ArticlePDF Available

Informing Long Term Lumber Buying: A Decision-Making Criteria for Wood Buyers Using a Simple Algorithm

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Lumber purchasing decisions rely mostly on historic lumber prices, or the corresponding price of their futures. Various, lumber specific, supply and demand conditions lead to an unpredictable weekly price if one employs basic economic and statistics tools. We propose a prediction model that builds on the historical change of the price from week to week to provide purchasing recommendations yearly. We tested our model using data from the Random Lengths weekly price catalog for six lumber types (1995-2014), comparing it to other purchasing strategies created from the spot and futures prices showing that it is better almost always.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Informing Long Term Lumber Buying: A Decision Making Criteria for Wood
Buyers Using a Simple Algorithm
Thanos Gentimis
Louisiana State University AgCenter
Shaun Tanger
Louisiana State University AgCenter
Maria Bampasidou
Louisiana State University AgCenter
Lumber purchasing decisions rely mostly on historic lumber prices, or the corresponding price of their
futures. Various, lumber specific, supply and demand conditions lead to an unpredictable weekly price if
one employs basic economic and statistics tools. We propose a prediction model that builds on the historical
change of the price from week to week to provide purchasing recommendations yearly. We tested our model
using data from the Random Lengths weekly price catalog for six lumber types (1995-2014), comparing it
to other purchasing strategies created from the spot and futures prices showing that it is better almost
always.
INTRODUCTION
Lumber in the United States is a heavily used commodity in manufacturing and housing
construction. Thus, the corresponding lumber markets are well established entities in the world of trade,
and the various lumber prices are the object of speculation from sellers and buyers alike. However, due to
complex supply and demand conditions, these prices regularly exhibit extreme volatility in the short-run
constituting forecasting a difficult task (Oliveira et al., 1977). These conditions can be linked to stumpage
costs, railroad strikes or railcar shortages, residential construction, and prices of substitutes like steel and
aluminum. In addition, the lumber market can be affected by macroeconomic conditions; the housing
bubble of 2006 followed by the great recession in 2009 are recent examples.
Traditionally, forecasting models for purchasing recommendations in lumber depend on historic
price series and futures prices. So far, studies have employed moving average analysis and regression
analysis to forecast lumber price series and address the volatility these series exhibit, by incorporating other
factors, like variables for demand, price movement and volume traded. The complexity of forecasting
lumber price series intensifies when we consider different production and trading regions, different species
and grades, lumber uses and respective dimensions needed. Considering an aggregated lumber price series
for grades, regions, and species implying that the law of one price holds for the lumber market can lead to
misspecifications of the forecasting model (Yin and Baek, 2005). This issue can also be encountered in
studies using futures prices and renders some of these models impractical in extended periods of time.
In this paper, we propose a new prediction model that builds on the movement of prices instead of
their actual values (spot or futures prices). The proposed model complements the existing literature,
utilizing only the aforementioned time series. Specifically, we use data from the Random Lengths weekly
price catalog for six lumber types for the years 1995 to 2014 and no other information. We do not aggregate
our data but instead examine stationarity, correlations between these six series, and seasonality patterns
separately for each price series. Keeping the data series disaggregated allows for a more robust empirical
analysis and targeted purchasing recommendations tied to the respective lumber type.
As indicated, successful buying and selling of lumber is dependent on traders accurately predicting
prices that they will face in the near future (Buongiorno et al, 1984). Many lumber market participants
engage in price discovery through following and/or transacting in the lumber futures market (Deneckere et
al., 1986; Hasan and Hoffman-MacDonald, 2012). Though thinly traded, the trading volume threshold,
which is necessary to facilitate efficient price discovery, is very low, the common price discovery measures
suggest that futures markets are dominant in the price discovery process (Admmer et al., 2016).
Calculations of the referenced authors indicates that only 42 percent of the total production in covered by
the futures market and find that only 1 of the 6 largest lumber trading companies took active positions in
the futures market despite other risk hedging behavior. However, many lumber buyers do not engage this
mechanism of price discovery, relying more heavily on recent prices and experience of trading networks
developed over time. Linkedin correspondence with a lumber trader indicated not all traders use the futures
market to determine buying and selling strategy. While some use it as a basis for contracting, those that
trade in the open markets will look at futures to decide if they should buy or sell. Others simply buy based
on inventory needs and demand that they face in the present. While recent findings in the lumber price
literature suggest that engaging the futures markets is efficiency increasing over not using it, consensus
does not exist on the subject (Parajuli and Zhang, 2016). Given lumber's thinly traded futures, several
researchers have found that spot and futures price series are not co-integrated, implying very little to no
role of futures in the price discovery process for lumber spot prices1.
However, using novel statistical methodology the two most recent publications on the subject, find
that indeed futures do aid traders in the price discovery process (Parajuli and Zhang, 2016; Mehrotra and
Carter, 2017). Two questions arise repeatedly in the literature:
1) Are futures prices merely following the same process as the spot prices due to end use demand? In other
words, are the same expectations and supply and demand conditions that influence spot prices and futures
prices and thus are redundant in the information they provide (Mehrotra and Carter, 2017), therefore
showing co-integration when its spurious? This question, while addressed remains unanswered in the
futures literature.
2) Are lumber futures a strong predictor for specific species that are not included in the futures contract?
For example, can futures be used to predict prices for southern yellow pine? The species mix in the futures
contracts is a significant component of North American lumber production, but it does not represent the
majority of the softwood lumber produced. We estimate that 20-25 percent of the softwood lumber
produced in 2009 was of species that could qualify for the contracts.”(Lutz, 2012, p.3). Lumber futures are
comprised of 2x4’s (8’ to 20’), graded at #1 and #2 of western SPF, Hem-fir, Engelmann Spruce, and
Lodgepole pine. This question has been examined empirically, but the evidence is mixed. However, if there
are strong correlations among lumber species, seemingly, the answer should be yes.
Yin and Baek (2005), undertake the most ambitious analysis on the subject of co-integration among
lumber species in the North American market. They find evidence supporting the law of one price for the
entire United States softwood lumber market (in other words, co-integrated), but unlike the futures and spot
prices literature there is far more agreement on the matter (Uri and Boyd, 1990; Jung and Doroodian, 1994;
Shahi et al., 2006; Shahi and Kant, 2009). They do mention that this relationship is not unanimous among
price series relationships. However, depending on the test groupings were co-integrated approximately 90
percent of the time, no matter the test.
Unfortunately, the same statistical question plagues this literature on the issue of co-integration as
that mentioned by Mehrotra in the futures prices literature. Namely, that species may be co-integrated, but
not due to substitutability, instead owing to the fact that all these co-integrating relationships are caused by
common-demand side factors (Shook et al., 2009). Softwood lumber is largely traded through wholesalers,
who can take speculative positions on a number of species through storage of the commodity and hold long
positions on a number of lumber species. Thus, prices for various species may show co-integration due to
liquidity constraints faced by the wholesalers, who trade multiple species concurrently (Pindyck and
Rotemberg, 1988; Shook et al., 2009). Regardless of a causal relationship, this would indicate that prices
for various lumber species are highly correlated and thus the futures should adequately predict any lumber
type prices including the southern yellow pine lumber we examine in this paper especially the #2 series.
On the other hand, there are several researchers who have examined the relationship of other
specific spot prices and the futures market and have not found this to be true (e.g. Hasan and Hoffman-
MacDonald, 2012; He and Holt, 2004; French, 1986; Fama and French, 2016). Mehrotra and Carter (2017)
believe this may be either due to the species differences in the lumber futures and spot prices, since the
specific lumber commodity traded on the futures market is not traded in any spot market, or due to a
statistical averaging issue common in time series (using monthly or quarterly averages). They use the price
of the expiring contract to serve as a spot price (thus removing the species mix issue). However, Parajuli
and Zhang (2016) using the same specific species series as Manfredo and Sanders (2008) do find co-
integration between the two series. This would indicate that the lack of integration is due to some other
factor(s). In fact, it may be a specification issue with how the authors are constructing their futures price
series, specifically the expiration date and when the price rolls over to the subsequent futures series. Parajuli
and Zhang (2016) use a continuous weekly series similar to that developed by Quandl. Interestingly, the
implications of these more recent findings, is that futures can be used as a hedging mechanism against
market volatility and as advance information of lumber markets.
While many researchers have devised various models and methods to examine the relationships of
lumber prices, those that employ futures or otherwise, do not reach the same conclusions. It may in fact be
the case that the series are exhibiting long memory (Niquidet and Sun, 2012), which may explain why at
times, two or more price series may co-integrate, but at other times they do not (a common issue in the
futures literature). Niquidet and Sun (2012) examine several lumber and pulp products and find that after
price shocks, despite the shock dissipating within 50 months, the effects can linger for 30 years. Among
lumber markets, Sun and Ning (2014) find that the southern markets tend to achieve equilibrium more
quickly than those of other North American lumber markets after price shocks. Assuming the co-integration
is true, one could use the delayed futures price to predict the movement of the actual price. Unfortunately,
our model neither confirmed, nor denied the existence of co-integration in a definite way, as we will explain
in section results.
In terms of forecasting lumber prices, the papers by Oliveira et al., (1977), Buongiorno et al.,
(1984), and Deneckere et al., (1986) are the most relevant to our analysis. Using a series of models from
ARIMA, Oliveira et al. (1977), found these simple time series models to be relatively accurate for short-
run predictions of lumber prices (within 10 percent of actual prices up to 4 weeks for SYP). Buongiorno et
al. (1984), compared a relatively complex econometric model, a futures model, and a lagged cash price
model in terms of predictive power. In the shorter-run (one quarter), FORSIM and futures models compared
favorably, but for longer term forecasts (2-3 quarters) the FORSIM model was superior. Both outperformed
the lagged cash price model. Further, findings in Deneckere et al. (1986), indicate that futures are an
effective hedge to blunt the variance of cash positions taken by the trader, making them effective for risk
averse traders.
The only other literature we were able to find on the issue of a decision framework for buying and
selling lumber was Kingslien (1975). They give an explicit methodology for producers to sell futures once
agreeing to contract to produce lumber, they also state that wholesalers and end purchasers can use the
tables with a simple formula to determine desired futures selling prices (i.e. Desired profit margin + Cost
of production - Adjustment factor for item(s) = Futures price). Then using their tables to arrive at the
adjustment factor, they offer producers guidelines for trading futures, given relationships that they establish
between non-contract and contract grade lumber prices and how they are related to expiring futures prices.
In this paper, we take a slightly different approach to advance the literature by adding this
interesting applied wrinkle: Given historical information in the respective weekly price series (futures or
spot), what action should be taken by lumber buyers (buy or don’t buy)? Specifically, we offer purchasing
recommendations based off probabilities of price movements rather on actual prices. We compare this
“long-history” model against other possible strategies to determine the best strategy to use over a given
period (2000-2015). Our findings indicate that among model alternatives, our model outperforms all other
strategies, including one that uses futures prices with up to six months of lags. We also examine these
recommendations in the context of warehouse space that the buyer has available. This has implications both
for the literature on futures and spot lumber prices and their relationships as well as real world implications
for buyers who wish to employ this method as a buying strategy for purchasing lumber throughout the entire
year. Our paper is structured as follows. The data section, discusses the lumber price series used in the
analysis and examines some of their properties, namely potential trends, correlations and seasonal patterns.
The following section, introduces the mathematical underpinnings of our model's estimation algorithm,
formulates the conceptual model and describes the computations. In the subsequent section, we compare
our model to others for various parameters and report our results. In the last two sections, we discuss our
findings in terms of main economic conditions and conclude this paper by presenting future venues for this
analysis.
DATA
Dataset Description
Our dataset comprises of weekly lumber prices provided by the independent price recording
company “Random Lengthsfor two grades and six types of softwood lumber described in the table below
(See Table 1).
TABLE 1
LUMBER PRICE SERIES
Price
Series
Pubdate
Description
Price
Year
Month
Week
Issue
LAGD
06-Jan-95
KD Southern Pine
(Eastside) #2 2x4
random Prices Net f.o.b.
Mill
420.00
1995
1
1
1
LAGD
13-Jan-95
KD Southern Pine
(Eastside) #2 2x4
random Prices Net f.o.b.
Mill
425.00
1995
1
2
2
LAGD
20-Jan-95
KD Southern Pine
(Eastside) #2 2x4
random Prices Net f.o.b.
Mill
420.00
1995
1
3
3
LAGD
27-Jan-95
KD Southern Pine
(Eastside) #2 2x4
random Prices Net f.o.b.
Mill
408.00
1995
1
4
4
Lumber products come in different grades, which are often related to the quality of the sawlog,
originally harvested and converted to the corresponding wood product. Typically, these are some form of
structural lumber (i.e. 2x4, 2x6) or plywood depending on the size and quality of the original sawlog.
Softwoods (or pine) such as these under examination in this manuscript, come in four grades based on either
their strength and/or appearance. Knots and other defects result in a lower grade. Most two-inch thick
softwood lumber (the 2 in 2x4) is graded for its strength rather than appearance.
The common grades found at your local lumberyard from best to worst are:
#1 Construction grade, #2 Standard grade, #3 Utility grade and #4 Economy grade. This study originated
from a collaborative project with a wood pallet producer in the Southeastern United States. Typically,
pallets used for shipping and hauling products utilize #4 grade quality lumber. However, many chain stores
(e.g. Walmart, Lowes) use #2 grade for floor displays of merchandise. This particular pallet producer
creates pallets for both of these uses, utilizing the lumber dimensions listed earlier in the text and thus our
analysis focuses on these particular lumber products. While we cannot make any generalizable claims about
other lumber species and how well our model performs relative to other predictive models, we see no reason
why this analysis could not be done to estimate purchasing options for other lumber types or other popular
wood products, such as plywood and engineered wood products.
The dataset covers the period of 1995-2014 and it was pre-processed to fit a standard 52-week
calendar with appropriate interpolations. In the original dataset, all months had 5 weeks, but some of them
had no entries. We found the weeks with the fewest entries throughout our dataset for each lumber type,
and removed them until a 52 week calendar was created. This may result to a small error in computations,
but since the comparisons are averaged out over many years, we do not anticipate that to be a major flaw.
A typical entry (row) of our dataset is presented in the table below (See Table 2) and our dataset has 6,240
rows. We use the dataset to perform both the training and testing of the model in this paper, but we plan to
expand our methods to other types in the future.
TABLE 2
TYPICAL ENTRY OF DATASET
Price Series
Description
Week
LAGE
KD Southern Pine (Eastside) #2 2x4 random Prices Net
f.o.b. Mill
1
Trends and Graphs
In this subsection, we present some simple descriptive statistics of our dataset and the associated
graphs. We viewed each lumber type as a separate time-series thus creating the graphs in Figure 1.
FIGURE 1
PRICES FOR VARIOUS LUMBER TYPES FOR THE YEARS 1995-2014
To check for stationarity and explore the attributes of our dataset we examined each price series
separately. The first three panels in Figure 1 (top row) are for grade #2 2x4, 2x6 and 2x8, respectively,
whereas the next three panels (bottom row) are for grade #4 2x4, 2x6 and 2x8, respectively. As we see in
Figure 1, there are no clear periodic behaviors overall but a further analysis of each time series separately
revealed some seasonality which we comment on below. Our analysis of the one week lagged price
differences showed that the week by week differences are not (statistically) significantly different than zero
throughout the years. Table 3 gives the relevant statistics.
TABLE 3
STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF THE ONE WEEK DIFFERENCE IN PRICE PER
LUMBER PRICE
Price Series
Mean
St. Dev.
SE
Tstat
Min
Max
LAGD
0.013
8.509
0.264
200.871
-35
53
LAGE
-0.023
9.228
0.286
139.792
-36
40
LAGF
-0.043
9.588
0.297
134.535
-40
40
LBPO
0.082
3.323
0.103
174.709
-20
18
LBPP
0.038
3.691
0.114
157.272
-20
18
LBPQ
0.059
3.485
0.108
138.808
-25
15
We then tried to identify common peaks and lows for the price of each individual lumber type over
the span of a year. In Figure 2, left panel for example, we plot the weekly prices for type LAGD for the
period 1995-2014. No clear trend can be discerned. This holds for the other five lumber types. Even when
we focus on the last five years of our study period, trends are not easy to see on a yearly basis as shown in
Figure 2 right panel.
FIGURE 2
LAGD WEEKLY PRICES FOR PERIODS (1995-2014) & (2012-2014)
We used the autocorrelation function both on the reported prices and on the one-week price
differences but no immediate periodic behavior was apparent. As one can see in Figure 3 and Figure 4, the
levels rarely exceed the $0.2 mark independent of how many lags we considered.
FIGURE 3
AUTOCORRELATION OF THE WEEKLY DIFFERENCE IN PRICES BY LUMBER TYPE
AND VARIOUS LAGS, PERIOD 1995-2014
FIGURE 4
AUTOCORRELATIONS OF THE PRICES BY LUMBER TYPE AND VARIOUS LAGS,
PERIOD 1995-2014
Our analysis revealed some seasonality in the quarterly price over the last five years as Figure 5
suggests, but again nothing definitive. For example, we see a spike on the price for the second quarter
followed by an average dip on the third quarter. Notice again some variations among years not only in the
pattern the prices for each lumber type exhibit but also at the levels. The normalization to 52 weeks had
minimal effect on the trend since we are averaging over a 13-week period.
FIGURE 5
QUARTERLY PRICES FOR ALL LUMBER TYPES FOR THE YEARS 2010-2014
One can thus suggest that the data, in its entirety, indicate stationarity, and no seasonality is
discernible. As an appendix, we included an analysis of our time series using the Dickey Fuller test and we
discuss our findings there, which conform to analyzing the lags.
Correlations
In this subsection, we shift our attention to the correlations between the prices of different types on
a yearly basis. Our observations hint at distinct trends among lumber types based on their number valuation.
Figure 6 presents our findings, where colored in red are all correlations above 90 percent.
We can see that various strong correlations appear among the six lumber types for most of the
years; for example in 2006 all prices are correlated among themselves. This would give credit to the “law
of one price” described in the literature. However, there are years like 2014 that only a few very strong
correlations can be found, which puts the global power of this law into question. In Figure 6, the last sub-
table shows that if the prices are treated as a long time series (1995-2014) the correlations are stronger
among the types that share a number valuation rather than between grade valuations (#2 vs. #4). This is
something worth exploring in future publications. Notice also that in general many correlation coefficients
are large, close to 0.9. This correlation can be explained if one thinks about the common uses of these types
of lumber as it was described in subsection dataset description above. In Figure 7 we provide more
information regarding the correlations between different lumber prices for all years.
FIGURE 6
CORRELATIONS BETWEEN DIFFERENT LUMBER TYPES FOR THE YEARS 1995-2014
FIGURE 7
CORRELATIONS BETWEEN DIFFERENT LUMBER TYPES FOR ALL YEARS
Once more, we would like to comment that lumber price series are characterized by high volatility
especially in the short-run. In addition, lumber price series are sensitive to market fluctuations including
the lumber market (use of lumber, regions, etc.) and the housing market as well as macroeconomic factors
like interest rates (e.g. Karali, 2011). These factors could help explain the price variation we observe
throughout the years and suggest that no simple model like a regression or moving average would fit the
data series well. Although our model did not exploit the connections we identified, we will surely be
pursuing that venue in future publications.
MODEL
The analysis above indicated that a clear forecast of the weekly price is intractable. In this section,
we present a conceptual model that relates buying strategies to predicted movement of prices. Our models
aims at identifying the turning points, which seemed more stable through the years.
Conceptual Model
We consider an agent, a lumber buyer, who has historic data on lumber prices (spot or futures can be
considered). Each week, the agent makes purchasing decisions based on the direction he or she anticipates
the prices will move based on the forecast and disregards the spot price. This setting allows us to discretize
the price in the following sense. Every week there are three possible scenarios: “The price will go up from
the previous week, the price will go down, or the price will stay the same.”
Let X1, X2,…
,
X52 be random variables corresponding to the purchasing decisions, one for each week.
For each of the Xi
we have three possible directions:
1) ,=The price goes up from the previous week.
2) ,=The price stays the same as the last week.
3) ,=The price goes down from last week.
Due to the cyclic nature of the yearly calendar, week 1 uses week 52 as a previous week with minor
adjustments. FIGURE 8
MATHEMATICAL DESCRIPTION OF THE STATES
We can compute the conditional probabilities ( =,|=,) for all possible cases on
the assumption that the variables and  are not independent. The purchasing decision for week i may
affect the purchasing decision for week i+1. To make predictions stronger, we also compute the two-step
conditional probabilities, i.e. ( =,|=,, =,). Clearly, these probabilities change
throughout the year and seasonality is easier to uncover using aggregate historical data in this setting.
We propose three weekly purchasing recommendations for our buyer, namely “Don't Buy (DB),
Buy (B+), and Fill the inventory (B++).” The (DB) and (B++) options are self-explanatory. The (B+)
strategy allows the buyer to satisfy immediate demand and store some extra units for future applications.
In our implementation, the (B+) strategy corresponds to buying twice as much as the needed quantity (2
units) but that can be changed at will. The aggressive purchasing strategy (B++) is not uncommon when
there is lack of information or uncertainty and in our implementation is driven by two consecutive
indications of increased lumber prices for the weeks that follow although again that can be extended to a
bigger time period for other examples. The aggressive buying strategy could be justified with the buyer
making sure they capitalize on a forecasted big increase in prices.
Predictive Model
Our method uses a greater than five year history period (training period) to identify the movements
in lumber prices for the selected period. Additional inputs include, the starting year for the predictions, the
lumber type; the storage capacity and how long of a history should be included in the prediction. In our
implementation, all previous history is included up to the selected year.
Two new variables are created; one that contains the prices forwarded by one week (FOW1) and
another one where prices are forwarded by two weeks (FOW2). The direction is captured by the difference
between the current price and the two forward prices (FOW1 and FOW2) and turned into an indicator
variable with values, +1 if the price goes up, -1 if the price goes down and 0 if it is unchanged. For the last
two weeks (week 51 and week 52) prices from the next year are utilized, and when those are not available,
they are extrapolated using past prices from these weeks.
For each week, the model computes the probability of the price change in the next two weeks using
the selected years as follows:
=(1 > ) , =(1 < ),=(1 = ) (1)
=(2 > ) , =(2 < ),=(2 = ) (2)
Obviously ++= 1 and ++= 1. Finally, the model creates purchasing
recommendations based on the following three cases:
1)  > and  >, where = 0.2 is a threshold chosen through experimentation. To
compute this parameter, we tested various alphas with increments of 0.05, on the first 10 years of
the dataset and we chose the alpha with the lowest yearly cost for all lumber types on average. In
this case, we anticipate that on average the price will increase dramatically for both the next two
weeks. Thus, the algorithm suggests an aggressive buy (B++).
2)  0 and  0. In this case, we assume that on average the price will go down or
stay the same the next two weeks. The model suggests a halt on purchasing (DB).
3) Everything else, which means that the prices do not follow a clear trend the next two weeks, but at
least one of the two is on average a little bit greater or equal to the current week's price. The model
recommends a moderate buy (B+).
Model Implementation
Our dataset contains information on six types of lumber and respective prices for the years 1995-
2014. In order for the model to stabilize, we require five years of price series data, so our smallest starting
year is 2000. To allow for the implementation of the predictive algorithm and the three recommendations
(B+, B++, and DB) we impose a lower bound on the storage capacity to be four units. That is the minimal
warehouse size since we require one operational unit and a possible purchase up to three more units. Note
that the variable “unitsis an arbitrary measure of quantity and it can be adjusted to the operational schema
of any lumber purchasing entity. Also, note that a smaller storage capacity would disregard the three
purchasing choices. For example, at storage capacity of three units the recommendations (B++) and (B+)
will lead to the same purchasing strategy of purchasing two units.
Although theoretically there is no upper bound to the capacity of the warehouse, we decided to stop
it at nine, presenting us with six different cases to test in our experiment. Thus, following the rule of thumb
we have more than 30 comparisons per year (36 in our case) which leads to safe and easily interpretable
statistical results. Furthermore, when we multiply by the number of years (15) we end up with 540 different
possible test cases.
As mentioned earlier, our algorithm provides information for the forward prices (FOW1, and
FOW2), and the direction of the price change with respect to the current price for the two weeks that follow,
(, and , respectively). A snapshot of the information can be found in Table 4.
TABLE 4
INTERMEDIATE TABLE SHOWING THE ALGORITHM AT WORK
Price
Series
Description
Year
Week
Price
FOW1
FOW2
D
FOW1
D
FOW2
LAGE
KD Southern…
1995
1
395
400
380
+1
-1
LAGE
KD Southern…
1995
2
400
380
380
-1
-1
LAGE
KD Southern…
1995
3
380
380
0
LAGE
KD Southern…
1995
4
380
Using the logic statements above the algorithm outputs a list of recommendations for each week of
that year. A representation of the information we have (after cleaning up the dummy columns) is shown in
Table 5. As a reminder, the recommendation Buy (B+) recommends the purchase of units that will satisfy
immediate demand and some additional units, in our experimentation set arbitrarily to two. One could alter
this to match other purchasing schemes if needed.
TABLE 5
WEEKLY PRICES FOR YEAR 2002 FOR LUMBER TYPE LAGE INCLUDING THE
MODEL'S RECOMMENDATIONS
Price Series
Description
Year
Week
Price
Recommendation
LAGE
KD Southern…
2002
1
395
B++
LAGE
KD Southern…
2002
2
400
B+
LAGE
KD Southern…
2002
52
430
DB
EXPERIMENTAL RESULTS
To test the predictive capabilities of our model we created a purchasing strategy for each year and
each lumber type. We do not allow arbitrage to take place; our agent is only allowed to purchase lumber
units and not sell, hence not taking advantage of potential price differences. We impose two restricting
assumptions: we demand one lumber unit to operate and the warehouse size is limited. The first assumption
is important to satisfy immediate demand for the operation; the second assumption is important for the
implementation of the predictive algorithm and is a realistic restriction. Lastly, our model requires having
the same amount of units (s) in store at the start and the end of each year.
The purchasing strategy, based on the suggestion tables of our model proceeds week by week as
follows: Based on our recommendation table we fill the warehouse if the suggestion is (B++). We buy two
units if the suggestion is (B+), in anticipation of a moderate price increase. Finally, if the recommendation
is (DB) we halt purchases unless the warehouse is empty in which case we buy one unit to cover the
operational needs of the week. In addition, as we get closer to the end of the year our purchases are modified
in such a way so that we do not exceed the amount of units (s) set as our end of the year goal in the
warehouse.
Table 6 shows the proposed purchases, stored quantity and the actual cost per week for the lumber
type “KD Southern Pine (Eastside) #2 2x8 random Prices Net f.o.b. Mill (LAGF),” during the year 2010.
The total cost for that year is computed and compared to the other suggestion models described below.
Notice that although our method does not always predict the correct movement of the spot prices, if one
looks at the overall output for the year then on average the prediction is informative and in most cases leads
to a better yearly purchasing strategy.
TABLE 6
A PURCHASING STRATEGY FOR LAGF IN 2010
Number
TAG
Year
Week
Price
Recommendation
Purchases
Stored
Quantity
Cost
2861
LAGF
2010
1
239
B++
9
1
2151
2862
LAGF
2010
2
247
B+
1
9
247
2863
LAGF
2010
3
264
B+
1
9
264
2864
LAGF
2010
4
287
B+
1
9
287
2865
LAGF
2010
5
308
B+
1
9
308
2866
LAGF
2010
6
326
B++
1
9
326
2867
LAGF
2010
7
333
B++
1
9
333
2868
LAGF
2010
8
327
B++
1
9
327
2869
LAGF
2010
9
317
B+
1
9
317
2870
LAGF
2010
10
304
DB
0
9
0
2871
LAGF
2010
11
302
DB
0
8
0
2872
LAGF
2010
12
310
DB
0
7
0
2873
LAGF
2010
13
320
B+
2
6
640
2874
LAGF
2010
14
337
B++
3
7
1011
2875
LAGF
2010
15
357
B++
1
9
357
2861
LAGF
2010
16
371
B+
1
9
371
2862
LAGF
2010
17
375
DB
0
9
0
2863
LAGF
2010
18
369
DB
0
8
0
2904
LAGF
2010
44
229
B+
2
3
458
2905
LAGF
2010
45
232
B+
2
4
464
2906
LAGF
2010
46
233
B+
2
5
466
2907
LAGF
2010
47
233
B+
0
6
0
2908
LAGF
2010
48
228
DB
0
5
0
2909
LAGF
2010
49
224
DB
0
4
0
2910
LAGF
2010
50
223
B+
0
3
0
2911
LAGF
2010
51
224
B+
0
2
0
2912
LAGF
2010
52
227
B++
0
1
0
In the following subsections, we compare our “long-history” method with other strategies and
recommendation methods, using different warehouse sizes.
Naive Method
The simplest purchasing strategy that will satisfy all the assumptions of our experiment is buying
one unit every week. We call this the naive method, and we use it as a first benchmark to prove the
predictive power of our method. Figure 9 shows the difference in yearly cost of our long-history method vs
the naïve method, for all years and all lumber types for various warehouse sizes.
FIGURE 9
LONG-HISTORY METHOD VS NAÏVE METHOD
Note: In red, we report the losses of the long history methods vs the naive one, for all years, all lumber types and
various warehouse sizes with initial quantity 1.
Our long-history method outperforms the naive one more than 95 percent of the times assuming
the starting lumber quantity in the warehouse is one. It is interesting that the naive method performs better
than ours mostly in year 2000 and only for large warehouses during the years 2006 and 2009. For year
2000, an explanation could be that the 5-year history is not enough for our prediction algorithm to compute
the correct yearly movements. Another reason could be the mini recession that hit the lumber market during
that period. A thorough analysis for the years of the recession including 2009 is presented in the section
discussion that follows. If we confine ourselves to a warehouse of size 4 (moderate or average size
warehouse) we win constantly independent of the starting and ending quantity.
Random Method
In order to prove the predicting capabilities of our long-history method independent of the purchasing
schema, we created the “random” purchasing method as follows. For each year and each lumber type a new
recommendation table was created using the same labels (B++, B+ and DB) drawn randomly from a
distribution whose probabilities are equal to the probabilities of (B++, B and DB) in the recommendation
tables of our long-history method.
The algorithm again fills the warehouse when the recommendation is (B++), buys two units when the
recommendation is (B+) and halts purchases if there recommendation is (DB). Once more, we make sure
the demand of one unit is covered weekly and the purchases are adjusted so that at the end of the year we
have the same quantity s in our inventory as when we started.
Our strategy is better than the “random” one 80 percent of the times for warehouse sizes of four to
nine units and a starting quantity of one. We note here that we almost always lose in 2009 against the
“random” strategy as Figure 10 suggests. We discuss this in depth in section Recession.
FIGURE 10
LONG-HISTORY METHOD VS RANDOM METHOD
Note: In red, we report the losses of the long history methods vs the random one, for all years, all lumber types and
various warehouse sizes with initial quantity 1.
Short-term Method
We also implemented a classic “short term” prediction strategy as follows. For each week, we computed
the movement based only on the previous week. If the price went up significantly, we recommend (B++)
in anticipation of a price hike. If it went up by a moderate amount, we recommend (B+) in anticipation of
a moderate price increase. Finally, if the prices went down we recommend (DB) as we believe prices will
keep falling. Our purchase suggestions again follow the rules of meeting demand (i.e. have at least one unit
a week) and adjust so that by the end of the year we have the same starting quantity in storage. To distinguish
big increases vs short increases we computed the mean of the positive increases for each lumber type
throughout the years up to the starting year and used that as a cutoff point.
Once again, the “long-history” method is better than the “short-term” method 78 percent of the
times as can be seen in Figure 11. Again, we see a failure of our method to correctly identify the price
movements in 2009 compared to this one.
FIGURE 11
LONG-HISTORY METHOD VS SHORT-TERM METHOD
Note: In red, we report the losses of the long history methods vs the short-term one, for all years, all lumber types
and various warehouse sizes with initial quantity 1.
Futures Method
Finally, we wanted to analyze the predictive capabilities of the futures price series. We also wanted to test
the assumption that is prevalent in the literature, that the futures and spot price are co-integrated. This would
imply that using delayed versions of the futures price time series instead of the reported price would lead
to a better price forecasting. In our first attempt at creating recommendations from the futures prices, we
repeated our method but replaced the price series with various delayed versions of the futures price up to
26 weeks (roughly half a year).
FIGURE 12
LONG-HISTORY METHOD VS FUTURES METHOD
Note: In red, we report the losses of the long history methods vs the futures one, for all years, all lumber types and
various warehouse sizes with initial quantity 1.
We then computed 26 recommendation tables and found the one that yielded the smallest yearly
costs on average for all lumber types. We then compared that to our own method. The following table (See
Table 7) presents the results of the best futures-based recommendation system against ours. It turns out that
the best performance happens when we chose the non-lagged version.
TABLE 7
PERCENTAGE OF WINNINGS OF THE LONG-HISTORY METHOD VS FUTURES METHOD
FOR VARIOUS LAGS
Lag
Percentage
None
67.22%
1 Week
69.63%
2 Weeks
74.26%
3 Weeks
74.81%
4 Weeks
72.81%
5 Weeks
74.81%
6 Weeks
75%
7 Weeks
79.26%
8 Weeks
83.7%
9 Weeks
84.44%
As one can see our long-history strategy is better than the futures recommendation in the majority of cases
(67 percent). Again, in 2008 and 2009 our method is clearly outperformed by the futures one.
DISCUSSION
Our analysis revealed some interesting results for the period of the recent recession of 2006 to 2010.2 We
found that during this time both lumber prices and housing starts had been dropping since 2006. Lumber
traders recognized the phenomena in late 2005 as volumes of lumber futures reached levels not seen since
1985, which not surprisingly coincided with a large drop in housing starts-although lumber prices generally
moved in a positive direction. As housing starts, lumber prices, and futures prices collapsed, the volume of
futures traded continued to rise, with abnormally high volumes until the trough in housing starts and lumber
prices subsided in April of 2009. Again, futures prices seemed to indicate a recovery as their numbers began
to improve for the first time in January of that year.
Table 8 presents the performance of the methods examined for the six different lumber types and
warehouse sizes four through nine (for a total of 36 cases) for the years 2007-2009.
TABLE 8
METHOD COMPARISONS FOR YEARS 2007-2009
Methods
2007
2008
2009
Long-history
27/36
3/36
5/36
Naïve
0/36
0/36
0/36
Random
9/36
1/36
31/36
Futures
0/36
32/36
0/36
Short-term
0/36
0/36
0/36
It is clear that in 2007, traders believed that markets would rally and they did slightly, as such the
“normal” price histories still do a good job of predicting behavior, however the “random” model performs
second best as credit markets begin to short circuit. By the start of 2008, we are in the designated time of
the credit crisis and lumber traders continue to hedge in large volume futures trading. At this point (January
of 2008) housing starts are at their lowest since 1991. While lumber prices rally slightly in the middle of
the year, housing starts continue to slide. This can be attributed to the steepest lumber production decline
on record (Random Lengths). It is clear that traders are now driving the markets in futures trading as the
futures model dominates the other two. The randomness has been driven from the model, largely everyone's
belief is that the market is contracting and will continue to do so.
Our price histories no longer perform as well, as such a cataclysmic event is not included in their
history. Lastly, and probably the most strangely is the 2009 outcomes, where the “randommodel performs
more strongly than either the “long-history" model or the “futures” model. Interestingly, this is right when
the housing market starts to make its recovery, although the recovery is muted as another panic hits in late
summer of 2009 as housing starts start to decline in August and continue down until October, before rallying
again. This U-shaped market shown in Figure 13 seems to cause problems for both the “futures” model
as well as the “long-history” model. Here it is probable that all methods based on historic price series fail
since the market is in full disarray and thus the fact that the “random” model’s recommendations give the
best results for this year should not come as a surprise. It is important here to note that the “naïve” approach
loses all the time to some other model. So even during the years of crisis employing some of the other
models will lead to better results than employing no model at all.
FIGURE 13
SPOT LUMBER PRICES FOR THE YEARS 1995-2017
CONCLUSIONS-FUTURE WORK
Our long-history data predicting model, although simple in its nature, manages to capture effectively the
changes in the price of these six lumber types on a yearly basis. Without the use of other external
information, the purchasing strategies produced almost always exceed the “naïve” and “random” approach.
Once again, in a future endeavor associations between the various lumber prices will be analyzed, since
according to common practice, these types of lumber are used in conjunction with each other for various
constructions and applications.
In this version of our algorithm, we are not concerned about the magnitude of the price change but
only for its direction. In a later publication, the magnitude of price changes will be used to get a better
understanding of the phenomenon. Also, during our analysis, we discovered inconsistencies in the creation
and dissemination of the “futures” time-series. Thus in a future effort we will try to identify the roots of
some of the problems we spotted in the creation of a continuous futures times series, and utilize some
general statistics-driven ideas to create a more robust version of it.
Furthermore, reflecting on the failure of our method to predict well during the times of crisis, we
will be exploring the creation of a switching mechanism to other models, utilizing shorter histories or even
randomness, when various market indices cross specific critical thresholds. Exclusion criteria for various
turbulent years will be implemented, since the time series information from those years could affect
negatively the predicting capabilities of our algorithm when the market resumes its natural cycles.
Finally, we note that due to the simple nature of the information needed, the model and its
extensions can be employed to forecast prices series for other forest products and agricultural commodities.
Our codes where written mostly in the statistical language R and some of the time series analysis utilized
the package “forecast(Hyndman and Khandakar, 2008). The codes can be made available after a
communication with the authors.
ENDNOTES
1. Information can be found at http://www.cmegroup.com/trading/agricultural/lumber-and-pulp/random-
length-lumber_quotes_volume_voi.html. Trading volume was at 1,244 as of this writing.
2. Officially, the subprime mortgage crisis occurred from December of 2007 and lasted until June of
2009. Housing starts peaked in January 2006, at 2.273 million seasonally adjusted starts. The lumber
futures composite reached its low in January of 2009 and housing starts reached their bottom
approximately four months later, which interestingly enough is the time lag of two futures contracts.
Perhaps futures traders saw evidence of the recovery in their business.
REFERENCES
Admmer, P., Bohl, M. T. & Gross, C. (2016). Price discovery in thinly traded futures markets: How thin is
too thin? Journal of Futures Markets, 36, (9), 851-869.
Buongiorno, J., Huang, F.M. & Spelter, H. (1984). Forecasting the price of lumber and plywood:
econometric model versus futures markets. Forest Products Journal. 34, (7), 13-18.
Deneckere, R., Buongiorno, J. & Il Bark, S. (1986). Optimal hedging in lumber futures markets. Forest
Science, 32 (3), 634-642.
Fama, E. F. & French, K. R. (2016). Commodity futures prices: Some evidence on forecast power,
premiums, and the theory of storage. In: The World Scientific Handbook of Futures Markets. World
Scientific, 79-102.
French, K. R. (1986). Detecting spot price forecasts in futures prices. Journal of Business, 59, (2), S39-S54.
Hasan, S. & Hoffman-MacDonald, J. (2012). Price convergence in the lumber futures market. Journal of
Global Business Management, 8, (2), 126-133.
He, D. & Holt, M. (2004). Efficiency of forest commodity futures markets. In: Meetings of the American
Agricultural Economics Association Selected Paper.
Hyndman, R. J. & Khandakar, Y. (2008). Automatic time series forecasting: the forecast package for R.
Journal of Statistical Software, 26 (3), 1-22.
Jung, C. & Doroodian, K. (1994). The law of one price for us softwood lumber: a multivariate cointegration
test. Forest Science, 40 (4), 595-600.
Karali, B. (2011). What drives daily volatility in lumber futures markets? Forest Science, 57 (5), 379-392.
Kingslien, H. K. (1975). A decision framework for trading lumber futures. Corvallis: Oregon State
University, School of Business.
Lutz, J. (2012). There are no futures in timber. Forest Research Notes 9 (4), 4th Quarter.
Manfredo, M. R. & Sanders, D. R. (2008). Price discovery in a private cash forward market for lumber.
Journal of Forest Economics, 14 (1), 73-89.
Mehrotra, S. N. & Carter, D. R. (2017). Forecasting performance of lumber futures prices. Economics
Research International, (Vol. 2017) (Article ID 1650363), 8 pages, doi:10.1155/2017/1650363.
Niquidet, K. & Sun, L. (2012). Do forest products prices display long memory? Canadian Journal of
Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie, 60 (2), 239-261.
Oliveira, R. A., Buongiorno, J. & Kmiotek, A. M. (1977). Time series forecasting models of lumber cash,
futures, and basis prices. Forest Science, 23 (2), 268-280.
Parajuli, R. & Zhang, D. (2016). Price linkages between spot and futures markets for softwood lumber.
Forest Science, 62 (5), 1-8.
Pindyck, R. S. & Rotemberg, J. J. (1988). The excess co-movement of commodity prices.
Shahi, C., Kant, S. & Yang, F. (2006). The law of one price in the North American softwood lumber
markets. Forest Science, 52 (4), 353-366.
Shahi, C. K. & Kant, S. (2009). Cointegrating relationship and the degree of market integration among the
North American softwood lumber product markets. Canadian journal of forest research, 39 (11),
2129-2137.
Shook, S.R., Plesha, N. & Nalle, D. J. (2009). Does cointegration of prices of North American softwood
lumber species imply nearly perfectly substitutable products? Canadian Journal of Forest
Research, 39 (3), 553-565.
Sun, C. & Ning, Z. (2014). Timber restrictions, financial crisis, and price transmission in North American
softwood lumber markets. Land Economics, 90 (2), 306-323.
Uri, N. D. & Boyd, R. (1990). Considerations on modeling the market for softwood lumber in the United
States. Forest Science, 36 (3), 680-692.
Yin, R. & Baek, J. (2005). Is there a single national lumber market in the United States? Forest Science, 51
(2), 155-164.
APPENDIX A. Dickey-Fuller Tests
The Dickey-Fuller test assumes as a null hypothesis that the differences between consecutive elements of
the time series do not depend on the previous values, but are just random errors. We say then that a unit
root is present in our autoregressive model. We tested our time series for each lumber type on the whole
history of our dataset and on the last five years using the specific Dickey-Fuller t-distribution
(computations in R). Table A.1 presents the test results for the whole history and Table A.2 for the last
five years.
TABLE A.1
DICKEY-FULLER TEST FOR EACH LUMBER PRICE (1995-2014)
LAGD
LAGE
LAGF
LBPO
LBPP
LBPQ
p-value
0.007
0.011
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.014
TABLE A.2
DICKEY-FULLER TEST FOR EACH LUMBER PRICE (2010-2014)
LAGD
LAGE
LAGF
LBPO
LBPP
LBPQ
p-value
0.341
0.353
0.421
0.133
0.038
0.142
According to table A.1 we should reject the null hypothesis, i.e. that the time-series has a unit root,
for all types if we view it throughout the years. On the other hand, if we focus only on the last five years
we have a completely different picture, namely according to table A.2 we fail to reject the null hypothesis
for all types except LBPP.
Contacting Author:
Thanos Gentimis, PhD
Assistant Professor, Research
Experimental Statistics
Louisiana State University
53 Martin D. Woodin Hall, Baton Rouge, LA 70803
office 225-578-7205
tgentimis@agcenter.lsu.edu
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
We test the forecasting power and information content of lumber futures prices traded on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange, from 1995 to 2013, at four forecast horizons. A Mincer-Zarnowitz regression finds evidence of statistically significant forecasting power at all forecast horizons. The results also support the presence of a time-varying risk premium for the shorter forecast horizons. A Granger causality test provides evidence that lumber futures prices lag spot prices in information assimilation over longer forecast horizons, while neither lagging nor leading over shorter forecast horizons.
Article
Full-text available
Price discovery is one of the central functions of futures markets. In this article, we evaluate the relative contributions of spot and futures markets to the price discovery of softwood lumber. We estimate a bivariate vector error correction model using weekly lumber futures and spot price data from 1980 to 2015 and assess the price linkages and dynamic relationship between lumber futures and spot markets. Our empirical results show that the futures market plays a dominant role in price discovery of softwood lumber. In certain periods of the United States-Canada softwood lumber dispute, the lumber spot market also plays a significant role in the price discovery of softwood lumber in the United States.
Article
Full-text available
Competition among the South, the West, and Canada as major softwood lumber production regions has been affected by timber resource endowments, public land policies, and the general economy. To assess spatial price linkages, a threshold vector error correction model is applied on softwood lumber prices from 1978 to 2011. Price transmission is found to be nonlinear and asymmetric. The South is more adaptive to price disequilibrium. Short-term price adjustments are more sophisticated over the period of 1991 to 1993 related to the federal timber restrictions than over the period of 2008 to 2009 related to the global financial crisis.
Article
Full-text available
Studies in spatial market integration of the North American softwood lumber products have mostly focused on the question of whether prices in distinct market locations are cointegrated or not. However, the informational deficiencies in market integration studies were fulfilled in this analysis by examining a continuum of the degree of market integration rather than using the dichotomous approach whereby markets are deemed either integrated or not. Firstly, the methodology of permanent-transitory decomposition in a multivariate vector error correction model was used to estimate the cointegrating relationship of the North American markets for three categories of softwood lumber products: Spruce-Pine-Fir (SPF), Douglas fir (DF), and Hemlock fir (HF). Secondly, a consistent ranking of the degree of market integration was constructed by estimating the reaction time for prices to return back to the steady-state equilibrium, using generalized impulse response functions and persistence profiles. Our results indicate that the long-run price equilibrium relationship for all SPF and HF products is driven by both the production (in Canada) and consumption (in USA) sides of the markets, whereas that for DF products is driven by the consumption (USA) side only. Generally, the degree of market integration for HF products is lower than that for SPF products and higher than that for DF products.
Article
Full-text available
The existence of the Law of One Price (LOP) in the North American (10 regional) markets for aggregate softwood lumber and homogeneous softwood lumber products is tested using the Johansen co-integration test and monthly price data for the Softwood Lumber Agreement (SLA) (1996-2001) period and the post-SLA (2001-2004) period. For the aggregate softwood lumber market, the LOP exists neither in the North American aggregate market nor in any combination of one regional market of Canada and all the five regional markets of the United States, nor in one regional market of the United States and all five regional markets of Canada; however, some of the regional markets are co-integrated. The regional markets of homogeneous softwood products in the two countries are co-integrated during both the SLA and post-SLA period. Further studies are essential to understand the difference between the aggregated and homogeneous softwood products market co-integration and to develop a comprehensive and comparative perspective of the Canadian and the US softwood lumber markets.
Article
Most financial asset returns exhibit volatility persistence. This article investigates this phenomenon in the context of daily returns in lumber futures markets. The volatility of lumber futures is found to vary with different phases of the United States-Canada softwood lumber trade dispute. Daily price volatility was the highest in the post-Softwood Lumber Agreement period (2001-2005), followed by the Softwood Lumber Agreement period (1996 -2000) and the period with trade disputes and temporary tariffs (1992-1995). An inverse relationship between inventory levels and volatility is found. Further, the inventory effect on volatility varies across the different periods of the trade dispute. An inverse relation between time to delivery and volatility is also found. Moreover, it is shown that although volatility persistence exists in the lumber futures market, the time gap between the arrival of news to the markets and the delivery time of futures contracts is the fundamental variable in explaining volatility persistence.
Article
This study uses the Engle-Granger cointegration method to examine the correlation relationship among prices of North American softwood lumber species, wood-based panel prices, and US single-family housing starts. The methodol- ogy employed is identical to that used by US petitioners in the latest round of the Canada - United States softwood lumber trade dispute, whereby petitioners argued that all North American species of softwood lumber were considered to be nearly perfect substitutes for one another. Tests for nonstationarity using the augmented Dickey-Fuller unit root test, as well as our cointegration results, confirm petitioners' results. We find evidence of a long-term cointegrating relationship among the prices of North American softwood lumber species. However, we found no clear evidence of nearly perfect substitut- ability among different North American softwood lumber species. Additional analysis reveals that a long-run equilibrium relationship also exists between North American softwood lumber species and four types of wood-based panel products, as well as US single-family housing starts. Given that the price movements of different wood-based panel products and sin- gle-family housing starts are highly correlated with the price movement of North American softwood lumber species, we fail to conclude that North American softwood lumber species can be claimed as nearly perfect substitutes. Furthermore, we find that the petitioners' analysis is deficient in that it does not account for the fact that cointegration in prices among North American species of softwood lumber can be caused by common demand-side factors, such as residential construc- tion activity.
Article
This article revisits the question of whether the law of one price (LOP) holds for the United States lumber markets, with the most disaggregate data and a large number of price combinations for different products, regions, and species. We also paid close attention to issues related to how we should conduct unit root tests with a potential structural break, whether we should include intercept and time trend in a co-integration model, and what lag length should be chosen. After exhaustive investigations, we find overwhelming evidence supporting the LOP for the entire United States softwood lumber market. We believe that this finding has profound implications on our market modeling and policy analysis. FOR. SCI. 51(2):155–164.
Article
This paper reports on the development of autoregressive-integrated-moving-average (ARIMA) forecasting models for (i) various lumber cash prices, (ii) the lumber futures prices, and (iii) the basis series for the lumber cash prices. The ARIMA models are fitted to weekly data by employing Box-Jenkins (1970) time series modeling procedure. Relatively accurate shortrun forecasts are obtained with the cash and futures price series models; however, the utility of the basis series models appears dubious. Forest Sci. 23:268-280.
Article
This paper investigated the effectiveness of the lumber futures market in hedging unexpected price variations. The related optimum hedge ratio, i.e., the fraction of the cash position that should be hedged to minimize risk, was also studied. The measure of hedging effectiveness used was the correlation between cash and futures price, conditional on information available at the time of hedging. The analysis of weekly price data showed that during the period June 1980 to February 1985 optimum use of the lumber futures market could have reduced the variance in gain or loss by 50 to 90 percent. Longer hedges were generally more effective and so were those liquidated near the closure of the futures contract. The best strategy was to hedge the cash position entirely, except for hedges liquidated within 8 weeks of contract closure for which hedge ratios of 60 to 80 percent were most effective. Forest Sci. 32:634-642.