Conference PaperPDF Available

Dynamic EROI of the global energy system in future scenarios of transition to renewable energies

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

The transition from fossil fuels to Renewable Energy Sources (RES) is an indispensable condition to achieve sustainable socioeconomic systems. Despite their indisputable environmental benefits, their technical performance can be, in some cases, worse than those of fossil fuels. This is the case of the Energy Return on Energy Invested (EROI). Much work has been carried out to estimate the EROI of individual RES technologies; fierce debates about methodological issues are still not closed. In this work, we approach this issue by dynamically estimating the EROI of the whole energy system in future scenarios of transition to renewables. For this, we apply the global MEDEAS-World simulation model, which computes the dynamic EROI (standard, EROIst) of individual renewable technologies as a function of the associated energy requirements to build the infrastructure (construction phases and materials). The EROI point of use (EROIpou) of the whole energy system is obtained taking into account the additional energy investments to cope with RES intermittency (i.e. storage, overcapacities and overgrids) as well as the related distribution energy losses. Two scenarios up to 2050 are simulated: (1) Business-as-usual (BAU, continuation of current trends) and (2) "Green Growth" (GG, higher economic growth, faster transition to RES, higher efficiency improvements, etc.). The contribution of RES in the energy mix increases from ~15% to over 30% in BAU and almost 50% in GG by 2050. This penetration of RES technologies in the energy mix translates into a decrease of the EROIpou of the whole energy system from current 6:1 to 5:1 (BAU) and below 3:1 (GG) by 2050. These results put into question the viability of the Green Growth paradigm as it is being currently presented.
Content may be subject to copyright.
1
Dynamic EROI of the global energy system in future scenarios of transition to
renewable energies
Iñigo Capellán-Pérez*
Research Group on Energy, Economy and System Dynamics
University of Valladolid, Spain
email: inigo.capellan@uva.es
Carlos de Castro
Applied Physics Department
Escuela de Arquitectura, Av Salamanca, 18
University of Valladolid, 47014, Valladolid, Spain
ccastro@termo.uva.es
Luis Javier Miguel González
Systems Engineering and Automatic Control
Escuela de Ingenierías Industriales, Paseo del Cauce s/n,
University of Valladolid, 47011 Valladolid, Spain
ljmiguel@eii.uva.es
ABSTRACT
The transition from fossil fuels to Renewable Energy Sources (RES) is an indispensable
condition to achieve sustainable socio-economic systems. Despite their indisputable
environmental benefits, their technical performance can be, in some cases, worse than those
of fossil fuels. This is the case of the Energy Return on Energy Invested (EROI). Much work
has been carried out to estimate the EROI of individual RES technologies; fierce debates
about methodological issues are still not closed. In this work, we approach this issue by
dynamically estimating the EROI of the whole energy system in future scenarios of transition
to renewables. For this, we apply the global MEDEAS-World simulation model, which
computes the dynamic EROI (standard, EROIst) of individual renewable technologies as a
function of the associated energy requirements to build the infrastructure (construction phases
and materials). The EROI point of use (EROIpou) of the whole energy system is obtained
taking into account the additional energy investments to cope with RES intermittency (i.e.
storage, overcapacities and overgrids) as well as the related distribution energy losses. Two
scenarios up to 2050 are simulated: (1) Business-as-usual (BAU, continuation of current
trends) and (2) “Green Growth” (GG, higher economic growth, faster transition to RES,
higher efficiency improvements, etc.). The contribution of RES in the energy mix increases
from ~15% to over 30% in BAU and almost 50% in GG by 2050. This penetration of RES
technologies in the energy mix translates into a decrease of the EROIpou of the whole energy
system from current 6:1 to 5:1 (BAU) and below 3:1 (GG) by 2050. These results put into
question the viability of the Green Growth paradigm as it is being currently presented.
KEYWORDS
Energy Return on Energy Investment; high penetration of renewables; energy trap; Green
Growth; integrated assessment modelling
* Corresponding author
2
1. INTRODUCTION
The transition from fossil fuels to Renewable Energy Sources (RES) is an indispensable
condition to achieve sustainable socio-economic systems. Despite their indisputable
environmental and social benefits (e.g. lower pollution [1] and the possibility to be managed
at local, participative level [2]), the technical performance of RES technologies can be, in
some cases, worse than those of fossil fuels. In fact, fossil fuels are characterized by favorable
physical-chemical properties (e.g. high power density, storable, inert at standard ambient
conditions, etc.) that allow manageable, high-quality energy flows to easily supply human
societies. In contrast, RES technologies generally require more land surface (i.e. lower power
density, [3–5]), their use competes with other processes of the biosphere REF, while those
with a higher potential (i.e. wind, solar) are critically affected by their intermittence and
variability [4,6,7] and have been generally found to have lower Energy Return on Energy
Invested (EROI), the energy delivered from a process divided by the energy required to get it
over its lifetime, than fossil fuels [8,9]:
Considering the EROI allows to take a “net energy” approach in energy systems analysis,
which represents a number of advantages in relation to the conventional “gross energy”
approach: the relevant dimension is the energy available to the society (not the energy
produced by power plants) [10–12], internalization of factors that affect the whole energy
system that are not captured by the monetary costs of individual power plants (such as the
additional costs for the system related with distribution, intermittency of RES, etc.) [13–18];
and detection of potential harmful situations of increasing gross energy output while
decreasing the net energy delivered to the society, i.e. the so-called “energy trap” [19,20].
Much work has been carried out to estimate the EROI of individual RES technologies [9,21–
24]; however important differences exist depending on the technology, system design and
location, and the field is plagued with methodological discrepancies related with the
functional units (e.g., a megajoule of heat energy versus a megajoule of grid electricity) or the
boundaries of the analysis (i.e. mine-mouth vs end use or energy technology vs energy
system) [11,25–29]. From a societal/metabolic point of view, the relevant dimension is the
energy available to the society (not the energy produced by power plants). In fact, a
favourable EROI over the long-term has been identified as an historical driver of evolution
and increasing complexity [10–12]. Societies with high EROIst values are generally more
prosperous, given that more energy is available for discretionary purposes relative to that
which must be reinvested in the energy sector and basic maintenance [30]. [31] and [32]
calculated that discretionary economic production drops rapidly when EROIst falls below 5:1.
Therefore, for a society to be prosperous, the EROIst of its energy sources should be much
greater than 5:1. [33] estimated that an EROIst of 1015:1 is the minimum EROIst needed for
modern industrial consumer societies to support such things as modern healthcare, education,
and arts (discretionary spending) in addition to basic needs (e.g., food, shelter, and clothing),
a result similar to the one obtained by [17].
Thus, it is of key importance to understand the socioeconomic consequences of the large-scale
replacement of fossil fuels with RES. The energy transition to renewable resources and new
energy conversion and storage devices will affect the fraction of energy reinvestment
available for discretionary economic production [14,16,17,34], even having the potential to
create scenarios known as of “energy trap”, which may imply a reduction of the net energy
available to society if the construction of new infrastructure grows too rapidly [20,34].
3
The literature review reveals that recent work has been directed to estimate both (1) the
historic evolution EROI of national energy systems, and (2) the EROI associated to high RES
penetration scenarios. A diversity of methodologies is being applied, including proxy methods
based on economic data [33,35], input-ouput tables [36], optimization of electricity mix [37];
some including storage in the framework such as [13] and [18].
The aforementioned studies apply the EROI as a static concept, i.e. assuming that the energy
invested is proportional to the energy obtained along the lifespan of the functioning power
plant. However, power plants require, in fact, energy investment upfront to construct,
providing energy returns only over the lifespan of the facility. This representation worsens the
negative implications of potential energy trap scenarios. In this sense, different works have
focused on the dynamic integration of EROI to obtain more realistic results [19,34,38,39].
Here we present the developed methodology to implement the net energy approach in the
MEDEAS simulation model, a global energy-economy-environment system dynamics model
focused on the biophysical dimensions and interactions of the transition towards RES [40].
This model, which computes the dynamic EROI (standard, EROIst) of individual renewable
technologies as a function of the associated energy requirements to build the infrastructure
(construction phases and materials). The EROI point of use (EROIpou) of the whole energy
system is obtained taking into account the additional energy investments to cope with RES
intermittency (i.e. storage, overcapacities and overgrids) as well as the related distribution
energy losses.
A variation in the EROI of the energy system has implications for the rest of the energy-
economy-environment system. However, this has been very rarely taken into account in the
literature. In this sense, having the energy system embedded in the whole biophysical and
socio-economic system as considered in MEDEAS allows to account for the net energy
actually available for the society, and its implications for the rest of the system.
As it will be shown in the paper, this novel dynamic, energy-systems approach, allows to
reconcile some of the extant methodological discrepancies currently existing in the field.
2. METHODOLOGY
The representation of the net energy approach in the MEDEAS model includes 5 key
novelties which significantly improve the current state-of-the-art of the field:
1. Endogenous calculation of the EROIst of individual technologies taking as a starting
point the materials required in the construction, operation and maintenance phases as
well as their recycling rates [41],
2. Dynamic and endogenous representation of the EROIst of individual technologies
accounting for the up-front costs per technology as well the configuration of the
energy mix (i.e. requirement of overcapacities to deal with intermittency in high RES
penetration scenarios),
3. Allocation of technologies based on their relative EROIst (higher EROI technologies
tend to cover a larger share of the energy capacity demand).
4. Computation of the EROI of the whole energy system (including overcapacities,
storage and overgrids),
5. Incorporation of the implications of the variations in the EROI of the system for the
total final energy demand.
An extensive literature review has been performed to identify the materials required to
construct, operate and maintain the so-called “scalable” RES technologies for electricity
4
generation, i.e. (solar CSP, solar PV, wind onshore and wind offshore), i.e. those renewable
sources characterized by a higher techno-sustainable potential [42,43]. Two more
technologies are considered in this bottom-up assessment of material requirements which are
also considered key for the large-scale deployment of RES: electric batteries and overgrids.
This way, requirements for a total of 58 materials have been reviewed (of which 19 minerals).
This approach allows to endogenize the EROIst of each technology depending on the
recycling rate of the minerals (the energy consumption per unit of material consumption is
very different depending on the fact if the material is virgin or recycled). The applied
methodology is fully documented in [41].
In relation to the estimation of EROI of the system, it is not appropriate to approach the
question by using estimates of “buffered” EROIs for each renewable technology (as done for
example by [44] considering pumped hydro storage for wind and solar PV) given that these
values are of little or no use given that energy systems are designed so that different
technologies can partially complement and substitute for each other [45]. In this work a step
further is performed in relation to previous works by jointly considering the implications of
complementarity and intermittence of different RES sources for the EROI of the system. This
way, the required overcapacities, storage and overgrids are not assigned to a particular
technology but to the whole energy system.
Two scenarios are simulated in MEDEAS global model to 2050 in order to illustrate the
importance of considering all the aforementioned factors in the planning of the transition
towards a low carbon economy: (1) Business-as-usual (BAU, continuation of current trends)
and (2) “Green Growth” (GG, higher economic growth, faster transition to RES, higher
efficiency improvements, etc.). We select the GG paradigm as alternative scenario to current
trends given that key global international organizations have embraced these concepts
including the World Bank, the UNEP, the OECD, the European Commission and it is the
center of debate in international forums [46–51]. In a word, it is the alternative paradigm
assumed by the establishment to avoid the adverse impacts on human societies of the global
environmental change.
2.1. EROIpou of the system
Ideally, the concept of EROIext should be used when assessing systemic implications of the
variation of EROI over time. However, the practical estimation of EROIext is very complex
and subject to many uncertainties. To date, few studies have attempted to evaluate it
estimating the economic costs associated with the construction of the energy system, and
using average energy intensities to transform to energy inputs (e.g. [26,28]). This
methodology is questioned by other authors, which prefer to assign a “zero” energy cost to
those categories.
Here we take a conservative approach estimating the EROI of the system from both a
standard ( ) and point-of-use ( ) approach.
Different energy flows and conversions are required in the social metabolism in order to make
available final energy to the society:
(1) Useful energy used by society
(2) direct (i.e. on site) and indirect (i.e. offsite energy needed to make the products used on
site) energy requirements to build, operate, maintain and disposal the plant of energy
generation.
(3) Additional energy requirements so the system correctly handles RES intermittency
(4) Distribution losses
5
(5) Energy requirements to build the machines and infrastructure required to construct the
capital which allows to make the energy investments (2), (3) and (4)
Attending to the definition of standard EROI, the EROI of the system is defined as the ratio
between the final energy delivered to society and the energy required for the production of
energy vectors ( ):
If including more factors such as distribution losses and the additional energy requirements so
the system correctly handles RES intermittency, i.e. extending the boundaries, the EROI of
the system from a “point of use” approach ( ) can be defined as follows:
The following assumptions are taken to compute the :
1. For the sake of simplicity, the EROIst of non-renewable energy sources (oil, gas, coal
and uranium) is assumed to be constant over time. This simplification can be
considered as conservative, given that in the long term the EROI of these fuels will
tend to decrease. Indeed, recent analyses have found that the trend is already
decreasing for fuels such as oil and gas [9,52].
2. The EROIst is dynamically estimated for renewable technologies for the generation of
electricity. The EROIst of other renewables such as liquid biofuels or technologies for
heat generation is considered to be constant over time.
3. Overgrids and overcapacities related to the increasing penetration of variable
renewable technologies in the system are endogenously obtained in the model.
Overcapacities reduce the effective CF of each technology decreasing its EROI.
Overgrids are modelled as an additional component of the material intensity (kg/MW)
each technology as described in [41].
4. Additional storage losses are modelled following [13]. The reduction of EROIst at grid
scale depends on the ratio of electrical energy stored over the lifetime of a storage
device to the amount of embodied electrical energy required to build the device (i.e. an
analog to EROI for storage technologies, the Energy Stored on Energy Invested
(ESOI)); a certain level of curtailement (φ) and the efficiency of the electric storage
(η).
A step further, at least conceptually, would be to accounting for the energy requirements to
build, operate, maintain and dispose the machines and infrastructure (5) required to make the
energy investments (2), (3) and (4). This way we would arrive to an “extended” definition of
the EROI of the system:
2.2. Modelling framework of MEDEAS
MEDEAS-World (MEDEAS-W) is a global, one-region energy-economy-environment model
(or integrated assessment model). It is a simulation model which has been designed applying
6
System Dynamics,1 which facilitates the integration of knowledge from different perspectives
and disciplines as well as the feedbacks from different subsystems. The model typically runs
from 1995 to 2050 (although the simulation horizon may be extended to 2100 if necessary,
e.g. when focusing on climate change issues). MEDEAS-W is structured into seven main
submodules: Economy, Energy, Infrastructures, Materials, Land Use, Social and
Environmental Impacts Indicators and Climate Change (see Figure 2). The main variables that
connect the different modules are represented by arrows.
Energy consumption
required
Economy (IOT)
&
Population
Energy
(NR & RES
availability)
Climate
model Materials
CO2 emissions
Energy supply
availability
Energy
consumption
CC damage function
Land-use change
CO2 emissions
Requi red mate rials
for energy systems
Mater ial consumption
Energy for material
consumpti on
Land use
Social &
Environmental
impacts
indicators
Energy
infrastructures
CC impacts
Future demand
Figure 1: MEDEAS-World model schematic overview. Source: [40].
The main characteristics of each module are:
Economy and population: the global economy in MEDEAS is modelled following a
post-Keynesian approach assuming non-clearing markets (i.e. not equilibrium) and
demand-led growth, combined with supply-side constraints such as energy
availability. The economic structure is captured by the dynamic integration of global
WIOD input-output tables which include 35 industrial sectors and households [53].
Final energy intensities by sector are obtained combining information from WIOD
environmental accounts [54] and the IEA Balances (2018). Population evolves
exogenously as defined by the user. See [56] for more details on this submodule.
Energy: this module includes the renewable and non-renewable energy resources
potentials and availability taking into account biophysical and temporal constraints. In
particular, the availability of non-renewable energy resources depends on both stock
and flow constraints [57–59]. In total, 34 primary energy sources and 5 final fuels are
1 Developed in Vensim DSS software for Windows Version 6.4E (x32). Also available in Python open-source
code. Both codes are available in http://www.medeas.eu/.
7
considered (electricity, heat, solids, gases and liquids), with large technological
disaggregation. The intermittency of RES is considered in the framework, computing
endogenous levels of overcapacities, storage and overgrids depending on the
penetration of variables RES technologies. A net energy approach accounting for the
EROI of both individual technologies and the EROI of the system is applied. This
submodule is mainly based on the previous model WoLiM [60]. Transportation is
modelled in high detail, differentiating between different types of vehicles for
households, as well as freight and passenger inland transport (see [40] for details).
Energy infrastructures represent power plants to generate electricity and heat, allowing
to consider planning and construction delays.
Climate: this module projects the climate change levels due to the GHG emissions
generated by human societies (non-CO2 emissions are exogenously set taking as
reference RCPs scenarios [61]). The carbon and climate cycle is adapted from C-
ROADS [62,63]. This module includes a damage function which impacts sectors’
economic output depending on the level of global temperature change [64].
Materials: materials are required by the economy with emphasis on those required for
the construction and O&M of alternative energy technologies [41]. Option of
recycling policies.
Land-use: this module currently mainly accounts for the land requirements of the RES
energies.
Social and environmental impacts: this module translates the “biophysical” results of
the simulations into metrics related with social and environmental impacts. The
objective of this module is to contextualize the implications for human societies in
terms of well-being for each simulation.
The model dynamically operates as follows. For each period: firstly, a sectoral economic
demand is estimated from an exogenous and dynamic GDPpc objective. Using energy-
economy hybrid Input-Output Analysis, and combining monetary output and energy
intensities by final energy sources, the final energy demand required to meet economic
demand is obtained. Secondly, the energy submodel computes the net available final energy
supply, which may satisfy (or not) the required demand: the economy adapts to eventual fuel
scarcity. Thirdly, materials required to build, operate, maintain, dismantle, etc. are estimated.
This allows to estimate the EROI of the system as well as to assess eventual material
bottlenecks (although material availability does not constrain economic output in current
model version). Fourthly, the climate submodel computes the GHG emissions, whose
accumulation derives into a certain level of climate change, which in turns feed-back the
economic output. Land and water additional requirements are accounted for. Finally, social
and environmental impacts are translated from the biophysical results. This way, MEDEAS
incorporates two limits to growth that are rather rarely considered (even separately) in the
literature: consistent climate change impacts and energy availability (which interact with the
variation of EROI level of the system).
For a detailed documentation of the MEDEAS-World model, see [40].
8
3. RESULTS
Figure 3 shows the dynamic evolution up to 2050 of the EROIpou of the system obtained in
the simulation of the BAU and GG scenarios with MEDEAS-W model. The obtained results
reveal that, under the applied assumptions, the current EROIpou of the system is ~6:1 values,
and that it has decreased from ~7:1 since 1995.
In BAU scenario, this trend continues reaching a value of 5:1 by 2050, due to the slight
penetration of RES in the system (which almost reaches 30%, doubling its current
contribution to the total primary energy supply TPES-). In GG scenario, the fastest pace of
penetration of RES technologies (which almost reach 50% of TPES by 2050, drive the
EROIpou of the system to values below 3:1.
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
2025
2030
2035
2040
2045
2050
Adimensional
EROIpou system
BAU
GG
Figure 2: Dynamic evolution of the EROIpou of the energy system for scenarios BAU and
GG.
The reduction in the EROI of the system has implications for the rest of the system: in order
to satisfy the same level of final net energy consumption, the system needs to process more
energy and materials to make it available for the society. This phenomenon is modelled in
MEDEAS-W through a function of overdemand. In BAU scenario, the overdemand does not
represent significant levels and remains below +2% in almost all the simulated period.
However, in scenario GG, overdemand skyrockets over the period almost reaching +25% by
2050. This means that, in order to satisfy the same final net energy demand, the system needs
to process 25% more of energy.
The additional increase of final energy demand related with the deployment of RES in GG
scenario has also important implications for the efficiency of the system. In terms of final
energy intensities, this effect has the potential to counteract the effect of higher exogenous
9
efficiency improvements which are assumed in this scenario. It is noteworthy that when
computing the total final energy intensity without the feedback of the EROI of the system, the
total final energy intensity steadily decreases over the simulated period, while including the
feedback produces a rebound in this metric in the 2040 decade which points towards a
rematerialization of the economic system caused by RES penetration in the mix.
4. CONCLUSION
The obtained results show that net energy analysis is key to correctly model the transition
towards energy systems based on RES. In this sense, findings from previous works are
confirmed [13,15,18,34]. Renewables at low market penetration represent relatively low
integration costs for the full energy system. However, as the penetration increases and
displaces conventional dispatchable fuel sources, the energetic costs associated with the
required overcapacities, overgrids and storage substantially reduce the EROI of the whole
system due to energy requirements for both construction and operation of the modified energy
system. In particular, the obtained values below 3:1 for the EROIpou of the system in the
Green Growth scenario are below the thresholds identified in the literature to sustain high
levels of development (<10:1 Hall et al., [17,28], <5:1 [32]). This result puts into question the
viability of the Green Growth paradigm as it is being currently presented. In fact, one the key
assumptions of this narrative, i.e. the absolute decoupling of economic growth in relation to
energy use, is showed not to be consistent with the levels of material and energy required to
perform the energy transition towards RES.
From a methodological point of view, this works presents a number of novel contributions in
relation to the state-of-the art of energy systems analysis and EROI, allowing to reconcile
some of the extant discrepancies in the literature [11,25–29]: (1) the dynamic approach allows
to overcome the limitations of the common static approaches; and (2) the required
overcapacities and storage in high RES penetration scenarios are not assigned to any specific
technology, but rather to the whole energy system.
The computation of both the EROI of the system and the EROI-based allocation of RES
technologies in the energy mix represents a key novelty in relation to the current modelling
state of the art. Virtually all models used for policy-advice are based on gross energy output
and rely on price-based allocations methods (e.g. IEA, IPCC, national governments, etc.). To
our knowledge, very few models take a net energy approach (GEMBA [65]; NETSET [39],
and even less are the studies considering the allocation of technologies depending on their
relative EROI (e.g. [37]). However, it should be keep in mind that the EROI does not capture
all the benefits and disadvantages of a given technology. For example, in the case of rooftop
PV, despite its lower efficiency in relation to ground-based plants, it does not require
additional land.
As any modelling study, this work presents a number of limitations. These may be addressed
in further work. For example, the implications of the drop of the EROI of the system to very
low levels are not fully captured in the current framework. In reality, if the system does not
include « inteligent/correcting controls » a sharp drop in the EROI of the system to such low
levels should endogenously induce a collapse of the system (as for example in [32], where the
model allows to endogenously estimate the relevant EROI threshold). An option would be to
consider the link between the energetic investments in the energy module and the related
monetary investments in the Economy module (as performed by [34,65]).
Further work may deepen the study of the allocation of energy technologies depending on
their relative EROI. This would allow to improve the criteria for successfully planning the
10
transition to RES. From the point of view of material availability, given that the model tracks
the material consumption of alternative technologies, further work could be directed to the
analysis of the implications for potential material bottlenecks in the context of transition to
RES (e.g. [66–69]). Further work may also be directed to explore alternative ways to analyse
the implications of the evolution of the EROI of the energy system to the whole socio-
economic system. In this sense, IO seems a promising approach [36].
Finally, a holistic analysis of the full energy-economy-environment system in the context of
the transition towards RES is needed, taking into account the interaction between declining
EROI levels with other key factors such as climate change impacts, non-renewable energy
resources availability or demand-management policies which go beyond the usual
technological policies.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This work has been partially developed under the MEDEAS project, funded by the European
Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme under grant agreement No
691287. Iñigo Capellán-Pérez also acknowledges financial support from the Juan de la Cierva
Research Fellowship of the Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness of Spain (no. FJCI-
2016-28833).
REFERENCES
[1] IPCC. Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Fifth Assess Rep Intergov
Panel Clim Change 2014.
[2] Becker S, Kunze C. Transcending community energy: collective and politically
motivated projects in renewable energy (CPE) across Europe. People Place Policy
2014;8:180–191.
[3] Capellán-Pérez I, de Castro C, Arto I. Assessing vulnerabilities and limits in the
transition to renewable energies: Land requirements under 100% solar energy scenarios.
Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2017;77:760–82. doi:10.1016/j.rser.2017.03.137.
[4] MacKay DJC. Solar energy in the context of energy use, energy transportation and
energy storage. Philos Trans R Soc Lond Math Phys Eng Sci 2013;371:20110431.
doi:10.1098/rsta.2011.0431.
[5] Scheidel A, Sorman AH. Energy transitions and the global land rush: Ultimate drivers
and persistent consequences. Glob Environ Change 2012;22:588–95.
doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2011.12.005.
[6] Trainer T. A critique of Jacobson and Delucchi’s proposals for a world renewable
energy supply. Energy Policy 2012;44:476–81. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.09.037.
[7] Wagner F. Considerations for an EU-wide use of renewable energies for electricity
generation. Eur Phys J Plus 2014;129:1–14. doi:10.1140/epjp/i2014-14219-7.
[8] Hall CAS. Will EROI be the Primary Determinant of Our Economic Future? The View
of the Natural Scientist versus the Economist. Joule 2017;1:635–8.
doi:10.1016/j.joule.2017.09.010.
[9] Hall CAS, Lambert JG, Balogh SB. EROI of different fuels and the implications for
society. Energy Policy 2014;64:141–52. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.05.049.
[10] Hall CAS. Energy Return on Investment as Master Driver of Evolution 2017:59–72.
doi:10.1007/978-3-319-47821-0_6.
[11] Hall CAS, Klitgaard KA. Energy and the Wealth of Nations: Understanding the
Biophysical Economy. New York, NY: Springer New York; 2012.
11
[12] King CW. Information Theory to Assess Relations Between Energy and Structure of the
U.S. Economy Over Time. Biophys Econ Resour Qual 2016;1:10. doi:10.1007/s41247-
016-0011-y.
[13] Barnhart CJ, Dale M, Brandt AR, Benson SM. The energetic implications of curtailing
versus storing solar- and wind-generated electricity. Energy Environ Sci 2013;6:2804–
10. doi:10.1039/C3EE41973H.
[14] Carbajales-Dale M, Barnhart CJ, Brandt AR, Benson SM. A better currency for
investing in a sustainable future. Nat Clim Change 2014;4:524–7.
doi:10.1038/nclimate2285.
[15] Carbajales-Dale M, Barnhart CJ, Benson SM. Can we afford storage? A dynamic net
energy analysis of renewable electricity generation supported by energy storage. Energy
Environ Sci 2014;7:1538. doi:10.1039/c3ee42125b.
[16] Dale M, Krumdieck S, Bodger P. Global energy modelling A biophysical approach
(GEMBA) part 1: An overview of biophysical economics. Ecol Econ 2012;73:152–7.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.10.014.
[17] Hall CAS, Balogh S, Murphy DJR. What is the Minimum EROI that a Sustainable
Society Must Have? Energies 2009;2:25–47. doi:10.3390/en20100025.
[18] Palmer G. A Framework for Incorporating EROI into Electrical Storage. Biophys Econ
Resour Qual 2017;2:6. doi:10.1007/s41247-017-0022-3.
[19] Kessides IN, Wade DC. Deriving an Improved Dynamic EROI to Provide Better
Information for Energy Planners. Sustainability 2011;3:2339–57.
doi:10.3390/su3122339.
[20] Zenzey E. Energy as a Master Resource. State World 2013 Sustain. Still Possible,
Worldwatch Institute, Washington: Island Press; 2013, p. 73–83.
[21] Bhandari KP, Collier JM, Ellingson RJ, Apul DS. Energy payback time (EPBT) and
energy return on energy invested (EROI) of solar photovoltaic systems: A systematic
review and meta-analysis. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2015;47:133–41.
doi:10.1016/j.rser.2015.02.057.
[22] de Castro C, Carpintero Ó, Frechoso F, Mediavilla M, de Miguel LJ. A top-down
approach to assess physical and ecological limits of biofuels. Energy 2014;64:506–12.
doi:10.1016/j.energy.2013.10.049.
[23] Kubiszewski I, Cleveland CJ, Endres PK. Meta-analysis of net energy return for wind
power systems. Renew Energy 2010;35:218–25. doi:10.1016/j.renene.2009.01.012.
[24] Price L, Kendall A. Wind Power as a Case Study. J Ind Ecol 2012;16:S22–7.
doi:10.1111/j.1530-9290.2011.00458.x.
[25] De Castro C, Capellán-Pérez I. Concentrated Solar Power: actual performance and
foreseeable future in high penetration scenarios of renewable energies 2018.
[26] Ferroni F, Hopkirk RJ. Energy Return on Energy Invested (ERoEI) for photovoltaic
solar systems in regions of moderate insolation. Energy Policy 2016;94:336–44.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2016.03.034.
[27] Murphy DJ, Carbajales-Dale M, Moeller D. Comparing Apples to Apples: Why the Net
Energy Analysis Community Needs to Adopt the Life-Cycle Analysis Framework.
Energies 2016;9:917. doi:10.3390/en9110917.
[28] Prieto PA, Hall CAS. Spain’s Photovoltaic Revolution: The Energy Return on
Investment. 2013th ed. Springer; 2013.
[29] Raugei M, Sgouridis S, Murphy D, Fthenakis V, Frischknecht R, Breyer C, et al. Energy
Return on Energy Invested (ERoEI) for photovoltaic solar systems in regions of
moderate insolation: A comprehensive response. Energy Policy 2017;102:377–84.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2016.12.042.
12
[30] Day JW, D’Elia CF, Wiegman ARH, Rutherford JS, Hall CAS, Lane RR, et al. The
Energy Pillars of Society: Perverse Interactions of Human Resource Use, the Economy,
and Environmental Degradation. Biophys Econ Resour Qual 2018;3:2.
doi:10.1007/s41247-018-0035-6.
[31] Murphy DJ. The implications of the declining energy return on investment of oil
production. Philos Trans R Soc Math Phys Eng Sci 2014;372:20130126.
doi:10.1098/rsta.2013.0126.
[32] Brandt AR. How Does Energy Resource Depletion Affect Prosperity? Mathematics of a
Minimum Energy Return on Investment (EROI). Biophys Econ Resour Qual 2017;2:2.
doi:10.1007/s41247-017-0019-y.
[33] Lambert JG, Hall CAS, Balogh S, Gupta A, Arnold M. Energy, EROI and quality of life.
Energy Policy 2014;64:153–67. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.001.
[34] Sers MR, Victor PA. The Energy-missions Trap. Ecol Econ 2018;151:10–21.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.04.004.
[35] Atlason RS. EROI and the Icelandic society. Energy Policy 2018;120:52–7.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2018.04.069.
[36] Brand-Correa LI, Brockway PE, Copeland CL, Foxon TJ, Owen A, Taylor PG.
Developing an Input-Output Based Method to Estimate a National-Level Energy Return
on Investment (EROI). Energies 2017;10:534. doi:10.3390/en10040534.
[37] Limpens G, Jeanmart H. Electricity storage needs for the energy transition: An EROI
based analysis illustrated by the case of Belgium. Energy 2018;152:960–73.
doi:10.1016/j.energy.2018.03.180.
[38] Neumeyer C, Goldston R. Dynamic EROI Assessment of the IPCC 21st Century
Electricity Production Scenario. Sustainability 2016;8:421. doi:10.3390/su8050421.
[39] Sgouridis S, Csala D, Bardi U. The sower’s way: quantifying the narrowing net-energy
pathways to a global energy transition. Environ Res Lett 2016;11:094009.
doi:10.1088/1748-9326/11/9/094009.
[40] Capellán-Pérez I, de Blas I, Nieto J, De Castro C, Miguel LJ, Mediavilla M, et al.
MEDEAS Model and IOA implementation at global geographical level. GEEDS,
University of Valladolid; 2017.
[41] De Castro C, Capellán-Pérez I, Miguel LJ. Revised standard EROI of alternative
technologies for the energy transition 2018.
[42] IPCC. Special Report on Renewable Energy Sources and Climate Change Mitigation.
United Kingdom and New York (USA): Cambridge University Press; 2011.
[43] Smil V. Energy Transitions: History, Requirements, Prospects. Santa Barbara,
California, USA: Praeger; 2010.
[44] Weißbach D, Ruprecht G, Huke A, Czerski K, Gottlieb S, Hussein A. Energy intensities,
EROIs (energy returned on invested), and energy payback times of electricity generating
power plants. Energy 2013;52:210–21. doi:10.1016/j.energy.2013.01.029.
[45] Trainer T. Estimating the EROI of whole systems for 100% renewable electricity supply
capable of dealing with intermittency. Energy Policy 2018;119:648–53.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2018.04.045.
[46] European Commission. A Roadmap for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in
2050. Brussels: COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE
EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND
SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS; 2011.
[47] Jacobs M. Green growth: economic theory and political discourse. Cent Clim Change
Econ Policy Work Pap No 108 Grantham Res Inst Clim Change Environ Work Pap No
92 2012.
13
[48] OECD. OECD work on green growth.
Http://Www.Oecd.Org/Greengrowth/Oecdworkongreengrowth.Htm (Retrieved 12-3-
2018): OECD; 2018.
[49] OECD. Towards green growth. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development; 2011.
[50] UNEP. Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to sustainable development and poverty
eradication. United Nations Environment Programme; 2011.
[51] World Bank. Inclusive green growth: the pathway to sustainable development. World
Bank Publications; 2012.
[52] Gagnon N, Hall CAS, Brinker L. A Preliminary Investigation of Energy Return on
Energy Investment for Global Oil and Gas Production. Energies 2009;2:490–503.
doi:10.3390/en20300490.
[53] Dietzenbacher E, Los B, Stehrer R, Timmer M, Vries G de. The Construction of World
Input–Output Tables in the Wiod Project. Econ Syst Res 2013;25:71–98.
doi:10.1080/09535314.2012.761180.
[54] Genty A. Final database of environmental satellite accounts: technical report on their
compilation. WIOD Deliverable 4.6, Documentation.; 2012.
[55] IEA. IEA World Energy Statistics and Balances. Paris (France): IEA/OECD; 2018.
[56] Nieto J, Carpintero Ó, Miguel LJ, de Blas I. Is it worth more growth? Macro-economic
modelling under energy constraints 2018.
[57] Campbell CJ, Laherrère J. The end of cheap oil. Sci Am 1998;278:60–5.
[58] Kerschner C, Capellán-Pérez I. Peak-Oil and Ecological Economics. In: Spash CL,
editor. Routdlege Handb. Ecol. Econ. Nat. Soc. Routledge, Abingdon: 2017, p. 425–35.
[59] Mohr SH, Wang J, Ellem G, Ward J, Giurco D. Projection of world fossil fuels by
country. Fuel 2015;141:120–35. doi:10.1016/j.fuel.2014.10.030.
[60] Capellán-Pérez I, Mediavilla M, de Castro C, Carpintero Ó, Miguel LJ. Fossil fuel
depletion and socio-economic scenarios: An integrated approach. Energy 2014;77:641–
66. doi:10.1016/j.energy.2014.09.063.
[61] van Vuuren DP, Edmonds JA, Kainuma M, Riahi K, Weyant J. A special issue on the
RCPs. Clim Change 2011;109:1–4. doi:10.1007/s10584-011-0157-y.
[62] Fiddaman T, Siegel LS, Sawin E, Jones AP, Sterman J. C-ROADS simulator reference
guide. 2016.
[63] Sterman J, Fiddaman T, Franck T, Jones A, McCauley S, Rice P, et al. Climate
interactive: the C-ROADS climate policy model. Syst Dyn Rev 2012;28:295–305.
doi:10.1002/sdr.1474.
[64] Capellán-Pérez I, de Castro C. Integration of global environmental change threat to
human societies in energy-economy-environment models, Budapest (Hungary): 2017.
[65] Dale M, Krumdieck S, Bodger P. Global energy modelling A biophysical approach
(GEMBA) Part 2: Methodology. Ecol Econ 2012;73:158–67.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.10.028.
[66] EC. Critical raw materials for the UE. Report of the Ad-hoc Working Group on defining
critical raw materials. European Commission; 2010.
[67] Elshkaki A, Graedel TE. Dynamic analysis of the global metals flows and stocks in
electricity generation technologies. J Clean Prod 2013;59:260–73.
doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2013.07.003.
[68] García-Olivares A, Ballabrera-Poy J, García-Ladona E, Turiel A. A global renewable
mix with proven technologies and common materials. Energy Policy 2012;41:561–74.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.11.018.
14
[69] Valero A, Valero A, Calvo G, Ortego A. Material bottlenecks in the future development
of green technologies. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2018;93:178–200.
doi:10.1016/j.rser.2018.05.041.
... This consideration still leaves out the reduction necessary to account for the long-distance transmission backbone mentioned by Pickard. Capellán-Peréz et al. reported an EROEI of the whole energy sector running solely on renewable energy sources with a necessary battery backup equal to 3 [36]. For this reason, we ran a model sensitivity analysis predominantly for the EROEI ranging from 3 to 7 or up to 15 in two instances. ...
Article
Full-text available
Introduction: Energy return on energy invested (EROEI) of fossil fuels has been declining sharply, while modern renewable energy sources generally have even lower EROEI than fossil fuels. It has been repeatedly proven that economic growth expressed in the form of growth of real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is closely related to intensified energy consumption and escalated usage of natural resources in general. This problem remains scarcely explored in pure economic modelling. Objectives: This study presents a novel model titled Energy Extended Neoclassical Growth Model (EENGM), which focuses on the consequences of declining quantity and quality of extractable fossil fuels and lower quality of the succeeding renewable energy technology for economic growth. Method: The Neoclassical growth model is translated into a system dynamics format and is extended by important feedback mechanisms, which are identified as important from the literature and mostly missing from the analyzed system dynamics models with a similar scope. Two scenarios assess the EENGM performance: business as usual (BAU) and the sustainability strategy (SUS). Results: Sensitivity analysis is performed for the Energy Return on Energy Invested (EROEI) parameter and results in the investment share in GDP varying between 27 and 40%, while the energy sector investment largely displaces investment in other economic sectors. The EENGM is associated with new behavior whereby the underperforming energy sector limits GDP growth and seizes most of the available investment. The adoption of the SUS strategy causes 28% lower cumulative fossil fuel aggregate consumption which still corresponds to higher than 1.5 °C global warming compared to the preindustrial levels. Conclusion: The share of consumption in the GDP of an economy undergoing energy transition can approach levels previously seen only in totally war-oriented economies. Even omitting other negative environmental feedback, the feasibility of the successful energy transition of the system in its contemporary form, with the currently available renewable energy technology, seems to be highly uncertain.
Book
Full-text available
Parrique T., Barth J., Briens F., C. Kerschner, Kraus-Polk A., Kuokkanen A., Spangenberg J.H. 2019, 78 pp. Is it possible to enjoy both economic growth and environmental sustainability? This question is a matter of fierce political debate between green growth and post-growth advocates. Over the past decade, green growth clearly dominated policy making with policy agendas at the United Nations, European Union, and in numerous countries building on the assumption that decoupling environmental pressures from gross domestic product (GDP) could allow future economic growth without end. Considering what is at stake, a careful assessment to determine whether the scientific foundations behind this “decoupling hypothesis” are robust or not is needed. This report reviews the empirical and theoretical literature to assess the validity of this hypothesis. The conclusion is both overwhelmingly clear and sobering: not only is there no empirical evidence supporting the existence of a decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures on anywhere near the scale needed to deal with environmental breakdown, but also, and perhaps more importantly, such decoupling appears unlikely to happen in the future. The validity of the green growth discourse relies on the assumption of an absolute, permanent, global, large and fast enough decoupling of economic growth from all critical environmental pressures. The literature reviewed clearly shows that there is no empirical evidence for such a decoupling currently happening. This is the case for materials, energy, water, greenhouse gases, land, water pollutants, and biodiversity loss for which decoupling is either only relative, and/or observed only temporarily, and/or only locally. In most cases, decoupling is relative. When absolute decoupling occurs, it is observed only during rather short periods of time, concerning only certain resources or forms of impact, for specific locations, and with very small rates of mitigation. There are at least seven reasons to be skeptical about the occurrence of sufficient decoupling in the future: Rising energy expenditures, Rebound effects, Problem shifting, The underestimated impact of services, The limited potential of recycling, Insufficient and inappropriate technological change, and Cost shifting. Each of them taken individually casts doubt on the possibility for sufficient decoupling and, thus, the feasibility of “green growth.” Considered all together, the hypothesis that decoupling will allow economic growth to continue without a rise in environmental pressures appears highly compromised, if not clearly unrealistic. This report highlights the need for a new conceptual toolbox to inform and support the design and evaluation of environmental policies. Policy-makers have to acknowledge the fact that addressing environmental breakdown may require a direct downscaling of economic production and consumption in the wealthiest countries. In other words, we advocate complementing efficiency-oriented policies with sufficiency policies, with a shift in priority and emphasis from the former to the latter even though both have a role to play. From this perspective, it appears urgent for policy-makers to pay more attention to and support the developing diversity of alternatives to green growth.
Article
Full-text available
Analyses proposing a high share of concentrated solar power (CSP) in future 100% renewable energy scenarios rely on the ability of this technology, through storage and/or hybridization, to partially avoid the problems associated with the hourly/daily (short-term) variability of other variable renewable sources such as wind or solar photovoltaic. However, data used in the scientific literature are mainly theoretical values. In this work, the actual performance of CSP plants in operation from publicly available data from four countries (Spain, the USA, India, and United Arab Emirates) has been estimated for three dimensions: capacity factor (CF), seasonal variability, and energy return on energy invested (EROI). In fact, the results obtained show that the actual performance of CSP plants is significantly worse than that projected by constructors and considered by the scientific literature in the theoretical studies: a CF in the range of 0.15–0.3, low standard EROI (1.3:1–2.4:1), intensive use of materials—some scarce, and significant seasonal intermittence. In the light of the obtained results, the potential contribution of current CSP technologies in a future 100% renewable energy system seems very limited.
Article
Full-text available
Decarbonizing world economies implies the deployment of “green technologies”, meaning a renovation of the energy sector towards using renewable sources and zero emission transport technologies. This renovation will require huge amounts of raw materials, some of them with high supply risks. To assess such risks a new methodology is proposed, identifying possible bottlenecks of future demand versus geological availability. This has been applied to the world development of wind power, solar photovoltaic, solar thermal power and passenger electric vehicles for the 2016–2050 time period under a business as usual scenario considering the impact on 31 different raw materials. As a result, 13 elements were identified to have very high or high risk, meaning that these could generate bottlenecks in the future: cadmium, chromium, cobalt, copper, gallium, indium, lithium, manganese, nickel, silver, tellurium, tin and zinc. Tellurium, which is mostly demanded to manufacture solar photovoltaic cells, presents the highest risk. To overcome these constraints, measures consisting on improving recycling rates from 0.1% to 4.6% per year could avoid material shortages or restrictions in green technologies. For instance, lithium recycling rate should increase from 1% to 4.8% in 2050. This study aims to serve as a guideline for developing eco-design and recycling strategies.
Article
Full-text available
To face climate changes and energy dependency, governments encourage their industries and communities to increase the share of renewable energy (RE). However, the RE production is mostly inflexible. The risk of unmatching electricity market grows. Tools such as power plant flexibility, import/export, demand side management, storage and RE curtailment are developed to handle this problem. This study focuses on the energy storage mix required for the energy of the electricity system to high RE shares. An hour based model is developed in order to optimise the renewable energy and storage assets by maximising the energy return on investment (EROI) while respecting power fluxes constraints. The model is used to quantify the storage needs for the energy transition of Belgium. An in-depth analysis is performed for four scenarios. Depending on the RE deployment and nuclear share, EROI between 5 and 10.5 are obtained. Large scale storage is required as soon as the energy mix has more than 30% of RE. With more than 75% of RE, power to gas becomes unavoidable. This study highlights that curtailment can be limited to less than 5% of RE production. These values are the result of the optimum between increasing storage, RE capacity and curtailment.
Article
Full-text available
To meet the COP21 2 °C climate target, humanity would need to complete a transition to renewable energy within the next several decades. But for decades, fossil fuels will continue to underpin many fundamental activities that allow modern society to function. Unfortunately, net energy yield from fossil fuels is now falling, and despite substantial growth in renewable energy, total global energy demand and fossil fuel consumption are still increasing. Recent studies document promising trends in net energy yield from new renewable energy, particularly wind and solar. However, most studies do not fully consider the complexities of multiple factors including production intermittency, storage, the need to replace a massive infrastructure network, and lack of fungibility of different energy sources. Also, oft-overlooked, is that human impacts have caused widespread degradation of natural ecosystems and the provisioning of ecosystem goods and services, especially affecting vulnerable areas like coastal zones and arid regions. An accelerated renewable energy transition to meet climate targets and replace declining stocks of high net yielding fossil fuels will compete with resources needed for crucial investments to mitigate already locked in climate change and environmental degradation impacts. Integrative approaches that include all costs can help balance interdependent factors such as net energy dynamics, resource allocation, and ecosystem degradation. Energy-climate investment pathways produce economic output and quality of life tradeoffs that must be considered. Accordingly, developing future energy policy requires a systems approach with global boundaries and new levels of appreciation of the complex mix of interrelated factors involved.
Article
Full-text available
• Download high-res image (296KB) • Download full-size image Charles A.S. Hall is a Systems Ecologist who received his PhD under Howard T. Odum at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill in 1970. He was professor over the past 45 years at Cornell University, the University of Montana, and the College of Environmental Science and Forestry of the State University of New York. He is now retired (but very active as Professor Emeritus) in Western Montana. Dr. Hall is the author or editor of 14 books and 300 scholarly articles and has been awarded the distinguished Hubbert-Simmons Prize for Energy Education and the Lifetime Achievement Award from the International Society of BioPhysical Economics. He is best known for his development of the concept of EROI, or energy return on investment, which is an examination of how organisms, including humans, invest energy into obtaining additional energy to improve biotic or social fitness, and also a new field, BioPhysical Economics, as a supplement or alternative to conventional economics. He has applied systems and EROI thinking to a broad series of biological, resource, and economic issues in more than 30 countries. His most recent books are Energy and the Wealth of Nations: An Introduction to BioPhysical Economics (with Kent Klitgaard), America's Most Sustainable Cities and Regions (with John Day), and Energy Return on Investment. A unifying Principle for Biology, Economics and Sustainability, all available from Springer. He is coeditor with Ugo Bardi and Gaël Giraud of the journal BioPhysical Economics and Resource Quality.
Article
The requirement to reduce emissions to avoid potentially dangerous climate change implies a dilemma for societies heavily dependent on fossil fuels. Reducing emissions will necessitate the transition from relatively high EROI dispatchable fossil fuels to a combination of relatively low EROI intermittent renewables and geographically limited non-intermittent renewables. As renewable capacity requires energy to construct there is an initial fossil fuel cost to creating new renewable capacity. An insufficiently rapid transition to renewables will imply a scenario in which it is impossible to avoid either transgressing emissions ceilings or facing energy shortages; we term this the energy-emissions trap. In this paper, we construct a mathematical model, termed EETRAP, that builds the EROI metric and the energy characteristics of renewable generation into a macroeconomic framework. EETRAP is used for simulation analysis to test how differing assumptions about the EROI of intermittent renewables will affect the time-path of renewable investment necessary to escape the energy-emissions trap. For all runs of the model, the renewable investment rate by 2050 is significantly larger than the current energy investment rate. For declining intermittent renewable EROI, the renewable investment rate crowds out other forms of investment leading to a declining economic growth rate.
Article
In this paper, the societal Energy Return on Investment (EROIsoc) is estimated for Iceland between 1960 and the present. The results indicate that the overall EROIsoc was around 27:1 in the early 1960s, and was volatile for a period of time before stabilizing at around 45:1 in 1974 after establishing a strong mix of renewable energy. These findings further show that Icelanders have generally had access to energy sources with higher EROI than if they had relied on fossil fuels, except for the period between 1963 and 1967. If they had relied on fossil fuels alone, Icelanders would now have access to combined resources with an EROI of around 16:1, likely too low for prosperity, and an even lower EROI for long periods of time. Regarding policies, this paper shows that relying on an energy grid mix with an EROI higher than 20-30:1, especially for island nations, has the potential to raise the standard of living greatly. For policymakers in island nations, attention should be given to this relationship between high-EROI energy sources with low price volatility and the standard of living.
Article
Until the last few years it has not been possible to estimate the energy return on energy invested (EROI) for 100% renewable energy supply systems, because simulations indicating the amount of capacity required were not available. This study takes the finding of a recent simulation for 100%renewable Australian electricity supply, along with commonly quoted EROI values for the technologies involved, and derives a conclusion for total energy supply system EROI. The EROI values for individual renewable technologies do not provide a reliable guide to the system value because of the large amount of redundant plant that must be on hand to enable whole systems to meet demand reliably despite intermittency. The general finding is that 100% renewable supply systems probably have values that are too low to sustain energy intensive societies.