PreprintPDF Available

Abstract and Figures

One reason to be concerned about income inequality is the idea that people not only care about their own absolute income, but also their income relative to various reference groups (e.g. co-workers, friends, neighbors, relatives, etc.). We use Canadian linked employer-employee data to estimate the casual effect of co-worker pay on a worker’s reported job and pay satisfaction. Since worker satisfaction can affect the worker’s productivity, organizational commitment, turnover, creativity and innovation, as well as the firm’s productivity and profitability, this is an issue that requires more attention and careful examination. In models that control for a rich set of workplace characteristics, we find that coworker pay has a large positive and significant effect on both pay and job satisfaction. In our preferred models with establishment-level fixed effects, the effect of coworker pay on pay satisfaction is half as large, and the effect on job satisfaction completely disappears, suggesting that part (all) of what previous studies attribute to the effect of coworker pay on worker pay (job) satisfaction is driven by unobserved heterogeneity across firms or establishments. Our results also suggest that the effect of coworker pay on worker satisfaction is much stronger for workers who leave their job during the following year. Finally, we find that while coworker pay has a positive effect on pay satisfaction among Canadian-born whites, it has a negative effect among immigrants and Canadian-born visible minorities.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Job Satisfaction and Coworker Pay in Canadian Firms
Mohsen Javdani
Department of Economics
University of British Columbia Okanagan
Brian Krauth
Department of Economics
Simon Fraser University
Abstract
One reason to be concerned about income inequality is the idea that people not only care
about their own absolute income, but also their income relative to various reference groups (e.g.
co-workers, friends, neighbors, relatives, etc.). We use Canadian linked employer-employee data
to estimate the casual effect of co-worker pay on a worker’s reported job and pay satisfaction.
Since worker satisfaction can affect the worker’s productivity, organizational commitment,
turnover, creativity and innovation, as well as the firm’s productivity and profitability, this is an
issue that requires more attention and careful examination. In models that control for a rich set of
workplace characteristics, we find that coworker pay has a large positive and significant effect on
both pay and job satisfaction. In our preferred models with establishment-level fixed effects, the
effect of coworker pay on pay satisfaction is half as large, and the effect on job satisfaction
completely disappears, suggesting that part (all) of what previous studies attribute to the effect of
coworker pay on worker pay (job) satisfaction is driven by unobserved heterogeneity across firms
or establishments. Our results also suggest that the effect of coworker pay on worker satisfaction
is much stronger for workers who leave their job during the following year. Finally, we find that
while coworker pay has a positive effect on pay satisfaction among Canadian-born whites, it has
a negative effect among immigrants and Canadian-born visible minorities.
1
1. Introduction
While status has long been a key concept for many social scientists (Runciman 1966,
Diener and Biswas-Diener 2000, and others), it has received relatively less attention in economics.
However, the growing inequality documented by Piketty (2014) and others has made
understanding the role of status in behavior and well-being more central. The utility of an
individual who is concerned with status is not only affected by own income, but also by income
relative to some comparison or reference group (e.g. co-workers, friends, neighbors, relatives,
etc.). As Akerlof and Yellen (1990), Frank (1985), Frank and Sunstein (2001) and Layard
(2005a,b) argue, if relative income has a considerable impact on individual utility, some well-
established ideas about economic policy need to be re-considered. For example, the externalities
implied by a concern with status may mean that the social cost of inequality is significantly greater
than is commonly understood.
In this article we use linked employer-employee data from Canada to quantify the effect of
co-workers’ wages on worker’s self-reported job and pay satisfaction. Worker satisfaction both
directly enters into subjective well-being and may also have important effects on productivity,
organizational commitment, turnover, creativity and innovation, and firm’s profitability (See
Akerlof et al. 1988; Freeman 1978, Judge et al. 2001; Koys 2000; Mangoine and Quinn 1975;
McEvoy and Cascio 1985, Patterson et al. 2004, and Yee et al. 2008 for examples). Surprisingly,
we are only aware of three studies - Clark et al. (2009), Brown et al. (2008), and Godechot and
Senik (2015) - that examine the effect of co-worker wage on worker satisfaction. By using richer
data than these previous studies, we can better account for workplace characteristics that could be
correlated with wages and also affect worker’s satisfaction directly.
There are two contrasting mechanisms by which a given reference group’s relative income
(keeping the individual’s own income fixed) affects an individual’s subjective well-being. A status
effect occurs when increased reference group income induces a feeling of relative deprivation
driven by a sense of unfairness, envy, shame, or rivalry (for example, Easterlin 1995; Falk and
Knell 2004, Marx 1849, p.163; Smith 1880, p.466). The status effect will impose a negative
externality on individual’s well-being and will create a negative relationship between reference
group’s relative income and the individual’s utility. A signal effect, also known as Hirschman’s
tunnel effect (Hirschman and Rothschild 1973), occurs when increased reference group income
provides a positive signal about the individual’s own future prospects. If worker satisfaction is
influenced by these expectations, the signal effect will create a positive relationship between the
reference group’s income and the worker’s satisfaction.
1
Since the status effect and signal effect
operate in different directions, satisfaction can be positively or negatively related to reference
group income.
A long-standing literature in economics emphasizes the role of various comparison groups
in determining an individual’s utility (e.g. Bolton 1991; Bolton and Ockenfels 2000; Burchell and
Yagil 1997; Capelli and Chauvin 1991; Duesenberry 1949; Easterlin 1974, 1995; Kingdon and
Knight 2007; and others). A related empirical literature also provides evidence on the relationship
between relative income and individual subjective well-being (Brown et al. 2008; Capelli and
Sherer 1988; Card et al. 2012; Clark et al. 2009; Clark and Oswald 1996; Ferrer-i-Carbonell 2005;
Hamermesh 2001; Hills 1980; Luttmer 2005; McBride 2001; Senik 2004Van Praag and Ferrer-i-
Carbonell 2004; Ward and Sloane 2000; Watson et al. 1996). Most of these empirical studies find
1
Another reason why income could have a positive impact on own satisfaction is altruism (Charness and Rabin 2002).
2
a negative relationship between individual satisfaction and income relative to a comparison group.
This finding is consistent with the status effect dominating. However, there are also studies that
find a positive relationship between individual well-being and relative income, suggesting that
signal effect dominates (Brown et al. 2008; Clark et al. 2009; Senik 2004Kingdon and Knight
2007).
We are only aware of three prior studies that specifically examine the effect of relative
wage within the workplace (rather than some other comparison group) on worker satisfaction.
Clark et al. (2009) estimate the relationship between job satisfaction and co-worker average wage
using 16,000 observations on around 4,000 workers in survey data from the Danish sample of the
European Community Household Panel merged with administrative records of workers between
1994 and 2001. Their analysis employs random effect ordered probit regressions and fixed effect
linear regressions to account for individual-level unobserved characteristics (e.g. genes,
upbringing, etc.) that affect worker’s job satisfaction and may be correlated with how workers
match with firms. They find that the higher the establishment average wage (i.e. the better-paid
the co-workers are), the more satisfied the worker is with her job. They argue that this is because
the higher wages of co-workers acts as a signal of promising future prospects for the worker that
dominates the status effect. They also find that the establishment average wage is a good predictor
of an individual’s wage in the future, which is consistent with the mechanism underlying the signal
effect.
Brown et al. (2008) estimate the relationship between pay satisfaction and the worker’s
pay rank within the workplace using data from approximately 16,000 employees in approximately
900 workplaces in the 1997-98 UK Workplace Employee Relations Surveys (WERS98). Building
upon range-frequency theory developed by psychologists and the results of a laboratory-based
experiment, they argue that absolute and relative pay are not the only pay-related determinants of
a worker’s wellbeing, and worker’s satisfaction is partly driven by her relative pay rank within the
establishment, even after controlling for absolute and relative pay. Brown et al. find that pay rank
has a positive significant impact on pay satisfaction, even when controlling for co-worker average
wage, and therefore plays and important independent role in determining pay satisfaction.
2
Godechot and Senik (2015) use a French linked employer-employee data by matching a
2009 survey of 3000 employees (SalSa) with administrative data (DADS-2008). They find that
workers in firms with higher median wage report higher levels of pay satisfaction (regardless of
their position in the wage distribution). Their results also suggest that workers’ pay satisfaction is
negatively affected by the average/median wage of workers in other firms but in the same coarse
occupational category (4 categories: blue collars, clerks, intermediate and managers), age group
(1835, 3645, 4655, 5665), and region, regardless of whether they are above or below the
reference wage. They argue that while the former result is consistent with the existence of a signal
effect within the firm, the latter is consistent with the existence of a status effect outside the firm.
One limitation of these prior studies relative to our study is that their identification
strategies do not fully account for what Manski (2000) calls “correlated effects”: unobserved
workplace-level characteristics that directly affect worker satisfaction and may be correlated with
2
Senik (2004) and Kingdon and Knight (2007) also find that other’s income has positive impact on individual well-
being. Senik (2004) uses a balanced panel survey of the Russian population from 1994 to 2000, with individuals with
similar characteristics (education, experience, occupation, region, sex, age) as the reference group. Kingdon and
Knight (2007) use national household survey of 1993 in South Africa with average income of others in the local
residential cluster as the reference group.
3
co-workers’ wage. As suggested by Abowd, Kramarz and Margolis (1999), Bronars and Famulari
(1997), Dickens and Katz (1987), and others, inter-firm wage differentials explain a large portion
of variation in individuals’ wages. These inter-firm wage differentials remain even after
controlling for observed and time-invariant unobserved worker characteristics and peer effects.
This highlights the importance of firm-level characteristics that generate these inter-firm wage
differentials. It is reasonable to believe that at least some of these firm-level characteristics will
also affect workers’ satisfaction directly. Therefore, part of the effect that is attributed to the
influence of co-workers’ wages on individual satisfaction might be driven by those firm-level
characteristics that are not accounted for in the research design. For example, low-income workers
at higher-paying firms might report higher levels of satisfaction not because of a stronger signal
effect but rather because of other unobserved firm-level characteristics such as better provision of
non-pecuniary benefits, better human resource practices, or a more relaxed work environment. In
fact, Clark et al. (2009) point out the potential bias this omission might introduce in their estimates:
Any rents that are paid [to workers] will consist of earnings (which we measure) and perks (which
we do not). In this case, conditional on own earnings, co-workers earnings will be correlated with
the firm provision of perks [an unobserved firm-specific characteristic], which has a direct effect
on job satisfaction.
3
Another issue regarding the identification strategy used by Clark et al. (2009) is that their
fixed and random effects are at the individual level since they have a longitudinal sample of
workers. As a result, their models are identified by variation in average establishment earnings
within an individual over time. Inevitably, some of this variation comes from workers switching
employers (which would be potentially associated with large changes in average establishment
earnings). This creates even more concerns regarding the bias that could be introduced by
unobserved establishment-level characteristics and also limits the interpretation of their results as
the estimated relationship between job satisfaction and relative earnings will be partly driven by
movers. In contrast, our analysis uses establishment fixed effects and our models are identified by
year-to-year variation in measured wages within the establishment. In other words, as opposed to
previous studies that compare the effect of co-workers’ wages on job/pay satisfaction of similar
workers across different workplaces, we compare the effect of co-worker’ wages on similar
workers within the same workplace over time. This within-establishment strategy has its own
limitations. For example, at least some of the measured within-establishment variation is likely to
be measurement error, implying that our results may be subject to attenuation bias and therefore
understate the magnitude of the true effect. We however mitigate these concerns by exploiting
3
They argue that this is not a potential concern since their results suggest that “only the satisfaction of those earning
less than the measure of establishment earnings [75th percentile of earning within the firm in this case] was related to
establishment earnings. The perks explanation will then only hold if any such non-monetary rewards are specifically
not targeted towards higher-paid workers (which may seem unlikely).” We argue however that this is not very unlikely.
It is in fact very reasonable to assume that non-pecuniary benefits provided to workers (such as pension coverage,
training, dental and health coverage, or even work conditions such as shift work, irregular shifts, workplace safety,
etc.) are not the same for all workers. One can imagine a scenario where there are small differences across workplaces
in these non-pecuniary benefits provided to those at the top (e.g. management positions), but there are larger
differences in benefits provided to those at the lower parts of the wage distribution. This will produce results that are
consistent with findings of Clark et al. (2007) and also consistent with our claim that unobserved workplace
heterogeneity could potentially drive these results. It is also possible that perks are targeted similarly to all workers
within establishments, but high-earners don’t care much about these perks. Therefore, while differences across
workplaces in perks generate differences in satisfaction for those at the bottom, they do not affect the satisfaction for
those at the top.
4
alternative identification strategies, explained in section 2, to account for unobserved heterogeneity
across establishments.
Another contribution of our study is to explore the effect of co-worker wages on both job
and pay satisfaction and to investigate whether co-worker wages affect these two measures
differently. Clark et al. (2009) use job satisfaction as their outcome of interest, while Brown et al.
(2008) use pay satisfaction as their outcome of interest. Although job and pay satisfaction are
highly correlated, as the results of Capelli and Sherer (1988) suggest, reference group wages could
have different effects on pay satisfaction and job satisfaction.
4
Moreover, when comparing similar
specifications, while Clark et al. (2009) find that average wage within establishment has a positive
and significant effect on worker’s job satisfaction, Brown et al. (2008) find that average wage
within establishment has a smaller and statistically insignificant effect on worker’s pay
satisfaction.
5
This potential differential impact bears further investigation as it could provide
valuable insights into understanding the driving mechanisms behind both job satisfaction and pay
satisfaction, and could help to understand whether one can reasonably use these two measures
interchangeably. In addition, having measures of both job and pay satisfaction provides an
alternative proxy variable strategy for accounting for unobserved firm characteristics: controlling
for job satisfaction (as a proxy variable for those characteristics) when we examine the effect of
co-worker wages on pay satisfaction.
6
The richness of our data also allows us to overcome some of the other limitations of the
previous studies. Brown et al. (2008) use a sample of workers with only 64% response rate, which
potentially affects the representativeness of their sample and therefore limits the external validity
of their results. In contrast, we use a nationally representative Canadian data with more than 80
percent employee response rate. Clark et al. (2009) use a panel survey that suffers from a
significant attrition between the first and the last year of the survey (around 29 percent). This
attrition undermines the validity of their results given that it is most likely non-random and
potentially mainly due to not being able to follow workers who switch employer or leave the job
market, which in turn is correlated with job satisfaction. Clark et al. (2009) also use annual earnings
to construct their inequality measure. Although they control for the number of hours worked per
week, they do not have information on the number of weeks worked per year. This can under-
estimate the impact of wage inequality on job satisfaction if larger gaps in annual earnings within
firms are due to fewer weeks worked per year, which could also affect job satisfaction. Our data
is based on a representative sample of workers, with a new sample drawn in every odd year, and
therefore does not suffer from the problem of attrition. We also have workers hourly wage rate
rather than their annual earnings.
Finally, our data enables us to test the validity of the signaling theory more directly. As the
model developed by Clark et al. (2009) suggests, “the signal effect is more likely to dominate the
4
Capelli and Sherer (1988) use a survey of 579 randomly selected employees working for a major airline to examine
the effect of outside market (i.e. average wage at other similar airline companies for equivalent jobs and seniority
levels) on worker’s job and work satisfaction. They find that outside market wages negatively affect worker’s pay
satisfaction, while they positively affect work satisfaction. They argue that this might be due to informational effect
of outside market wages, revealing information about the general job quality.
5
The effect of average wage becomes positive and significant only when measures of pay rank and pay range are also
included in the regressions (Table 6a).
6
The underlying identification assumption is that establishments where workers have similar job satisfaction levels
have similar working conditions (conditional on other factors such as worker’s own wage and other observed
individual and establishment-level characteristics).
5
status effect, so that others’ earnings are positively correlated with my own well-being, as the
match destruction rate is lower”. Since we observe each worker twice (in two consecutive years)
in our data, we are able to estimate the effect of co-workers’ wages on worker’s job and pay
satisfaction separately for those whose match destroys/survives the year after. Assuming that
individuals take their future into account, which is one of the main assumptions in the model
developed by Clark et al. (2009), the positive effect of co-workers’ wages on worker satisfaction
should be weaker for those whose match is more likely to be destroyed in the next year. We will
also examine whether the effect of relative income on worker satisfaction differs for younger
versus older workers, Canadian-born versus immigrant workers, and visible minority versus
“white” workers. Since the information conveyed by co-worker wage may vary across these
groups, the signaling effects may also vary. Finally, since our data provides measures of the
existence of pay equity policies within firms, we will exploit this information to examine whether
the effect of co-workers’ wages on worker satisfaction differs across employers with and without
pay equity policies.
There have always been discussions in economics about the credibility and robustness of
results drawn from analyses that are based on subjective reports such as job and pay satisfaction.
We believe however that there are several reasons to take results from such studies seriously. First,
the use of measures such as job and pay satisfaction has a very long tradition in the psychology
literature.
7
In addition, the reported measures of job satisfaction are found to be strongly correlated
with mental health (Faragher et al. 2005; Ramirez et al. 1996; Wall et al. 1978), length of life
(Palmore 1969), coronary heart disease (Sales and House 1971), labour turn-over (Akrelof et al.
1988; Freeman 1978; McEvoy and Cascio 1985), absenteeism (Clegg 1983), productivity and job
performance (Mangione and Quinn 1975), and business outcomes (Koys 2001; Patterson et al.
2004; Yee et al. 2008). Bradburn and Caplovitz (1965) also find evidence that suggests
individuals’ self-evaluations, although measured with error, display consistency through time.
Freeman (1978) argues that the answers to questions about how people feel toward their job are
not meaningless but rather convey useful information about economic life that should not be
ignored.”
1.1 Choice of reference group
The choice of co-workers within the same establishment as the reference group and their
average wage as the relative-pay variable is an important issue that merits some discussion,
especially given the fact that a detailed and clear discussion about appropriate reference groups to
study social interactions and inequality is missing in the economic literature (Manski 2000,
Schaffner and Torgler 2008). This is perhaps partly due to the fact that the universe of individuals
or groups within which inequality comparisons are made is broad and depends on different factors
such as context, object of interest, and individual characteristics. Moreover, depending on the
reference group and the referent used by the individual, the mechanisms through which inequality
comparisons affect individual well-being and the individual’s response to these comparisons could
vary.
As Schaffner and Torgler (2008) point out, “it is possible that more than one reference
group is relevant for an individual.” We believe co-workers within the same establishment could
be considered as one of these relevant reference groups to examine inequality comparisons and
their potential impact on well-being. There are numerous laboratory experiments and field studies
7
Spector (1985) reports that by 1985 4,793 articles had been written on the topic of job satisfaction of employees.
6
from different countries and industries that find within-workplace social comparisons regarding
wages, effort, and decision rights affect workers’ performance (see Herbst and Mas (2015) and
Charness et al. (2016) for a review). There is also evidence that suggests these peer effects are
present even within a workplace with heterogeneously skilled workers and is not only limited to
workers with the same level of ability (e.g. Charness et al. 2014, Bonein 2016). The existence of
well-documented peer effects within the workplace highlights the importance of workplace as a
social context to examine inequality comparisons. As Bonein (2016) points out, recent efforts by
firms, such as Google, Facebook, and many others to introduce new physical spaces (open-plan
offices, places to relax, etc.), new information technologies (within-workplace social networks,
chat, email), or workshop sessions are all attempts towards favouring interactions within the
workplace to foster social comparisons that are expected to enhance productivity and effort.
8
Co-
workers are among the individuals with whom one regularly interacts on a daily basis. As Pleban
and Tesser (1981) argue, physical proximity is one of the elements that affects individuals’
tendency to engage in comparison and reflection through what they define as closeness.
9
They
argue that without this sense of closeness, individuals are not able to engage in comparison
processes. In the context of co-workers, this physical proximity creates involvement in a unit
relation (Heider 1958, Pleban & Tesser 1981) and in exchanges (Homans 1961). It also reduces
information costs and complexities involved (Goodman 1977) and generates psychological
closeness (Pritchard 1969). These factors all foster comparison.
The degree of comparison and how it affects one’s well-being is partly determined by
perceived similarities in characteristics of others to one’s self. These similarities increase issue-
related communications and positioning (McPherson, Smith-Lovin, & Cook 2001) and induce a
competitive orientation and a higher level of identification (Friedkin 1993). However, what is
perceived as similarity from an individual’s point of view, and its implications for signal versus
status effects, are important in understanding and defining one’s choice of comparison group.
Similarities could be based on observed characteristics such as occupation, experience, age, skill,
ability or performance (Festinger 1954, Blau 1962, Blau 1974, Clark and Oswald 1999). However,
as Gastrof and Suls (1978) emphasize, “similarity has not always supported the prediction of a
choice of a similar other for comparison.” For example, results from different experimental studies
(e.g. Wheeler at al. 1969, Gruder 1971, Gruder etl al. 1975, Suls and Tesch 1978) suggest that
individuals with similar performance are not the most likely choice for comparison and subjects
often express more interest in comparing themselves to dissimilar others. There is evidence that
suggests this comparison with dissimilar others could take the form of upward comparison (Dakin
& Arrowood 1981, Gruder 1977, Nosanchuk & Erikson 1985, Wood 1989, Micheli and
Castelfranchi 2007) motivated by self-evaluation (Thornton & Arrowood 1966) or self-
improvement (Major, Testa, & Bylsma 1991, Lockwood & Kunda 1997). Alternatively, people
8
Consistent with these practices, a body of experimental evidence suggests that enabling social comparisons among
workers, which could generate additional information about efforts exerted by co-workers, could positively impact
worker’s exerted effort (e.g. Bonein 2014, Gächter and Thöni 2014, Gächter et al. 2013). For example, using a gift-
exchange experiment, Bonein (2014) finds evidence that suggests “Regardless of their ability, workers exert levels of
effort that are positively related to those of their coworkers. This strategic complementarity of efforts could be
explained by leading models of social preferences and inequity aversion (Fehr and Schmidt, 1999), or by social norms
and desire to comply with them (López-Pérez 2008). Bonein (2014) and Gächter et al. (2013) find evidence more
consistent with the former explanation.
9
This is also one of the central concepts in social information processing model developed in psychology (see Salancik
and Pfeffer 1978) where proximity to the attitudes, information and behaviour of others exposes individuals to social
information which in turn affects their behaviour and beliefs.
7
could also engage in downward comparison (Wills 1981) for example to improve their sense of
self-esteem (Aspinwall & Taylor 1993).
Therefore, these similarities/dissimilarities affect whether an individual assimilates or
contrasts himself relative to advantaged/disadvantaged others, which in turn determines the
function of this inequality comparison. In the context of the signal effect discussed before, through
which comparison can positively affect well-being, one could argue that it is the comparison with
relatively more skilled, capable, and successful co-workers that could potentially have a stronger
signal effect on one’s future prospects. For example, for an entry-level worker in accounting
department comparison with a senior accountant in the same establishment with 10 years of
experience will perhaps provide more meaningful information regarding his future prospects (i.e.
signal effect). At the same time, comparison with a co-worker with similar years of experience in
his own department, or even in the sales or IT department, is potentially more relevant in inducing
a feeling of relative deprivation (i.e. status effect). For a professor of philosophy while comparison
with a colleague in economics department might not provide much of a signal, but it could induce
a feeling of envy or unfairness along the lines of the status effect. Using panel data from 26 NBA
seasons, Schaffner and Torgler (2008) find that more narrowly referenced groups, such as
teammates, have the strongest effect of inequality comparison while other characteristics such as
geographical, age or experience similarities are less relevant.
Therefore, based on arguments presented above, we believe one’s comparison with co-
workers in terms of relative pay could be based on both similarities and dissimilarities in
characteristics. Only focusing on co-workers with similar characteristics could potentially block
some of the avenues through which comparison could affect well-being. For this reason, we choose
to focus on average co-worker as the comparison group without imposing any conditions on
similarities in certain characteristics between the worker and his reference group beyond being co-
workers within the same establishment. We would like to emphasize again that by defining the
comparison group in this manner we are not suggesting that this is the only relevant comparison
group for relative-pay. As we discussed above, we are focusing on one of these comparison groups,
which is one of the most relevant groups in terms of relative-pay comparisons for the reasons
outlined above. This allows us to focus on the specific issue of workplace heterogeneity in
estimating the effect of co-worker wage on worker satisfaction, contrasting our work to others
while we keep the comparison group constant in order to be able to draw a meaningful comparison.
This is not to suggest however that there are no other meaningful comparisons to be made in this
context.
2. Data and methodology
The Workplace and Employee Survey (WES) is an annual longitudinal survey of
approximately 6,000 Canadian employers and their employees between 1999 and 2006. The target
population of employers consisted of all business locations in Canada with paid employees in
March of the survey year.
10
In the 1999, 2001, 2003, and 2005 surveys, the sample of employers
was refreshed with new employers from the Statistics Canada Business Register to maintain a
10
Employers in Yukon, Nunavut and Northwest Territories and employers operating in crop production, animal
production, fishing, hunting, trapping, private households, religious organizations and public administration were
excluded from the sample. Public administration, which includes establishments primarily engaged in the enactment
and judicial interpretation of laws and their pursuant regulations and the administration of programs based on them,
accounts for around 6.5 percent of employment in Canada (Statistics Canada, Table 281-0024).
8
representative cross-section of Canadian firms.
11
A maximum of twenty-four employees were
sampled from each establishment in each odd year, and were followed the next year.
12
When
properly weighted, the employee sample is representative of the Canadian workforce in the target
population of employers; all of our analysis incorporates sample weights from Statistics Canada.
Most of our analysis is based on the pooled 1999, 2001, 2003 and 2005 cross-sections. The data
from even-numbered years are not used in the main analysis to avoid sample selection problems
associated with employee attrition in these years. However, for part of our analysis that examines
the relationship between relative wage and worker satisfaction separately for those whose match
destroys/survives the year after, we exploit the longitudinal aspect of the employee data and use
the even year observations for each worker to identify whether their match destroys or survives
during the second year of the survey.
13
The primary dependent variables in our study are self-reported measures of job satisfaction
and pay satisfaction based on the questions “Considering all aspects of this job, how satisfied are
you with the job?” and “Considering the duties and responsibilities of this job, how satisfied are
you with the pay and benefits you receive?” Workers have five options for answering these
questions: very satisfied, satisfied, dissatisfied, very dissatisfied, and no opinion. We restrict the
sample to workers with non-missing responses to job and pay satisfaction questions (i.e. exclude
workers who respond “no opinion”) between the ages of 25 and 65 from establishments that have
at least two sampled workers.
14
These restrictions result in a sample of roughly
15
75,000 workers
from about 7,500 establishments. Table 1 displays weighted sample means of key variables in our
analysis.
In our baseline analysis, we estimate linear regression models in which the satisfaction
variable is coded as 4 for “very satisfied”, 3 for “satisfied”, 2 for “dissatisfied” and 1 for “very
dissatisfied”. We also estimate ordered logit models as a robustness check (see Section 3.2.2).
The satisfaction level of worker i working in establishment j at time t is represented by the
variable sijt and is modeled in our preferred specification as:
           (1)
11
The sampling unit for employers in the WES is a location (or workplace) as opposed to a firm (or enterprise).
Therefore, if a firm has several locations, all those locations are in the target population from which the sample of
employers are drawn.
12
The number of workers sampled from each firm was proportional to firm’s size except workplaces with fewer than
four employees where all employees are selected. We should also mention that there was no employee survey (only
employer survey) in 2006.
13
The randomly selected workers in each odd year make one of four transitions between the two interviews: enter
unemployment or self-employment, move to a new employer, stay with the same employer, or attrit (i.e. cannot be
contacted for the second interview). We should clarify that a change of employer does not mean that the worker has
attrited. Only employees whose first-year employer is not in business during the second interview year are excluded
to be re-interviewed. Workers who moved to a new employer after the first interview, regardless of whether the new
employer is part of the selected sample of workplaces or not, are still included to be followed and re-interviewed. As
for attrition, it can happen due to several reasons that we cannot identify in our data such as refusal, unable to contact
or locate, absent for duration of survey, own illness, deceased, or unusual or special circumstances.
14
The proportion of workers who respond “no opinion” is around 0.003 in our data. Our results are robust to other
ways of handling these observations.
15
Exact sample sizes are not currently available due to Statistics Canada release restrictions, but will be included in
the final version of the paper.
9
The key explanatory variables in this model are the worker’s own log hourly wage (wijt) as well as
a summary measure (or vector of summary measures) of current wages among other workers at
the same workplace (), and the parameters of interest will be their coefficients γ1 and γ2.
16
In
the primary specification,  will be the log average wage among co-workers. We also estimate
specifications in which the effect of average co-worker wages is different for high-wage and low-
wage workers, and specifications in which worker satisfaction depends on wage rank.
In addition to those key explanatory variables, our preferred model includes an
establishment fixed effect (, a year fixed effect (dt), and an extensive set of individual-level
control variables (Xijt). These controls include detailed or coarse occupational categories (48 and
6 categories, respectively), race and immigrant status (white Canadian, visible minority Canadian,
white immigrant, visible minority immigrant, Aboriginal), gender, language spoken at home (3
categories), language spoken at work (3 categories), language spoken at home different from
language spoken at work, highest level of schooling (8 categories), marital status (6 categories),
number of dependent children (5 categories), age (9 categories), a quadratic in years of (actual)
full-time labour market experience, a quadratic in tenure with current employer, number of times
promoted while working for the current employer, an indicator for full-time employment, and
whether the respondent’s job is covered by a collective bargaining agreement (CBA) or union.
The ideal model would include both individual fixed effects and establishment fixed effects
to account for unobserved individual-level and establishment-level heterogeneity. The structure of
our data however does not allow us to use individual fixed effects in our estimation.
17
The results
of Clark et al. (2009) suggest however that exclusion of individual fixed effects does not introduce
any bias in estimated results. In other words, they find that conditional on workers observed
characteristics and own wage, there is no systematic sorting of workers across firms based on
individual unobserved characteristics that are also correlated with worker job satisfaction.
18
Godechot and Senik (2015) also perform a series of tests to examine whether their results are
driven by workers’ self-selection into different firms. They also conclude that their data does not
validate the idea that the association between the notions of reference wage and wage satisfaction
is driven by people’s self-selection into certain firms or regions.We therefore focus our attention
on establishment-level heterogeneity to examine whether they play any role in explaining the
previous findings.
Heterogeneity across establishments is addressed using three different strategies. Our main
results are derived using model (1) with establishment fixed effects. This model allows persistent
unobserved differences across establishments that affect both satisfaction and wages. It has the
limitation that the parameters of interest are identified from year-to-year variation of co-worker
wages within establishments, so consistent estimation requires this variation to be both real (i.e.,
is not the result of measurement error) and exogenous. In addition, the potential that co-worker
16
We do not use employee-level weights provided in the WES to generate these summary measures. These weights
are designed to make the overall sample of workers in the WES representative of the population of Canadian
workers. There are no weights provided in the WES to make the random sample drawn from each firm
representative of the population within the firm.
17
As noted in Section 3, workers are only followed for one year and there is a new random sample of workers drawn
from within each establishment in every odd year.
18
In fact, even intuitively, it is hard to come up with a scenario that would suggest conditional on individual observed
characteristics and own wage, workers might be systematically sorted across firms based on some unobserved
characteristics (e.g. genes, upbringing) that are also correlated with job satisfaction.
10
wages serve as a proxy for unobserved perks is still an issue to the extent that there is year-to-year
variation in perks that is correlated with the year-to-year variation in wages. Finally, the fact that
establishment wages are estimated from a random sample of workers within each establishment
implies that there is some degree of classical measurement error, so the social effect estimates are
subject to attenuation bias and will underestimate the true effect.
Another relevant consideration is the potential for heterogeneity in response that is
implicitly assumed away when using a single parameter to describe the social effect. Presumably
annual variations in wage growth within the firm would be driven mostly by trends in the firm’s
business conditions. Both theories (signal effect and status effect) apply to this source of variation,
but since both theories rely on the social context of the comparison, their absolute and relative
strength may be different when responding to changes (my co-workers have higher wages than
they did last year) versus responding to levels (my co-workers have high wages). This may provide
an explanation for different findings when using establishment fixed effects versus when using
establishment characteristics without implying that either findings are incorrect.
Our second strategy for addressing workplace heterogeneity is to take advantage of the
WES to estimate regressions without establishment effects but with a rich set of establishment
characteristics included in the vector of control variables:
        
    (2)
The establishment-level characteristics in
 include industry (14 categories), establishment size
(4 categories), degree of competition (4 categories), an indicator for the existence of a pay or
employment equity policy in the firm, an indicator for non-profit firms, average quit rate,
proportion of full-time employees, an indicator for good/fair rating of labour-management
relations, a standardized z-score measure for provision of non-wage benefits (e.g. dental care, life
insurance, supplemental medical, pension plan, group RRSP, stock purchase, etc), logarithm of
training expenditures per worker, an indicator for existence of any incentive schemes in the
compensation system (group incentive systems such as productivity/quality grain sharing,
individual incentive systems such as bonus, piece-rate and commissions, merit pay and skill-based
pay, profit sharing), and an indicator for existence of any innovative work practices (employee
suggestion programs, flexible job design, information sharing with employees, problem-solving
teams, joint labour-management committees, self-directed work groups).
Our third strategy is to control for average satisfaction  among co-workers:
            (3)
When  is included in the model we are interpreting it in part as a proxy for the overall working
environment at the establishment, and so we do not give a causal interpretation to its coefficient
γ3. The idea behind this strategy is that co-worker satisfaction can act as a proxy variable for
otherwise unobservable features of the working environment that are relevant to the worker’s own
satisfaction.
19
One advantage of using co-worker job satisfaction is that it may capture time-
varying establishment-level unobserved factors that might affect worker job/pay satisfaction and
19
By controlling for average co-worker job satisfaction we are comparing worker job/pay satisfaction across firms
where co-worker job satisfaction is similar, but co-worker pay is different. In other words, we are assuming that firms
where workers have similar job satisfaction levels have similar working conditions, conditional on wages and other
observed characteristics.
11
may be correlated with the year-to-year variation in coworker wages. Moreover, this identification
strategy is affected less by attenuation bias than models with establishment fixed effects.
3. Results
3.1 Main regression results
Table 2 displays results from estimating linear models for both job and pay satisfaction as
described in Section 2 above. Column (1) uses a simplified model with no additional control
variables other than year effects, while column (2) adds personal and job characteristics, and
columns (3) and (4) add occupation in coarse and detailed categories respectively. These four
regressions are included mostly for informational purposes as they do not account for
heterogeneity across employers. Columns (5) through (7) show our three approaches to accounting
for workplace heterogeneity as described in Section 2. Column (5) uses detailed establishment-
level control variables, column (6) controls for average co-worker job satisfaction, and column (7)
uses establishment fixed effects. As discussed in Section 2, column (7) is our preferred
specification.
As one might expect, the worker’s own pay has a positive and significant effect on both
job and pay satisfaction in all specifications. The effect of own pay on pay satisfaction is about
twice as large as its effect on job satisfaction. This suggests, not surprisingly, that reported job
satisfaction contains more information about a job other than the amount of pay received. Co-
worker pay also has a positive and significant relationship with both pay satisfaction and job
satisfactions in models that do not account for workplace heterogeneity (columns 1 to 4). However,
the effect of co-worker wage on pay satisfaction is more than twice as large as its effect on job
satisfaction. Our estimated effect on pay satisfaction is similar to or somewhat larger than that
found by Brown et al. (2008, Table 5) or Godechot and Senik (2015),
20
but our estimated effect
on job satisfaction is generally smaller than that found by Clark et al. (2009, Table 2 column 3).
21
Column (5) shows that accounting for workplace heterogeneity by detailed establishment-
level control variables does not reduce the estimated effect of co-worker wage, and in fact slightly
increases it. However, column (7) shows that our preferred strategy of using establishment fixed
effects does substantially reduce the estimated effect of co-worker wage. The effect of co-worker
pay on job satisfaction disappears (it becomes quantitatively small and statistically insignificant),
while the effect on pay satisfaction reduces by 35-45 percent but remains at least marginally
significant. Similar results are seen in column (6) when workplace heterogeneity is addressed by
controlling for co-worker job satisfaction. This suggests that smaller estimated effect of co-worker
average pay in the model with establishment fixed effects is unlikely to be driven entirely by
attenuation bias due to measurement error we discussed before. In addition, comparing the
estimated effect of co-worker pay in columns (6) and (7) with column (5) also seems to suggest
that even the very detailed set of observed establishment-level characteristics available in the WES
20
The coefficient on co-worker average wage in our pay satisfaction regression is 0.074, and the dependent variable
is coded on a scale of 1 to 4 with a standard deviation of 0.73. The coefficient in Brown et al. (2008, Table 5) is
0.077 and their dependent variable is coded on a scale from 1 to 5 with a standard deviation of 1.10. The coefficient
in Godechot and Senik (2015, Table 1) is 0.046, and their dependent variable is coded on a scale of 1 to 4 with a
standard deviation of 0.72.
21
The coefficient on co-worker average wage in our job satisfaction regression is 0.031, and the dependent variable
is coded on a scale of 1 to 4 with a standard deviation of 0.66. The coefficient in Clark et al. (2009, Table 2 column
3) is 0.08, and their dependent variable is coded on a scale of 1 to 6 with a standard deviation of 0.95.
12
do not do enough in accounting for workplace heterogeneity, which seems to be driven by
unobserved establishment-level characteristics.
The novelty of our results is two-fold. First, our results suggest that it is important to control
for workplace heterogeneity that might be correlated with co-worker pay and also affect worker
satisfaction. Failure to account for workplace heterogeneity seems to over-estimate the true effect
of co-worker pay on worker satisfaction. It would be interesting to know more about the
establishment characteristics that are associated with higher average wages and higher levels of
employee satisfaction. Using the same data as our study, Javdani (2015) finds that “Firms that pay
higher premiums to their employees (after accounting for inter-firm differences in workforce
composition) are on average larger, more likely to have a pay equity program, face more
competition, are more likely to provide non-wage benefits, have lower quit rates, have higher
training expenditures, have higher productivity, are more likely to have incentive compensation
schemes.”
Second, co-worker pay seems to have different effects on worker job and pay satisfaction.
An increase in average co-worker wage does not have any effect on worker job satisfaction, while
its effect on pay satisfaction is positive and statistically significant. The point estimate implies
that a 10% increase in average co-worker wage raises worker pay satisfaction by 0.0046 points.
This effect is quite small: 0.63% of a standard deviation or 14% of the effect of a 10% increase in
own wage. While job and pay satisfaction are highly correlated, our results suggest they are
determined and affected by sometimes different factors. That is, workers in the WES evaluate their
pay satisfaction in relation to the pay of others in their workplace, but their job satisfaction is not
affected by this comparison. In addition, since the effect is positive (implying a signaling effect),
these results also suggest that pay satisfaction is forward looking to some extent. That is, it reflects
satisfaction with the trajectory of pay rather than just the current level.
Given this difference in results between pay satisfaction and job satisfaction, we might
wonder what other characteristics of the job and workplace have different relationships with pay
and job satisfaction. This question can be partially answered by looking at the other regression
coefficients (available in our online appendix, table A1) in specification (5), which uses
establishment characteristics rather than establishment fixed effects. In those regressions, we find
the biggest difference is for unionization (which has a strong negative association with job
satisfaction but a strong positive association with pay satisfaction). The negative association
between unionization and job satisfaction is a common and extensively-debated finding in the
literature. Other substantial differences appear for past history of promotions (which has a strong
positive association with job satisfaction but a much weaker association with pay satisfaction), and
industry (lowest pay satisfaction is found in Real Estate, Rental and Leasing Operations followed
by Finance and Insurance, while lowest job satisfaction is found in Labour Intensive Primary
Manufacturing followed by Secondary Product Manufacturing). Other characteristics such as firm
size, establishment quit rate, the use of innovative work practices, and quality of labour relations
have a similar association with both forms of satisfaction.
3.2 Robustness checks
3.2.1 Alternative reference groups
As discussed in Section 1.1, co-workers are a natural reference group to think about when
considering pay comparisons, they are not the only reference group whose pay may influence
worker satisfaction. Empirically there are two related questions to answer: what other reference
13
groups matter and how do they matter, and is there any reason to believe that co-worker pay is
acting as a proxy for the pay of some more important and substantially different reference group.
To investigate this question, we constructed two alternative reference groups and estimated our
model with these reference groups in place of or in addition to co-workers.
The first alternative reference group is co-workers who are in the same (broad) occupation.
One concern with using all co-workers as the reference group is that includes workers on very
different career paths or at very different levels within those paths. Narrowing the reference group
to include only those in the same occupation partially addresses this issue. Column (2) of Table 3
reports the results from using same-occupation co-workers as the reference group instead of all
co-workers. As the results show, the coefficients are very similar in magnitude to our main results
(reported in column 1). Although data limitations make it difficult to further narrow the within-
firm comparison group, these results suggest that further narrowing would not change our main
results.
The second alternative reference group is all workers in the same (detailed) occupation and
industry. This reference group allows for the likelihood that workers make comparisons to the pay
received by similar workers at other firms, and that these comparisons influence worker
satisfaction. Because this comparison group is not a subset of co-workers (unlike our same-
occupation co-workers comparison group), we estimate models in which this comparison group is
included in addition to co-workers as well as those in which it is included in place of co-workers.
The results for the specification that includes both comparison groups are reported in column (3)
of Table 3. The coefficients on co-worker average wage do not change substantially, suggesting
that co-worker wages are not acting as a proxy for wages of similar workers outside of the firm.
The coefficients on same-occupation-and-industry average wages show an interesting pattern: a
sizeable and statistically significant positive effect on job satisfaction, but a smaller and
statistically insignificant positive effect on pay satisfaction. Note that this is the opposite of our
findings for co-worker pay. Column (4) shows results for a specification that does not include co-
worker average wage; these results are similar to those reported in column (3). Taken together,
these results suggest that workers make comparisons both within and outside of the firm, that these
comparisons affect satisfaction in different ways, and that it is reasonable to analyze these effects
separately.
22
3.2.2 Alternative measures of co-worker wages
Although our basic model assumes that workers care specifically about the average wage
of their co-workers, the literature has considered other potentially relevant features of the co-
worker wages. Table 4 reports results using alternative characterizations of coworker relative pay.
Column (1) in the table repeats our main results (i.e., column 7 of Table 2) for ease of
comparison. The results in column (2) are based on an alternative behavioral assumption in which
a worker cares about his or her rank within the workplace’s pay distribution, as in Brown et al.
(2008). This pay rank variable is constructed using the workplace’s full earnings distribution rather
than just the random sample of surveyed employees, so this variable may be less subject to
22
We also examine whether co-workers in different age categories have different effects on worker satisfaction, and
whether this effect depends on worker’s own age category. Results from these models are reported in our online
appendix (table A2) and are similar to our main results (i.e., column 7 of Table 2). More specifically, we find that co-
workers in different age categories have similar impacts on worker satisfaction, regardless of worker’s own age
category.
14
measurement error and attenuation bias. In the WES, workplaces are asked to report the number
of permanent full-time and part-time employees in each of the following annual earnings
categories: $80k and above, $60k-80k, $40k-60k, $20k-40k, $20k and below. We use this
information along with the total number of employees within the establishment to calculate the
proportion of workers that are in a higher earnings category.
23
The results in column (2) are
qualitatively similar to those in column (1): pay rank does not appear to affect job satisfaction, but
has a positive and significant association with pay satisfaction. To put the coefficient into context,
a 10-percentile downward move within the firm’s pay distribution (keeping one’s own pay fixed)
would imply a 0.006 or 0.82% of a standard deviation increase in pay satisfaction. Column (3)
reports results for a specification that includes both average pay and pay rank, and yields very
similar results to those in columns (1) and (2).
24
The results in column (4) allow an asymmetric effect of co-worker average wage depending
on whether the worker’s own wage is higher or lower than the average, as is considered by Clark
et al. (2009). The results for job satisfaction are similar to our baseline results and suggest that co-
worker wages have little effect on either those with above average or below average wages. In
contrast, the results for pay satisfaction support the hypothesis of an asymmetric impact. For those
workers who make less than the average co-worker pay, increase in average co-worker pay (i.e.
increase in the difference between own pay and average co-worker pay) has a positive and
significant impact on pay satisfaction that is somewhat larger to what we find in column (1) where
we impose symmetry on the effect. However, for those workers who make more than the average
co-worker pay, an increase in average co-worker pay (i.e. decrease in the difference between own
pay and average co-worker pay) has no impact on pay satisfaction.
Finally, we also examine whether a measure that reflects wages in the upper-part of the
workplace wage distribution differently affects worker satisfaction. For example, the signal effect
might be stronger if workers at lower job levels look up to co-workers at high levels of hierarchy
as a signal of their future prospects within the firm. Our findings are reported in columns (3) and
(4) in Table A3 in our online appendix. They suggest that using the 75th percentile of wage
distribution within firm produces similar results to average wage, whether included on its own or
along with controlling for median co-worker pay.
25
3.2.3 Ordered logit model
In addition to the linear models estimated for Table 2, we estimated analogous ordered
logit models as a robustness check. The detailed ordered logit results are not reported here, but
are generally consistent with the findings for the linear model reported in Table 2.
Using the ordered logit model for the analysis is somewhat complicated by the use of
sample weights in the WES. Statistics Canada does not allow the release of unweighted results
from the restricted-access WES data. However, the standard estimation procedures (e.g.,
23
For those workers who earn more than $80,000, since there is no higher earnings category identified by the survey
question, we cannot directly calculate the proportion of workers in higher earnings categories. Therefore, for those
workers who fall in this category we set the proportion of workers in higher earnings categories to zero.
24
As another alternative measure, we also use median co-worker wage. These results are reported in our online
appendix, Table A3 (column 2) and are qualitatively similar to our results using average co-worker pay. The estimated
coefficients are however quantitatively larger when we use median wage.
25
The one exception is the regression for pay satisfaction, without controlling for median and with firm characteristics
rather than firm fixed effects. In that case, the coefficient on 75th percentile is positive and significant. These results
are not reported here, but are available upon request.
15
Baetschmann et al. 2015) for conditional (fixed effect) logit models do not accommodate
individual-level weights because they involve conditioning on group-level counts. We address this
in several ways. First, we compared the weighted and unweighted results for linear models. Based
on this comparison we do not believe the weights have a quantitatively important effect on the
results. Second, we estimated ordered logit models with weights and firm level control variables
rather than fixed effects. These results can be released, and are qualitatively similar to those for
weighted linear models with firm level control variables. Finally, we estimated conditional (fixed
effect) ordered logit models without weights and found that these were qualitatively similar to
those for unweighted linear models with fixed effects.
3.3 Heterogeneity
Tables 5a through 5c consider various forms of heterogeneity in the effect of co-worker
pay on worker satisfaction. Workers may vary substantially in the relative importance of the signal
effect and the status effect, and so may vary substantially in the magnitude and even direction of
the overall social effect. For comparison purposes, column (1) in Table 5a reproduces the results
from our preferred specification with establishment fixed effects and detailed worker and job
characteristics, i.e., column (7) in Table 2.
Columns (2) and (3) divide the sample by worker age. Since the signal effect operates
through co-worker pay being a signal of future pay for the worker, it is presumably stronger in
younger workers who have more potential for future pay growth and more uncertainty about its
likely magnitude. Consistent with our previous results, we find that co-worker pay does not affect
job satisfaction for either young workers or old workers. However, in line with the aforementioned
hypothesis, our results suggest that while co-worker pay does not have a significant effect on pay
satisfaction for older workers, it has a positive and significant effect on younger worker’s pay
satisfaction. This contrast is only suggestive, as the difference between older and younger workers
is not statistically significant even at 10%.
Columns (4) and (5) in Table 5a divide the sample by whether or not the firm has a pay
equity policy. Firms with effective pay equity policies are more likely to raise the wage of workers
that are low-paid relative to comparable workers in the firm, implying a stronger signal effect.
Consistent with this hypothesis, we find that co-worker pay has a larger effect on pay satisfaction
in firms with pay equity relative to those without pay equity. However, both estimates are
statistically insignificant due to the increased standard errors, as is the difference between the
estimates. Columns (6) and (7) in Table 5b divide the sample by unionization (i.e., whether the job
is covered by a collective bargaining agreement). Here we see little difference between those in
unionized and non-unionized jobs.
Columns (8), (9) and (10) in Table 5b take advantage of the longitudinal structure of the
WES, and divide the sample into three groups: workers who show up in year t of the survey but
not t+1 (i.e. attriters), workers whose match is destroyed in t+1, and workers who are still with
same employer in t+1. Subsequent employment changes are clearly endogenous and so these
empirical relationships cannot be given a strict causal interpretation. However, they are potentially
informative as to which groups are driving our main results. As the table shows, co-worker pay
has no statistically significant relationship with the job satisfaction of workers who stay with their
firm during the second year, but has a large positive and significant relationship with the job
satisfaction of workers whose match is destroyed. We also find that while co-worker pay has a
positive and significant impact on pay satisfaction of both of these groups, the effect is almost
16
twice as large for those whose match is destroyed in the second year.
26
These results are in contrast
with the predictions of the model developed by Clark et al. (2009) which suggests “the signal effect
is more likely to dominate the status effect, so that others’ earnings are positively correlated with
my own well-being, as the match destruction rate is lower”. Therefore, assuming that individuals
take their future into account, which is one of the main assumptions in the model developed by
Clark et al. (2009), the positive effect of co-workers’ wages on worker satisfaction should be
weaker for those whose match destroys the year after. One potential explanation of our results is
that some workers might be more ambitious and motivated to advance in their career, and therefore
are more positively and strongly affected by the relative income of their reference group (a stronger
signal effect). These workers might have a wider reference group (i.e. similar workers in higher-
paying firms) and use inter-firm mobility when possible as a channel to improve their future
prospects, and therefore are more likely to leave their employer.
27
Consistent with this hypothesis,
our results suggest that these workers experience a larger wage growth between the two interview
years (around 4 percent) compared to those who stay with their firm.
We also examine whether there exists any heterogeneity in the effect of own wage and
co-worker wage on worker satisfaction by gender. There is evidence that suggests men and
women might be affected differently in environments that involve status or signal effects (e.g.
Clark 1997, Niedrele and Vesterlund 2007). These results are reported in the last three columns
of Table 5b. We find no evidence of heterogeneity by gender in the job satisfaction regressions.
There exists, however, some heterogeneity in our regressions of pay satisfaction. More
specifically, we find that own pay has a stronger positive impact on women compared to men
(0.4 versus 0.27), a difference that is statistically significant. On the other hand, women’s pay
satisfaction seem to be less influenced by the co-worker pay relative to their male counterparts
(0.03 versus 0.06), a difference that is not statistically significant.
These two findings are consistent with Clark (1997) who suggests there might exist real
gender differences in utility from working in that women on average expect less from working and
are therefore more satisfied with any given job. This in turn suggests that women will be on average
more satisfied with a given pay relative to their male counterparts. In addition, given their lower
expectations, they might pay less attention to co-worker pay as a signal effect, and therefore this
comparison would affect them to a lesser extent. Smaller positive effect of co-worker pay among
women is also consistent with evidence that suggests women are more likely to shy away from
competitive environments (e.g. Gneezy, Niederle, and Rustichini 2003, Gneezy and Rustichini
2004, Niedrele and Vesterlund 2007 & 2010).
Table 5c displays results from estimating our preferred specification allowing for the main
coefficients to differ by immigration and visible minority status.
28
,
29
Both social comparisons and
26
WES allows us to identify whether the match was destroyed by the firm or the worker. We also estimated models
where we only focused on workers whose match was destroyed because they left the firm, and we find similar results
to those reported in column (7).
27
Having a wider reference group does not necessarily imply that the signal effect will be weaker. It could be a signal
of how ambitious the worker is, and the fact that not only she cares about the wages of coworkers within the same
establishment, but she also has her eyes on opportunities outside the firm as well.
28
The results in Table 4b can be interpreted as allowing all coefficients other than establishment fixed effects to vary
across the four groups. Given that we don’t observe a very large number of workers with establishments, allowing
establishment effects to vary by these four categories will result in very imprecisely estimated establishment effects.
29
“Visible minority” is a standard classification in Canada. “Visible minority refers to whether a person belongs to a
visible minority group as defined by the Employment Equity Act and, if so, the visible minority group to which the
17
predictions of future wages are potentially different across these groups. For example, a gap
between current own wage and co-worker wage may be a signal of future wage growth for white
Canadian-born workers and a signal of ongoing discrimination for visible minority or immigrant
workers. We find that while co-worker pay has no impact on job satisfaction of white Canadian-
born workers, it has a negative impact on job satisfaction of other groups, although none of the
estimates are statistically significant. We also find that while co-worker pay has a positive and
significant impact on pay satisfaction of white Canadian-borns, it has a significantly large and
negative impact on pay satisfaction of visible minority Canadian-borns. We also find that the effect
on white immigrants is positive, while it is negative for visible minority immigrants, although both
estimated effects are small and statistically insignificant. One potential explanation for these
results is that apart from white Canadian-borns, other groups might believe that the average wages
of their co-workers is not a good indicator of their prospects in the future. This could be due to the
fact that they have fewer opportunities to receive promotions and climb up the ladder. Using the
same data set, Javdani (2017) and Javdani and McGee (2017) find that both visible minority
Canadian-borns and visible minority immigrants are less likely to have been promoted and are
promoted fewer times, compared to white Canadian-borns. Javdani (2017) also finds that visible
minority Canadian-borns receive lower returns to promotion. The different effects on Canadian-
born versus immigrant visible minorities could be due to the fact that while for both groups average
co-worker pay is not a good signal of their future prospects (i.e. a weak signal effect), for the latter
group this might not have a strong negative externality (i.e. status effect) since they might also
compare their pay with similar workers back in their country of origin and be content with their
pay in Canada. Visible minority Canadian-borns however do not make this comparison (since
Canada is their country of origin) and therefore higher average co-worker pay might be a signal of
discrimination and therefore impose substantial negative externality on them through the status
effect.
4. Conclusion
We examine whether co-worker pay has any impact on worker’s job and pay satisfaction. We also
examine whether unobserved firm-level characteristics that might be correlated with co-workers’
pay and also affect worker satisfaction will influence these results. Consistent with Clark et al.
(2009) and Brown et al. (2008) we find that average co-worker pay has a positive impact on
worker’s job/pay satisfaction. However, contrary to previous studies we also estimate models that
account for unobserved firm-level characteristics that might bias these results. Our results suggest
that after taking into account the unobserved firm-level heterogeneity, the effect of co-worker pay
on job satisfaction disappears, and the effect on pay satisfaction reduces by 35 to 45 percent. The
implications of these results are two-fold. First, our results suggest that it is important to control
for inter-firm heterogeneity that might be correlated with co-worker pay and also affect worker
satisfaction. Failure to account for inter-firm heterogeneity seems to over-estimate the true effect
of co-worker pay on worker satisfaction. Second, co-worker pay seems to have different effects
on worker job and pay satisfaction. While job and pay satisfaction are highly correlated, our results
suggest they are determined and affected by sometimes different factors. That is, workers in the
person belongs. The Employment Equity Act defines visible minorities as "persons, other than Aboriginal peoples,
who are non-Caucasian in race or non-white in colour". The visible minority population consists mainly of the
following groups: Chinese, South Asian, Black, Arab, West Asian, Filipino, Southeast Asian, Latin American,
Japanese and Korean.” (Statistics Canada, 2015). We define our indicator of visible minority status likewise.
18
WES evaluate their pay satisfaction in relation to wages of others in their workplace, but their job
satisfaction is not affected by this comparison.
We also find evidence of asymmetry in the effect of co-worker pay on pay satisfaction. We find
that while the effect is positive for those who make less than their average co-worker pay, it is
small and statistically insignificant for those who earn higher than the average co-worker pay. Our
results also suggest that there exists significant heterogeneity in the effect of co-worker pay on pay
satisfaction. We find that the effect is positive and large for younger workers, while it is small and
statistically insignificant for older workers. We also find that the effect is larger in firms that have
a pay equity policy. Our results also suggest that the effect is larger among workers whose match
destroys during the next year, relative to those whose match survives. Finally, we find that while
the effect on pay satisfaction is positive and significant for white Canadian-born workers, it is very
large and negative for visible-minority Canadian-borns, and small and statistically insignificant
for white and visible minority immigrants.
19
References
Abowd, J. M., Kramarz, F., Margolis, D. N. (1999). High wage workers and high wage firms.
Econometrica 67(2): 251- 334.
Akerlof, G. A., Rose, A. K., Yellen, J. L., Ball, L., Hall, R. E. (1988). Job switching and job
satisfaction in the US labor market. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1988(2), 495-594.
Akerlof, G., Yellen, J. (1990). The fair wageeffort hypothesis and unemployment. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 105, 255284.
Aspinwall, L. G., & Taylor, S. E. (1993). The effects of social comparison direction, threat, and
self-esteem on affect, self-evaluation, and expected success. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology 64, 708-722.
Baetschmann, G., Staub, K. E., Winkelmann, R. (2015). Consistent estimation of the fixed effects
ordered logit model. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society) 178(3),
685-703.
Blau, P. M. (1962). Patterns of choice in interpersonal relations. American Sociological Review
27, 41-56.
Blau. (1974). Patterns of communication among theoretical high energy physi- cists. Sociometry
37, 391-406.
Bolton, G.E. (1991). A comparative model of bargaining: Theory and evidence. American
Economic Review 81, 1096-1136.
Bolton, G.E., Ockenfels, A. (2000). A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. American
Economic Review 100, 166-193.
Bonein, A. (2014). Social comparison and peer effects with heterogeneous ability (No. 201411).
Center for Research in Economics and Management (CREM), University of Rennes 1, University
of Caen and CNRS.
Bradburn, N. M., Caplovitz, D. (1965). Reports on Happiness. Aldine Publishing Company.
Bronars, S., Famulari, M., (1997). Wage, tenure, and wage growth variation within and across
establishments. Journal of Labor Economics 15(2): 285317.
Brown, G. D., Gardner, J., Oswald, A. J., Qian, J. (2008). Does wage rank affect employees’ well
being? Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 47(3), 355-389.
Burchell, B., Yagil, D. (1997). Socioeconomic and political initiators of pay comparison. Work
Employment and Society 11, 737-748.
Card, D., Mas A., Moretti, E., Saez, E., (2012). Inequality at work: The effect of peer salaries on
job satisfaction. American Economic Review 102, 2981-3003.
Cappelli, P., Chauvin, K. (1991). An inter-plant test of the efficiency wage hypothesis. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 106, 769-787.
Cappelli, P., Sherer, P.D. (1988). Satisfaction, market wages, and labor relations: An airline study.
Industrial Relations 27, 56-73.
20
Charness, G., Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 117 (3), 817869.
Charness, G., Gross, T., & Guo, C. (2014). Merit pay and wage compression with productivity
differences and uncertainty. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 233-247.
Charness, G., Cobo-Reyes, R., Lacomba, J. A., Lagos, F., & Pérez, J. M. (2016). Social
comparisons in wage delegation: Experimental evidence. Experimental Economics 19(2), 433-
459.
Clark, A. E., Oswald, A. J. (1996). Satisfaction and comparison income. Journal of Public
Economics 61(3), 359-381.
Clark, A. E. (1997). Job satisfaction and gender: why are women so happy at work?. Labour
economics, 4(4), 341-372.
Clark, A. E., Kristensen, N., WestergårdNielsen, N. (2009). Job satisfaction and coworker wages:
Status or signal? The Economic Journal 119(536), 430-447.
Clegg, C. W. (1983). Psychology of employee lateness, absence, and turnover: A methodological
critique and an empirical study. Journal of Applied Psychology 68(1), 88.
Dakin, S., & Arrowood, A. J. (1981). The social comparison of ability. Human Relations 34, 89-
109.
Diener, E., Biswas-Diener, R. (2000). New directions in subjective well-being research: the cutting
edge. Indian Journal of Clinical Psychology 27, 2133.
Dickens, W. T., Katz, L. F. (1987). Inter-industry wage differences and industry characteristics. In
Unemployment and the Structure of Labor Markets, edited by K. Lang and J. Leonard, pp. 48-89.
New York: Basil Blackwell.
Duesenberry, J. (1949). Income, Savings and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge:
University of Harvard Press.
Easterlin, R.A. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence.
In: David, P.A., Reder, M.W. (Eds.), Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in
Honor of Moses Abramovitz, pp. 89125. New York and London: Academic Press.
Easterlin, R. (1995). Will raising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organization 27, 3547.
Falk, A., Knell, M. (2004). Choosing the Joneses: Endogenous goals and reference standards.
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 106(3), 417-435.
Faragher, E.B., Cass, M., Cooper, C.L. (2005). The relationship between job satisfaction and
health: A meta-analysis. Occupational and Environmental Medicine 62(2), 105-112.
Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. (2005). Income and well-being: an empirical analysis of the comparison
income effect. Journal of Public Economics 89(5), 997-1019.
Festinger, L. (1954). A theory of social comparison processes. Human Relations 7, 117-140.
Frank, R.H. (1985). Choosing the Right Pond: Human Behaviour and the Quest for Status. Oxford
University Press, London.
21
Frank, R.H., Sunstein, C.R. (2001). Cost-benefit analysis and relative position. University of
Chicago Law Review 68, 323374.
Freeman, R. B. (1978). Job satisfaction as an economic variable. American Economic Review
68(2), 135-141.
Friedkin, N. E. (1993). Structural bases of interpersonal influence in groups: A longitudinal case
study. American Sociological Review 58, 861-872.
Gastorf, J. W., & Suls, J. (1978). Performance evaluation via social comparison: Performance
similarity versus related-attribute similarity. Social Psychology 297-305.
Gneezy, U., Niederle, M., & Rustichini, A. (2003). Performance in competitive environments:
Gender differences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(3), 1049-1074.
Gneezy, U., & Rustichini, A. (2004). Gender and competition at a young age. American Economic
Review, 94(2), 377-381.
Godechot, O., & Senik, C. (2015). Wage comparisons in and out of the firm. Evidence from a
matched employeremployee French database. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,
117, 395-410.
Goodman, P. S. (1977). Social comparison processes in organizations. In B. M. Staw & G.
Salancik (Eds.), New Directions in Organizational Behavior (pp. 97132). Chicago, IL: St. Claire
Press.
Gruder, C. L. (1971). Determinants of social comparison choices. Journal of Experimental Social
Psychology 7(5), 473-489.
Gruder, C. L., Korth, B., Dichtel, M., & Glos, B. (1975). Uncertainty and social comparison.
Journal of Research in Personality 9(1), 85-95.
Gruder, C. (1977). Choice of comparison persons in evaluating oneself. In J. Suls & R. L. Miller
(Eds.), Social comparison processes: Theoretical and empirical perspectives (pp. 21-42).
Washington, DC: Hemisphere.
Hamermesh, D.S. (2001). The changing distribution of job satisfaction. Journal of Human
Resources 36, 1-30.
Herbst, D., & Mas, A. (2015). Peer effects on worker output in the laboratory generalize to the
field. Science 350(6260), 545-549.
Heider, F. (1958). The psychology of interpersonal relations. New York: Wiley.
Hills, F.S. (1980). The relevant other in pay comparisons. Industrial Relations 19, 345-350.
Hirschman, A., Rothschild, M. (1973). The changing tolerance for income inequality in the course
of economic development, Quarterly Journal of Economics 87(4), 54466.
Homans, C. G. (1961). Social Behavior: Its Elementary Forms. New York: Harcourt, Brace &
World.
Javdani, M. (2017). Does Color Matter? Estimating Differences in Promotions and Returns to
Promotions between White and Visible Minority Canadian-Borns. Working paper.
Javdani, M., McGee, A. (2017). Intra-Firm Upward Mobility and Immigration. IZA Working
Paper No. 7378.
22
Javdani, M. (2015). Glass ceilings or glass doors? The role of firms in male‐female wage
disparities. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, 48(2), 529-560.
Judge, T. A., Thoresen, C. J., Bono, J. E., Patton, G. K. (2001). The job satisfactionjob
performance relationship: A qualitative and quantitative review. Psychological Bulletin 127(3)
376.
Kingdon, G., Knight, J. (2007). Community, comparisons and subjective well-being in a divided
society. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation 64(1), 6990.
Koys, D. J. (2001). The effects of employee satisfaction, organizational citizenship behavior, and
turnover on organizational effectiveness: A unitlevel, longitudinal study. Personnel Psychology
54(1), 101-114.
Layard, R., (2005a). Happiness: Lessons from a New Science. New York and London: Penguin.
Layard, R., (2005b). Rethinking public economics: The implications of rivalry and habit. In: Bruni,
L., Porta, P.L. (Eds.), Economics and Happiness: Reality and Paradoxes, pp. 147169. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Lockwood, P., & Kunda, Z. (1997). Superstars and me: Predicting the impact of role models on
the self. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 73, 91-103.
Luttmer, E., 2005. Neighbors as negatives: relative earnings and well-being. Quarterly Journal
of Economics 120 (3), 9631002.
Major, B., Testa, M., & Bylsma, W. (1991). Responses to upward and downward social
comparisons: The impact of esteem-relevance and perceived control. In J. Suls & T. A. Wills
(Eds.), Social comparison: Contemporary theory and research (pp. 237-260). Hillsdale, NJ:
Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc
Mangione, T. W., Quinn, R. P. (1975). Job satisfaction, counterproductive behavior, and drug use
at work. Journal of Applied Psychology 60(1), 114.
Manski, C. (2000). Economic analysis of social interactions, Journal of Economic Perspectives
14(3), 11536.
Marx, K. (1849). Wage labour and capital. In: Marx, K., Engel, F. (Eds.), Selected Works, vol. 1.
Progress Publishers, Moscow.
McBride, M. (2001). Relative-income effects on subjective well-being in the cross-section.
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 45, 251-278.
McEvoy, G. M., Cascio, W. F. (1985). Strategies for reducing employee turnover: A meta-
analysis. Journal of Applied Psychology 70(2), 342.
McPherson, M., Smith-Lovin, L., & Cook, J. M. (2001). Birds of a feather: Homophily in social
networks. Annual Review of Sociology 27, 415-444.
Miceli, Maria, and Cristiano Castelfranchi. 2007. “The Envious Mind.” Cognition & Emotion
21(3):44979.
Niederle, M., & Vesterlund, L. (2010). Explaining the gender gap in math test scores: The role of
competition. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(2), 129-44.
23
Niederle, M., & Vesterlund, L. (2007). Do women shy away from competition? Do men compete
too much?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 1067-1101.
Nosanchuk, T. A., & Erikson, B. H. (1985). How high is up? Calibrating social comparison in the
real world. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 48, 624-634
Palmore, E. (1969). Predicting longevity: A follow-up controlling for age. The Gerontologist 9(4),
247-250.
Patterson, M., Warr, P., West, M. (2004). Organizational climate and company productivity: the
role of employee affect and employee level, Journal of Occupational and Organizational
Psychology 77(2), 193216.
Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st Century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Pleban, R., & Tesser, A. (1981). The effects of relevance and quality of another’s performance on
interpersonal closeness. Social Psychology Quarterly 44, 278-285.
Pritchard, R. D. (1969). Equity theory: A review and critique. Organizational Behavior and
Human Performance 4, 176-211.
Ramirez, A. J., Graham, J., Richards, M. A., Gregory, W. M., Cull, A. (1996). Mental health of
hospital consultants: the effects of stress and satisfaction at work. The Lancet 347(9003), 724-
728.
Runciman, W.G. (1966). Relative Deprivation and Social Justice. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Salancik, G. R., & Pfeffer, J. (1978). A social information processing approach to job attitudes and
task design. Administrative science quarterly 224-253.
Sales, S. M., House, J. (1971). Job dissatisfaction as a possible risk factor in coronary heart disease.
Journal of Chronic Diseases 23(12), 861-873.
Schaffner, M., & Torgler, B. (2008). Relative Income Position, Reference Groups, and
Performance: The Impact of Closeness.
Senik, C. (2004). When information dominates comparison: A panel data analysis using Russian
subjective data. Journal of Public Economics 88(910), 2099123.
Smith, A. (1880). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Spector, P. E. (1985). Measurement of human service staff satisfaction: Development of the job
satisfaction survey. American Journal of Community Psychology 13(6), 693-713.
Suls, J. M., & Tesch, F. (1978). Students' preferences for information about their test performance:
A social comparison study. Journal of Applied Social Psychology 8(2), 189-197.
Thornton, D., & Arrowood, A. J. (1966). Self-evaluation, self-enhancement, and the locus of social
comparison. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 2(Suppl. 1), 40-48.
Van Praag, B., Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. (2004). Happiness Quantified: A Satisfaction Calculus
Approach. London: Oxford University Press.
Wall, T. D., Clegg, C. W., Jackson, P. R. (1978). An evaluation of the job characteristics model.
Journal of Occupational Psychology 51(2), 183-196.
24
Ward, M.E., Sloane, P.J. (2000). Non-pecuniary advantages versus pecuniary disadvantages; Job
satisfaction among male and female academics in Scottish universities. Scottish Journal of
Political Economy 47, 273-303.
Watson, R., Storey, D., Wynarczyk, P., Keasey, K., Short, H. (1996). The relationship between
job satisfaction and managerial remuneration in small and medium-sized enterprises: An empirical
test of 'comparison income' and 'equity theory' hypotheses. Applied Economics 28, 567-576.
Wheeler, L., Shaver, K. G., Jones, R. A., Goethals, G. R., Cooper, J., Robinson, J. E., ... & Butzine,
K. W. (1969). Factors determining choice of a comparison other. Journal of Experimental Social
Psychology 5(2), 219-232.
Wills, T. A. (1981). Downward comparison principles in social psychology. Psychological
Bulletin 90, 245-271.
Wood, J. V. (1989). Theory and research concerning social comparisons of personal attributes.
Psychological Bulletin 106, 231-248.
Yee, R. W., Yeung, A. C., Cheng, T. E. (2008). The impact of employee satisfaction on quality
and profitability in high-contact service industries. Journal of Operations Management 26(5), 651-
668.
25
Tables
Table 1: Summary statistics, WES data
Variable
Average
or %
Variable
Number of (worker) observations
~75,000
Years of full time work experience (average)
Hourly wage (average)
(standard deviation)
$21.33
Job Characteristics:
(standard deviation)
(12.9)
% full time
Job satisfaction (average score)
3.24
% member of union or covered by CBA
(standard deviation)
(0.66)
Tenure with current employer (average), years
% very satisfied (4)
34.7
Times promoted at current employer (average)
% satisfied (3)
56.5
Language most often spoken at work
% dissatisfied (2)
7.0
% French
% very dissatisfied (1)
1.9
% English*
Pay satisfaction (average score)
2.92
% Other
(standard deviation)
(0.73)
% Home and work language not the same
% very satisfied (4)
19.2
Occupations (coarse categories)
% satisfied (3)
57.7
% Manager
% dissatisfied (2)
19.3
% Professional
% very dissatisfied (1)
3.8
% Technical/trades
Personal characteristics:
% Marketing/sales
% White Canadian-born*
77.2
% Clerical/administrative
% Visible minority Canadian-born
1.6
% Production worker*
% White immigrant
10.8
Firm characteristics
% Visible minority immigrant
8.7
Number of firms
% Aboriginal
1.7
Industry
% Male
48.2
% Resource
Age (average)
42.1
% Labor intensive tertiary manufacturing
% age 25-29*
11.3
% Secondary product manufacturing
% age 30-34
13.8
% Capital intensive tertiary manufacturing
% age 35-39
16.4
% Construction
% age 40-44
17.6
% Transportation, warehousing, wholesale
% age 45-49
16.1
% Communication and other utilities
% age 50-54
12.8
% Retail trade and consumer services
% age 55-59
8.5
% Finance and insurance
% age 60-65
3.5
% Real estate, rental and leasing operations
Highest educational attainment
% Business services
% Ph.D., Master's, or M.D
4.8
% Education and health services
% Other graduate degree
2.3
% Information and cultural industries
% Bachelor's degree
14.4
% Primary product manufacturing*
% Some university
8.2
% with pay equity policy
% Completed college
21.2
% with employment equity policy
% Some college or trade certificate
22.9
% non-profit
% High school diploma
16.4
Average quit rate, %
% Less than high school*
9.8
% full time employees
Marital status
% with incentive schemes
% Married
60.5
% with innovative work practices
% Common law
13.8
% with good/fair labour relations
% Separated
2.9
Log training expenditures per worker
% Divorced
5.8
Firm size (4 categories)
% Widowed
1.0
% [less than 20 workers]*
% Single*
16.0
% [between 20 and 99 workers]
Language most often spoken at home
% [between 100 and 499 workers]
% French
22.4
% [more than 500 workers]
26
Notes: * indicates the reference category for regressions. All means are computed using sample weights provided in the data. Statistics Canada
does not permit reporting these means without using the weights. Firm-level variables are averaged over workers and not over firms (e.g.
“% non -profit” is the % of wo rkers that are working in non -profit firms, not the % of firms that are non-profit).
% English*
69.0
Degree of competition (4 categories)
% Other
8.6
% [zero]
Number of dependent children
% [1 to 5 firms]
% Zero*
48.5
% [6 to 20 firms]
% One
18.1
% [more than 20 firms]*
% Two
24.2
% Three
7.3
% Four or more
1.9
27
Table 2: Effect of own and coworker wages on worker satisfaction, WES data
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.199***
(0.012)
0.200***
(0.014)
0.181***
(0.016)
0.184***
(0.016)
0.194***
(0.016)
0.184***
(0.017)
0.168***
(0.018)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
-0.003
(0.016)
0.025
(0.016)
0.031*
(0.016)
0.029*
(0.016)
0.037**
(0.017)
0.012
(0.016)
-0.013
(0.024)
Average coworker job satisfaction
0.131***
(0.015)
R2- (total)
0.022
0.046
0.049
0.057
0.062
0.064
0.123
R2- (within)
0.037
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.293***
(0.014)
0.335***
(0.017)
0.356***
(0.019)
0.368***
(0.020)
0.373***
(0.020)
0.368***
(0.020)
0.329***
(0.021)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.025
(0.019)
0.060***
(0.019)
0.074***
(0.019)
0.070***
(0.019)
0.084***
(0.020)
0.040**
(0.020)
0.046*
(0.026)
Average coworker job satisfaction
0.143***
(0.015)
R2- (total)
0.044
0.062
0.067
0.075
0.082
0.083
0.163
R2- (within)
0.043
Controlling for:
Personal and job characteristics
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Coarse occupations
No
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
Detailed occupations
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Observed firm-level characteristics
No
No
No
No
Yes
No
No
Establishment fixed effects
No
No
No
No
No
No
Yes
Number of observations
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. All specifications include year fixed
effects. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are robust to clustering at the firm level. Significance levels: ***
< 1%, ** < 5%, * < 10%.
28
Table 3: Alternative reference groups
Co-workers,
column (7)
from Table 2
Co-workers in same
occupation
All workers in same occupation and
industry
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.168***
(0.018)
0.174***
(0.020)
0.167***
(0.018)
0.168***
(0.018)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
-0.013
(0.024)
-0.013
(0.024)
Ln(Average wage of coworkers in same coarse
occupational category)
0.004
(0.022)
Ln(Avg wage of workers in same detailed
occupational category and industry)
0.088*
(0.051)
0.087*
(0.051)
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.329***
(0.021)
0.332***
(0.024)
0.328***
(0.021)
0.322***
(0.021)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.046*
(0.026)
0.048*
(0.025)
Ln(Average wage of coworkers in same coarse
occupational category)
0.049**
(0.023)
Ln(Avg wage of workers in same detailed
occupational category and industry)
0.030
(0.050)
0.032
(0.050)
Number of observations
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. Regressions include controls for personal and job
characteristics, detailed occupation, and establishment and year fixed effects as in specification (7) of Table 2. Standard errors are reported in
parentheses and are robust to clustering at the firm level. Significance levels: *** < 1%, ** < 5%, * < 10%.
29
Table 4: Alternative measures of coworker wages, WES data
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.168***
(0.018)
0.163***
(0.019)
0.162***
(0.019)
0.152***
(0.030)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
-0.013
(0.024)
-0.012
(0.024)
proportion of coworkers in higher earnings categories
-0.022
(0.023)
-0.023
(0.024)
(Ln(ACW) Ln(OW)) * I(OW <= ACW)
-0.002
(0.031)
(Ln(ACW) Ln(OW)) * I(OW > ACW)
-0.029
(0.032)
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.414***
(0.020)
0.346***
(0.024)
0.352***
(0.024)
0.369***
(0.033)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.046*
(0.026)
0.047*
(0.026)
proportion of coworkers in higher earnings categories
0.061***
(0.026)
0.061**
(0.027)
(Ln(ACW) Ln(OW)) * I(OW <= ACW)
0.069***
(0.033)
(Ln(ACW) Ln(OW)) * I(OW > ACW)
0.015
(0.037)
Number of observations
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. Regressions include controls for personal and job
characteristics, detailed occupation, and establishment and year fixed effects as in specification (7) of Table 2. Standard errors are reported in
parentheses and are robust to clustering at the firm level. Significance levels: *** < 1%, ** < 5%, * < 10%.
30
Table 5a: Heterogeneity in effect of own and coworker wages on worker satisfaction, WES data
Preferred
specification,
column (7)
from Table 2
Workers
younger
than 45
Workers
older
than 45
Difference
Firms
with
pay equity
Firms
without
pay equity
Difference
(1)
(2)
(3)
(2)-(3)
(4)
(5)
(4)-(5)
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.168***
(0.018)
0.169***
(0.024)
0.180***
(0.022)
-0.011
(0.031)
0.135***
(0.033)
0.177***
(0.019)
-0.042
(0.036)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.013
(0.024)
0.001
(0.027)
-0.031
(0.029)
0.032
(0.030)
0.001
(0.047)
0.018
(0.024)
-0.017
(0.043)
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.329***
(0.021)
0.324***
(0.026)
0.345***
(0.027)
-0.021
(0.033)
0.322***
(0.039)
0.330***
(0.023)
-0.008
(0.039)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.046*
(0.026)
0.066**
(0.029)
0.015
(0.032)
0.051
(0.032)
0.073
(0.047)
0.041
(0.026)
0.032
(0.045)
Number of observations
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. Regressions include controls for personal and job
characteristics, detailed occupation, and establishment and year fixed effects as in specification (7) of Table 2. Standard errors are reported in parentheses
and are robust to clustering at the firm level. Significance levels: *** < 1%, ** < 5%, * < 10%.
Table 5b: Heterogeneity in effect of own and coworker wages on worker satisfaction, WES data
Union
Non-Union
Difference
Attriters
(Workers
that show up
in year t but
not t+1)
Workers
with a
destroyed
match in t+1
Workers
whose
match
survived in
year t+1
P-value (all
equal)
Male
workers
Female
workers
P-Value (11)
= (12)
(6)
(7)
(6)-(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
(8)=(9)=(10)
(11)
(12)
(11)-(12)
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.162***
(0.032)
0.173***
(0.020)
-0.011
(0.037)
0.104***
(0.040)
0.112***
(0.063)
0.192***
(0.025)
0.115
0.158***
(0.021)
0.178***
(0.022)
0.414
Ln(Average coworker wage)
-0.033
(0.052)
-0.013
(0.024)
-0.020
(0.050)
-0.083*
(0.048)
0.105*
(0.060)
-0.039
(0.032)
0.032**
0.00628
(0.029)
-0.0336
(0.028)
0.219
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.362***
(0.039)
0.319***
(0.024)
0.043
(0.044)
0.218***
(0.046)
0.344***
(0.068)
0.372***
(0.029)
0.014**
0.274***
(0.024)
0.394***
(0.027)
0.000***
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.044
(0.047)
0.044
(0.027)
0.000
(0.043)
-0.001
(0.051)
0.130*
(0.069)
0.075**
(0.034)
0.214
0.062**
(0.028)
0.029
(0.033)
0.357
Number of observations
~75,000
~50,000
~75,000
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. Regressions include controls for personal and job characteristics, detailed occupation, and establishment
and year fixed effects as in specification (7) of Table 2. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are robust to clustering at the firm level. Significance levels: *** < 1%, ** < 5%, *
< 10%.
Table 5c: Heterogeneity in effect of own and coworker wages on worker satisfaction, WES
data
Canadian-born,
white
Canadian-born,
visible minority
Immigrant,
white
Immigrant,
visible minority
P-value (all equal)
(11)
(12)
(13)
(14)
(11)=(12)=(13)=(14)
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.152***
(0.020)
0.229**
(0.098)
0.189***
(0.044)
0.224***
(0.055)
0.476
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.003
(0.023)
-0.137
(0.097)
-0.072
(0.049)
-0.063
(0.050)
0.162
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.337***
(0.023)
0.508***
(0.100)
0.260***
(0.044)
0.279***
(0.071)
0.084*
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.060**
(0.026)
-0.376***
(0.101)
0.016
(0.049)
-0.021
(0.060)
< 0.001***
Number of observations
~75,000
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. Regressions include controls for personal and job
characteristics, detailed occupation, and establishment and year fixed effects as in specification (7) of Table 2. Standard errors are reported in
parentheses and are robust to clustering at the firm level. Significance levels: * ** < 1%, ** < 5%, * < 10%.
1
Appendix
Appendix Table A1: Coefficients for workplace and job characteristics (based on
specification (5) in Table 2, WES data
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
(1)
(2)
Full-time
0.002
-0.012
Union/CBA coverage
-0.037**
0.042**
Tenure, years
-0.004**
-0.003
(Tenure)2
0.006
0.002
# times promoted
0.017***
0.006
Work language French
0.048
0.003
Work language other
0.014
0.003
Home language different from work language
0.001
-0.048
Industry
Resource
-0.003
0.031
Labor intensive tertiary manufacturing
-0.083***
-0.062**
Secondary product manufacturing
-0.056**
-0.043
Capital intensive tertiary manufacturing
-0.032
-0.044
Construction
0.007
-0.015
Transportation, warehousing, wholesale
-0.002
-0.034
Communication and other utilities
0.013
-0.025
Retail trade and consumer services
0.047
-0.001
Finance and insurance
-0.000
-0.095**
Real estate, rental and leasing operations
-0.052
-0.110***
Business services
-0.026
-0.078**
Education and health services
0.026
-0.077
Information and cultural industries
-0.014
-0.083**
Primary product manufacturing*
(excluded)
(excluded)
Employment equity policy
-0.002
-0.02
Non-profit
0.017
-0.047
Average quit rate, %
-0.225***
-0.201***
% full time employees
-0.044
-0.066**
Incentive scheme
0.012
-0.009
Innovative work practices
0.027**
0.027*
Good/fair labour relations
-0.021
-0.048***
Index of non-wage benefits (z-score)
-0.012
0.001
Log training expenditures per worker
-0.002
0.002
Firm size
[less than 20 workers]*
(excluded)
(excluded)
[between 20 and 99 workers]
-0.0487***
-0.112***
[between 100 and 499 workers]
-0.0536***
-0.086***
[more than 500 workers]
-0.039*
-0.057**
Degree of competition
[zero firms]
-0.007
0.020
[1 to 5 firms]
0.000
0.011
[6 to 20 firms]
-0.012
0.015
[more than 20 firms]*
(excluded)
(excluded)
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. Regressions include controls for
personal and job characteristics, detailed occupation, and year fixed effects as in specification (5) of Table 2. Standard errors are
not reported in the interest of space. Significance levels: *** < 1%, ** < 5%, * < 10%.
2
Appendix Table A2: Alternative reference groups by age
Co-workers,
column (7)
from Table 2
Co-workers
by age
category
Co-workers by
age category and
heterogenous
effect by worker
age
(1)
(2)
(3)
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.168***
(0.018)
0.165***
(0.022)
0.164***
(0.022)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
-0.013
(0.024)
Ln(Average wage of coworkers younger than 45)
0.014
(0.028)
Ln(Avg wage of coworkers older than 45)
0.028
(0.022)
Ln(Average wage of coworkers younger than 45)*I(worker younger than 45)
0.003
(0.0294)
Ln(Average wage of coworkers younger than 45)* I(worker older than 45)
0.031
(0.027)
Ln(Avg wage of coworkers older than 45)*I(worker younger than 45)
0.033
(0.037)
Ln(Avg wage of coworkers older than 45)*I(worker older than 45)
0.025
(0.026)
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.329***
(0.021)
0.336***
(0.026)
0.336***
(0.026)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.046*
(0.026)
Ln(Average wage of coworkers younger than 45)
0.040
(0.028)
Ln(Avg wage of coworkers older than 45)
0.029
(0.026)
Ln(Average wage of coworkers younger than 45)*I(worker younger than 45)
0.032
(0.031)
Ln(Average wage of coworkers younger than 45)* I(worker older than 45)
0.040
(0.030)
Ln(Avg wage of coworkers older than 45)*I(worker younger than 45)
0.053
(0.035)
Ln(Avg wage of coworkers older than 45)*I(worker older than 45)
0.017
(0.031)
Number of observations
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. Regressions include controls for personal
and job characteristics, detailed occupation, and establishment and year fixed effects as in specification (7) of Table 2. Using firm
characteristics instead of firm fixed effects also produces similar results. These results are available upon request. Standard errors are
reported in parentheses and are robust to clustering at the firm level. Significance levels: *** < 1%, ** < 5%, * < 10%.
3
Appendix Table A3: Alternative measures of co-worker wages
Co-workers,
column (7)
from Table 2
Median wage
within
establishment
7th percentile of
wage within
establishment
Median & 75th
percentile of
wage within
establishment
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Dependent variable: job satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.168***
(0.018)
0.166***
(0.019)
0.174***
(0.019)
0.169***
(0.020)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
-0.013
(0.024)
Ln(Median wage within establishment)
0.024
(0.032)
0.065
(0.044)
Ln(75th percentile of wage within establishment )
-0.018
(0.025)
-0.050
(0.034)
Dependent variable: pay satisfaction
Ln(Own wage)
0.329***
(0.021)
0.307***
(0.022)
0.314***
(0.022)
0.308***
(0.022)
Ln(Average coworker wage)
0.046*
(0.026)
Ln(Median wage within establishment)
0.085**
(0.035)
0.137***
(0.036)
Ln(75th percentile of wage within establishment )
0.038
(0.026)
0.015
(0.029)
Number of observations
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
~75,000
Notes: All regression coefficients are estimated using sample weights provided in the data. Regressions include controls
for personal and job characteristics, detailed occupation, and establishment and year fixed effects as in specification (7) of
Table 2. Using firm characteristics instead of firm fixed effects also produces similar results. These results are available upon
request. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are robust to clustering at the firm level. Significance levels:
*** < 1%, ** < 5%, * < 10%.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
When workers' efforts are not contractible, we investigate whether the display of workers' efforts to coworkers influences wage and effort decisions. We find that employers mainly increase the wages offered to the more valuable workers when they are observed that increases the difference in wages in such setting. We find evidence of peer pressure and strategic complementarity in efforts. Additionally, low-ability workers are more sensitive to peer pressure than their more productive coworkers, and these workers exert less effort with increases in the reciprocity of their coworkers. Finally, the display of workers' efforts to coworkers is detrimental to the employer's payoff but enhances efficiency.