ArticlePDF Available

Geoeconomics with Chinese characteristics: the BRI and China’s evolving grand strategy

Authors:

Abstract

China has become the second largest economy in the world in a historically unprecedented space of time. Subsequently, China has begun to exert a form of geoeconomic influence that is changing the way we think about both the nature of international relations in the 21st century and about the precise uses China’s policymakers will put their growing power into. This paper explores these debates and China’s evolving approach to foreign and strategic policies through the prism of the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI). If the BRI becomes a reality it will quite literally cement China’s place at the centre of a regional network of production processes that will inevitability enhance China’s overall economic and geopolitical importance. At the very least, China’s ascent is forcing a reassessment about the nature of power and influence in the contemporary international system. Not only is the nature of economic organisation currently raising important theoretical and practical questions about the basis of international competition, but it is also becoming increasingly clear that the power and influence of national governments are largely determined by relative shifts in the balance of economic power, as much as it is by more traditional strategic factors.
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at
http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=reps20
Economic and Political Studies
ISSN: 2095-4816 (Print) 2470-4024 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/reps20
Geoeconomics with Chinese characteristics: the
BRI and China’s evolving grand strategy
Mark Beeson
To cite this article: Mark Beeson (2018): Geoeconomics with Chinese characteristics: the BRI and
China’s evolving grand strategy, Economic and Political Studies
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/20954816.2018.1498988
Published online: 03 Sep 2018.
Submit your article to this journal
View Crossmark data
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Geoeconomics with Chinese characteristics: the BRI and
Chinas evolving grand strategy
Mark Beeson
Political Science and International Relations, University of Western Australia, Perth, Australia
ABSTRACT
China has become the second largest economy in the world in a
historically unprecedented space of time. Subsequently, China has
begun to exert a form of geoeconomic influence that is changing
the way we think about both the nature of international relations
in the 21st century and about the precise uses Chinas policy-
makers will put their growing power into. This paper explores
these debates and Chinas evolving approach to foreign and stra-
tegic policies through the prism of the Belt and Road Initiative
(BRI). If the BRI becomes a reality it will quite literally cement
Chinas place at the centre of a regional network of production
processes that will inevitability enhance Chinas overall economic
and geopolitical importance. At the very least, Chinas ascent is
forcing a reassessment about the nature of power and influence
in the contemporary international system. Not only is the nature
of economic organisation currently raising important theoretical
and practical questions about the basis of international competi-
tion, but it is also becoming increasingly clear that the power and
influence of national governments are largely determined by rela-
tive shifts in the balance of economic power, as much as it is by
more traditional strategic factors.
ARTICLE HISTORY
Received 12 September 2017
Accepted 28 March 2018
KEYWORDS
Belt and Road Initiative;
grand strategy;
geoeconomics; geopolitics;
rise of China
Introduction
China has become the second largest economy in the world in a historically unprece-
dented space of time. Remarkable as this achievement is, it is not only Chinas sheer
material significance that has attracted so much attention of late: the feature of
Chinas ascent that has really begun to define recent commentary is what the
leadership of the Peoples Republic of China (PRC) will do with its growing power
and economic leverage (Heilmann and Schmidt 2014; Kastner 2016). In short, China
has begun to exert a form of geoeconomicinfluence that is changing the way we
think about both the nature of international relations in the 21st century and about
the precise uses Chinas policymakers will put their growing power into (Beeson and
Li 2015; Norris 2016; Blackwill and Harris 2016).
CONTACT Mark Beeson mark.beeson@uwa.edu.au Political Science and International Relations, University of
Western Australia, Perth, Australia
!2018 Economic and Political Studies
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES
https://doi.org/10.1080/20954816.2018.1498988
This paper explores these debates and Chinas evolving approach to foreign and
strategic policies through the prism of the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI). For some
observers, the BRI represents nothing less than a new Marshall Plan with Chinese
characteristics (Chen 2014). Equally significantly, perhaps, it is centred on a newly
important geographical arena. Even if such assessments prove to be somewhat over-
blown, there is no doubt that if the BRI is realised and that remains a moot point
at this stage it will be the most significant economic and strategic development in
the 21st century so far. Indeed, if the BRI becomes a reality it will quite literally
cement Chinas place at the centre of a regional network of production processes that
will inevitability enhance Chinas overall economic and geopolitical importance
(Beeson and Li 2016).
The general economic expansion and industrialisation of East Asia had already
forced us to rethink some of our most basic assumptions about the nature of eco-
nomic development (Stubbs 2005; Ozawa 2009). Now Chinas ascent is forcing a
reassessment about the nature of power and influence in the contemporary inter-
national system (Agnew 2005). Not only is the nature of economic organisation cur-
rently raising important theoretical and practical questions about the nature of
national economies and the basis of international competition (Baldwin 2016), but it
is also becoming increasingly clear that the power and influence of national govern-
ments is largely determined by relative shifts in the balance of economic power, as
much as it is by more traditional strategic factors.
To develop and illustrate these arguments the paper proceeds as follows. First, I
put the idea of geoeconomic influence in theoretical and historical contexts. The key
point here is that traditional geopolitics and geoeconomics have always been linked
(Strange 1994), but some historical circumstances are especially conducive to the
application of economic leverage and/or statecraft. Having established this conceptual
terrain, I explore how China is attempting to utilise its growing economic power
generally through an examination of the BRI in particular. Finally, I consider the
implications of Chinas economic re-emergence for extant power structures, especially
as they may determine the prospects for a process of hegemonic tradition.
Geoeconomics and geopolitics
It is hardly novel to claim that economic development and change have potentially
important geopolitical consequences. Indeed, Gilpin (1981), as a realist scholar, has
long argued that underlying material transformations and economic restructuring
have a concomitant impact on the distribution of power, upsetting the status quo and
potentially creating the preconditions for a hegemonic transition. While there is cur-
rently a good deal of renewed attention being given to the possible relevance of such
ideas in the context of the bilateral relationship between the US and China (Allison
2017), the reality is that the world has only witnessed one major international transi-
tion in the modern period. It is consequently difficult to make generalisations about
what the current economic and strategic expansion of China might mean for the
international system.
2 M. BEESON
Nevertheless, before we consider how Chinas rise may be transforming both its
own prospects and those of the international system more generally, it is worth mak-
ing a few general historical points as they can provide a comparative framework with
which to make sense of the contemporary period. The key points to make about
Americas earlier hegemonic ascent is that, firstly, it replaced a very similar power in
the shape of Britain, and one with limited capacity to resist. Even if Britain had been
more powerful, the fact that the US subscribed to similar values and ideas meant
there was less incentive to push back against a rising power in quite the same way.
Secondly, the US was initially reluctant to assume the hegemonic mantle, and it
would take the drastic international reordering and chaos triggered by the WWII to
make it clear to Americans that they could and perhaps should provide inter-
national leadership (Kindleberger 1973). Crucially, it was the USs overwhelming eco-
nomic importance in the post-war period that allowed it to impose itself on the
international system and create a highly institutionalised system that reflected its own
normative preferences (Beeson and Higgott 2005).
The reality that Americas dominant economic position allowed it to shape an inter-
national order that was conducive to its own national interestswas not only beneficial
to the US itself, however. Even critical scholars have pointed out that one of the rea-
sons the international order that the US largely created has proved so durable is that it
provided real benefits for other states, too (Cox 1987). The fact that the US had the
wherewithal to provide significant material assistance to many of the distressed econo-
mies of Western Europe and East Asia also helped entrench its dominant position and
influence. Put differently, Americas rapidly evolving post-war grand strategy, which
was primarily geared to containingthe spread of Soviet-inspired communism (Gaddis
1982), was reinforced by a distinctive form of statecraft in which geoeconomic power
was utilised to achieve geopolitical ends (Kunz 1997).
In this context, the Marshall Plan was in the right place at the right time. During
the crisis of 1947the very survival of a number of European countries as independ-
ent liberal-capitalist entities seemed in doubt as Europes devastated economies and
infrastructure struggled to cope with the aftermath of war (Milward 1984). Equally
significantly, the Soviet Union was not just a formidable economic and strategic com-
petitor, but a significant ideological rival. The interwar period had been marked by
an almost terminal crisis of capitalism that culminated in the WWII; the renaissance
and ultimate triumph of capitalism as the dominant form of global political and eco-
nomic organisation were far from assured. It was against this backdrop of economic
crisis and ideological rivalry that the Americans instituted the Marshall Plan. While
the immediate goal of the Marshall Plan was to provide a direct boost to Europes ail-
ing economies, in the eyes of its architects it was seen as the key to social harmony,
to the survival of private-enterprise capitalism, and to the preservation of political
democracy(Hogan 1987, 428).
At the outset, therefore, it is important to emphasise that Chinas Marshall Plan, if
it materialises, will operate in very different political and strategic circumstances. But
before we consider its possible practical implications and significance, it is important
to say something about the nature of geoeconomic power which changed international
circumstances that are seemingly making more important and influential in these days.
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES 3
From Geopolitics to Geoeconomics
In recent history, no event has been of greater long-term significance than the ending
of the Cold War. Although the former Soviet Union was the principal protagonist
while the Cold War persisted its main casualty when it ended, it is also important to
recognise its significance for the US and China. Not only was the US overwhelmingly
preoccupied with the ideological and strategic struggle that characterised the Cold
War period, but China was also effectively marginalised politically and economically
for decades. Truly, the PRC had its own problems and priorities to be content with
(Breslin 2007), but it is clear in retrospect that its economic development was held
back and its potential to play a larger international role was profoundly circumscribed
by the logic of the Cold Wars ideological rivalries (Naughton 1996).
One of the first observers to grasp the possible long-term significance of the Cold
Wars ending is Edward Luttwak. Writing in the immediate aftermath of the almost
entirely unpredicted and peaceful demise of the Soviet Union, Luttwak (1990) argues
that the decreased importance of traditional ideological and especially strategic rival-
ries mean that states would begin to prioritise economic development, which was rap-
idly becoming the locus of interstate rivalry and competition. Indeed, this would
provide a new rationale and raison d^
etre for states that were suddenly liberated from
the crushing, all-consuming confrontations of the Cold War. Other writers have use-
fully drawn attention to the potential use of economic statecraftbefore this (Baldwin
1985), but the declining importance and even utility of traditional military power
after the Cold War appeared to give a renewed and seemingly permanent importance
to economic rather than geostrategic instruments of influence.
We now understand, of course, that the peace dividendpromised by the Cold
Wars ending has proved difficult to realise, and that a rather old fashioned preoccu-
pation with military security and spending has continued to dominate the thinking
and actions of policymakers in many countries. In part, this can be explained by the
disastrous presidency of George W. Bush and the woefully misguided decision to
invade Iraq (Packer 2005), an action that destabilised the entire Middle East region
and led directly to the current international obsession with the threat of terrorism.
Significantly, even Japan, which for some observers represented the quintessential
exemplar of an entirely new kind of trading statethat had eschewed conventional
ideas of national security (Rosecrance 1986), has seemingly succumbed to the siren
song of traditional national security.
And yet it is important to recognise that for decades Japan did demonstrate that
other national developmental priorities were not only possible but actually highly
effective. Moreover, Japan provided a master class in acquiring overseas geoeconomic
influence despite the legacy of its actions during the WWII. Indeed, for some
observers, Japans economic success seemed to epitomise the changing logic of inter-
national competition: Japan achieved through foreign investment after the WWII
what it had been unable to achieve through force of arms (Hatch and Yamamura
1996). It is also important to recognise that the Japanese experience has provided
important policy ideas and models for Chinas leaders, too even if they might be
loath to admit to taking advice from such a source (Heilmann and Melton 2013).
Nevertheless, Chinas leaders are beginning to employ a range of strategies and
4 M. BEESON
initiatives that are attempting to achieve similar sorts of geoeconomic goals, albeit
with distinctive Chinese characteristics.
Geoeconomics in practice
Geoeconomics has recently become increasingly prominent in the academic literature.
It is not difficult to see why: the remarkable economic rise of China and the deter-
mination of its leaders to turn this material power into political and even ideational
influence take some explaining and geoeconomics offers a persuasive way of doing
so. There is, however, no complete agreement on quite what the term means or the
best way of conceptualising it. For some observers, geoeconomics is part of a trad-
itional form of great power politics. Hence, geoeconomics is applying economic
instruments to advance geopolitical ends(Blackwill and Harris 2016, 8). In this con-
ception, geoeconomics is realist power politics by other means; national interests
remain pre-eminent, and geoeconomics provides one increasingly important way of
pursuing them. As far as China is concerned, Blackwill and Harris (2016, 135) suggest
that the principal goal of its leadership is to foster asymmetrical economic depend-
ence on China among certain countries and once that is achieved to shape their
foreign policies in ways congenial to Chinas national interests.
More nuanced readings of emerging geoeconomics capture some of its complexity
and contradictions. For Cowen and Smith (2009,2425) changes in the nature of the
international system challenge geopolitical conceptions and may better be captured
today by a geo-economicconception of space, power and security, which sees geopol-
itical forms recalibrated by market logics geoeconomics recasts rather than simply
replaces geopolitical calculation. In this formulation, the sort of geoeconomic competi-
tion that Luttwak highlighted is the key to understanding contemporary international
relations. Not only does such competition now routinely occupy a range of actors
beyond the state, but it has the capacity to reshape the state itself and the thinking of
the political elites that claim to represent it.
Perhaps the principal manifestation of this possibility and its limitations can be
seen in Chinas experience in the recent reform era. On the one hand, as China has
been integrated more fully into a global capitalist economy dominated by the US and
the enduring institutional architecture it created in the aftermath of the WWII,
Chinas domestic structures have been transformed. The most important example of
this possibility occurred when China joined the World Trade Organisation (WTO), an
event that entrenched capitalist economic practices and norms in the PRC, and which
effectively snuffed out domestic opposition to further market-oriented reform (Breslin
2007). In this regard, there is little doubt that an enormous process of socialisation
has been occurring in China, and not just at the elite level. On the contrary, Chinais
a very different entity than it was 40 or even 20 years ago (Steinfeld 2010).
On the other hand, however, it is apparent that there are limits to this process.
Despite Chinas WTO accession occurring as a consequence of Americas geoeco-
nomic power, especially as exercised through institutions, China retains distinctive
characteristics that have proved impervious to wholesale reform. Indeed, one of the
most potentially significant consequences of Chinas economic and political
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES 5
transformation is that its leadership is beginning to assert itself internationally in pre-
cisely the same way that the US has for the past half century or more. Clearly, many
in China believe that this is an especially opportune time to assert the countrys lead-
ership, a belief that gained momentum in the aftermath of the American-made global
financial crisis(Ren 2017). The key questions in this context are about the sort of
norms and principles that China will seek to champion, and the ways in which its
elites will seek to promote them (Chin and Thakur 2010). In this context, a number
of points are especially important when thinking about the Chinese experience
generally and the prospects for and significance of the BRI in particular.
First, China especially under the leadership of Xi Jinping has clearly abandoned
Deng Xiaopings famous admonition about keeping a low profile to achieve something
(Yan 2014). Now, by contrast, Chinas elites are both increasingly confident about their
capabilities and their right to occupy a more central position in the mechanisms of glo-
bal governance. Indeed, one of the principal drivers of Chinas new assertiveness is the
sense that the existing institutional order reflects and entrenches a form of American
hegemony that works against Chinese interests and is designed to contain Chinas
international influence (Zhao 2013). Whatever the merits of this sort of analysis, there
is little doubt that it informs the thinking of many of the more influential actors in
Chinas non-transparent foreign policy making process (Jakobson and Knox 2010).
Second, the precise form these ambitions will take is a work-in-progress, and there
is a good deal of policy experimentation at both the domestic and international levels.
At the level of direct geoeconomic influence of a sort that the BRI looks certain to
consolidate, China has become an increasingly important and influential source of
direct investment and engagement from Africa to Latin America, as well as within
the Asianregion it has traditionally dominated (Das 2009). There are striking paral-
lels between Japans earlier expansion into Southeast Asia and Chinas current bilat-
eral ties with Africa in particular (Br
autigam and Tang 2014). While this relationship
is not always smooth or without its tensions and contradictions, Africa is providing
an important testing ground for Chinas evolving resource diplomacy and its efforts
to ensure long-term economic security and influence (Beeson, Soko, and Yong 2011).
Third, the precise form Chinas overseas engagement takes may have implications
for economic partners that are distinctive and different from those associated with
Anglo-Americanforms of neoliberal capitalism. As Jiang (2009, 592) observes, for
those who have faith in socialism with Chinese characteristics, Chinas reform expe-
riences in the past three decades can serve as a model for developing countries in
Africa on how to eliminate poverty and make strides in industrialisation. For
admirers of the so-called Beijing consensusthis is precisely what is so significant
about Chinas distinctive developmental experience: it represents an alternative path
to economic modernisation and expansion that is not burdened with the burdensome
demands of the better known and historically more influential Washington consensus
(Halper 2010; Lin 2011).
Finally, while China may be developing the sort of grand strategythat we associate
with the US and other great powers historically (Layne 2006), it is one predicated upon
distinctive Chinese priorities that are a reflection of its unique historical experience
(Goldstein 2005). The number one priority of Chinas grand strategy is the survival of
6 M. BEESON
the party-state and the leadership role of the Communist Party of China (CPC). As Qin
(2014, 309) points out, the security of the state and political system is the most import-
ant consideration in designing Chinas international strategy, a reality that shapes all
subsequent policy considerations. It is precisely this underlying logic which leads Wang
(2011, 74) to conclude that China, like Japan before it, has adopted a comprehensive
view of security that incorporates economic and non-traditional concerns with trad-
itional military and political interests. This distinctive nexus of strategic, economic and
political imperatives forms the core of Chinasnational interestas defined by the
party-state. Even if we recognise that national interestsare socially constructed, histor-
ically contingent manifestations of political power (Weldes 1996), that does not make
them any the less consequential when determining domestic and foreign policy.
While some of the claims made about Chinas influence are overblown and uncrit-
ical, the direction of travel seems clear: there is no doubt that Chinas leaders chafe
against some aspects of the existing order and are keen to either play a more promin-
ent role in the extant institutions or failing that create an alternative institutional
order of their own (Paradise 2016). Again, we need to recognise that this process is
still in its formative stages, but there are already important indications of the willing-
ness of Chinas elites to assume an international leadership role that is strikingly at
odds with former times. While this may be a measure of growing ambition, it is also
an equally telling indicator of the challenge of creating a viable alternative to the pre-
vailing order (Liao 2016). No initiative more clearly illustrates the possibilities and
constraints facing Chinese policymakers than the Asian Infrastructure Investment
Bank (AIIB), which may play a potentially crucial role in providing the financial
wherewithal for grandiose initiatives such as the BRI. Before examining the BRI itself,
therefore, it is important to explain the significance of the AIIB as it highlights key
issues that will determine the BRIs success.
Institutionalisation with Chinese characteristics
In 2014 at the Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation summit, President Xi Jinping pro-
posed establishing both the AIIB and a Free Trade Area of the Asia Pacific (FTAAP).
As Wang (2015) notes, both of these initiatives need to be seen in the context of a
geopolitical and geoeconomic competition with the US. In what Wang describes as
the biggest foreign policy shift in Beijing since 1989, he argues:
Xis strategy is a sophisticated and progressive one. Instead of directly challenging the
current existing international institutions, the Chinese are trying to create new platforms
that Beijing can control or substantially influence. Through these new initiatives, Beijing
aims to create a new international environment that is more favourable to China, one
that will limit strategic pressures from the United States In creating its own
alternatives, China maintains more control, and can make a greater impact Chinas
new strategy is to try to establish new institutions and platforms as tools for Beijing to
play the kind of role China cannot play in the ADB or IMF. (Wang 2015)
The emphasis on the geoeconomic aspect of Chinas foreign policy is also highlighted
by a prominent Chinese scholar Shi, who claims that China now uses two categories
of policy instruments: strategic militaryand strategic economic(Shi 2015).
An emphasis on the newly-prominent strategic economicelement of foreign policy
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES 7
will potentially have two major benefits for China: on the one hand, it may help to
reassure those neighbours alarmed by Chinas more assertive strategic policies, of
which there is a growing number. On the other, it will offer an alternative strategy
and institutional forum for those Chinese policymakers who have long chafed at the
dominance of the US and West more generally in the institutions like the IMF and
the World Bank (Clegg 2011).
Even in the East Asian region, which is the primary focus of Chinas pursuit of
greater international influence, it lacks a suitable outlet for its ambitions. Some of the
regions existing institutions, such as the Asian Development Bank, are dominated by
Chinas great rival Japan, and mean that China is comparatively uninfluential (Lim
and Vreeland 2013). Other institutional initiatives, such as the ASEAN Plus Three
(APT) grouping which includes all the states in the Association of Southeast Asian
Nations (ASEAN) in addition to Japan, South Korea and China itself are being
increasingly sidelined in the growing contest to represent the region (Beeson 2014).
Indeed, one of the most striking features of Chinas immediate neighbourhood is the
number of alternative definitions of the region in question and the most appropriate
organisation or initiative that might actually give expression to possible collective
goals. The net effect of these overlapping and competing institutions is that none of
them are especially effective (Beeson 2016).
More importantly from a Chinese perspective, none of the plethora of this regional
initiatives has the capacity to allow Chinas leaders to exercise leadership in the way
they might like. Even the APT, which China initially supported and looked set to
dominate, has been rendered less effective by the emergence of rival groupings such as
the East Asia Summit, which includes other major powers like India, Japan and, most
consequentially, the US (Terada 2012). Indeed, it is a concern about the prospects of
Chinese domination that has led other states to pursue a form of institutional bal-
ancingas a response to Chinas growing power (He 2015). The development of new
initiatives like the AIIB and the FTAAP is, therefore, partly a recognition of Chinas
difficulty in influencing the way by which extant organisations operate.
Given the complex patchwork of overlapping regional initiatives it is far from clear
how important or effective the AIIB will actually be. Although the ideational influ-
ence of the AIIB may be limited at this stage, it is important not to lose sight of its
symbolic and practical potential. At one level, the AIIB is clearly an attempt by
Chinese leaders to create an institution that reflects Chinas norms, preferences and
interests, in precisely the way some scholars have predicted (Chan, Lee, and Chan
2012). It is possible even likely that it will prove difficult for China to exert an
uncontested influence over the lending practices of the AIIB or the crucial condition-
ality that accompanies any loans and assistance. In order to win the support of coun-
tries such as the UK and Australia, the AIIB has had to take seriously concerns about
good governanceand transparency (Perlez 2015). Nevertheless, at another level, such
technical issues will not undermine the Banks attractiveness to potential borrowers in
Asia. On the contrary, the potentially less stringent conditionality associated with the
Beijing as opposed to the Washington Consensus makes the AIIB potentially much
more attractive to Asian leaders desperate for much-needed infrastructure investment
and not enamoured of liberal political or economic reforms (Browne 2015). It is
8 M. BEESON
important to remember that Chinas engagement with extant international institutions
has been driven by a desire to protect state sovereignty and Asian-style intervention-
ism, not to undermine it (Chin and Thakur 2010)an idea borrowers might find
entirely acceptable and palatable.
When Premier Li Keqiang indicated Chinas willingness to consult with relevant par-
ties across Asia and beyond regarding the formal establishment of the AIIB in 2014, the
attractiveness of the proposal was enhanced by Chinas willingness to provide US$100
billions of initial capital. Negotiations and consultations culminated in 21 countries sign-
ing a Memorandum of Understanding (MOU) for the establishment of the AIIB in
Beijing on 24 October 2014. In a major diplomatic coup for China and indication of its
growing geoeconomic influence, the UK became the first major Western power to lodge
an application to be a founding member on 12 March 2015, despite the clear unhappi-
ness of its key ally, the US (Anderlini 2015). Britainsleadwasrapidlyfollowedbyother
key European countries, including Germany, France and Italy. South Korea and
Australia also decided to join the AIIB in April 2015. Australias decision also occurred
despite the wishes of the US and after acrimonious cabinet divisions. The point to
emphasise again is that even for some of the USs most loyal and reliable allies, geoeco-
nomic issues could trump geopolitical ones at times (Branigan 2015).
Whatever the basis and merits of Americas concerns, a number of points are worth
emphasising. First, there are arguably limits to what the US can do to influence, much
less stop, a fundamental restructuring of global economic activity and the concomitant
results: not only do such processes reflect a long-term return to normalas China
reassumes its briefly interrupted regional ascendancy, but the US is itself a beneficiary
of, and highly dependent on Chinas economic development, significantly limiting its
capacity for pushback (Cohen and DeLong 2010; Altman and Hass 2010). Second,
there is still a significant need for investment finance in Southeast and Central Asia
where infrastructure frequently remains poor and an obstacle to economic develop-
ment and integration. The ADB (2012) suggests that countries in the Asian-Pacific
region need to invest about US$8 trillion in infrastructural building and replacement
between 2010 and 2020. Third, the BRI has the potential to help address the new nor-
malof more moderate Chinese growth by alleviating the overcapacity problems in the
domestic economy (Noesselt 2017). The final point to stress is that China is already
the largest source of international lending, with or without the AIIB. In fact, China
now provides more international development finance than all of the worlds six
major multilateral financial institutions put together(Kynge 2016). Put differently,
Chinas sheer material importance to the global economy has already transformed its
position and given it the potential to play a much more significant role in the inter-
national system, and not just in its immediate neighbourhood. The question is
whether the BRI is a feasible expression of Chinas growing international ambitions.
One belt, one road one ambition?
Seen in the context of long run economic restructuring, an expanding material geoe-
conomic influence, to say nothing of a rising tide of nationalism (Hornby 2017), the
development of a more self-confident and externally-oriented policy agenda was
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES 9
perhaps inevitable. It is no coincidence, therefore, that Chinas leaders, especially Xi
Jinping, have been talking about the possibility of re-establishing the fabled Silk
Roadand the old trade routes that were an important expression of Chinas long-
standing economic importance in Asia. Chinas BRI is the key manifestation of this
goal, which potentially marries direct and indirect sources of influence.
There are two principal aspects to the BRI, a Silk Road Economic Belt(SREB)
and a Maritime Silk Road(MSR). As the name suggests, the MSR is designed to
more effectively link and integrate the maritime states of Southeast and South Asia in
particular. The SREB, by contrast, is intended to re-establish and modernise trad-
itional overland connections with Central and South Asia, ultimately linking them to
both China itself and ultimately to Europe. An integrated network of ports, railways
and roads of the sort that China has great experience in delivering is envisaged, a
development that will consolidate Chinas place at the centre of economic activity
across much of Asia (Pitlo 2015). The seriousness with which the Chinese leadership
is taking this initiative can be gauged from the fact that the BRI was included in the
comprehensive reform blueprint of the Party leadership, and adopted as a key policy
priority before 2020 (Central Committee of the Communist Party of China 2013).
Although it is too soon to judge how effectively such grand ambitions will be real-
ised, some predictable implications and consequences of BRIs possible trajectory are
already becoming clear. It is also clear that China has both the state capacity and the
practical experience to make such a project a reality: key agencies, such as the
National Development and Reform Commission (NRDC), have developed detailed
plans for the implementation of specific aspects of the BRI. It is important to empha-
sise that despite the shift to a more market-oriented economy, the state and its devel-
opmental agencies continues to play a major role in the overall coordination of
economic development. As Heilmann and Melton (2013, 581583) note:
Chinas planning system evolved alongside the economic transition and remains central
to almost all domains of public policy making and the political institutions that have
fostered Chinas high-speed growth and economic stability the very essence of state
development planning has been preserved in China as a governmental effort at strategic
policy coordination, resource mobilisation and macroeconomic control.
Equally importantly, Chinas domestic record of economic expansion and the cre-
ation of domestic infrastructure are unparalleled. Indeed, so extensive has Chinas
capacity and need to deliver continuing infrastructure and other forms of domestic
investment become to overall development that some consider that it has actually
become a liability. Chinas infamous ghost citiesand the perverse incentive struc-
tures that continue to encourage such developments at the provincial government
level are frequently cited as the most glaring illustration of the drawback of breakneck
development (Walter and Howie 2011). Chinas response to the global financial crisis
of 2008, when a massive programme of domestic investment was unleashed, has
entrenched the problems of overcapacity and a growing economic and political reli-
ance on unsustainable internal development (Jiang 2015).
This backdrop of growing concerns about the sustainability of Chinas domestic
growth model has led some observers to claim that one of the BRIs principal attrac-
tions is its potential to solve the growing problem of surplus domestic capacity (Lo
10 M. BEESON
2015). While this may, indeed, be desirable from the perspective of a government
that derives much of its authority and legitimacy from its capacity to sustain rising
living standards and economic stability (Yang and Zhao 2015), shifting domestic
problems overseas is also fraught with potential long-term difficulties. As Huang
(2016, 321) points out, dumping excess capacity to the Belt & Roadcountries could
spoil the entire game. This is a possibility that is already beginning to worry some
foreign governments, and not just in those countries that are likely to feel the direct
impact of the BRI. On the contrary, many governments in the European Union are
concerned about the impact of state-subsidised competition on the still fragile and
under-performing economies of Western Europe (Casarini 2016). European
responses, albeit varied and uncoordinated, are a reminder that foreign reactions to
Chinas plans will ultimately determine its success or failure.
The BRI is a two-way street
If there is one thing Chinas leaders ought to appreciate, it is that exerting inter-
national influence and realising grand strategic ambitions is not simply dependent on
the actions of the dominant partner. On the contrary, as Chinas preoccupation with
American hegemonismreminds us, the actions of subordinate states are the critical
determinants of the way in which various foreign policy initiatives and hegemonic
goals are realised (Deng 2001). There are already some doubts about Chinas capacity
to exert the same sort of soft powerthat many observers especially in the US
(Nye 2004)saw as a key element of the success and durability of American influ-
ence (Beeson and Xu 2015). Although Chinas leaders might like to think of them-
selves as having more in common with the South, and states in the periphery
rather than the Western core, the reality is that Chinas growing international eco-
nomic presence has already generated a degree of resistance and concerns about neo-
colonialism (Lumumba-Kasongo 2011).
Such considerations are important given that many observers view the BRI as the
quintessential manifestation of Chinas potential economic leverage and more pro-
active approach to foreign policy-making more generally (Clarke 2017). This is an
especially important consideration in the context of Norriss(2016, 61) claim that
Chinas growing economic stature has enabled it to shift from a grand strategy that
merely sought to enable its economic goals to one that can begin to leverage its grow-
ing economic power to achieve foreign policy goals that previously may have been
out of reach. While China is plainly much more influential than it once was, it is
also apparent that there are potentially major contradictions in the rationale for, and
application of, some of Chinas ambitious goals, especially where geoeconomic and
geopolitical goals intersect.
Despite the supposed importance of the BRICS grouping, for example, which
includes Brazil, Russia, India and South Africa in addition to China itself, there are
underlying tensions between its members, not least because of Chinas dominant pos-
ition (Pant 2013). The recent flare up of territorial tensions between India and China
is a reminder of the tenuous nature of their new partnership (Buckley and Barry 2017),
a relationship that may be stretched to breaking point because of Pakistans prominent
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES 11
role in the evolving BRI blueprint (Afridi and Khalid 2016). It is also important to rec-
ognise that for China one of the principal drivers of its Westward marchis securing
its own borders and minimising the threat of internal instability posed by Xingjiang
(Wang 2012; Clarke 2005). Even if Chinas neighbours can be persuaded that its for-
eign policies are driven primarily by domestic security and developmental imperatives
rather than hegemonic ambitions, the prospect of achieving something close to control
of Halford Mackinders fabled heartlandis likely to be just as alarming to traditional
regional rival Russia as it is for the US (Fallon 2015).
One of the most critical tests of the efficacy of the BRI will be its reception in
Southeast Asia. Whatever one may think about the legitimacy of Chinas territorial
claims in the South China Sea, their inherently threatening nature and Chinas will-
ingness to use its growing military capabilities to reinforce them ought to provoke a
major reaction in Southeast Asia generally and from the ASEAN in particular
(Hayton 2014). In reality, however, ASEANs response has been fitful, incoherent and
ineffective. In part, this has occurred as a direct consequence of a highly successful
policy of divide and rule on Chinas part: states, such as Cambodia in particular, are
in favour of Chinese policies (Kynge, Haddou, and Peel 2016), making any unified
policy position on the part of ASEAN even more difficult than usual (Beeson 2015).
Likewise, the Philippines under the erratic leadership of Rodrigo Duterte has back-
tracked from its high-profile opposition to Chinas claims, despite winning a notable
legal victory at the Permanent Court of Arbitration in The Hague. Even more signifi-
cantly from the perspective of the long-term strategic trajectory of the region, per-
haps, Duterte has moved toward China and away from its traditional ally, the US
(Moss 2016).
Admirers of Chinas policy especially in the PRC itself have tended to stress
the Chinas governments constructive contribution to regional development, which
will be reinforced by the MSR in Southeast Asia, and the generally positive implica-
tions of Chinaswin-windiplomacy (Tseng 2016; Lu 2016). While there is little
doubt that Southeast Asia does need significant infrastructure development, the MSR
initiative is only likely to deepen the inherent policy differences between ASEANs
maritime and mainland states. Perhaps the most revealing bellwether state in this
context is Vietnam, which occupies an ambiguous position as both a mainland and
maritime state, but one with an enormous stake in the resolution of the maritime ter-
ritorial disputes. Despite initially seeming to move toward greater strategic ties with
the US as a way of balancing Chinas growing influence (Perlez 2016), more recently
it seems a rapprochement may be possible with China, its vitally important and his-
torically problematic neighbour (Nguyen 2017). If China can re-establish cordial ties
with Vietnam, given the fraught nature of recent relations, the auguries for its wider
regional ambitions look promising.
Concluding remarks
Chinas place in the global economy and the institutions that seek to manage it have
changed significantly over the last few years. Indeed, China currently looks more of a
responsible stakeholderthan does the US under the leadership of Donald Trump
12 M. BEESON
(Wolf 2017). The fact that Chinas leaders can make a case to be the champions of
globalisation in the absence of American leadership is a remarkable turn of events
and one that illustrates how rapidly some of the seemingly central pillars of the
existing order can shift (Browne 2016). While there is no doubt that Xi Jinping has
placed his personal stamp on the way in which China engages with the wider world
(Chen and Wei 2017), it is important to recognise why this matters in quite the way
it does: without an underlying transformation in the structure and scale of the
Chinese economy the influence of any Chinese leader, no matter how able or
proactive, would be significantly reduced.
Chinas economic rise has given Chinas leaders generally, and Xi in particular,
much greater potential agency. It is clear that they are keen to use it to restore
Chinas place at the forefront of international diplomacy and great power politics.
Recovering Chinas former dominant position, especially in its own region, is plainly
something that is widely supported by both the leadership of the PRC and by the
population more generally, even if there is some debate about its impact on foreign
policy (Johnston 2017). What we can be sure of is that Chinas enhanced geoeco-
nomic power and influence is clearly allowing it to pursue and achieve these ambi-
tions much more quickly than many observers had imagined possible only a decade
or two ago. The question now is how Chinas leaders will attempt to pursue such
goals and what role key initiatives such as the BRI will play in helping them realise
such ambitions.
For analysts such as Miller (2017, 11, 18), there is no doubt that
President Xis mission is to return China to what he regards as its natural, rightful and
historical position as the greatest power in Asia. That does not mean that China has to
replace the US as the worlds only superpower, but it does mean that Asia has to
predominate in its own backyard the goal of Chinas economic diplomacy is
to create a modern tribute system, with all roads literally leading to Beijing.
The inauguration of the BRI suggests that the conception of Chinasbackyardhas
expanded far beyond the boundaries of the original tribute system. Now Chinas lead-
ers are looking to expand their influence beyond Northeast and even Southeast Asia,
and to Central Asia and beyond. In some ways this is entirely predictable, even if
some regional powers struggle to deal with its implications for them and for the
extant security architecture dominated by the US. This is, after all, what established
or aspirant great powers do. It is precisely what the US did in the WWII aftermath,
when its changed economic status meant that its leaders felt compelled to assume
responsibility for the maintenance and management of the international order.
We should not be surprised about China attempting to play a similar sort of role
given its history and sense of exceptionalism (Zhang 2013)another trait it shares
with the US. In this context, the BRI has immense symbolic and practical importance.
If it succeeds and given Chinas recent development, it would be foolish to bet
against such an outcome it will not only restore Chinas diplomatic fortunes, but
will also reinforce its geoeconomic influence for the foreseeable future. Barring a not
impossible economic or political upheaval in China itself, the BRI may be the most
tangible manifestation yet of Chinas seemingly unstoppable rise to regional primacy.
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES 13
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.
References
ADB (Asian Development Bank). 2012. Infrastructure for Supporting Inclusive Growth and
Poverty Reduction in Asia. Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Afridi, Manzoor Khan, and Iram Khalid. 2016. Politics of Interdependence: A Case of China-
Pakistan Economic Corridor.South Asian Studies 31 (2): 277290.
Agnew, John. 2005. Hegemony: The New Shape of Global Power. Philadelphia: Temple
University Press.
Allison, Graham. 2017. Destined for War: Can America and China Escape Thucydidess Trap?
Boston: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.
Altman, Roger C., and Richard N. Hass. 2010. American Profligacy and American Power:
The Consequences of Fiscal Irresponsibility.Foreign Affairs 89 (6): 2534.
Anderlini, Jamil. 2015. UK Move to Join China-led Bank a Surprise Even to Beijing.
Financial Times, 26 March.
Baldwin, David A. 1985. Economic Statecraft. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Baldwin, Richard A. 2016 The Great Convergence: Information Technology and the New
Globalization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Beeson, Mark. 2014. Regionalism and Globalization in East Asia: Politics, Security and
Economic Development, 2nd ed. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Beeson, Mark. 2015. Can ASEAN Cope with China?Journal of Current Southeast Asian
Affairs 35 (1): 528.
Beeson, Mark. 2016. Multilateralism in East Asia: Less than the Sum of Its Parts?Global
Summitry 2 (1): 5470.
Beeson, Mark, and Richard Higgott. 2005. Hegemony, Institutionalism and US Foreign
Policy: Theory and Practice in Comparative Historical Perspective.Third World Quarterly
26 (7): 11731188.
Beeson, Mark, and Fujian Li. 2015. What Consensus? Geopolitics and Policy Paradigms in
China and the US.International Affairs 91 (1): 93109.
Beeson, Mark, and Fujian Li. 2016. Chinas Place in Regional and Global Governance: A New
World Comes into View.Global Policy 7 (4): 491499.
Beeson, Mark, Mills Soko, and Wang Yong. 2011. The New Resource Politics: Can Australia
and South Africa Accommodate China?International Affairs 87 (6): 13651384.
Beeson, Mark, and Shaomin Xu. 2015. Leadership with Chinese Characteristics: What Role
for Soft Power?In Global and Regional Leadership of BRICS Countries, edited by Stephen
Kingah and Cintia Quiliconi, 169188. London: Springer.
Blackwill, Robert D, and Jennifer M Harris. 2016. War by Other Means: Geoeconomics and
Statecraft. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Branigan, Tania. 2015. Support for China-led Development Bank Grows Despite US
Opposition.The Guardian, 14 March.
Bräutigam, Deborah, and Xiaoyang Tang. 2014. “‘Going Global in Groups: Structural
Transformation and Chinas Special Economic Zones Overseas.World Development 63:
7891.
Breslin, Shaun. 2007. China and the Global Economy. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Browne, Andrew. 2015. Developing Countries See Hope in Beijing-led Bank.Wall Street
Journal, 24 March.
Browne, Andrew. 2016. Western Retreat Makes Room for Chinese Advance.The Wall Street
Journal, 5 July.
Buckley, Chris, and Ellen Barry. 2017. China Tells India that It Wont Back Down in Border
Dispute.New York Times, 4 August.
14 M. BEESON
Casarini, Nicola. 2016. When All Roads Lead to Beijing. Assessing Chinas New Silk Road
and Its Implications for Europe.The International Spectator 51 (4): 95108.
Central Committee of the Communist Party of China. 2013. Decision of the Central
Committee of the Communist Party of China on Some Major Issues Concerning
Comprehensively Deepening the Reform.http://www. china. org. cn/china/third_plenary_
session/2014-01/16/content_31212602. htm
Chan, Gerald, Pak. K. Lee, and Lai-Ha Chan. 2012. China Engages Global Governance: A New
World Order in the Making? London: Routledge.
Chen, Dingding 2014. ChinasMarshall PlanIs Much More.The Diplomat 10. https://thedi-
plomat.com/2014/11/chinas-marshall-plan-is-much-more/
Chen, Te-Ping, and Lingling Wei. 2017. Chinas Xi Jinping Seizes Role as Leader on
Globalization.The Wall Street Journal, 17 January.
Chin, Greg, and Ramesh Thakur. 2010. Will China Change the Rules of Global Order?The
Washington Quarterly 33 (4): 119138.
Clarke, Michael. 2005. Chinas Strategy in Xinjiang and Central Asia: Toward Chinese
Hegemony in the Geographical Pivot of History?Issues & Studies 41 (2): 75118.
Clarke, Michael. 2017. The Belt and Road Initiative: Chinas New Grand Strategy?Asia
Policy 24 (1): 7179.
Clegg, Jenny. 2011. China at the Global Summit Table: Rule-taker, Deal-wrecker or Bridge-
builder?Contemporary Politics 17 (4): 447465.
Cohen, Stephen S., and J. Bradford DeLong. 2010. The End of Influence: What Happens When
Other Countries Have the Money. New York: Basic Books.
Cowen, Deborah, and Neil Smith. 2009. After Geopolitics? From The Geopolitical Social to
Geoeconomics.Antipode 41 (1): 2248.
Cox, Robert W. 1987. Production, Power, and World Order: Social Forces in the Making of
History. New York: Columbia University Press.
Das, Dilip K. 2009. A Chinese Renaissance in an Unremittingly Integrating Asian Economy.
Journal of Contemporary China 18 (59): 321338.
Deng, Yong. 2001. Hegemon on the Offensive: Chinese Perspectives on US Global Strategy.
Political Science Quarterly 116 (3): 343365.
Fallon, Theresa. 2015. The New Silk Road: Xi Jinpings Grand Strategy for Eurasia.American
Foreign Policy Interests 37 (3): 140147.
Gaddis, John Lewis. 1982. Strategies of Containment: A Critical Appraisal of Postwar American
Security Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Gilpin, Robert. 1981. War and Change in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Goldstein, Avery. 2005. Rising to the Challenge: Chinas Grand Strategy and International
Security. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Halper, Stefan. 2010. The Beijing Consensus: How Chinas Authoritarian Model Will Dominate
the Twenty-first Century. New York: Basic Books.
Hatch, Walter and Yamamura, Kozo. 1996. Asia in Japans Embrace: Building a Regional
Production Alliance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hayton, Bill. 2014. The South China Sea: The Struggle for Power in Asia. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
He, Kai. 2015. Contested Regional Orders and Institutional Balancing in the Asia Pacific.
International Politics 52 (2): 208222.
Heilmann, Sebastian, and Oliver Melton. 2013. The Reinvention of Development Planning in
China, 19932012.Modern China 39 (6): 580628.
Heilmann, Sebastian, and Dirk H. Schmidt. 2014. Chinas Foreign Political and Economic
Relations: An Unconventional Global Power. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.
Hogan, Michael J. 1987. The Marshall Plan: America, Britain, and the Reconstruction of
Western Europe, 19471952. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hornby, Lucy. 2017. China Battles to Control Growing Online Nationalism.Financial Times,
9 January.
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES 15
Huang, Yasheng. 2016. Understanding Chinas Belt & Road Initiative: Motivation, Framework
and Assessment.China Economic Review 40: 314321.
Jakobson, Linda, and Dean Knox. 2010. New Foreign Policy Actors in China.SIPRI Policy
Paper 26.
Jiang, Wenran. 2009. Fuelling the Dragon: Chinas Rise and Its Energy and Resources
Extraction in Africa.The China Quarterly 199 (1): 585609.
Johnston, Alastair Iain. 2017. Is Chinese Nationalism Rising? Evidence from Beijing.
International Security 41 (3): 743.
Kastner, Scott L. 2016. Buying Influence? Assessing the Political Effects of Chinas
International Trade.Journal of Conflict Resolution 60 (6): 9801007.
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1973. The World in Depression 1929-1939. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Kunz, Diane B. 1997. Butter and Guns: Americas Cold War Economic Diplomacy. New York:
Free Press.
Kynge, James. 2016. China Becomes Global Leader in Development Finance.Financial
Times, 17 May.
Kynge, James, Leila Haddou, and Michael Peel. 2016. How China Bought Its Way into
Cambodia.Financial Times, 8 September.
Layne, Christopher. 2006. The Peace of Illusions: American Grand Strategy From 1940 to the
Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Liao, Nien-chung Chan. 2016. The Sources of Chinas Assertiveness: The System, Domestic
Politics or Leadership Preferences?International Affairs 92 (4): 817833.
Lim, Daniel Yew Mao, and James Raymond Vreeland. 2013. Regional Organizations and
International Politics: Japanese Influence over the Asian Development Bank and the UN
Security Council.World Politics 65 (1): 3472.
Lin, Justin Yifu. 2011. China and the Global Economy.China Economic Journal 4 (1): 114.
Lo, Chi. 2015. Chinas Silk Road Strategy: The Opportunities and Pitfalls of Killing Three
Birds with One Stone.The International Economy 29 (4): 5455.
Lu, Jianren. 2016. The 21st Century Maritime Silk Road and China-ASEAN Industry
Cooperation.International Journal of China Studies 7 (3): 375389.
Lumumba-Kasongo, Tukumbi. 2011. China-Africa Relations: A Neo-imperialism or A Neo-
colonialism? A Reflection.African and Asian Studies 10 (23): 234266.
Luttwak, Edward. 1990. From Geopolitics to Geo-economics.The National Interest Summer:
1723.
Miller, Tom. 2017. Chinas Asian Dream: Empire Building along the New Silk Road. London:
Zed Books.
Milward, Alan S. 1984. The Reconstruction of Western Europe, 194551. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Moss, Trefor. 2016. Philippine Presidents Shift on U.S. Alliance Worries Military.The Wall
Street Journal, 16 September.
Naughton, Barry 1996. Growing out of the Plan: Chinese Economic Reform, 1978-1993.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Nguyen, Minh Quang. 2017. The Resurgence of China-Vietnam Ties.The Diplomat, 25
January. https://thediplomat.com/2017/01/the-resurgence-of-china-vietnam-ties/
Noesselt, Nele. 2017. Introduction: New Normalunder Xi Jinping.Journal of Chinese
Political Science 22 (3): 321325.
Norris, William J. 2016. Chinese Economic Statecraft: Commercial Actors, Grand Strategy, and
State Control. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Nye, Joseph S. 2004. Soft Power: The Means to Success in World Politics. New York: Public
Affairs.
Ozawa, Terutomo. 2009. The Rise of Asia: The Flying GeeseTheory of Tandem Growth and
Regional Agglomeration. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Packer, George. 2005. The Assassins Gate: America in Iraq. New York: Farrar, Strauss and
Giroux.
16 M. BEESON
Pant, Harsh. 2013. The BRICS Fallacy.The Washington Quarterly 36 (3): 91105.
Paradise, James F. 2016. The Role of Parallel Institutionsin Chinas Growing Participation
in Global Economic Governance.Journal of Chinese Political Science 21 (2): 149175.
Perlez, Jane. 2015. New China-led Bank Pledges to Fend off Graft.New York Times, 11
April.
Perlez, Jane. 2016. Why Might Vietnam Let U.S. Military Return China?New York Times, 19
May.
Pitlo, Lucio Blanco. 2015. ChinasOne Belt, One Roadto Where?The Diplomat, 17
February.
Qin, Yaqing. 2014. Continuity through Change: Background Knowledge and Chinas
International Strategy.The Chinese Journal of International Politics 7 (3): 285314.
Ren, Xiao. 2017. The G20: Emerging Chinese Leadership in Global Governance?Global
Policy 8 (4): 433442.
Rosecrance, Richard. 1986. The Rise of the Trading State: Commerce and Conquest in the
Modern World. New York: Basic Books.
Shi, Yinhong. 2015. Chinas Complicated Foreign Policy.European Council on Foreign
Relations, 31 March.
Steinfeld, Edward S. 2010. Playing Our Game: Why Chinas Rise Doesnt Threaten the West.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Strange, Susan. 1994. States and Markets, 2nd ed. London: Pinter Publishers.
Stubbs, Richard. 2005. Rethinking Asias Economic Miracle. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Terada, Takashi. 2012. ASEAN Plus Three: Becoming More Like a Normal Regionalism?In
The Routledge Handbook of Asian Regionalism, edited by Mark Beeson and Richard Stubbs,
364375. London: Routledge.
Tseng, Hui-yi Katherine. 2016. Re-contemplating the South China Sea Issue: Sailing with the
Wind of the 21st Century Maritime Silk Road.The Chinese Journal of Global Governance 2
(1): 6395.
Walter, Carl E., and Fraser J. T. Howie. 2011. Red Capitalism: The Fragile Financial
Foundations of Chinas Extraordinary Rise. Singapore: Wiley.
Wang, Jisi. 2011. Chinas Search for a Grand Strategy.Foreign Affairs 90 (2): 6879.
Wang, Jisi. 2012. “‘Marching Westwards: The Rebalancing of Chinas Geostrategy.
International and Strategic Studies 73: 111.
Wang, Zhen. 2015. Chinas Alternative Diplomacy.The Diplomat, 30 January. https://thedi-
plomat.com/2015/01/chinas-alternative-diplomacy/
Weldes, Jutta. 1996. Constructing National Interests.European Journal of International
Relations 2 (3): 275318.
Wolf, Martin. 2017. Donald Trump and the Surrendering of US Leadership.Financial Times,
30 May.
Yan, Xuetong. 2014. From Keeping a Low Profile to Striving for Achievement.The Chinese
Journal of International Politics 7 (2): 153184.
Yang, Hongxing, and Dingxin Zhao. 2015. Performance Legitimacy, State Autonomy and
Chinas Economic Miracle.Journal of Contemporary China 24 (91): 6482.
Yang, Jiang. 2015. Vulgarisation of Keynesianism in Chinas Response to the Global Financial
Crisis.Review of International Political Economy 22 (2): 360390.
Zhang, Feng. 2013. The Rise of Chinese Exceptionalism in International Relations.European
Journal of International Relations 19 (2): 305328.
Zhao, Suisheng. 2013. Delicate Balance of Power in the Asia-Pacific: The Obama
Administrations Strategic Rebalance and the Transformation of USChina Relationship.
Economic and Political Studies 1 (2): 109133.
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES 17
... Inspirada en la histórica Ruta de la Seda (RS), conocida por la travesía de Marco Polo que realizó en la Edad Media entre el continente de Europa y Asia Oriental, más adelante el Pacifico Meridional y América del Sur es influenciada por la actual IFR. Esta iniciativa no solo busca promover el comercio y la inversión, sino también fortalecer la influencia global de China, siendo comparada por algunos críticos con el Plan Marshall estadounidense (Beeson, 2018). ...
Article
Full-text available
La finalidad de este estudio es examinar las tendencias de la inversión china dentro del contexto de la Iniciativa de la Franja y la Ruta (IFR); además de reconocer las oportunidades que surgen para América Latina. Para ello, se recopiló la literatura que sintetiza las relaciones entre estas dos economías. Asimismo, se recurrió a diversas fuentes de información para evaluar los proyectos chinos en diversas regiones y compararlos con los de América Latina. Los resultados confirman un fuerte dinamismo de China, aunque recientemente suavizado por una mayor adversidad al riego. A su vez, hay un importante impulso con algunas grandes inversiones en la región; sobre todo en Sudamérica. Se concluye que la región posee condiciones favorables para capitalizar las oportunidades generadas por la IFR.
Article
Full-text available
The economic rise of China has changed the global economy. The authors explore China’s transformation from a low-cost manufacturing hub to an increasingly innovation- and service driven economy. Major growth drivers for the period 2010–2025 are analysed, including the paradigms of “Made in China” and the “Dual Circulation Strategy”. The export intensity of China’s economy is declining overall, with a tendency towards greater regional diversification and a gradual decoupling from North America and the European Union. At the same time, trade and investment activities are increasingly geared to the Belt and Road Initiative. Furthermore, labour and energy cost advantages for manufacturing operations in China are likely to diminish in the coming years, calling into question China’s attractiveness as a global manufacturing hub. In this regard, the further development of regional and industrial clusters is pivotal for China to enhance its global competitiveness and remain an attractive destination for foreign direct investment (FDI) in the medium term. On the other hand, high productivity in science and technology and rich deposits of critical minerals put China in a favourable position in advanced industries. Important challenges include the still wide development gap between rural and urban areas, the structural mismatch in the labour market, with persistently high youth unemployment, and the race to achieve carbon neutrality by 2060.
Article
This study revisits the relationship between trade and growth, emphasizing the functions of the global value chain (GVC). This is a pioneer study to empirically evaluate the impact of GVC trade on the economic growth of the South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC) nations from the perspective of the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI). The objective of this article is to analyze the potential contribution of BRI in the development of these countries backward, forward and sectoral-level GVC participation. We employed second-generation econometric techniques for this empirical analysis over the period 1990–2022. To ensure the robustness of the results of cross-sectional autoregressive distributed lag (CS-ARDL), we used the augmented mean group (AMG) and common correlated effects mean group (CCEMG) models. The results indicate that forward and backward GVC involvement increases economic growth for SAARC countries. On the contrary, due to improper implementation of domestic policies, economic environment and inadequate absorptive capacity, GVC participation comes with a negative impact on the economic growth of the sample countries. The sectoral GVC trade in manufacturing industries is linked to a favourable impact on growth, while sectoral GVC trade-in service shows a negative association with gross domestic product (GDP). The results of our analysis demonstrate that GVCs are a driver of economic growth. Countries can unlock potential gains by implementing policies that promote participation in GVCs and by strengthening domestic fundamentals through regional collaborations within the BRI.
Article
India–Japan relations over the last two decades have become a regionally and globally oriented ‘strategic partnership’ from a narrow bilateral relationship. A key factor driving this transformation has been the discourse of the Indo-Pacific regional construct. Considering the overwhelming space occupied by maritime affairs in the bilateral strategic agenda, describing contemporary India–Japan relations as an India–Japan Indo-Pacific Strategic Partnership is justified. The article attempts to provide an evolutionary account of the India–Japan Indo-Pacific strategic partnership. In doing so, it identifies four phases in the evolution of the partnership: conception, actualisation, consolidation, and resilience, corresponding to the evolution of the Indo-Pacific concept from a geographic idea to a strategic concept to a regional order framework.
Article
China, as one of the influential states in South Asia, has recently proposed a new strategy known as the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI). This development, along with China's increasing presence in South Asia, requires critical analysis. China's rapid engagement with South Asian states, has a significant impact on the geopolitical landscape of the region. Bangladesh, being an important state in South Asia, attracts the attention of powerful nations seeking to assert their influence. Over the past few years, China has emerged as one of Bangladesh's major economic and development partners. However, it is crucial to recognize that Chinese involvement in Bangladesh goes beyond mere economic cooperation and encompasses broader geopolitical, geostrategic and geoeconomic interests. It seems China’s south Asia policy shift from earlier landscape. Consequently, China's engagement with Bangladesh has implications not only for the trade but also for the wider geopolitical dynamics of South Asia. This research seeks to elucidate the economic ties between Bangladesh and China and examine their impact, influence, and relevance. This research aims to explore China's new South Asian policy by using the China-Bangladesh relationship as an illustrative example.
Book
When Strategies of Containment was first published, the Soviet Union was still a superpower, Ronald Reagan was president of the United States, and the Berlin Wall was still standing. This updated edition of Gaddis' classic carries the history of containment through the end of the Cold War. Beginning with Franklin D. Roosevelt's postwar plans, Gaddis provides a thorough critical analysis of George F. Kennan's original strategy of containment, NSC-68, The Eisenhower-Dulles "New Look," the Kennedy-Johnson "flexible response" strategy, the Nixon-Kissinger strategy of d'etente, and now a comprehensive assessment of how Reagan-- and Gorbachev-- completed the process of containment, thereby bringing the Cold War to an end. He concludes, provocatively, that Reagan more effectively than any other Cold War president drew upon the strengths of both approaches while avoiding their weaknesses. A must-read for anyone interested in Cold War history, grand strategy, and the origins of the post-Cold War world.
Book
“China”, Napoleon once remarked, “is a sleeping lion. Let her sleep, for when she wakes she will shake the world.” In 2014, President Xi Jinping triumphantly declared the lion had awakened. Under his leadership, China is pursuing a dream to restore its historical position as the dominant power in Asia. From the Mekong River Basin to the Central Asian steppe, China is flexing its economic muscles for strategic ends. By setting up new regional financial institutions, Beijing is challenging the post-World War II order established under the watchful eye of Washington. And by funding and building roads, railways, ports and power lines-a New Silk Road across Eurasia and through the South China Sea and Indian Ocean-China aims to draw its neighbours ever tighter into its embrace. Combining a geopolitical overview with on-the-ground reportage from a dozen countries, China’s Asian Dream offers a fresh perspective on the rise of China’ and asks: what does it means for the future of Asia?
Book
War and Change in World Politics introduces the reader to an important new theory of international political change. Arguing that the fundamental nature of international relations has not changed over the millennia, Professor Gilpin uses history, sociology, and economic theory to identify the forces causing change in the world order. The discussion focuses on the differential growth of power in the international system and the result of this unevenness. A shift in the balance of power - economic or military - weakens the foundations of the existing system, because those gaining power see the increasing benefits and the decreasing cost of changing the system. The result, maintains Gilpin, is that actors seek to alter the system through territorial, political, or economic expansion until the marginal costs of continuing change are greater than the marginal benefits. When states develop the power to change the system according to their interests they will strive to do so- either by increasing economic efficiency and maximizing mutual gain, or by redistributing wealth and power in their own favour.