ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

Trust is a fundamental precondition underpinning exchange and economic coordination but is costly to maintain. Given the potential for agents to enjoy zero-sum gains by opportunistically betraying the trust of exchanging counterparties, an edifice of occupational roles, organisational forms, and institutional practices have emerged in an effort to uphold trust. In simple terms, there exists a “cost of trust.” This paper provides numerical estimates of the cost of trust for the United States economy, based on an attribution of laborforce occupational data with varying degrees of trust-maintenance. Occupations represented in high cost-of-trust activities include managers, lawyers, and judges, tax professionals, accountants, and auditors. Overall, it is estimated that the cost of trust accounts for 35 percent of U.S. employment in 2010. The cost of trust has significant implications for the economic applicability of blockchain compared with conventional forms of ledger technology largely maintained by centralised third-party organizations.
!
!
The$JBBA$$|$$Volume$1$|$$Issue$2$$|$$2018$
1$
!
Competing In terests:
None declared.
Ethical approval:
Not applicable.
Author’s
contribution:
SD1, MN2 and JP3
designed and coordinated
this research and prepared
the manuscript in entirety.
Funding:
None declared.
Acknowledgements:
None declared.
Peer-R eviewed Research
OPEN ACCESS
ISSN Online: 2516-3957
ISSN Print: 2516-3949
https://doi.org/10.31585/jbba-1-2-(5)2018
The Cost of Trust: A Pilot Study
Sinclair Davidson1 PhD, Mikayla Novak2 PhD, Jason Potts3 PhD
RMIT Blockchain Innovation Hub, School of Economics, Finance and Marketing, RMIT University, Australia
Correspondence:
mikayla.novak@rmit.edu.au
Received: 9 August 2018 Accepted: 23 September 2018 Published: 6 October 2018
Abstract
Trust is a fundamental precondition underpinning exchange and economic coordination but is costly to
maintain. Given the potential for agents to enjoy zero-sum gains by opportunistically betraying the trust of
exchanging counterparties, an edifice of occupational roles, organizational forms and institutional practices have
emerged in an effort to uphold trust. In simple terms, there exists a “cost of trust.” This paper provides
numerical estimates of the cost of trust for the United States economy, based on an attribution of labor force
occupational data with varying degrees of trust-maintenance. Occupations represented in high cost-of-trust
activities include managers, lawyers and judges, tax professionals, accountants and auditors. Overall, it is
estimated that the cost of trust accounts for 35 per cent of U.S. employment in 2010. The cost of trust has
significant implications for the economic applicability of blockchain compared with conventional forms of
ledger technology largely maintained by centralized third-party organizations.
Keywords: blockchain, measurement, opportunism, transaction costs, trust
JEL Classifications: D02, J21, K42, O33, Z13
1. Introduction
Assessments of the economic dimensions of trust
appear to have enjoyed a resurgence of interest in recent
decades. Despite the contribution of trust in promoting
coordination economically, it is conceded trust is an
economically fragile condition potentially degraded by
a temptation to attain zero-sum gains by acting
dishonestly, therefore betraying trust [1]. An
environment conducive to trustful economic relations
thus requires various kinds of commitments, supported
by the allocation of resources, on the part of agents.
This very notion of commitment implies there are costs
incurred to uphold trust amongst heterogeneous agents
in the face of bounded rationality and opportunism [2].
The institutional economics literature has illuminated the
various ways in which economic agents partake in efforts
to enforce trust amongst each other. Contracts may be
structured to encourage parties to act in a trustworthy
manner [3, 4]. Coase [5] alluded to the rationale for the
modern corporation as resting in the desire to avoid
potential mistrust in bilateral market trades. The aim of
this paper is look beyond specific arrangements, as
important as they may be, and consider the broader,
economy-wide costs incurred in efforts to minimize
exchange-related mistrust.
One of the distinctive contributions of this paper is
that we provide preliminary numerical estimates of
the economy-wide “cost of trust” for the United
States. Drawing upon detailed occupational data it is
illustrated that the cost of trust is sizeable, in terms of
the employment share of the economy.
The importance of the cost of trust in modern
economic management is underlined by recent forms
of ledger innovation. The adoption of distributed
ledger technology, maintaining cryptographically-
secure distributed databases on peer-to-peer
computing networks, is held to reduce the cost of
opportunism and, consequently, galvanise trust with
respect to data integrity [6]. It is supposed that one
way that blockchain could reduce the cost of trust is
through the use of smart contracts to substitute for
conventional activities that aim to uphold trust within
labour markets.
2. Trust: Economically valuable, but costly to
maintain
It is a truism to suggest that, as sociable animals,
human beings are dependent on other people, not
only for survival but for the achievement of deeper
senses of flourishing. Although the significance of
!
!
The$JBBA$$|$$Volume$1$|$$Issue$2$$|$$December$2018$
2$
!
trust has long been recognized by researchers, including in the
economics discipline, the definition of trust itself is subject to
considerable ambiguity. For convenience, we draw upon the
Oxford Dictionary definition of trust to describe it as a state or
precondition wherein a person (or persons) has (or have) a belief
in the reliability, truth or ability of someone or something to
undertake or perform a given task or objective (tangible or
intangible). Subsumed within this definition is an appreciation that
trusting relations consist of the qualities of vulnerability, risk and
expectation (or uncertainty) [7].
The first aspect of trust (vulnerability) refers to a given individual’s
ex ante belief that others will at least not betray them, when they
need not be obliged to do so. It is in this context that we suggest
trust is a relational attribute with two generic classes of people
involved: the trustor and trustee. The trustor is the party who
places themselves in a vulnerable situation, whereas the trustee is
the party on whom trust is placed and who has an opportunity to
potentially take advantage of the trustor’s vulnerability [8].
Trust is also supposed to entail risk [1, 9]. As suggested by Oliver
Williamson, “trust is warranted when the expected gain from
placing oneself at risk to another is positive, but not otherwise.
Indeed, the decision to accept such a risk is taken to imply trust”
[9, p. 463]. Of course, it is possible for the trustor to avoid a risky
situation by abstaining from exchange. However, when doing so
one forgoes the associated advantages that go with exchanging with
the trustee, should trust be maintained [10].
Finally, there is the expectation that the trustee will not take
advantage of the opportunities opened up to betray the trustor’s
trust. Trust is warranted when the trustor expects the benefit from
making themselves vulnerable to the trustee (whose behavior is,
ultimately, not amenable to control) to be positive [11]. In the
absence of uncertainty, trust is not a significant issue under a
certain scenario the outcome is the same whether a trusting act was
involved.
In an industrialized market sphere, one may discern generalized
trust as entailing the fulfilment of commitments made in an
exchange process. In a generic sense it is said that, “whenever there
are gains from trade, there is a productivity advantage to any
institution or norm that assures traders that the other side will hold
up their end of the deal” [12, p. 83]. Whilst this statement is
generically correct, the many guises of market activity dictates that
the economic manifestations of trust are equally highly contextual
in nature [13].
Let us consider the conceptual basis for trust as described by
institutional economic theory. Writing in 1937, Ronald Coase
famously asked: if market activities are so efficacious, as is so often
lauded by economists, then why is so much market-oriented
activity practically mediated through organisations such as
centralised, hierarchical firms? His answer is that conducting
exchange transactions within markets is quintessentially costly [5].
There are “transaction costs” incurred in “obtaining relevant
information, the cost of bargaining and making decisions, and
finally the costs of policing and enforcing contracts” [14, p. 180].
For Coase, the firm helps absorb transaction costs enabling
transaction possibilities, and economic coordination, to expand.
Oliver Williamson extended Coase’s insights by theorizing about
when internalization of transaction costs is the preferred strategy
for launching productive economic activity. Williamson [2, 9]
suggests that internalization is necessary under conditions of
bounded rationality, small numbers of trading partners, asset
specificity and, most importantly, the exercise of opportunism in
exchange relations. Opportunism suggests that economic agents
will act strategically, “a condition of self-interest seeking with guile”
[2, p. 30], to the detriment of the economic interest of others. The
potential for incomplete contracting prevailing in economic
situations, including as a result of “hold up” refraining to commit
to contractual terms, also suggests that opportunism is an
important problem to be redressed [15].
Williamson is at pains to stress that not everyone will constantly act
in an opportunistic manner. Nonetheless, institutions are seen as
necessary to enforce trustworthy behavior on the part of those who
are otherwise prepared to exhibit opportunism in economic
exchange. The modern firm, for instance, is not only an
organizational strategy to redress transaction costs but is an
evolved hierarchical structure of contracts aimed at solving the
opportunism problem [16].
At this point it should be recognized that scarce economic
resources are absorbed in the process of upholding the trust which
leads to reductions in transaction costs and dynamic improvements
in economic coordination. In short, there is a cost of trust that
should be duly considered within the broader purview of trust
discourse. The notion of the cost of trust is prevalent in numerous
activities undertaken by economic agents e.g. IT security
spending, costs of record keeping, managerial control and
workplace surveillance, advertising and product branding, and so
on.
In no small part, the cost of trust is influenced by the context in
which trust-building efforts are maintained. Economic exchanges
differ in their complexity and their scope for opportunism. It seems
generally costlier to instigate specialized, trust-galvanizing
mechanisms when exchange occurs only once or infrequently.
Bromiley and Harris indicate that “optimal governance structure
should vary depending on these assessments. Economic actors
should build less costly control systems for relatively trustworthy
people than for less trustworthy people” [17, p. 126].
We concede there is some overlap between the cost of trust and
generic transaction costs associated with market exchange. The
costs borne by individuals to demonstrate they are trustworthy is
but one aspect of total costs in engaging with others economically.
For example, the cost of trust is distinct (though not completely)
from the search costs of obtaining information about goods and
services. From this standpoint the cost of trust can be assumed to
be sub-set of transaction costs, which have been estimated to
account for a sizeable portion of national product [18].
It should be briefly noted there are similarities between our
research and the effort of McCloskey and Klamer [19] to establish
a “cost of persuasion.” Referring to the cultural and sociological
dimensions of trust, Paul Lewis suggests that trust represents an
!
!
The$JBBA$$|$$Volume$1$|$$Issue$2$$|$$December$2018$
3$
!
inter-subjective social reality promulgated through (time-
consuming) discursive activity: “talk (along with other features of
conversations, such as smiling and laughter) is central to the
creation of trust” [20, pp. 189-190]. We concur with these
assessments that persuasion can be trust-building, but that trust
also helps create the social context in which persuasion is used [21].
3. Measuring the trust economy: Cost of trust estimates for
American economy
3.1 Method
In this paper we attempt to provide a preliminary assessment of
the cost of trust for key segments of the United States economy.
This raises the immediate question: on what basis might activity be
delineated on the basis of the cost of trust?
The methodological approach employed in this paper is similar to
that presented in [19]. The 2012 Statistical Abstract of the United
States [22] reported that there were about 139.1 million civilian
non-institutional employees aged 16 years and over in 2010. Table
616 of the Abstract provides information on the number of
employed civilians by the following occupational categories:
management, professional and related; service; sales and office;
natural resources, construction and maintenance; production, and
transportation and material moving. A further employment-by-
occupation breakdown is provided in the Supplemental Material.
We present an aggregate cost of trust by subjectively assigning
weights to occupations. These weights reflect an assessment about
the percentage of time or marginal product in each occupation
spent on maintaining or improving trustful relationships. A weight
of 1.0 indicates that personnel in an occupation given such
weighting spend all their time or effort in upholding trust. Other
weights used in this paper (0.75, 0.50 and 0.25) reflect our
assessment that employees in the relevant occupation use 75 per
cent, 50 per cent or 25 per cent of time or marginal product to
uphold trust, respectively.
Cost of trust weightings are assigned to all occupations. Once
weights are assigned, the employment figures are multiplied by the
weight to give a “cost-of-trust adjusted” employment total for the
U.S. economy. This aggregated total indicates the amount of
employment absorbed by (costly) activity dedicated to upholding
trust in the economy.
Although the assignment of weights to occupational categories are
subjective, they are informed by judgment partly relying upon
sources we consider help gauge the extent to which certain
employees primarily engage in trust-upholding activity:
!It is estimated in [18] that the aggregate size of transaction
costs in the U.S. economy over the period 1870 to 1970 by
demarcating occupations (and industries) into transaction and
non-transaction-intensive classifications. The transaction
cost-intensive occupations include managers, owners and
proprietors; foremen; sales workers; clerical workers;
professional workers; and protective workers. Wallis and
North [18] consider the costs borne by sellers and buyers to
establish market credibility as a transaction cost component.
These costs could also be considered to be part of the cost of
trust.
!In [19] subjective weights were assigned to occupations on the
basis of the perceived proportion of time that laborer in varied
occupations engage in persuasive communication with client
groups. Lawyers, judges, public relations specialists,
managerial supervisors, and salespeople were classified as
belonging to the high-persuasion category. Persuasion is
undertaken for a variety of reasons economically, one of which
is that a party to a potential transaction (usually a seller) wishes
to communicate they are trustworthy as an exchange partner.
!A December 2017 Gallup survey provided information on the
degree to which people in various occupations are rated
“high” or “very high” with regard to honesty and ethics [23].
Amongst the occupations rated as highly or very highly honest
and ethical include nurses, teachers, doctors and police
officers. People in occupations rated honest and highly ethical
are, ceteris paribus, perhaps less likely to endure costs
associated with developing or demonstrating trustworthiness
in economic exchange.
In addition to these sources, we draw upon the recent literature of
occupational task complexity [24, 25] as another background
source of information assisting in the derivation of cost-of-trust
weights. Highly complex occupational roles are perceived to
impose a high cost-of-trust, given the higher probability of
individuals working in such roles to opportunistically betray trust
by taking advantage of informational asymmetries and other
unique features of the working role.
3.2 Results and discussion
The result of the analysis for the U.S. economy in 2010 is presented
in Table 1, showing raw employment-by-occupation subtotals and
cost-of-trust adjusted employment for major occupational
categories. Overall, it is estimated that about 35 per cent of
employment in the United States relates to activity aimed at
upholding trustful economic relationships. The cost of trust ranges
from 48 per cent in management, professional and related
occupations to 13 per cent in natural resources, construction and
maintenance occupations.
Taking a deeper look at the distribution of cost of trust related
activity by sub-category, the cost of trust accounts for more than
50 per cent of time or product in protective service, health care,
business and financial operations and management occupations. At
the other end of the spectrum, it is estimated less than 20 per cent
activities undertaken by those in occupations related to farming,
fishing and forestry and production (a broad category largely
encompassing manufacturing activities) are accounted for by the
cost of trust.
3.3 Caveats
It is stressed that the results presented in this paper are preliminary,
and subject to several qualifications. The most important of these
is that the occupational trust weightings are subjective. A cost of
trust reweighting of the occupational figures will yield different
results, both in terms of the aggregate cost of trust adjusted
!
!
The$JBBA$$|$$Volume$1$|$$Issue$2$$|$$December$2018$
4$
!
employment data, as well as the distribution of occupations by
weight.
Other measures to establish the cost of trust are potentially
available. It may be possible to use a proxy measure of regulatory
intensity to indicate which economic activities bear a heavier cost
of trust. One may associate the degree of trust, for example, on an
industry basis with a measure of “regulatory restrictiveness” [26,
27]. The regulatory restrictiveness measure, provided by the
Mercatus Center of George Mason University, provides a count of
words contained in U.S. federal legislation which is likely to limit
economic and social choices, such as the words “shall,” “must,”
“may not,” “prohibited” and “required.” In this context, it is may
be possible to conceive certain industries as necessitating a
relatively high cost of trust to maintain their operations.
Another, and arguably more straightforward method, is to itemize
and aggregate the level of expenditures undertaken by the private
and public sectors to maintain trust in their operations. Such
expenditures may include IT security expenditures, record auditing
costs, the costs of tax filing, and the costs of complying with certain
government regulations.
4. Significance of cost of trust in presence of distributed
ledger technology
A host of techniques and strategies have been developed to solidify
trust economically. These include the development of a sound
personal reputation, ratification of contractual arrangements,
creation of firms that organize internal transactions and propagate
a “corporate culture” of honesty and reliability, and state
institutions to enforce trustworthy behavior and punish trust
defection.
Another, albeit much underappreciated, practice to uphold
generalized trust comes in the form of a ledger. In a generic sense,
the purpose of a ledger is to record and verify facts in their
economic, political or social manifestations. Ledgers contain
information jointly known about matters such as ownership,
identity, relations and exchange, all of which elicit economic
activity [28]. To promulgate a sense of generalized trust in a human
context, with idiosyncratic individuals maintaining different
languages, cultures, perspectives and objectives, ledgers help
establishes some kind of “common reality that everyone can bind
to” [29, p. 33].
The maintenance of ledgers has been identified by some scholars
as pivotal to long-run economic development [30, 31], and they
also appear to be a necessary condition for trustful relations to
occur. However, this condition is by no means sufficient because
opportunists could enjoy zero-sum gains by falsifying ledger
Table I: Distribution of United States occupational employment, adjusted for cost of trust [22]
!
Natural resources , construction, and maintenance occupations
!
!
The$JBBA$$|$$Volume$1$|$$Issue$2$$|$$December$2018$
5$
!
information. For ledgers to be economically effective there must
be a high degree of trust in them.
In the modern economy, firms and governments have come to act
as “controlling authorities” over the state and condition of ledgers.
The extent of allotted authority to such organizations include what
kind of information is to be (or not to be) presented in a ledger,
and what sorts of information is allowed (or not allowed) to be
added. This “institutionalized trust” has, to a considerable extent,
relegated (or even displaced) the role and importance of
personalized, small-scale trust networks into the background of
contemporary economic affairs.
The emergence of third party, ledger-controlling organizations,
which tend to exude hierarchic list and centralist characteristics,
have been associated with economies of scale and the Weberian
rationalization of political affairs. However, it has become
apparent, at least in some quarters, conventional ledger controls
have, themselves, come at some cost. For example, control over
ledger information by firms and governments potentially enable
them to concentrate power and capture significant rents [32].
Even more fundamentally, it is debatable to what extent the
organizational arrangements described here actually promote trust.
Centralized, hierarchical entities unwittingly pose as single points
of attack by cheaters, fraudsters, hackers and others seeking to
manipulate data to their advantage (in the field of accounting, for
example, see Jones [33]). In other words, hierarchical centralization
is insufficient to protect the integrity of ledgers. The imposition of
top-down ledger protocols could also reduce the degrees of
freedom to discover alternative bases of trust within society,
undermining intrinsic motivations by diverse economic actors to
forge trusting relations.
Despite the longstanding methodological attributes of ledgers, and
the organizational apparatuses used to sustain them economically,
in recent years ledger technologies have been subject to significant
innovation. One of the more prominent instances of ledger
innovation has been the blockchain a ledger enabling data and
information to be appended, stored and validated on a
cryptographically-secure basis amongst a distributed, peer-to-peer
network of computers. The blockchain aims to operate in such a
way that “the integrity of the devices and of the transactions can
be assured by a tamper-proof record that both parties can trust,
this mutual lack of knowledge about each other doesn’t manner”
[29, p. 127]. This starkly contrasts the traditional model predicated
on intermediated (but tamper-prone) third parties claiming
authoritative control over ledger amendment, security and
verification, in the name of galvanizing trust.
A key method through which blockchain can serve to uphold trust
is through the design and maintenance of “smart contracts,”
defined as “computer programs that secure, enforce, and execute
settlement of recorded agreements between people and
organizations” [34, p. 101]. It is conceivable that the blockchain-
enabled smart contract could serve as a pivot to help reduce the
cost of trust, at least relative to techniques employed in the
conventional economy. As explained by Van Rijmenam and Ryan
[35], “smart contracts are automatically and autonomously
executed, thereby taking out the need for human judgement and
minimizing the need for trust. In addition, smart contracts remove
the need for developing, implementing, or evaluating decisions by
management or employees … it becomes possible to automate
decision-making” [35, p. 20].
Given the terms of the smart contract are defined, executed and
enforced by its underlying programming code, there appears a
lesser need to maintain those pervasive, yet costly, timing-
consuming and labor-absorbing, techniques to uphold trust in the
non-blockchain economy. The opportunity to relieve workers of
tasks dedicated toward upholding trust has potentially significant
implications for future labor markets.
The cost of trust could, in one sense, be reduced to the extent that
smart contracting adoption displaces existing occupational roles
mainly devoted to upholding inter-personal trust
(“Schumpeterian” role disruption mechanism). Consider, for
example, the potential of smart contracts to automate legal and
regulatory provisions could displace (to some extent) the need for
lawyers [36]. The diffusion of smart contracts, and the concomitant
devolution of complex agreements and standards to the
blockchain, could also enable workers to renegotiate working roles
away from trust-intensive activity and toward service delivery,
strategic thinking and other roles (“Kirznerian” role arbitrage
mechanism). Both mechanisms are likely to operate in
complementary fashion and are hypothesized to potentially reduce
the cost of trust as blockchain, and in particular smart contracting,
become more prevalent.
We suppose that the cost of trust represents a standalone cost
category to ensure the conduct of exchange relations in the
economy grounded in trustful relations. As this paper suggests, the
cost of trust in a non-blockchain environment predominated by
third-party, centralized trust hierarchies is relatively substantial in
an economy-wide perspective. Cost of trust estimates should be
compared against the costs of blockchain use cases as an alternative
to the conventional trust-model of organizational hierarchy, or of
“forking” exercises within blockchain spaces intended to create
new domains of distributed trust.
5. Conclusion
There has been scant recognition thus far to the idea that the
establishment and perpetuation of trust in the economy
necessitates investment and other efforts and, as such, trust is
costly. Using an occupational dataset for the United States, we
establish that the cost of trust is a significant economic factor in
the modern economy. The aggregate cost of trust (proxied by the
amount of time and effort expended in each occupation to uphold
trusting relations) were estimated to account for about 35 per cent
of U.S. employment in 2010. To put it simply, the cost of trust to
the American economy is considerable.
This study draws attention to the significance of the cost of trust
in the context of ledger innovation, chiefly in the form of
blockchain (distributed ledger) technology. Questions concerning
the economic value of blockchain vis-à-vis conventional ledger
technologies would ideally incorporate cost of trust considerations
in their appraisals. In addition to this, specific applications of ledger
innovation could also be the subject of cost of trust research. The
potential for “tradetech” (i.e. the application of distributed ledger
technology and other technological advances to supply chain
!
!
The$JBBA$$|$$Volume$1$|$$Issue$2$$|$$December$2018$
6$
!
management) to reduce the cost of trust amongst supply chain
participants is one example of this.
We also see the cost of trust as a generalized framework for
rigorously contemplating the implications of trust bonds between
exchanging parties in the economy. Has the cost of trust changed
over time and, if so, how? What is the empirical relationship
between the cost of trust and aspects of macroeconomic or
industry-level performance? Does the cost of trust meaningfully
affect labor markets in any meaningful fashion, including through
the generation of wage premiums? How do public policies, and
even forms of public governance, interact with the cost of trust?
There is also a scope to refine the methodology for estimating the
cost of trust as new and improved forms of data become available.
These are only a few of the potential array of issues amenable to
further investigation by economists and other social scientists with
an interest in matters of trust.
References
[1] J. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, 1990.
[2] O. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New
York: Free Press, 1985,
[3] S. Grossman and O. Hart, "The Costs and Benefits of
Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,"
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94, no. 4, pp. 691-719, 1986.
[4] B. Holmstrom and P. Migrom, "Multitask Principal-Agent
Analysis: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design,"
Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, vol. 7, pp. 24-52,
1991.
[5] R. H. Coase, "The Nature of the Firm," Economica, vol. 4,
no. 16, pp. 386-405, 1937.
[6] C. Berg, S. Davidson and J. Potts, "Blockchains Industrialise
Trust," [Online]. Available:
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3074070.
[Accessed 8 May 2018].
[7] V. Sankaranarayanan, M. Chandrasekaran and S.
Upadhyaya, "Towards Modeling Trust Based Decisions: A
Game Theoretic Approach," in Computer Security -
ESORICS, J. Biskup and J. Lopez, Eds., Berlin, Springer-
Verlag, 2007, pp. 485-500.
[8] D. M. Rousseau, S. B. Sitkin, R. S. Burt and C. Camerer,
"Not so different after all: a cross-discipline view of trust,"
Academy of Management Review, vol. 23, no. 3, pp. 393-404,
1998.
[9] O. Williamson, "Calculativeness, trust, and economic
organization," Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 36, pp. 453-
486, 1993.
[10] N. Lubmann, "Familiarity, Confidence, Trust: Problems and
Alternatives," in Trust Making and Breaking Cooperative
Relations., D. Gambetta, Ed., Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1988, pp.
94-107.
[11] D. Furlong, “The Conceptualization of ‘Trust’ in Economic
Thought,” [Online]. Available:
https://opendocs.ids.ac.uk/opendocs/bitstream/handle/123456
789/3339/Wp35.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y. [Accessed 8
May 2018].
[12] C. Camerer, Behavioral Game Theory, Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 2003.
[13] R. Botsman, Who Can You Trust? How Technology Brought
Us Together - and Why It Could Drive Us Apart, London:
Porfolio Penguin, 2018.
[14] G. M. Hodgson, Economics and Institutions: A Manifesto
for a Modern Institutional Economics, Cambridge: Polity Press,
1988.
[15] B. E. Hermalin and M. L. Katz, "Information and the Hold-
Up Problem," RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 40, pp. 405-
423, 2009.
[16] P. E. Earl and J. Potts, "A Nobel Prize for Governance and
Institutions: Oliver Williamson and Elinor Ostrom," Review of
Political Economy, vol. 23, no. 1, pp. 1-24, 2011.
[17] P. Bromiley and J. Harris, "Trust, Transaction Cost
Economics, and Mechanisms," in Handbook of Trust Research,
R. Bachmann and A. Zaheer, Eds., Cheltenham, Edward Elgar,
2006, pp. 124-143.
[18] J. J. Wallis and D. North, "Measuring the Transaction Sector
in the American Economy: 1870-1970," in Long-term factors in
American economic growth, S. L. Engerman and R. E. Gallman,
Eds., Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1986, pp. 95-161.
[19] D. McCloskey and A. Klamer, "One Quarter of GDP is
Persuasion," American Economic Review, vol. 85, no. 2, pp. 191-
195, 1995.
!
!
The$JBBA$$|$$Volume$1$|$$Issue$2$$|$$December$2018$
7$
!
[20] P. A. Lewis, "Uncertainty, power and trust," Review of
Austrian Economics, vol. 21, pp. 183-198, 2008.
[21] J. Kurbalija, "Persuasion: The Essence of Diplomacy,"
DiploFoundation and Mediterranean Academy of Diplomatic
Studies, Geneva, 2013.
[22] United States Census Bureau, "Statistical Abstract of the
United States: 2012," Government Printing Office, Washington
DC, 2012.
[23] Gallup, “Nurses Keep Healthy Lead as Most Honest, Ethical
Profession,” [Online.] Available:
https://news.gallup.com/poll/224639/nurses-keep-healthy-lead-
honest-ethical-
profession.aspx?g_source=Economy&g_medium=newsfeed&g_c
ampaign=tiles. [Accessed 23 July 2018].
[24] C. Caines, F. Hoffmann, G. Kambourov, “Complex-Task
Biased Technological Change and the Labor Market,” [Online].
Available:
file://rmit.internal/USRHome/eh6/e38456/Downloads/SSRN-
id2920456.pdf. [Accessed 11 September 2018].
[25] M. Gittleman, K. Monaco, N. Nestoriak, “The Requirements
of Jobs: Evidence from a Nationally Representative Survey,”
[Online]. Available: http://www.nber.org/papers/w22218.
[Accessed 11 September 2019].
[26] O. Al-Ubaydli and P. A. McLaughlin, "RegData: A
Numerical database on industry-specific regulations for all United
States industries and federal regulations, 1997-2012," Regulation
& Governance, vol. 11, pp. 109-123, 2017.
[27] P.A. McLaughlin, O. Sherhouse, “QuantGov A Policy
Analytics Platform,” [Online]. Available:
http://docs.QuantGov.org/QuantGov_working_paper.pdf.
[Accessed 16 May 2018].
[28] C. Berg, S. Davidson, J. Potts, “Ledgers,” [Online]. Available:
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3157421.
[Accessed 8 May 2018].
[29] P. Vigna and M. J. Casey, The Truth Machine: The
Blockchain and the Future of Everything, New York: St. Martin's
Press, 2018.
[30] D. C. North, "Institutions," The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, vol. 5, pp. 97-112, 1991.
[31] B. S. Yamey, "Scientific Bookkeeping and the Rise of
Capitalism," The Economic History Review, vol. 1, pp. 99-113,
1949.
[32] S. Davidson, P. De Filippi, J. Potts, “Blockchains and the
economic institutions of capitalism, Journal of Institutional
Economics, vol.14, pp.639-658, 2018.
[33] M. J. Jones, Creative Accounting, Fraud and International
Accounting Scandls, Chichester: Wiley, 2010.
[34] D. Tapscott and A. Tapscott, Blockchain Revolution: How the
Technology Behind Bitcoin is Changing Money, Business and The
World, New York: Portfolio/Penguin, 2016.
[35] M. Van Rijmenam and P. Ryan, Blockchain: Transforming
Your Business and Our World, London: Routledge, 2019.
[36] J. Eyers, “Blockchain ‘smart contracts’ to disrupt lawyers,” The
Australian Financial Review, May 30, 2016. [Online]. Available:
https://www.afr.com/technology/blockchain-smart-contracts-
to-disrupt-lawyers-20160529-gp6f5e. [Accessed 11 September
2018].
... Rousseau et al. (1998, p. 395) defined trust as: "[…] a psychological state comprising the intention to accept vulnerability, based upon positive expectations of the intentions or behavior of another […] Trust is neither a behavior (e.g., cooperation) nor a choice (e.g., taking a risk), but an underlying psychological condition that can cause or result from such actions." It underpins exchange, economic coordination (Davidson et al. 2018b), and value creation (Berg et al. 2018b), reducing information asymmetries and moral hazard (Graafland 2020) and the need for costly monitoring and ex-post sanctioning of a breach (Mccannon et al. 2018). Although trust is usually understood as being exogenously provided (Berg et al. 2018a), it is costly to maintain (Davidson et al. 2018b), and it is not transitive (Werbach 2018). ...
... It underpins exchange, economic coordination (Davidson et al. 2018b), and value creation (Berg et al. 2018b), reducing information asymmetries and moral hazard (Graafland 2020) and the need for costly monitoring and ex-post sanctioning of a breach (Mccannon et al. 2018). Although trust is usually understood as being exogenously provided (Berg et al. 2018a), it is costly to maintain (Davidson et al. 2018b), and it is not transitive (Werbach 2018). Nevertheless, "in the context of the digital revolution, "who, what, when, and how people trust is changing" (Fenwick and Vermeulen 2018, p. 11). ...
... This transparency and confidence in the underlying code appear enough to claim the superfluity of trust and correlated institutions. However, trust concerns the parties' expectations and vulnerability (Rousseau et al. 1998) and can be expensive to manufacture conventionally (Davidson et al. 2018b). Conversely, in distributed ledgers, trust is enforced by the network rules; hence, trust moves from participants toward the technology's properties in the blockchain. ...
Article
Full-text available
Innovation and technology have been pivotal to last societies’ well-being. Among the most promising there is the blockchain, which has gained momentum with its narrative of disruption of many current institutions based on the libertarian promise that decentralized and trustless society and economy are possible. Technology and behaviors have reciprocal influence; this research investigates blockchains’ impacts on trust and (de)centralization, considered crucial aspects of markets and social functioning. The scope is to highlight the possible shortcomings and challenges of possible blockchain adoption on a large scale to construct a complementary and inclusive ecosystem that works for the general interest, avoiding unintentional negative impacts of a technology that may play a critical role in the infrastructure of our institutions.
... This shift moves trust from organizations and personal relationships to the platform and its providers (Calvaresi et al., 2019). The economic potential of such "trustless systems" is significant, as the cost of trust in the US economy was estimated at 35% of total employment (Davidson et al., 2018). ...
Chapter
Full-text available
Blockchain technology is poised to revolutionize the tourism industry by leveraging its core features-immutability, transparency, programmability, and decentralization. This research ferrets into how blockchain can reshape customer relationships, organizational structures, and interorganizational collaborations in tourism. It provides a comprehensive understanding of anticipated future of the tourism industry with blockchain integration. Economic theory suggests that blockchain can shift the balance of power in the tourism industry. By reducing the need for intermediaries and enabling direct interactions, blockchain can empower both service providers and customers, potentially leading to more competitive and customer-centric mar-150 ket dynamics. Blockchain technology has the potential to substantially transform the tourism industry by enhancing transparency, efficiency, and collaboration. By understanding its fundamental characteristics and potential in the tourism industry can better prepare for and leverage blockchain to create innovative solutions and gain a competitive edge.
... However, in DET, trust is costly to maintain. Trust is a fundamental precondition underpinning the exchange and economic coordination of a market (Davidson, Novak, and Potts 2018). In simple terms, a cost of trust is referred to as 'trust cost'. ...
Article
Full-text available
The increasing adoption of clean energy technologies, including solar and wind generation, demand response, energy efficiency, and energy storage (e.g. batteries and electric vehicles) have led to the evolution of the traditional electricity markets from centralised energy trading systems into Distributed Energy Trading (DET) systems. Consequently, savvy business executives are exploring how blockchain might impact their competitive advantage in the emerging DET markets. Due to its salient features of distributed ledger, consensus mechanisms, cryptography, and smart contracts, blockchain technology is being used to provide decentralised trust, immutability, security and privacy, and transparency in DET system. However, integrating blockchain in DET systems is facing technical, administrative, standardisation and economic barriers. Consequently, we seek to conduct a comprehensive market analysis to identify the specific challenges hindering the integration of blockchain in DET systems. Nonetheless, we noticed that there isn't any evaluation and review framework for conducting a systematic literature review on blockchain-based DET systems. Therefore, in this work we first proposed a conceptual evaluation and review framework for conducting a systematic literature review on blockchain-based DET systems. Then, using the proposed framework, we reviewed the current studies on blockchain-based DET systems to the identify specific challenges hindering the adoption of blockchain and their proposed solutions. Our review found that, although there has been tremendous progress in addressing the technical barriers, the administrative, standardisation and economic barriers have grossly been under reviewed.
Article
Trust is a key resource in financial transactions. Traditional financial institutions, and novel blockchain‐based decentralized financial (DeFi) services rely on fundamentally different sources of trust and confidence. The former relies on heavy regulation, trusted intermediaries, clear rules (and restrictions) on market competition, and long‐standing informal expectations on what banks and other financial intermediaries are supposed to do or not to do. The latter rely on blockchain technology to provide confidence in the outcome of rules encoded in protocols and smart contracts. Their main promise is to create confidence in the way the blockchain architecture enforces rules, rather than to trust banks, regulators, and markets. In this article, we compare the trust architectures surrounding these two financial systems. We provide a deeper analysis of how proposed regulation in the blockchain space affects the code‐ and confidence‐based architectures which so far have underwrote DeFi. We argue that despite the solid safeguards and guarantees which code can offer, the confidence in DeFi is still very much dependent on more traditional trust‐enhancing mechanisms, such as code governance, and antifraud regulation to address some of the issues which currently plague this domain, and which have no immediate, purely software‐based solutions. What is more, given the risks of bugs or scams in the DeFi space, regulation and trusted intermediaries may need to play a more active role, in order for DeFi to gain the trust of the next generation of users.
Article
Full-text available
Critically engaging with literature on post-politics, blockchain and algorithmic governance, and drawing also on knowledge gained from undertaking a three-year empirical study, the purpose of this article is to better understand the transformative capacity of government-led blockchain projects. Analysis of a diversity of empirical material, which was guided by a digital ethnography approach, is used to support the furthering of the existing debate on the nature of the post-political as a condition and/or strategy. Through these theoretical and empirical explorations, the article concludes that while the post-political represents a contingent political strategy by governmental actors, it could potentially impose an algorithmically enforced post-political ‘condition’ for the citizen. It is argued that the design, features and mechanisms of government-led projects are deliberately and strategically used to delimit a citizens’ political agency. In order to address this scenario, we argue that there is a need not only to analyse and contribute to the algorithmic design of blockchain projects (i.e. the affordances and constraints they set), but also to the metapolitical narrative underpinning them (i.e. the political imaginaries underlying the various government-led projects).
Article
Charities and humanitarian organizations have come under closer scrutiny over recent years. Highly publicized financial scandals, together with criticisms concerning the cost, effectiveness, and underlying motivations of certain charitable and humanitarian activities, appear to have corroded public trust. Can recent innovations in blockchain assist in improving nonprofit effectiveness and, through it, trust amongst donors, beneficiaries, and broader communities? This paper deploys a “cost of trust” framework to assess blockchain potential in reinforcing trust in charitable and humanitarian operations. Blockchain has been touted by its advocates as a potential solution for charities to reduce the cost of trust, by: (i) enabling observable funding flows; (ii) enforcing conditions regarding funding disbursement and use; and (iii) facilitating direct giving. Despite a growing number of use cases, limitations of this technology in reducing the cost of trust are also recognized in respect of complex relationships between donating and trust perceptions in heterogeneous environments.
Chapter
Full-text available
Introduction Organizational scholars increasingly recognize trust as an important factor in intra-and inter-organizational relations, significantly influencing everything from the behavior of teams to the performance of strategic alliances and supply chains. Ten years have passed since the publication of two early articles on organizational trust: Bromiley and Cummings (1995) and Cummings and Bromiley (1996). In reflecting on the scholarly impact of these papers – and what such an impact might mean for future work in organizational trust – we discuss the concept of trust, briefly revisit the papers, consider the different ways in which the research has been used, and offer thoughts on the relevance of trust to organizational research. Bromiley and Cummings suggest that the inclusion of trust would expand and extend the research framework of transaction cost economics (TCE). Yet this call for TCE research to include the concept of trust has been largely ignored. Why? We summarize and analyze the apparent justifications for omitting or ignoring trust, leading to a critical examination of several theoretical aspects of TCE. We distinguish between TCE's calcu-lativeness, based on assuming others are self-interest-seeking with guile, and trust, which we define as beliefs or actions not determined by such calculativeness. Defining trust All research on organizational trust faces the question of how to define trust. What do scholars mean when they use the term trust? Trust's many meanings in common usage have complicated the scholarly discussion. These alternative meanings make it difficult to clearly and rigorously define a scholarly construct. Trust researchers have responded to this complexity by defining trust in differing ways or by sub-dividing trust into a multi-plicity of sub-constructs that attend to the different meanings that trust has for people and for organizations. Therefore, scholars conceive of intra-and inter-organizational trust in many ways. Some define trust as intended or potential behavior. For example, Gambetta (1988, p. 217) defines trust as an assessment of another's likely behavior based on its influence on the probability of our choice of future actions: When we say that we trust someone or that someone is trustworthy, we implicitly mean that the probability that he will perform an action that is beneficial or at least not detrimental to us is high enough for us to consider engaging in some form of cooperation with him.
Article
Blockchains are a new digital technology that combines peer-to-peer network computing and cryptography to create an immutable decentralised public ledger. Where the ledger records money, a blockchain is a cryptocurrency, such as Bitcoin; but ledger entries can record any data structure, including property titles, identity and certification, contracts, and so on. We argue that the economics of blockchains extend beyond analysis of a new general purpose technology and its disruptive Schumpeterian consequences to the broader idea that blockchains are an institutional technology. We consider several examples of blockchain-based economic coordination and governance. We claim that blockchains are an instance of institutional evolution.
Article
In this paper we study the relationship between task complexity and the occupational wage- and employment structure. Complex tasks are defined as those requiring higher-order skills, such as the ability to abstract, solve problems, make decisions, or communicate effectively. We measure the task complexity of an occupation by performing Principal Component Analysis on a broad set of occupational descriptors in the Occupational Information Network (O*NET) data. We establish four main empirical facts for the U.S. over the 1980-2005 time period that are robust to the inclusion of a detailed set of controls, subsamples, and levels of aggregation: (1) There is a positive relationship across occupations between task complexity and wages and wage growth; (2) Conditional on task complexity, routine-intensity of an occupation is not a significant predictor of wage growth and wage levels; (3) Labor has reallocated from less complex to more complex occupations over time; (4) Within groups of occupations with similar task complexity labor has reallocated to non-routine occupations over time. We then formulate a model of Complex-Task Biased Technological Change with heterogeneous skills and show analytically that it can rationalize these facts. We conclude that workers in non-routine occupations with low ability of solving complex tasks are not shielded from the labor market effects of automatization.
Article
We introduce RegData, formerly known as the Industry-specific Regulatory Constraint Database. RegData annually quantifies federal regulations by industry for all U.S. industries and regulations from 1997 to 2010. The quantification of federal regulations at the industry level for all industries is without precedent. Researchers can use this database to study the determinants of industry regulations and to study regulations’ effects on a massive array of dependent variables, both across industries and across time. The database parses industries at the two-digit and three-digit North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) levels. We created this database by using text analysis to count binding constraints in the wording of regulations, as codified in the Code of Federal Regulations, and to measure the applicability of groups of regulations to different industries.
Article
Summary Attempts to conceptualise trust has led to a confusing array of definitions across the social sciences. This paper focuses on the emergence of trust in economic thought and clarifies its conceptualisation as a term used to identify a purely calculative theory of behaviour in which agents form subjective probabilities regarding the future action of others. This conceptualisation of trust is distinguished by two assumptions: (i) boundedly rational agents seek to minimise the costs of acquiring information; and (ii) agents' subjective probabilities regarding the future action of others are 'Bayesian' in that they can be attached to any future event and every belief relevant for decision-making is captured therein. Alternatively, if it is assumed that boundedly rational agents find some calculations too difficult to perform even if the information is available, trust is better conceptualised as a complexity- reducing social norm. This alternative conceptualisation of trust is grounded in sociology, but depending on the importance given to social context in forming agents' predispositions towards trusting (and non-trusting) behaviour, it can be employed both as a substitute and as a complement to the calculative conceptualisation of trust found in economic discourse.