols and thus work to distinguish the Bedouin from
“Egyptians.” While it cannot be said that these symbols define the
boundary, since this boundary emerges from sociopolitical and
economic conflicts, they help render this boundary socially legible.
Through a fusion of elements of both distinguishing traditions as
well as adopted symbols, the Bedouin have been able to articulate an
identity that reflects local conditions and evolving values.
This is not to say that the treatment of Nile Valley Egyptians in a
setting such as Cairo is necessarily better than the treatment of the
Aqaba Bedouin. State authorities, especially the feared state security
apparatus run by the Interior Ministry, came to rely on repression
and intimidation in many cases, and instances of torture and violence
against Egyptians were not uncommon. The sheer brutality of security
forces, resulting in the deaths of some 846 unarmed protestors
during the national uprising of January and February 2011, clearly
demonstrate that Egyptian citizens do not have as harmonious a
relationship with the state as my discussion of Bedouin perceptions
might otherwise suggest.296 However, these actions are far less visible
to the Bedouin than the perceived favoritism shown to the Egyptians
in Dahab and across Sinai, and it is state conduct within this arena,
more than in faraway settings such as Cairo and Alexandria, that has
shaped Bedouin understandings of state attitudes towards the Bedouin
and other social groups within the Egyptian state. Bedouin perceptions
have formed within their primary sociopolitical environment, the Sinai
Peninsula.
While Egyptian policies are largely responsible for shaping the
framework of Bedouin economic transformation, including their
296. At the moment, it is unclear what direction this relationship will take.
However, following the collapse of the Mubarak regime in February
2011, the security apparatus of the Interior Ministry was more or less
replaced with that of the military. Death toll figures taken from: Mulakhas
al-Taqrir al-Niha’i li-Lajna al-Tahqiq wa-Taqassi al-Haqa’iq bi-Sha’n
al-Ahdath allati Wa¯qabat Thawrat 25 Yanayir 2011 (Summary of the
Fact Finding Committee for the Events Accompanying the Revolution
of 25 January 2011), National Committee for the investigation and
fact finding regarding the events of January 25, Arab Republic of Egypt
(Arabic), http://www.ffnc-eg.org/assets/ffnc-eg_final.pdf.
Conclusions
202
marginalization from resort tourism and their adoption of illegal
or illicit practices, the Egyptians have placed responsibility on the
Bedouin themselves, attributing these patterns of Bedouin economics
to a set of inherent cultural traits that force the Bedouin into the
category of a “traditional” society. Furthermore, the Sinai Bedouin
have quite often been associated with crime and terrorism, especially
in state pronouncements which eschew all responsibility for instability
in the Sinai and instead blame the Bedouin, reinforcing their negative
reputation. Once again, this has been attributed to certain cultural
characteristics of the Bedouin themselves and not, in any way, to the
harsh economic circumstances to which the Egyptians have subjected
the Bedouin and the relative benefits of illicit activities.
Instead of addressing the causes of Bedouin involvement in such
activities, Egyptian authorities have resorted to repressive measures
that have reinforced these perceptions, increased Bedouin involvement
in such activities, and occasionally sparked violent confrontations
between the Bedouin and Egyptian forces, especially in the north
of the peninsula. In recent years, this issue has been receiving
increasing attention in the media, with many press accounts focusing
on clashes between the Northern Sinai Bedouin and the Egyptian
police and army, portraying the Bedouin as restive and dangerous.
Increasingly, though, the media has given attention to the perspective
of the Bedouin, notably in an article published in The Economist in
August 2010, which examined the causes of Bedouin discontent,
stating, “Native tribes in the north of the peninsula complain they
have been marginalised and left impoverished, while Egyptians from
the Nile Valley have colonised choice lands on its southern coast for
tourism,” motivating their turn towards illegal practices.297 However,
since the collapse of the Mubarak regime, outbreaks of violence
between Bedouin and security forces as well as instances of Bedouin
kidnappings of tourists have only served to reinforce their reputation
for dangerous and criminal behavior, undermining any progress
towards greater cooperation with the state.
Egyptian authorities are targeting the symptoms and not the causes
of the conflict, institutionalizing a repressive relationship instead of a
297. “Egypt’s Restive Bedouin: Why the Bedouin of the Sinai Peninsula Are
Angry,” The Economist, August 5, 2010.
Conclusions
203
potentially constructive one. Instead of addressing certain deficiencies
in their own policies encouraging this marginalization, they have
instead chosen to blame the Bedouin for failing to conform to the
standards set by the government and development agencies. By
stereotyping the Aqaba Bedouin with labels of criminality, Egyptian
authorities have cast their behavior as deviant as opposed to the
“legitimate” actions of the state, ensuring a marginal or subordinated
position for them in economic development. In this way, Egyptian
authorities have attempted to use this negative image to undermine
budget tourism as undesirable and focus development on multinational
resort tourism, promoting the agenda of the central government.
It is clear that at no point did the Egyptian authorities undertake
a concerted campaign to marginalize the Bedouin, and furthermore
that Egyptian policies are not purposefully constructed to discriminate
against them. The problem is one of perception. The Egyptian
authorities have come to view the Bedouin as a “traditional” society
due to their assumptions about who the Bedouin are and what
they do.298 These assumptions, based on faulty premises, have led
the Bedouin to consider Egyptian development as a neo-colonial
expression of domination. The question that remains, and which I
prefer not to address for lack of real substantiating evidence, is whether
the state’s essentialization and its claim to have a responsibility to
modernize “traditional groups” truly reflects authorities’ perceptions
of such groups or whether the state is merely attempting to justify its
preferred policies.
Bedouin Identity in Contemporary
Contexts
Despite processes of socio-economic transformation among the
Bedouin, a strong Bedouin identity has lingered in some form or
another. As this identity does not conform to ideal-type patterns of
Bedouin organization, the concept of the Bedouin as an objective
298. Dames and Moore, Sinai Development Study, vol. 6, “Settlement and
Social Development.”
Conclusions
204
occupational definition will not enrich our understanding of
contemporary Bedouin. Instead, it constrains our ability to examine
social transformation among integrating peripheries as we focus our
search on rigid and outdated typologies looking for this “traditional
society.” In other words, a lingering focus on Bedouin typologies
will prevent researchers from examining the social construction of
contemporary identities and the roles that they play in the age of states.
Both William Young and Dale Eickelman reach the same conclusion,
that Bedouin identities are “primarily social categories, not empirical
ones,” which will inevitably vary depending on context.299 Thus, it
is not useful to classify a group as Bedouin according to a specific
combination of culture traits; Bedouin identity comes from somewhere
else. In the words of Eickelman, “Perhaps the best question to ask
is not ‘What is a Bedouin?’ but ‘Who says of which group they are
Bedouin and why?’”300 Instead of searching for the Bedouin according
to defined typologies, it is better to seek to understand how and why a
Bedouin identity can be successfully deployed in national contexts.
In the context of economic development along the Aqaba Coast,
the best way to understand the manner of identity transformation
among the Bedouin is to return to Samuel Huntington’s Political
Order in Changing Societies. While Huntington remains a bit more
agnostic than myself in his attitudes towards the economic and political
aspects of modernization, he clearly identifies the complex relationship
between economic transformation, political development, and social
identity. A transformed Bedouin identity in Aqaba has been successful
precisely because it has been able to “achieve a new consciousness and
become the basis for new organization,” in turn because it is capable
of “meeting many of the needs of political identity, social welfare,
and economic advancement which are created by the processes of
299.
Dale F. Eickelman, Middle East and Central Asia: An Anthropological
Approach, 4
th
ed. (Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall, 2001), pp. 73–
74. See also Young, “‘The Bedouin’: Discursive Identity or Sociological
Category?”
300. Eickelman, The Middle East and Central Asia: An Anthropological
Approach, p. 74.
Conclusions
205
modernization [my emphasis].”301 While this identity as an idealized
type has remained largely unchanged, as have the communicated
symbols and values of the community, this study has unequivocally
shown the significant social and economic transformations already
experienced by the community.
In the contemporary era, defined by a system of territorially
bounded nation-states, this emergent Bedouin identity is most
effectively articulated in the language of ethnicity. This is an almost
inevitable result of state-building because it results in a situation
where “all groups, old as well as new… become increasingly aware
of themselves as groups and of their interests and claims in relation
to other groups [my emphasis].”302 In the context of the Aqaba
Bedouin, it serves to contest dominant, hegemonic national identities,
maintain cultural solidarity, and regulate intergroup interactions in
an increasingly heterogeneous social space. It plays the dual function
of providing avenues for the distribution of privileges and resources,
as well as providing a sense of belonging and social definition. This
identity is communicated through the deployment of cultural symbols
reflecting common descent, shared culture, and historical continuity,
which form the bases for group legitimacy in a nationally-defined
setting.
The effectiveness of ethnicity as a source of solidarity and definition
has to do with the importance of culture and history to notions of
familiarity and group feeling, as well as the centrality of ethnicity in
the articulation of nationalism.303 While this identity focuses on the
communication of primordial ties and culture, as we have seen and
as researchers like Salzmann, Eickelman, and Young have shown, the
Bedouin do not conform to ideal typologies, which themselves are
301. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies, p. 38. Huntington’s
“processes of modernization” are almost identical to the processes
I describe as “integrating.” I have removed the label “modernizing”
because of a lack of definition distinguishing precisely what is modern
from precisely what is traditional. Huntington appears unconcerned
with this distinction and focuses on “processes of modernization.”
302. Ibid., p. 37.
303. See Smith, The Ethnic Origins of Nations; see also Smith, Myths and
Memories of the Nation.
Conclusions
206
rooted in strong notions of occupational primordialism. How then,
can this seeming paradox be resolved? The answer comes from the
works of the instrumentalist writers, notably Eriksen and Cohen, who
show that while primordial elements legitimize these identities, the
purpose of the identity itself is to address challenges of contemporary
sociopolitical organization.
Acculturation and social transformation among the Aqaba Bedouin
has not led to the loss of their Bedouin identity. It has, instead, spurred
the Bedouin to defend their heritage, which they see as under threat
from Egyptian state policies due to the aforementioned integrative
processes that have led to a convergence in “operational culture,” that
is to say normative patterns of socioeconomic organization, between
Egyptians and the Bedouin. This convergence is incomplete due to
a different set of constraints imposed on each community; but from
discussions of patterns of urban settlement, issues of modesty, and
patterns of remittances, there is ample evidence showing that similar
structural conditions elicit similar responses from groups considered
culturally different. These and other similarities have led the Bedouin
to over-emphasize the traditional aspects of their culture in order to
maintain links to their ancestral pasts. Despite this focus on Bedouin
“traditions,” there is no denying that the Bedouin in Dahab have
embraced their socioeconomic transformations and are taking pride
in their new cultural forms. These new forms, however, have not
led to the adoption of national identities or the loss of primordially-
motivated solidarities.
Identity and Culture in the Contemporary
Arena
A number of Bedouin youths in Dahab have begun to lament the
seeming “disappearance” of Bedouin culture due to the sedentarization
of the Bedouin and their increasing acculturation.304 This does not
indicate that the Bedouin perceive that their identity is in decline or in
danger of disappearing, but that practices considered by the Bedouin
304. Conversation with Bedouin youth in Dahab, February 9, 2010.
Conclusions
207
to be traditional are disappearing in the face of development. The
Bedouin communicate this understanding by stipulating that Bedouin
culture remains alive in the desert villages, where practices that are
no longer utilitarian in an urban setting continue to form the basis for
Bedouin organization in the desert. The importance of maintaining
these “traditions” is that they form the symbolic basis for group feeling
and solidarity; they are what the Bedouin believe define them as a
culturally distinct community.
This concern creates somewhat of a paradox, in that while these
Bedouin continue to assert a strong sense of Bedouin identity,
they are increasingly concerned that they are conforming less and
less to notions of what it means to be a Bedouin. However, these
Bedouin admitted that after being exposed and growing accustomed
to the luxuries of settled life and technological development, notably
television, internet, and air conditioning, they are completely unwilling
to give these things up for the sake of returning to “tradition.” In any
event, this disappearance of culture is a perennial concern for the
Bedouin, in some ways motivating their preoccupation with heritage
defense. This is intimately connected to the issue of globalization,
which is a homogenizing process. While economic globalization, as it is
sometimes argued, is a continual process that began perhaps centuries
ago, the most recent wave of globalization has been increasingly
social instead of merely economic, leading to the proliferation of what
might be considered globalized forms of culture. The global adoption
of similar aspects of culture, including forms of entertainment and the
proliferation of global consumer items, have a homogenizing effect
in which distinct social groups—be they nations, ethnic groups, or
religions—are becoming culturally more similar. This has been made
possible through the availability across the globe of specific forms of
culture. One example is the globalization of MTV and even just the
news, which has allowed various groups to access identical pieces of
information. The internet is an additional step beyond, allowing for
the global sharing of information and rendering national boundaries
increasingly socially irrelevant.
A consequence of this homogenization has been the perception that
culture is disappearing, or that globalization entails a “loss of culture”
in which culture has been replaced by “consumerism” as a source of
Conclusions
208
self-definition.305 Since social groups tend to become more concerned
with their distinctiveness during periods of homogenization, they
have become very concerned with the consequences of globalization,
notably what they see as a loss of their unique identities. This only
serves to increase the importance of ethnic identities as a way to tie
people to their heritage and to continue to categorize and give order to
an increasingly homogenous social world marked by the disintegration
of “traditional” social frameworks. These are perceptions stemming
from the weakening of solidarity networks, such as the ethnic group,
that provide individuals with context and group feeling.
Compounding this pressure is the commercialization of culture,
where a reified culture is packaged for consumption. Through tourism,
another manifestation of globalization, Bedouin traditions, many of
which have lost their original significance due to transformation over
time, have assumed economic utility and have become a major source
of livelihood.306 Tourism as an avenue for the commercial transmission
of heritage is a primary vehicle for the display of culture both among
peripheral populations as well as the state. This is especially true for
groups such as the Aqaba Bedouin, since tourism as an industry is the
primary economic activity within their territory. As a consequence of
the commercialization of this culture, heritage defense is not merely
political and symbolic, but economic as well.
In this way, ethnogenesis has been a reaction to globalization and
homogenization; additionally, it is a way to compete with national
identities and core interests. It serves the purpose of maintaining
solidarity groups through the transmission of culture, which forms the
basis for familiarity and group feeling. Culture, in this context, is the
primary tool to link the individual to a group through the deployment
of shared symbols which form the basis of group feeling. In the
contemporary era, individuals look to the past and “tradition” as a
source of identification that ascribes “belonging” or definition to the
individual. Thus, globalization is not leading to the “loss of culture,” but
instead to the “homogenization of culture,” which is simultaneously
leading to a crisis of social identity necessitating the emergence of
305. Eriksen, Ethnicity and Nationalism, pp. 165, 166–168.
306. For a discussion on the role of tourism in processes of globalization, see
Daher, “Reconceptualizing Tourism in the Middle East,” p. 30.
Conclusions
209
ethnically-articulated identities. Culture is the primary tool of these
identities, which is why cultural defense is so vital to the social being
of such groups.
Additionally, globalization has resulted in the transcendence of
nationalism among these peripheral populations. In many respects
it has provided an alternative source of identity, allowing the Aqaba
Bedouin to identify with social groups outside the boundaries of their
state. This process undermines the claim that nationalism is the most
organic form of solidarity by providing a different framework based
on transnationalism. This framework understands that nations are not
homogenous and that similar positions within a social hierarchy can
also form the basis for a certain type of group feeling across national
borders. We might understand that globalization can encourage the
formation of “role solidarity,” or the identification with a social group
that exists outside national boundaries but which occupies a similar
role within their own national society, by adopting and communicating
similar cultural vehicles or symbols. One example of this sense of
solidarity has been Bedouin identification with African-American
culture due to the perception that both are repressed or marginalized
groups within their respective societies (see Figure 16). The adoption
of similar cultural symbols, for example Hip Hop, is symbolic of this
solidarity. In this way, the adoption of certain aspects of global culture
can be manifestations of local conditions.
This view of acculturation and identity transformation poses a
direct challenge to the assumptions of modernization, which predicts
a convergence of different groups’ values through the decline and
discarding of traditional identities for “modern” identities, values, and
patterns of solidarity. As this study shows, none of the sociopolitical
assumptions of modernization actually occurred, further suggesting
that the basic tenets of modernization theory do not constitute a
useful paradigm on which to base national development policies for
development. Perhaps a more accurate model of social change is
presented in a theory called “post-traditionalism” which allows us to
reconsider exactly what is meant by “tradition” and what a process
of acculturation implies.307 Simon suggests that it is better to view
307. Simon, “Development Reconsidered,” pp. 193–194.
Conclusions
210
tradition as “the accumulated amalgam of practices and beliefs from
previous epochs and domains,” challenging the dichotomy between
“traditional” and “modern” and instead presenting “tradition” as
the result of change over time.308 Post-traditionalism accepts this by
predicting a blending of tradition and acculturation, where evolving
cultural forms reflect “cross-cutting continuity and change, of old,
new, and hybrid identities, of reason and reaction, of gender and
power relations, of the preservation versus the transcendence of
categories, and of how and by whom they are negotiated, defined, and
safeguarded [= elites].” This approach explains many manifestations
of transforming Bedouin culture and more accurately approximates
avenues of cultural change and identity formation in contemporary
contexts. It furthermore allows for the adoption of new cultural forms
and the simultaneous retention of primordial solidarities.
308. Ibid.
Figure 16: Graffiti on a wall in a Bedouin neighborhood.
Photo by author, May 3, 2010.
Conclusions
211
The Implications of Development along
National Peripheries
From the study of the developing relationship between the Aqaba
Bedouin and the central Egyptian authorities, a number of conclusions
regarding nation-building and peripheral development can be drawn,
especially as relates to issues of integration and identity formation.
It is clear that a lingering tendency to predicate development
strategies on a modernization paradigm, while perhaps maximizing
state revenue, is complicating issues of integration and socialization
due to the sheer incongruence between the social expectations of
modernization and the social realities of development. This is not to
argue that all states and development authorities base their projects
on modernization theory, nor is it an accusation that development
agencies such as USAID, whose involvement in Sinai development
was discussed in chapter one, do this categorically. However, it is clear
that there is much congruence between the modernization literature
and the development rhetoric of the Egyptian state in Sinai. This has
necessarily undermined the fruits of national development programs,
leading to increasing tension and hostility between the core of national
societies and the margins as dominant social groups attempt to extend
national values and identity to the peripheries.
Transformation of identity in this context is a reaction based
on the particular form of state policies and social interaction. Of
primary importance is the structural position of a specific group
within a society, which results from socioeconomic relationships
developing between social groups within a state as well as between
the government and various social groups. If government policies lead
to the marginalization or repression of a non-dominant social group,
no amount of socialization, specifically through institutions such as
education and media, will convince this group to accept dominant
symbols or identities, which would be considered threatening or at
least alien instead of complimentary. More likely, as this study has
shown, peripheral social groups will turn to alternative identities that
provide greater utility and might successfully contest the assumptions
of dominant national identities. The Aqaba Bedouins’ rejection of
Egyptian cultural symbols in education—expressed through imagery
Conclusions
212
and nationalist histories as presented in lectures and state-approved
textbooks—is a perfect example of how socializing institutions such as
education and the media play a secondary role in identity formation.
The Bedouin claim that these symbols are culturally meaningless to
them and further claim that “the government doesn’t put Bedouin
history in the books at school. One hundred years from now, my
children won’t know who I am and where I came from.”309 This also
suggests that (a) the adoption of national identities is not a natural
or inevitable consequence of economic development or increasing
integration, and (b) it is impossible to force social conformity to
specific identities through coercive measures as long as state policies
and institutions favor the adoption of alternatives.
The only way to ensure the successful socialization of these groups
into dominant national identities is the articulation of these identities
to be able to reflect values considered universal within national
boundaries. This means that national ideologies cannot represent a
national core at the expense of peripheral social groups; if it does,
then a clash of interests will inevitably frustrate attempts at the
incorporation of these groups into national society. This also means
that if authorities hope to avoid ethnic or other social tensions, state
policies cannot benefit one group over another, nor can they seek to
appropriate group resources or undermine group distinctiveness by
attempting to suppress their history and heritage. These situations have
created marginal minorities, undermining national solidarity and often
stoking social conflict. However, as states such as the United States
demonstrate, wide, inclusive identities often lead to the emergence of
narrower “hyphenated-identities” that still subcategorize.
The conflict between the Bedouin and the Egyptian authorities
in Sinai resembles an indigenous peoples’ conflict, but this does
not mean that all Bedouin in all Middle Eastern contexts can be
considered “indigenous peoples” according to the definition given by
anthropologists and adopted in chapter four. In fact, in a number of
Middle Eastern states, Bedouin heritage and values play a dominant
role in national identities, such as in Jordan and Saudi Arabia. For
example, Saudi state-building was based strongly on tribal modes of
309. Interview with a Community Organizer, May 30, 2012.
Conclusions
213
alliance building, and Saudi identity contains a strongly “Bedouin”
element, notably in the relations between Saudi rulers and their subjects
and in patterns of solidarity and networks of distribution.310 In Jordan,
Bedouin descent plays a strong element in “Jordanian-ness,” notably
in opposition to Jordan’s “Palestinian” population. The Palestinian-
Jordanian dichotomy, interestingly enough, closely mirrors notions
of settled versus nomadic descent, implying that being “Jordanian”
means being of Bedouin descent, and Jordanian national identities
and values reflect these cultural origins.311 Furthermore, tribal identities
continue to play an important role in Jordanian society, and tribal
solidarities have been identified as a major source of stability for the
Jordanian state, as well as a shaper of voting patterns.312 That the role
of Bedouin identities varies across state boundaries is a consequence
of the social construction of national and ethnic identities and the
dominance of the state as the ultimate arbiter of social identity.
The particular case examined in this study is quite unique to the
conditions present in Dahab, and as a result must be considered a
micro study of local factors. However, while this study focused on the
conditions and consequences of state-building and development in
the Aqaba region of Sinai, and so cannot be said to be specifically
comparative, this does not mean that the phenomena under study
are unique to Egypt or that the processes described are not equally
applicable to other cases throughout the developing world. Indeed,
it should be self-evident from even a superficial glance at the
socioeconomic conditions within other developing states that similar
310. For an in-depth discussion on Saudi state-building and patterns of
national identity, see Kostiner, “Transforming Dualities: Tribe and State
Formation in Saudi Arabia.”
311. Yoav Alon, The Making of Jordan: Tribes, Colonialism and the
Modern State (London: I.B. Tauris, 2009), 156–157.
312. Yoav Alon, “The Tribal System in the Face of the State Formation
Process: Mandatory Transjordan, 1921–46,” International Journal
of Middle East Studies 37 (2005), pp. 213, 235. For a discussion of
voting patterns in Jordan, see Linda L. Layne, “Tribesman as Citizens:
‘Primordial Ties’ and Democracy in Rural Jordan,” in Linda Layne (ed.),
Elections in the Middle East: Implications of Recent Trends (Boulder,
CO: Westview, 1987).
Conclusions
214
types of conflicts are present within their borders, and that issues
of incorporation, socialization, and solidarity are primary problems
facing these countries today. In these countries, it is often the case
that economic development and the fuller integration of the state’s
territory and inhabitants have been primary preoccupations for the
regimes in control. Many of the states that have adopted an approach
towards economic development similar to Egypt’s have faced similar
clashes between national identities and peripheral ones. While
in the mantra of “modernization,” it is easy to view this conflict as
one between “modern” (national, core) identities and “primitive” or
“traditional” (peripheral) societies, it would be presumptuous to assert
that all “national” identities, by virtue of their being the dominant or
core identities of controlling regimes, are necessarily “modern,” or
that peripheral identities are necessarily traditional. Without delving
into a discussion of colonialist mentalities, we can nevertheless say
that it is exactly this understanding that legitimized the colonial
enterprise and which has lingered to dominate the thinking of statists
and modernists, often guiding the ideologies of governments focused
on development. Furthermore, it is in precisely this manner that
state-building and development might be considered “neo-colonial”
enterprises. While none of the Bedouin ever specifically used the term
“colonial” or “neo-colonial” during my time in Sinai, the language
they used to describe the Egyptians and their perception of Egyptian
development left no doubt that this was, in fact, their view.
Perhaps the greatest lesson to be taken from this study is the
importance of careful and deliberate planning when it comes
to peripheral development. Many states place primary value on
growth and revenue extraction. However, as this study has clearly
demonstrated, development is not merely an economic process. It
is also a social process leading to the adoption of new patterns of
organization, new social contacts, and often processes of acculturation
motivated by the need to adapt to changing environments. However,
it is apparent that authorities do occasionally neglect the social aspects
of development and express surprise at the “unintended” effects of
their development efforts. It is vital that state authorities understand
the structure and interests of peripheral populations and take careful
steps to ensure their incorporation into dominant identities by
Conclusions
215
coordinating development with the values and interests of both the
center and the periphery. This might require compromise on the part
of governments and development authorities to ensure cooperation
and that the interests of marginal populations are receiving due
attention. Under these circumstances, states will be more successful
instilling a sense of national solidarity in their peripheral populations
by tying them to the interests of the center. This is valid not only in
Egypt, but in all developing states dealing with issues of peripheral
development and nation-building.
217
Epilogue
July 2011– June 2012
In the aftermath of the events that shook Egypt following the January
25, 2011 uprisings, a question regarding the Sinai has arisen: To
what extent has the uprisings that led to the collapse of the Mubarak
regime altered the situation in the Sinai? Without a doubt, the issue
of Sinai has been a continual concern in 2011–2012, with repeated
attacks against the Israel–Egypt gas pipeline, clashes between the
Egyptian army and Bedouin in the north of the peninsula, the August
2011 attack on a bus load of civilians in the south of Israel, and the
August 2012 attack on an Egyptian police station, which led to armed
incursions into North Sinai by the Egyptian military. These events
have cast a negative light on the Sinai and its Bedouin inhabitants.
But all of these events occurred in the north of the peninsula, among
a socially and economically differentiated group of Bedouin.
The situation in the South has been quite different, but no less
traumatic. The incidents involving the kidnapping of tourists or factory
workers, which occurred throughout 2012 and continues in 2013,
as well as armed clashes between security forces and Bedouin in the
remote Wadi Firan in June 2012, represented an open challenge to
the Egyptian state, revealing its truly limited ability to control Sinai.313
313. “U.S. Tourists Freed Unharmed in Sinai,” Reuters, May 31, 2012,
<http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/05/31/us-egypt-sinai-
kidnapping-idUSBRE84U0DL20120531>; “Egypt Bedouin Kidnap
Two Brazilian Tourists,” Ahram Online, AFP, March 18, 2012, <http://
english.ahram.org.eg/NewsContent/1/64/37078/Egypt/Politics-/
Egypt-Bedouin-kidnap-two-Brazilian-tourists.aspx>; “U.S. Tourists, Guide
Kidnapped by Bedouins in Egypt’s Sinai Freed,” Al-Arabiya, February
3, 2012, <http://www.alarabiya.net/articles/2012/02/03/192306.
html>; “U.S. Tourists Freed Unharmed in Sinai,” Reuters, May 31,
2012, <http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/05/31/us-egypt-sinai-
kidnapping-idUSBRE84U0DL20120531>; “Bedouin Tribesmen,
Police Clash in Egypt’s Sinai, One Dead: Sources,” Reuters, June 4,
Epilogue
218
While demands have been made by the Bedouin for greater inclusion,
to which the SCAF314 and subsequently the government of Muhamad
Mursi, paid lip service, at the time of this writing, there appears to
be little ability or motivation on the part of the state to truly address
Bedouin complaints. In the aftermath of the attack on a police station
in North Sinai in August 2012, it instead appears that the state will
attempt to respond to continuing unrest with military force.
With the exception of the armed clashes between Egyptian police
and Bedouin in Wadi Firan, unrest in South Sinai has been far less
violent than in the North. The attention Sinai is receiving, which
often characterizes the peninsula as “lawless,” with its inhabitants
representing “criminal” elements—notably smugglers, human
traffickers, and terrorists—engaging in human rights abuses such as
rape, murder, torture, etc., the truth is that while there cannot be
any doubt that smuggling groups operating near the Israeli border are
conducting themselves in this manner, this characterization does not
apply to all of Sinai or even most of Sinai. Additionally, the militant
Islamist groups purported to be operating in Sinai, in which a number
of Bedouin are believed to be participating, continue to be largely
situated in the North as had been the case before 2010.
While the sensationalism of the stories of anarchy and violence in
the media has attracted overwhelmingly negative attention to Sinai
since the fall of the Mubarak regime, the reality in the South has
been far more subdued. Economically, little has changed: the Aqaba
Bedouin still face the same pressures for stability in a tourism market.
Despite the Aqaba region’s relative calm during the uprisings of
2010 and afterwards, national unrest has had a noticeable impact on
tourism in Sinai. As I detailed in chapter two, a theory advanced by a
number of anthropologists of tribalism is that in times of instability, the
Bedouin have learned to fall back on their subsistence structures. The
corollary, discussed in chapter four, is that this will be accompanied
by a reinvigoration of kinship ties within the Bedouin community.
During the course of my research I had the opportunity to see such
2012, <http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/06/04/us-egypt-sinai-
idUSBRE85310Z20120604>.
314. The Supreme Council of the Armed Forces, the group that seized power
from Mubarak in February 2011.
July 2011– June 2012
219
structures, but due to the lack of political instability until 2010, they
remained largely dormant; I never thought I would have a chance
to see what they looked like first-hand. In the aftermath of the Arab
Spring, however, I had the opportunity to visit Dahab in July 2011
and again in June 2012 and witnessed this phenomenon. The streets
of Dahab were strikingly empty. The Bedouin I spoke with complained
that without tourism, there was very little opportunity for work and
money was scarce. In these conditions, it appeared as if my friends
had fallen back on a more “traditional” pattern of social relations, with
the exception of those who maintain steady employment at scuba and
windsurfing clubs. One of my Bedouin friends began spending more
time with his father’s family, even going to lengths to prepare a plot
of his father’s land to begin building a house in case he decides to
marry. Another of my friends, who I had never seen wear anything
but jeans and a t-shirt, had begun wearing a jalabiyya, even though
he once told me he hated it. This shift towards greater conformity
with “traditional” patterns of social relations (read: those practiced by
the older generation) was conspicuous.
I have no doubt these changes in the face of the Egyptian revolution
are significant, but what, exactly, do they signify? Does any of this
challenge my original set of conclusions about the pace and direction
of social transformation? Or does it perhaps reinforce the theory of
security in kinship unconnected to issues of political identity? I think
that by looking only at this situation frozen in time, these questions
are exceedingly difficult to answer, and furthermore, it is far too
early to come to any lasting conclusions, especially when the future
of the Egyptian state itself is still so murky. When I asked my friend
why he was suddenly so concerned with securing a plot of land and
building a house, he replied, “What if the tourists do not come back?”
lending significant credence to the security argument. And while it
was clear from my last visit to Dahab that a more “traditional” set of
Bedouin social values were asserting themselves, another aspect of
Egyptian state collapse gave me cause for great optimism regarding
my conclusions.
While the Mubarak regime expended great energy to prevent
political mobilization, its collapse and the subsequent disorder that
gripped Sinai permitted precisely the type of mobilization that I
Epilogue
220
earlier posited, with the tentative emergence of Bedouin-oriented
organizations such as the television station, the inter-tribal Bedouin
council, and the Bedouin community center mentioned in chapter
five. (So far I have, unfortunately, been unable to follow up on the
first two and the third is still in its incipient phase.) This substantiates
the claim that the lack of Bedouin ethnic institutions was not a result
of a lack of a cross-tribal Bedouin identity or solidarity, but one of the
suppression of these forms of political mobilization in an authoritarian
state. The Bedouin continue to face a coordination dilemma that may
prove insurmountable, and the undeniable tension between tribes is
an obstacle to closer cooperation. However, with the collapse of the
Mubarak regime, and the seeming inability to reassert a strong sense
of sovereignty in the Sinai, it will now be up to the Bedouin to succeed
or fail on their own instead of attributing their failure to state policies
that attempt to prevent political mobilization.
The eventual outcome of the struggle in South Sinai will depend
on whether future Egyprian governments respect ethnic pluralism
and minority rights, and whether they continue supporting the
development paradigm that was the source of tension between the
Bedouin and Egyptian migrants in the first place. Furthermore, with
the continued conflict between the Egyptian security apparatus and
the Bedouin in North Sinai, it is difficult to imagine an Egyptian state
strongly influenced by its military interests giving greater freedom to
the Bedouin or making a concerted effort to integrate them more fully
into the economic fabric of Sinai.
In another regard, the Aqaba Bedouin have exploited this disorder
for gains in ways not so dissimilar from the Bedouin in the North.
While the presence of Egyptian authorities constrained the Bedouins’
ability to assert what they believed were their legitimate land rights,
the virtual disappearance of Egyptian security forces have led the
Bedouin to increasing boldness. The pace of their attempts to develop
the plots of land they have claimed have accelerated significantly.
Plots of land that contained simple cinderblock structures in my
previous visit have been augmented with gardens and property walls.
New neighborhoods, absent in 2009 and 2010, have emerged.
Furthermore, the visible police presence in Dahab has practically
disappeared. The Bedouin openly disparage the authorities and now
claim that while in the past they were afraid of the police, it is now
July 2011– June 2012
221
the turn of the police to be afraid of the people. Graffiti declaring “La
lil-Hukuma” (No to the government) had appeared in a number of
places in ‘Asala between my visits in 2011 and 2012.
Clearly, the Bedouin have seen the recent instability as an
opportunity to advance their own interests, and their actions have
been met with some rather harsh criticism by Egyptians and foreign
residents I spoke with in Dahab. One foreigner living in Dahab,
an employee at an apartment rental agency, suggested that this
opportunism was selfish and inappropriate at a time when Egyptians
should be coming together to build a better future and doing what
they could to help ensure stability. I think this clearly demonstrates
the rather large gap in perceptions between the Bedouin and other
groups in Dahab, who relate to the Egyptian establishment in Sinai
quite differently. More significantly, it appears quite suggestive of
Bedouin tendencies to contest state authority and speaks to the age-
old idea that tribes and states are fundamentally opposed institutions.
This, however, is a subject for another study.
Figure 17: Graffiti in ‘Asala declaring “No to the Government”
Photo by Author, June 2, 2012.
Epilogue
222
More central to this study is the idea that the processes I describe
are not solely unidirectional, but are dynamic and largely situationally
dependent. The strengthening of tribal kinship structures that I
witnessed gives credence to the idea that the causal mechanism driving
identity transformation lies within economic conditions and state
policies, or more fundamentally, the ability of the state to implement
its policies and enforce them. As with much else in life, only time will
tell.
223
Bibliography
Abu Lughod, Janet. “Migrant Adjustment to City Life: The Egyptian
Case.” The American Journal of Sociology 67 (1962), pp. 22–32.
Abu Lughod, Lila. Veiled Sentiments: Honor and Poetry in a
Bedouin Society. Berkeley: University of California, 1999.
Alexander, Jeffrey C. “Core Solidarity, Ethnic Outgroup, and Social
Differentiation: A Multidimensional Model of Inclusion in Modern
Societies.” In National and Ethnic Movements, edited by Jaques
Dofny and Akinsola Akiwowo, pp. 5-28. Beverley Hills: Sage
Publications Ltd, 1980.
Ali, Dina F. “Case Study of Development of the Peripheral Coastal
Area of South Sinai in Relation to its Bedouin Community.” MA
Thesis, Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, 1998.
Alon, Yoav. The Making of Jordan Tribes, Colonialism and the
Modern State. London: I.B. Tauris, 2009.
–––––––. “The Tribal System in the Face of the State Formation
Process: Mandatory Transjordan, 1921-46.” International Journal
of Middle East Studies 37 (2005), pp. 213–240.
Anderson, Benedict. Imagined Communities: Reflections on the
Origin and Spread of Nationalism. 2nd ed. London: Verso, 1991.
Ayubi, Nazih N. The State and Public Policies in Egypt Since
Sadat. Political Studies of the Middle East Series. Reading, U.K.:
Ithaca Press, 1991.
Aziz, Heba. “Employment in a Bedouin Community: The Case of
the Town of Dahab in South Sinai.” Nomadic Peoples 4.2 (2000),
pp. 28–47.
Bibliography
224
Baer, Gabriel. “Some Aspects of Bedouin Sedentarization in 19th
Century Egypt.” Die Welt Des Islams 5.1/2 (1957), pp. 84–98.
Bahoora, Haytham. “Shock-and-Awe Nation Building: Iraq’s Neo-
Liberal Reconstruction.” Jadaliyya.com. Arab Studies Institute, 14
May 2012. <http://www.jadaliyya.com/pages/index/5522/shock-
and-awe-nation-building_iraqs-neo-liberal-re>.
Bailey, Clinton. “Dating the Arrival of the Bedouin Tribes in Sinai
and the Negev.” Journal of the Economic and Social History of the
Orient 28 (1985), pp. 20–49.
Baram, Amatzia. “Neo-Tribalism in Iraq: Saddam Hussein’s
Tribal Policies 1991–96.” International Journal of Middle East
Studies 29.1 (1997), pp. 1–31.
Barkey, Karen, and Sunita Parikh. “Comparative Perspectives on the
State.” Annual Review of Sociology 17 (1991), pp. 523–549.
Barnett, Michael N., and Raymond D. Duvall. “Power in International
Politics.” International Organization 591 (2005),pp. 39–75.
Barth, Fredrik. “Introduction.” In Ethnic Groups and Boundaries:
The Social Organization of Culture Difference, edited by Fredrik
Barth, pp. 9–38. Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1969.
Bates, Daniel G. and Amal Rassam. Peoples and Cultures of the
Middle East. 2nd ed. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall Inc., 2001.
Behbehanian, Laleh. “Policing the Illicit Peripheries of Egypt’s
Tourism Industry.” Middle East Report 216 (2000), pp. 32–34.
Beissinger, Mark R. Nationalist Mobilization and the Collapse of
the Soviet State. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 2002.
Brady, Henry E., and David Collier, eds. Rethinking Social Inquiry
Diverse Tools, Shared Standards. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield,
2010.
Bibliography
225
Brass, Paul R. “Ethnic Groups and the State.” In Ethnicity and
Nationalism: Theory and Comparison, edited by Paul Brass,
pp. 247–299. New Delhi: Sage Publications, 1991.
Brigham, John C. “Ethnic Stereotypes.” Psychological Bulletin 76.1
(1971), pp. 15–38.
Cleveland, William L. The Making of an Arab Nationalist:
Ottomanism and Arabism in the Life and Thought of Sati al-Husri.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1971.
Cohen, Abner. “Introduction: The Lessons of Ethnicity.” In Urban
ethnicity, edited by Abner Cohen, pp. ix-xxiv. London: Tavistock,
1974.
–––––––. Two-dimensional Man: An Essay on the Anthropology of
Power and Symbolism in Complex Society. Berkeley: University of
California, 1974.
Daher, Rami Farouk. Tourism in the Middle East: Continuity,
Change, and Transformation (Tourism and Cultural Change).
Minneapolis: Channel View Publications, 2006.
Dames and Moore International. Sinai Development Study, Phase I:
Final Report. 7 Volumes. Washington D.C.: United States Agency
for International Aid, 1985.
Delacroix, Jaques and Charles Ragin. “Modernizing Institutions,
Mobilization, and Third World Development: A Cross-National Study.”
American Journal of Sociology 84.1 (1978), pp. 123–150.
Durkheim, Émile. The Division of Labor in Society. New York: Free,
1984.
Eickelman, Dale F. Middle East and Central Asia: An Anthropological
Approach. 4th ed. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall, 2001.
Bibliography
226
Epstein, A. L. Politics in an Urban African Community. Manchester:
Published on Behalf of the Rhodes-Livingstone Institute by Manchester
University Press, 1958.
–––––––. Ethos and Identity: Three Studies in Ethnicity. Tavistock:
London, 1978.
Eriksen, Thomas Hylland. Ethnicity and Nationalism—
Anthropological Perspectives (Anthropology, Culture and Society).
2nd ed. New York: Pluto, 2002.
–––––––. “The Cultural Contexts of Ethnic Differences.” Man, New
Series 26.1 (1991), pp. 127–144.
–––––––. “Ethnicity Versus Nationalism.” Journal of Peace Research
28.3 (1991), pp. 263–278.
Etzioni, Amitai. “A Self-Restrained Approach to Nation-Building by
Foreign Powers.” International Affairs 80.1 (2004), pp. 1–17.
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. “Explaining Ethnic
Cooperation.” American Political Science Review 90.4 (1996),
pp. 715–735.
Gardner, Ann. “At Home in South Sinai.” Nomadic Peoples 4.2
(2000), pp. 48–67.
Gardner, Ann and Emanuel Marx. “Employment and Unemployment
Among Bedouin.” Nomadic Peoples 4.2 (2000), pp. 21–27.
Geertz, Clifford. “Thick Description, Towards an Interpretive Theory
of Culture.” In Interpretation of Cultures (Basic Books Classics),
pp. 3–32. New York: Basic, 2000.
Gellner, Ernest. Nations and Nationalism. 2nd ed. Oxford: Blackwell,
2006.
Bibliography
227
Gereffi, Gary and Stephanie Fonda. “Regional Paths of Development.”
Annual Review of Sociology 18 (1992), pp. 419–448.
Gershoni, Israel and James P. Jankowski. Commemorating the
Nation: Collective Memory, Public Commemoration, and
National Identity in Twentieth-century Egypt. Chicago: Middle East
Documentation Center, 2004.
Glassner, Martin I. “The Bedouin of South Sinai under Israeli
Administration.” Geographical Review 64.1 (1974), pp. 31–60.
Habyarimana, James P., Macartan Humphreys, Daniel N. Posner,
and Jeremy M. Weinstein. Coethnicity: Diversity and the Dilemmas
of Collective Action. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2009.
Hall, Stuart. “Introduction: Who Needs Identity?” In Questions of
Cultural Identity, edited by Stuart Hall and Paul Du Gay, pp. 1–17.
London: Sage Publications, 1996.
Hinnebusch, Raymond A. “The Politics of Economic Reform in
Egypt.” Third World Quarterly 14.1 (1993), pp. 159–171.
Hobbs, Joseph. “Speaking with People in Egypt’s St. Katherine’s
National Park.” Geographical Review 86.1 (1996), pp. 1–21.
–––––––. “Troubling Fields: The Opium Poppy in Egypt.” Geographical
Review 88.1 (1998), pp. 64–85.
–––––––. “Exploration and Discovery with the Bedouin of Egypt.”
Geographical Review 91.1/2 (2001), pp. 285–294.
Hobsbawm, Eric. “Introduction: Inventing Traditions.” In The
Invention of Tradition, edited by Eric Hobsbawm and Terence
Ranger, pp. 1–14. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992.
Bibliography
228
Homa, David. “Touristic Development in Sinai.” In Tourism in the
Middle East Continuity, Change, and Transformation, edited
by Rami Farouk Daher, pp. 237–262. Minneapolis: Channel View
Publications, 2006.
Horowitz, Donald L. Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkeley: University
of California, 1985.
Huntington, Samuel P. Political Order in Changing Societies. New
Haven: Yale University Press, 1968.
Ismail, Mahmud. Nationalism in Egypt before Nasser’s Revolution.
PhD Dissertation, University of Pittsburgh, 1978.
Inglehart, Ronald and Wayne E. Baker. “Modernization, Cultural
Change, and the Persistence of Traditional Values.” American
Sociological Review 61 (Looking Forward, Looking Back: Continuity
and Change at the Turn of the Millennium) (2000), pp. 19–51.
Jacobs, Jessica. “Have Sex Will Travel: Romantic ‘Sex Tourism’
and Women Negotiating Modernity in the Sinai.” Gender, Place &
Culture 16.1 (2009), pp. 43–61.
Jankowski, James, and Israel Gershoni, eds. Rethinking Nationalism
in the Arab Middle East. New York: Columbia University Press,
1997.
Jankowski, James P. “Arab Nationalism in ‘Nasserism’ and Egyptian
State Policy, 1952–1958.” In Rethinking Nationalism in the Arab
Middle East, edited by James P. Jankowski and Israel Gershoni,
pp. 150–167. New York: Columbia University Press, 1997.
Kedourie, Elie. The Chatham House Version, and Other Middle-
Eastern Studies. London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson, 1970.
Kennett, Austin. Bedouin Justice: Law and Customs Among the
Egyptian Bedouin. London: Kegan Paul Int’l Ltd, 2000.
Bibliography
229
Kerr, Malcolm H. The Arab Cold War: Gamal ‘Abd al-Nasir and His
Rivals. London: Oxford UP, 1971.
Khazanov, Anatoly M. Nomads and the Outside World. Madison:
University of Wisconsin, 1994.
Khoury, Philip S. and Joseph Kostiner, eds. Tribes and State
Formation in the Middle East. London: IB Tauris and Com, 1991.
Kollock, Peter. “Social Dilemmas: The Anatomy of Cooperation.” Annual
Review of Sociology 24.1 (1998), pp. 183–214.
Kostiner, Joseph. The Making of Saudi Arabia: 1916 – 1936: From
Chieftaincy to Monarchical State. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1993.
–––––––. “Transforming Dualities: Tribe and State Formation in Saudi
Arabia.” In Tribes and State Formation in the Middle East, edited
by Philip S. Khoury and Joseph Kostiner, pp. 226–251. Berkeley:
University of California, 1990.
Lareau, Annette and Jeffrey J. Shultz. Journeys through
Ethnography: Realistic Accounts of Fieldwork. Boulder: Westview
Press, 1996.
Lavie, Smadar. “When Leadership Becomes Allegory: Mzeina Sheikhs
and the Experience of Military Occupation.” Cultural Anthropology
4.2 (1989), pp. 99–136.
–––––––. The Poetics of Military Occupation: Mzeina Allegories
of Bedouin Identity under Israeli and Egyptian Rule. New York:
University of California Press, 1991.
Layne, Linda L. Home and Homeland the Dialogics of Tribal and
National Identities in Jordan. Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1994.
Bibliography
230
–––––––. “Tribesman as Citizens: ‘Primordial Ties’ and Democracy
in Rural Jordan.” In Elections in the Middle East: Implications of
Recent Trends, edited by Linda Layne, pp. 113–148. Boulder, CO:
Westview, 1987.
Lerner, Daniel. Passing of Traditional Society: Modernizing the
Middle East. New York: Macmillan Publishing, 1958.
Lippman, Thomas W. Egypt After Nasser: Sadat, Peace, and the
Mirage of Prosperity. New York: Paragon House, 1989.
Lipset, Seymour Martin. “Some Social Requisites of Democracy:
Economic Development and Political Legitimacy”. The American
Political Science Review. 53.1 (1959), pp. 69–105.
–––––––. Political Man; The Social Bases of Politics. Garden City,
N.Y.: Doubleday, 1960.
Maddy-Weitzman, Bruce. “Contested identities: Berbers, ‘Berberism’
and the state in North Africa.” The Journal of North African Studies,
6.3 (2001), pp. 23–47.
Manuel, George and Michael Posluns. The Fourth World: An Indian
Reality. Collier: MacMillan-Canada, 1974.
Marx, Emanuel. “The Tribe as a Unit of Subsistence: Nomadic
Pastoralism in the Middle East.” American Anthropologist 79.2
(1977), pp. 343–363.
–––––––. “Changing Employment Patterns of Bedouin in South Sinai.”
In The Changing Bedouin, edited by Emmanuel Marx and Avhsalom
Shmueli, pp. 173–186. New Brunswick: Transaction Books, 1984.
–––––––. “Economic Change among Pastoral Nomads in the Middle
East.” In The Changing Bedouin, edited by Emmanuel Marx and
Avhsalom Shmueli, pp. 1–16. New Brunswick: Transaction Books,
1984.
Bibliography
231
–––––––. “Tribal Pilgrimages to Saints’ Tombs in South Sinai.” In
Islamic Dilemmas: Reformers, Nationalists, and Industrialization:
The Southern Shore of the Mediterranean, edited by Ernest Gellner,
pp. 104–131. New York: Mouton, 1985.
–––––––. “Oases in South Sinai,” Human Ecology 27.2 (1999),
pp. 341–357.
–––––––. “Hashish Smuggling by Bedouin in South Sinai.” In
Organized Crime Culture, Markets and Policies (Studies of
Organized Crime), edited by Dina Siegel and Hans Nelen, pp. 29–
37. New York: Springer, 2007.
Massialas, Byron G. Education and the Political System. Reading:
Addison-Wesley, 1969.
Meyer, John W. “The Effects of Education as an Institution.” The
American Journal of Sociology 83.1 (1977), pp. 55–77.
Migdal, Joel S. Strong Societies and Weak States: State-Society
Relations and State Capabilities in the Third World. Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1988.
Mitchell, J. Clyde. The Kalela Dance. Manchester: Manchester
University Press, 1956.
–––––––. “Perceptions of Ethnicity and Ethnic Behavior: An Empirical
Explanation.” In Urban Ethnicity, edited by Abner Cohen, pp. 1–35.
London: Tavistock, 1974.
Mitchell, Timothy. Colonising Egypt. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1988.
Murray, G.W. “The Land of Sinai.” The Geographical Journal 119.2
(1953), pp. 140–153.
Bibliography
232
–––––––. Sons of Ishmael: A Study of the Egyptian Bedouin. New
York: AMS, 1978.
Nash, John. “Non-Cooperative Games.” The Annals of Mathematics.
54.2 (1951), pp. 286–295.
Opperman, Martin. “Tourism Space in Developing Countries.”
Annals of Tourism Research 20 (1953), pp. 535–556.
Pachirat, Timothy. “The Political in Political Ethnography: Dispatches
from the Kill Floor.” In Political Ethnography: What Immersion
Contributes to the Study of Power, edited by Edward Schatz,
pp. 143–161. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2009.
Perevolotsky, Avi. “Orchard Agriculture in the High Mountain Region
of Southern Sinai.” Human Ecology 9.3 (1981), pp. 331–357.
Podeh, Elie. The Decline of Arab Unity: The Rise and Fall of the
United Arab Republic. Brighton: Sussex Academic Press, 1999.
Popkin, Samuel L. The Rational Peasant: The Political Economy of
Rural Society in Vietnam. Berkeley: University of California Press,
1979.
Posner, Daniel. “The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why
Chewas and Tumbakas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in
Malawi.” American Political Science Review 98 (2004), pp. 529–
546.
–––––––. Institutions and Ethnic Politics in Africa. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2005.
Przeworski, Adam. “The Last Instance: Are Institutions the
Primary Cause of Economic Development?” European Journal of
Sociology 45.2 (1999), pp. 165–188.
Bibliography
233
Rabinovich, Itamar and Milton Esman. “Introduction.” In Ethnicity,
Pluralism, and the State in the Middle East, edited by Itamar
Rabinovich and Milton Esman. Cornell: Cornell University Press,
1988.
Rabinowitz, Dan. “Themes in the Economies of the Bedouin of South
Sinai in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries.” International
Journal of Middle East Studies 17.2 (1985), pp. 211–228.
Raymond, André. Cairo. Translated by Willard Wood. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press, 2000.
Reid, Donald M. “Nationalizing the Pharaonic Past: Egyptology,
Imperialism and Egyptian Nationalism, 1922-1952.” In Rethinking
Nationalism in the Arab Middle East, edited by Israel Gershoni and
James Jankowski, pp. 127–149. New York: Columbia University
Press, 1997.
Ritter, Carl. The Comparative Geography of Palestine and the
Siniatic Peninsula. Translated by William Gauge. Vol. 1. New York:
Haskell House, 1969.
Salzman, Philip C. “Tribal Organization and Subsistence: A Reply to
Emanuel Marx.” American Anthropologist 81.1 (1979), pp. 121–
124.
–––––––. “Multi-Resource Nomadism in Iranian Baluchistan.” In
Perspectives on Nomadism, edited by William Irons and Neville
Dyson-Hudson, pp. 60–69. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1972.
Scott, James C. The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and
Subsistence in Southeast Asia. New Haven: Yale University Press,
1976.
–––––––. Seeing like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the
Human Condition Have Failed. New Haven: Yale University Press,
1998.
Bibliography
234
–––––––. The Art of Not Being Governed: an Anarchist History of
Upland Southeast Asia. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2009.
Shayo, Moses. “A Model of Social Identity with an Application to
Political Economy: Nation, Class, and Redistribution.” American
Political Science Review. 103:2 (2009).
Simon, David. “Development Reconsidered: New Directions in
Development Thinking.” Geografiska Annaler. Series B, Human
Geography 79.4 (Current Development Thinking) (1997), pp. 183–
201.
Smith, Anthony D. The Ethnic Revival. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1981.
–––––––. The Ethnic Origins of Nations. Oxford: Blackwell, 1986.
–––––––. Myths and Memories of the Nation. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 2000.
Soleiman, Ishra. “Denied Existence: Libyan-Berbers under Gaddafi
and Hope for the Current Revolution.” Muftah, 24 March, 2011.
Web. http://muftah.org/?p=961.
Sweet, Louise E. “Camel Raiding of the North Arabian Bedouin: A
Mechanism of Ecological Adaptation.” In Peoples and Cultures of
the Middle East, Volume 1, edited by Louise E. Sweet, pp. 265–289.
New York: The Natural History Press, 1970.
Turner, James. “Universal Education and Nation Building in Africa.”
Journal of Black Studies 2.1 (1971), pp. 3–27.
Van Maanen, John. “Playing Back the Tape.” In Experiencing
Fieldwork: An Inside View of Qualitative Research, edited by W.B.
Shaffer and R.A. Stebbins, pp. 31–42. Thousand Oaks: Sage, 1991.
Vatikiotis, P.J. The History of Modern Egypt. 4th ed. London:
Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1991.
Bibliography
235
Weinstein, Eugene A. and Paul Deutschberger. “Some Dimensions of
Altercasting.” Sociometry 26.4 (1963), pp. 454–466.
Wendt, Alexander. “Anarchy Is What States Make of It: The Social
Construction of Power Politics.” International Organization 46.2
(1992), pp. 391–425.
–––––––. Social Theory of International Politics. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1999.
Wimmer, Andreas. Nationalist Exclusion and Ethnic Conflict:
Shadows of Modernity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2002.
Wyrtzen, Johnathan. “Colonial State Building and the Negotiation
of Arab and Berber Identity in Protectorate Morocco.” International
Journal of Middle East Studies 43 (2011), pp. 227–249.
Young, William C. “”The Bedouin”: Discursive Identity or Sociological
Category? A Case Study from Jordan.” Journal of Mediterranean
Studies 9.2 (1999), pp. 275–299.
“International Day of the World’s Indigenous Peoples.” ACPP-
Working for Justice & Peace in Asia. Asian Center for the Progress
of Peoples. Web. http://www.acpp.org/sevents/0809.html.
Mulakhas al-Taqrir al-Niha’i li-Lajna al-Tahqiq wa-Taqassi al-
Haqa’iq bi-Sha’n al-Ahdath allati Wa¯qabat Thawrat 25 Yanayir
2011 (Summary of the Fact Finding Committe for the Events
Accompanying the Revolution of 25 January 2011). National
Committee for the investigation and fact finding regarding the events
of January 25. Arab Republic of Egypt. Arabic. http://www.ffnc-eg.
org/assets/ffnc-eg_final.pdf.
War on Drugs: Report of the Global Commission on Drug Policy.
Rep. Global Commission on Drug Policy, June 2011. Web. http://
globalcommissionondrugs.org.
Bibliography
236
Newspaper Articles
“Egypt’s Restive Bedouin: Why the Bedouin of the Sinai Peninsula
Are Angry.” The Economist 5 August 2010.
“Four Foreigners Sentenced for Drugs.” Middle East Times, 2001,
issue 41.
“Six arrested, drugs seized in south Sinai bust.” Agence France-
Presse, 27 February 1997.
“Bedouin Camps Demolished: The Claims of Sinai’s Indigenous
Tribes are Swept Away by the Tidal Wave of Development.” The
Cairo Times, 22 July 1999.
“Bedouin Tribesmen, Police Clash in Egypt’s Sinai, One Dead:
Sources.” Reuters, 4 June 2012. http://www.reuters.com/
article/2012/06/04/us-egypt-sinai-idUSBRE85310Z20120604.
“Egypt Bedouin Kidnap Two Brazilian Tourists.” Ahram Online.
AFP, 18 Mar. 2012. Web. http://english.ahram.org.eg/
NewsContent/1/64/37078/Egypt/Politics-/Egypt-Bedouin-kidnap-
two-Brazilian-tourists-.aspx.
“U.S. Tourists, Guide Kidnapped by Bedouins in Egypt’s Sinai
Freed.” Al-Arabiya. 3 Feb. 2012. http://www.alarabiya.net/
articles/2012/02/03/192306.html.
“U.S. Tourists Freed Unharmed in Sinai.” Reuters, 31 May 2012.
http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/05/31/us-egypt-sinai-
kidnapping-idUSBRE84U0DL20120531.
Adel Abdellah, “Even Tourists and Tourism Operators Say Yes to the
MB.” EgyptVotes.org. 4 January 2012. http://www.egyptvotes.org/
en/politics/item/400.html.
Beasley-Murray, Ben. “Green Lines: The Tourist Development Agency
Uses Environmental Rhetoric to Justify Demolishing Bedouin-Owned
Bibliography
237
Camps in Favor of Big Hotels.” The Cairo Times, 30 September
1999.
Ibrahim, Amirah. “Push and Pull.” Al-Ahram Weekly. 3-9 March
2011. http://weekly.ahram.org.eg/2011/1037/eg41.htm.
Nahmias, Roee. “Dahab Bombers Were Sinai Bedouins.” Yediot
Ahronot Online. 26 Apr. 2006.
Ottaway, David B. “Egypt Tries Hard to Lure Settlers to Sinai Region.”
The Washington Post, 25 April 1983.
Sobi, Samir. “Of Camels and Bedouin.” Al-Ahram Weekly, English
Edition. Issue No 1055, 7-13 July 2011. http://weekly.ahram.org.
eg/2011/1055/special.htm.