Conference PaperPDF Available

MEDEAS-World: a new IAM framework integrating biophysical and socioeconomic constraints

Authors:

Figures

Content may be subject to copyright.
MEDEAS-World: a new IAM framework integrating biophysical and socioeconomic constraints
Iñigo Capellán-Pérez1*, Ignacio de Blas1, Jaime Nieto1, Carlos De Castro1, Luis Javier Miguel1,
Margarita Mediavilla1, Óscar Carpintero1, Luis Fernando Lobejón1, Noelia Ferreras-Alonso2, Paula
Rodrigo1, Fernando Frechoso1, David Álvarez Antelo1, Pedro L. Lomas1, Gonzalo Parrado Hernando1.
1Group of Energy, Economy and System Dynamics of the University of Valladolid (Spain)
2CARTIF Foundation, Parque Tecnológico de Boecillo, Boecillo 47151, Spain
*Corresponding author: inigo.capellan@uva.es.
Summary
Here MEDEAS-World is introduced, a new global energy-economy-environment model which is
being specifically developed to include feedbacks between subsystems and plausible alternative
assumptions which are not usually considered in IAMs. Particularly, MEDEAS-W considers: (1) input-
output economic analysis within a system dynamics structure; (2) geological supply constraints
determine non-renewable energies availability; (3) the techno-sustainable potential or renewables;
(4) potential mineral scarcity; (5) the energy return on energy invested (EROI) of the full energy
system and its feedback; and (6) climate change impacts consistent with natural scientists’
assessments. Experimental results confirm that current trends are deeply unsustainable, while a
simulation implementing Green Growth policies indicates that this paradigm may have serious
drawbacks which are not detected in models characterized by a sequential structure and considering
standard assumptions in relation to the aforementioned points.
Extended abstract
Introduction & Methodology
Dozens, if not hundreds, Integrated Assessment Models (IAMs) have been developed in the last
decades since the pioneer World3 was developed in the early 1970s (Meadows et al., 1972). Despite
great advances performed in the field over the years, most IAMs (and especially those more policy-
influential), share a core set of common assumptions whose validity is being disputed in the
scientific discussion. First, IAMs are generally characterized by a rather sequential structure with
limited feedbacks among the represented subsystems. The discrepancy between natural scientists’
understanding of ecological feedbacks and the representations of environmental damage (if any)
found in IAMs is especially relevant for the case of climate change impacts, critically affecting policy-
advice (Cumming et al., 2005; Diaz and Moore, 2017; Lenton and Ciscar, 2013; Stern, 2013). Second,
a lack of plurality in the methods to represent the economic dimension has been detected in the
literature, dominated by conventional economic equilibrium and optimization approaches, with
important limitations to capture socioeconomic system dynamics and the role of macroeconomic
policies for sustainability governance (Hardt and O’Neill, 2017; Scrieciu et al., 2013). Third, fossil fuel
resource abundance, understood as the vast geological availability accessible at an affordable price,
is a default assumption in most of the prominent integrated assessment models (IAMs) used for
climate policy analysis; hence, future energy transitions are thus largely modelled as demand-driven
transformations (Capellán-Pérez et al., 2016; Höök and Tang, 2013). Fourth, it is usually assumed
that the resource base of renewable energy sources (RES) provides no practical limitation if
adequate investments are forthcoming, which is disputed by a branch of literature (de Castro et al.,
2014, 2013, 2011; Miller and Kleidon, 2016; Moriarty and Honnery, 2016). Finally, fifth, most models
adopt a gross energy approach disregarding the implications that the future evolution of the Energy
Return on Energy Investment (EROI) may have for the system (Carbajales-Dale et al., 2014).
Here we present the global version of the MEDEAS framework (EU and country-level models are in-
development), which is been designed with the aim to tackle the aforementioned limitations in the
current state-of-the art of IAMs. MEDEAS-World (MEDEAS-W) is a global, one-region, simulation
model which has been designed applying System Dynamics,1 which facilitates the integration of
knowledge from different perspectives and disciplines as well as the feedbacks from different
subsystems. The model typically runs from 1995 to 2050 (although the simulation horizon may be
extended to 2100 if necessary, e.g. when focusing on climate change issues). MEDEAS-W is
structured into seven main submodules: Economy, Energy, Infrastructures, Materials, Land Use,
Social and Environmental Impacts Indicators and Climate Change (see Figure 1). The main variables
that connect the different modules are represented by arrows.
Figure 1: MEDEAS-World model schematic overview. Source: (Capellán-Pérez et al., 2017).
The main characteristics of each module are:
Economy and population: the global economy in MEDEAS is modelled following a post-
Keynesian approach assuming non-clearing markets (i.e. not forcing general equilibrium) and
demand-led growth, combined with supply-side constraints such as energy availability. The
economic structure is captured by the adaptation and dynamic integration of global WIOD
1 Developed in Vensim DSS software for Windows Version 6.4E (x32). Also available in Python open-source
code (http://www.medeas.eu/).
Energy consumption
required
Economy (IOT)
&
Population
Energy
(NR & RES
availability)
Climate
model Materials
CO2 emissions
Energy supply
availability
Energy
consumption
CC damage function
Land-use change
CO2 emissions
Requi red mate rials
for energy systems
Mater ial consumption
Energy for material
consumpti on
Land use
Social &
Environmental
impacts
indicators
Energy
infrastructures
CC impacts
Future demand
input-output tables resulting in 35 industries and 4 institutional sectors (Dietzenbacher et
al., 2013). Final energy intensities by sector are obtained combining information from WIOD
environmental accounts (Genty, 2012) and the IEA Balances (2018). Population evolves
exogenously as defined by the user. See (Nieto et al., 2018) for more details on this
submodule.
Energy: this module includes the renewable and non-renewable energy resources potentials
and availability taking into account biophysical and temporal constraints. In particular, the
availability of non-renewable energy resources depends on both stock and flow constraints
(Campbell and Laherrère, 1998; Kerschner and Capellán-Pérez, 2017; Mohr et al., 2015).
Comprehensive analysis of the techno-sustainable potential of RES for electricity and heat
(de Castro et al., 2014, 2013, 2011; Moriarty and Honnery, 2016). In total, 34 primary energy
sources and 5 final fuels are considered (electricity, heat, solids, gases and liquids), with
large technological disaggregation. The intermittency of RES is considered in the framework,
computing endogenous levels of overcapacities, storage and overgrids depending on the
penetration of variables RES technologies. A net energy approach accounting for the Energy
return on energy invested (EROI) of individual technologies as well as for the whole system is
applied (which is in turn feed-backed to the Economy module). Transportation is modelled in
high detail, differentiating between different types of vehicles for households, as well as
freight and passenger inland transport).
Energy infrastructures represent power plants to generate electricity and heat.
Climate: this module projects the climate change levels due to the greenhouse gas emissions
generated by human societies (non-CO2 emissions are exogenously set taking as reference
the Representative Concentration Pathways scenarios (van Vuuren et al., 2011)). The carbon
and climate cycle is adapted from C-ROADS (Fiddaman et al., 2016; Sterman et al., 2012).
This module includes a climate damage function consistent with natural scientists’
assessments which dynamically affects sectors’ economic output depending on the level of
global temperature change.
Materials: materials are required by the economy with emphasis on those required for the
construction and O&M of alternative energy technologies (De Castro et al., 2018). Option of
recycling policies available. Estimation of the potential mineral scarcity,
Land-use: this module currently mainly accounts for the land requirements of the RES
energies.
Social and environmental impacts: this module translates the “biophysical” results of the
simulations into metrics related with social and environmental impacts. The objective of this
module is to contextualize the implications for human societies in terms of well-being for
each simulation.
(For a detailed documentation of the MEDEAS-World model, see (Capellán-Pérez et al., 2017)).
Experimental results
Despite MEDEAS-W is still in development, it is already possible to produce experimental results.
Two scenarios are simulated in MEDEAS global model to 2050 in order to illustrate the importance of
considering all the aforementioned factors in the planning of the transition towards a low carbon
economy: (1) Business-as-usual (BAU, continuation of current trends) and (2) “Green Growth” (GG,
higher economic growth, faster transition to RES, higher efficiency improvements, etc.).
BAU scenario outputs indicate that, if current trends continue, economic growth will not be able to
be maintained globally in the next decades due to the interaction of dangerous climate change and
energy scarcities. The policy targets applied in the GG scenario allow for a lower temperature
increase by the mid-century (+1.7ªC); however, this is at the cost of a fall in the EROI of the energy
system (<4:1): the fast transition to RES in the GG scenario implies a re-materialization of the
economy. Moreover, the economic demand driven by the levels of desired GDPpc cannot be
satisfied over the studied period due to the inability of RES, efficiency improvements and alternative
technologies to reach a substitution rate to compensate the decline in fossil fuel availability. As a
result, the GDPpc is in a downward trend by the end of the studied period also in this scenario. The
obtained results indicate that the GG paradigm, often promoted by institutions as the way to going
forward to achieve a sustainable energy transition, may have serious drawbacks when considering
feedbacks and plausible alternative assumptions which are not considered in most models of the
literature.
As any model, MEDEAS-W is subject to a number of limitations which are planned to be addressed in
future work. Among them, we highlight the following: full dynamization of the IO matrixes and
allocation of energy scarcities, consideration of inequalities within and between countries, the
extension of the net energy approach to all energy technologies and resources and the inclusion of a
full land-use submodule.
References
Campbell, C.J., Laherrère, J., 1998. The end of cheap oil. Sci. Am. 278, 6065.
Capellán-Pérez, I., Arto, I., Polanco-Martínez, J.M., González-Eguino, M., Neumann, M.B., 2016.
Likelihood of climate change pathways under uncertainty on fossil fuel resource availability.
Energy Environ. Sci. 9, 24822496. https://doi.org/10.1039/C6EE01008C
Capellán-Pérez, I., de Blas, I., Nieto, J., De Castro, C., Miguel, L.J., Mediavilla, M., Carpintero, Ó.,
Rodrigo, P., Frechoso, F., Cáceres, S., 2017. MEDEAS Model and IOA implementation at
global geographical level (Deliverable MEDEAS project, http://www.medeas.eu/deliverables
No. D4.1). GEEDS, University of Valladolid.
Carbajales-Dale, M., Barnhart, C.J., Brandt, A.R., Benson, S.M., 2014. A better currency for investing
in a sustainable future. Nat. Clim. Change 4, 524527. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2285
Cumming, G.S., Alcamo, J., Sala, O., Swart, R., Bennett, E.M., Zurek, M., 2005. Are Existing Global
Scenarios Consistent with Ecological Feedbacks? Ecosystems 8, 143152.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10021-004-0075-1
De Castro, C., Capellán-Pérez, I., Miguel, L.J., 2018. Revised standard EROI of alternative technologies
for the energy transition. Under Review.
de Castro, C., Carpintero, Ó., Frechoso, F., Mediavilla, M., de Miguel, L.J., 2014. A top-down
approach to assess physical and ecological limits of biofuels. Energy 64, 506512.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2013.10.049
de Castro, C., Mediavilla, M., Miguel, L.J., Frechoso, F., 2013. Global solar electric potential: A review
of their technical and sustainable limits. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 28, 824835.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2013.08.040
de Castro, C., Mediavilla, M., Miguel, L.J., Frechoso, F., 2011. Global wind power potential: Physical
and technological limits. Energy Policy 39, 66776682.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2011.06.027
Diaz, D., Moore, F., 2017. Quantifying the economic risks of climate change | Nature Climate Change.
Dietzenbacher, E., Los, B., Stehrer, R., Timmer, M., Vries, G. de, 2013. The Construction of World
InputOutput Tables in the Wiod Project. Econ. Syst. Res. 25, 71–98.
https://doi.org/10.1080/09535314.2012.761180
Fiddaman, T., Siegel, L.S., Sawin, E., Jones, A.P., Sterman, J., 2016. C-ROADS simulator reference
guide (No. v74).
Genty, A., 2012. Final database of environmental satellite accounts: technical report on their
compilation. WIOD Deliverable 4.6, Documentation.
Hardt, L., O’Neill, D.W., 2017. Ecological Macroeconomic Models: Assessing Current Developments.
Ecol. Econ. 134, 198211. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.12.027
Höök, M., Tang, X., 2013. Depletion of fossil fuels and anthropogenic climate changeA review.
Energy Policy 52, 797809. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.10.046
IEA, 2018. IEA World Energy Statistics and Balances, World Energy Statistics and Balances (database).
IEA/OECD, Paris (France).
Kerschner, C., Capellán-Pérez, I., 2017. Peak-Oil and Ecological Economics, in: Spash, C.L. (Ed.),
Routdlege Handbook of Ecological Economics: Nature and Society. Abingdon, pp. 425435.
Lenton, T.M., Ciscar, J.-C., 2013. Integrating tipping points into climate impact assessments. Clim.
Change 117, 585597. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-012-0572-8
Meadows, D.H., Meadows, D.L., Randers, J., Behrens III, W.W., 1972. The Limits to Growth. Universe
Books.
Miller, L.M., Kleidon, A., 2016. Wind speed reductions by large-scale wind turbine deployments
lower turbine efficiencies and set low generation limits. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 201602253.
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1602253113
Mohr, S.H., Wang, J., Ellem, G., Ward, J., Giurco, D., 2015. Projection of world fossil fuels by country.
Fuel 141, 120135. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fuel.2014.10.030
Moriarty, P., Honnery, D., 2016. Can renewable energy power the future? Energy Policy 93, 37.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2016.02.051
Nieto, J., Carpintero, Ó., Miguel, L.J., de Blas, I., 2018. Is it worth more growth? Macro-economic
modelling under energy constraints. Under Review.
Scrieciu, S., Rezai, A., Mechler, R., 2013. On the economic foundations of green growth discourses:
the case of climate change mitigation and macroeconomic dynamics in economic modeling.
Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Energy Environ. 2, 251268. https://doi.org/10.1002/wene.57
Sterman, J., Fiddaman, T., Franck, T., Jones, A., McCauley, S., Rice, P., Sawin, E., Siegel, L., 2012.
Climate interactive: the C-ROADS climate policy model. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 28, 295305.
https://doi.org/10.1002/sdr.1474
Stern, N., 2013. The Structure of Economic Modeling of the Potential Impacts of Climate Change:
Grafting Gross Underestimation of Risk onto Already Narrow Science Models. J. Econ. Lit. 51,
838859. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.51.3.838
van Vuuren, D.P., Edmonds, J.A., Kainuma, M., Riahi, K., Weyant, J., 2011. A special issue on the
RCPs. Clim. Change 109, 14. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-011-0157-y
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
Our society faces a dilemma. While continued economic growth is ecologically unsustainable, low or negative rates of economic growth are accompanied by adverse social impacts. Hence there is a need for macroeconomic tools that can help identify socially sustainable post-growth pathways. The emerging field of ecological macroeconomics aims to address this need and features a number of new macroeconomic modelling approaches. This article provides (1) a review of modelling developments in ecological macroeconomics, based on the literature and interviews with researchers, and (2) an analysis of how the different models incorporate policy themes from the post-growth literature. Twenty-two ecological macroeconomic models were analysed and compared to eight policy themes. It was found that environmental interactions and the monetary system were treated most comprehensively. Themes of income inequality, work patterns, indicators of well-being, and disaggregated production were addressed with less detail, while alternative business models and cross-scale interactions were hardly addressed. Overall, the combination of input-output analysis with stock-flow consistent modelling was identified as a promising avenue for developing macroeconomic models for a post-growth economy. However, due to the wide interpretation of what “the economy” entails, future research will benefit from employing a range of approaches.
Article
Full-text available
Significance Understanding the limits of electricity generation from winds is a requirement for planning a renewable energy future. A difficulty in estimating such limits is that wind turbines remove kinetic energy from the atmosphere, so that many turbines should reduce wind speeds, ultimately setting a limit to how much kinetic energy can be taken out of the atmosphere. We show that this slowdown effect can be accounted for by detailed climate model simulations and a relatively simple method that does not directly simulate atmospheric dynamics. This slowdown effect is critical to consider, as it makes each turbine less productive and shows that few land areas can yield more than 1.0 W e m ⁻² of electricity at large scales.
Article
Full-text available
Uncertainties concerning fossil fuel resources availability have traditionally been deemphasized in climate change research as global baseline emission scenarios (i.e., scenarios that do not consider additional climate policies) have been built on the assumption of abundant fossil fuel resources for the 21st century. However, current estimates are subject to critical uncertainties and an emerging body of literature is providing revised estimates. Here we consider the entire range of revised estimates, applying an integrated assessment model to perform a likelihood analysis of climate change pathways. Our results show that, by the end of the century, the two highest emissions pathways from the IPCC, the Representative Concentration Pathways RCP6 and RCP8.5, where the baseline scenarios currently lie, have probabilities of being surpassed of 42% and 12% respectively. In terms of temperature change, the probability of exceeding the 2°C level by 2100 remains very high (88%), confirming the need for urgent climate action. Coal resource uncertainty determines the uncertainty about the emission and radiative forcing pathways due to the poor quality of data. We also find that the depletion of fossil fuels is likely to occur during the second half of the century accelerating the transition to renewable energy sources in baseline scenarios. Accordingly, more investments would be needed to ensure this transition. In turn, the mitigation efforts would be less than currently estimated. Hence, the integrated analysis of resource availability and climate change is essential to obtain internally consistent climate pathways.
Article
Full-text available
Net energy analysis should be a critical energy policy tool. We identify five critical themes for realizing a low-carbon, sustainable energy future and highlight the key perspective that net energy analysis provides.
Article
Understanding the value of reducing greenhouse-gas emissions matters for policy decisions and climate risk management, but quantification is challenging because of the complex interactions and uncertainties in the Earth and human systems, as well as normative ethical considerations. Current modelling approaches use damage functions to parameterize a simplified relationship between climate variables, such as temperature change, and economic losses. Here we review and synthesize the limitations of these damage functions and describe how incorporating impacts, adaptation and vulnerability research advances and empirical findings could substantially improve damage modelling and the robustness of social cost of carbon values produced. We discuss the opportunities and challenges associated with integrating these research advances into cost–benefit integrated assessment models, with guidance for future work.
Article
Fossil fuels face resource depletion, supply security, and climate change problems; renewable energy (RE) may offer the best prospects for their long-term replacement. However, RE sources differ in many important ways from fossil fuels, particularly in that they are energy flows rather than stocks. The most important RE sources, wind and solar energy, are also intermittent, necessitating major energy storage as these sources increase their share of total energy supply. We show that estimates for the technical potential of RE vary by two orders of magnitude, and argue that values at the lower end of the range must be seriously considered, both because their energy return on energy invested falls, and environmental costs rise, with cumulative output. Finally, most future RE output will be electric, necessitating radical reconfiguration of existing grids to function with intermittent RE.
Article
Scientists describe the scale of the risks from unmanaged climate change as potentially immense. However, the scientific models, because they omit key factors that are hard to capture precisely, appear to substantially underestimate these risks. Many economic models add further gross underassessment of risk because the assumptions built into the economic modeling on growth, damages and risks, come close to assuming directly that the impacts and costs will be modest and close to excluding the possibility of catastrophic outcomes. A new generation of models is needed in all three of climate science, impact and economics with a still stronger focus on lives and livelihoods, including the risks of large-scale migration and conflicts.