Available via license: CC BY 4.0
Content may be subject to copyright.
WHAT WE DON’T SEE WHEN WE SEE COPYRIGHT AS
PROPERTY
JESSICA LITMAN*
ABSTRACT. For all of the rhetoric about the central place of authors in the
copyright scheme, our copyright laws in fact give them little power and less
money. Intermediaries own the copyrights, and are able to structure
licenses so as to maximise their own revenue while shrinking their pay-outs
to authors. Copyright scholars have tended to treat this point superficially,
because –as lawyers –we take for granted that copyrights are property;
property rights are freely alienable; and the grantee of a property right
stands in the shoes of the original holder. I compare the 1710 Statute of
Anne, which created statutory copyrights and consolidated them in the
hands of publishers and printers, with the 1887 Dawes Act, which served
a crucial function in the American divestment of Indian land. I draw
from the stories of the two laws the same moral: Constituting something
as a freely alienable property right will almost always lead to results mir-
roring or exacerbating disparities in wealth and bargaining power. The
legal dogma surrounding property rights makes it easy for us not to notice.
KEYWORDS:Copyright, Property, Authors’Rights, alienability, DawesAct.
I. INTRODUCTION
If you follow copyright law, it can’t have escaped your attention that, in the
US, the community of copyright law scholars has been deeply polarised
for the past 25 years. Some of us see ourselves as advocates for the
* John F. Nickoll Professor of Law and Professor of Information, University of Michigan. Address for
Correspondence: University of Michigan Law School, 625 S. State St., Ann Arbor, MI 48109, USA.
Email: jdlitman@umich.edu. This essay is adapted from the 13th Annual University of Cambridge
Centre for Intellectual Property and Information Law International Intellectual Property Lecture, deliv-
ered at Emmanuel College on 13 March 2018. I’m grateful to Jon Weinberg, Rebecca Giblin, Lionel
Bentley, Gautam Hans, Pam Samuelson, Kirsten Carlson and Laura Harlow for their extremely helpful
comments and suggestions. I first learned about the Dawes Act from Judge Betty Binns Fletcher, when
she was working on her en banc opinion in Blackfeet Tribe of Indians v State of Montana, 729 F.2d
1192 (9th Cir. 1984), aff’d 471 U.S. 759 (1985). I was lucky to clerk for Judge Fletcher that year,
and her continuing encouragement and support was immensely helpful in my career as a legal scholar.
Judge Fletcher died in 2012 at the age of 89 –an active senior judge who was still carrying a full case
load. According to the New York Times, she presided over a 9th Circuit hearing a week before her death.
Douglas Martin, “Betty Binns Fletcher Dies at 89; Liberal Stalwart on the Bench”,New York Times,
24 October 2012, available at <https://www.nytimes.com/2012/10/25/us/betty-binns-fletcher-liberal-
federal-judge-dies-at-89.html>.
Cambridge Law Journal, Page 1 of 23 © Cambridge Law Journal and Contributors 2018. This is an Open Access article,
distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which
permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
doi:10.1017/S0008197318000600
1
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
undervalued interests of readers and other users; others argue that we need
to increase the copyright protection we give to authors. It’s gotten a little
ugly.
1
We’ve called one another bad names.
2
Advocates for copyright own-
ers have described scholars who defend the rights of users as hired guns
paid by Google to write papers advancing its business interests.
3
Some
of us have stopped reading the work of scholars perceived to be on the
other side.
4
I believe (or at least I hope) that that whole sorry era is almost over, or
will be over as soon as we forgive one another for all the nasty name-
calling. As concrete reform proposals have emerged from the muck, it
has become apparent that what was billed as a conflict between authors
and users was never about that at all. Instead, what’s been going on is a
fight to the death among intermediaries. The highly publicised record
label lawsuits against individual users of peer-to-peer file-sharing applica-
tions
5
turn out to have been a feint in a fight to hold Internet service pro-
viders liable for the activity of their subscribers.
6
Bitter complaints about
online consumer piracy
7
were largely a prelude to efforts by major
1
See e.g. T. Reilly, “Copyright and a Synergistic Society”(2017) 18 Minnesota Journal of Law, Science
& Technology 575, at 591–609 (analysing scholarship arguing for limits on copyright and attributing
the authors’views to “copyright envy”).
2
See e.g. H. Hansen, D.O. Carson, E. Moglen, W. Seltzer and C. Sims, “Mickey Mice? Potential
Ramifications of Eldred v. Ashcroft”(2003) 13 Fordham Intell.Prop.Media & Ent.L.J 771, at 787
(“the anti-copyright professors”); H. Horbaczewski, “No Silver Lining for the Emperor’s New
Clothes: Golan and the Traditional Contours of Copyright”(2012) 59 J. Copyright Soc’y U.S.A.
865, at 865 (“scholars that viewed the copyright law as a constitutional abomination”); I.F.
Koenigsberg, “The Fifth Annual Christopher Meyer Memorial Lecture: Humpty Dumpty in
Copyright Land”(2004) 51 J. Copyright Soc’y U.S.A. 677, at 680 (“enemies of copyright”); M.A.
Lemley, “Faith-Based Intellectual Property”(2015) 62 UCLA Law Review 1328, at 1343 (“the IP faith-
ful”); Reilly, “Copyright and a Synergistic Society”, p. 625 (“anti-author proponents”); ibid., at p. 626
(“if one reads professorial accounts such as these closely, one can also detect the perfidious underlying
presence of ‘copyright envy’”); P. Samuelson, “The Copyright Grab”,WIRED, 1 January 1996, avail-
able at <https://www.wired.com/1996/01/white-paper/> (“copyright maximalists”); P. Schwartz and W.
M. Treanor, “Essay, Eldred and Lochner: Copyright Term Extension and Intellectual Property as
Constitutional Property”(2003) 112 Yale L.J. 2331, at 2331 (“the IP Restrictors”). Cf. K. McLeod,
Freedom of Expression (New York 2005), 65 (referring to copyright bullies as “overzealous copyright
bozos”).
3
See B. Mullins and J. Nickas, “Inside Google’s Academic Influence Campaign”,Wall Street Journal,
14 July 2017, available at <https://www.wsj.com/articles/paying-professors-inside-googles-academic-
influence-campaign-1499785286>; A. Rogers, “Google’s Academic Influence Campaign: It’s
Complicated”,WIRED, 14 July 2017, available at <https://www.wired.com/story/googles-academic-
influence-campaign-its-complicated/>.
4
See J. Litman, “War & Peace: The 34th Annual Donald C Brace Lecture”(2006) 53 J. Copyright Soc’y
U.S.A. 1; J. Litman, “The Politics of Intellectual Property”(2009) 27 Cardozo Arts & Ent.L.J. 313.
5
See e.g. Capitol Records v Thomas-Rasset, 692 F.3d 899 (8th Cir. 2012); Sony BMG Music
Entertainment v Tenenbaum, 660 F.3d 487 (1st Cir. 2011).
6
E.g. BMG Rights Management v Cox Communications, 881 F.3d 293 (4th Cir. 2018); EMI Christian
Music v MP3Tunes, 844 F.3d 79 (2d Cir. 2016). See C. Doctorow, Information Doesn’t Want to Be
Free: Laws for the Internet Age (San Francisco 2014), 80–89.
7
See e.g. Privacy and Piracy: The Paradox of Illegal File Sharing on Peer-to-Peer Networks and the
Impact of Technology on the Entertainment Industry, Hearing Before the Permanent Subcommittee
on Investigations of the Senate Committee on Government Affairs, 108th Congress (30 September
2003), 19–20 (testimony of L.L. Cool, recording artist); Promoting Investment and Protecting
Commerce Online: Legitimate Sites v. Para-sites, Hearing Before the Subcommittee On Intellectual
Property of the House Judiciary Committee, 112th Congress (14 March 2011), 61–62 (testimony of
Frederick Huntsberry, Paramount Pictures).
2 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
copyright owners to narrow the safe harbours for online services.
8
Legacy
intermediaries (by which I mean publishers, record labels, and movie stu-
dios) are fighting with new-fangled intermediaries (that is, online service
providers, platforms, and digital delivery businesses); what they are really
fighting about is who gets to eat the biggest piece of pie.
9
Copyright scholars can safely leave them to work it out without our help.
If the core question in that dispute is whether the law ought to favour pub-
lishers over platforms or vice versa, the answer is unlikely to significantly
change the copyright ecosystem. Neither side has much of a claim to the
moral high ground.
10
The players on both sides are large, well-financed
businesses with lots of lawyers in harness, so they don’t particularly
need the assistance of legal scholarship. That debate is less compelling
from a theoretical or policy perspective than many other problems the copy-
right system faces. If the distribution of goodies among old-fangled and
new-fangled intermediaries won’t have much impact on decisions sur-
rounding the balance the law should strike among writers and readers,
many scholars will lose interest in this particular conflict. So, after we
get our feet extracted from all the mud we’ve thrown at each other, I expect
that the community of copyright scholars will move on to more intriguing
issues.
In this essay, I hope to do two things. First, I’d like to focus attention on
an important issue that should have been central to our prior debates, but
somehow wasn’t: For all of the rhetoric about the central place of authors
in the copyright scheme, our copyright laws in fact give them little power
and less money. If a legal regime purportedly designed for the benefitof
authors systematically short-changes them, why does that happen and
what options might we have to respond? Copyright scholars mention this
problem often,
11
but have only rarely given it sustained attention.
8
See e.g. United States Copyright Office: Section 512 Public Roundtable, 2 May 2016, available at
<https://www.copyright.gov/policy/section512/public-roundtable/transcript_05-02-2016.pdf>.
9
See e.g. R. Levine, Free Ride: How the Internet is Destroying the Culture Business and How the
Culture Business Can Fight Back (London 2011); J. Taplin, Move Fast and Break Things: How
Facebook, Google, and Amazon Cornered Culture and Undermined Democracy (New York 2017);
G. Pessach, “Deconstructing Disintermediation: A Skeptical Copyright Perspective”(2013) 31
Cardozo Arts & Ent.L.J. 833; M. Rasenberger and C. Pepe, “Copyright Enforcement and Online File
Hosting Services: Have Courts Struck the Proper Balance”(2012) 59 J. Copyright Soc’y U.S.A.
627. Compare S.E. Siwek, Copyright Industries in the US Economy: 2016 Report (December 2016),
available at <http://www.iipawebsite.com/pdf/2016CpyrtRptFull.PDF>, with Computer and
Communications Industry Association, Fair Use Industries in the U.S. Economy: Economic
Contributions of Industries Relying on Fair Use (2017), available at <http://www.ccianet.org/wp-con-
tent/uploads/2017/06/Fair-Use-in-the-U.S.-Economy-2017.pdf>; US Copyright Office, Section 512
Study (2017), available at <https://www.copyright.gov/policy/section512/> (public comments and tran-
scripts of public roundtables).
10
See J.C. Ginsburg, “The Place of the Author in Copyright”in R.L. Okediji (ed.), Copyright Law in an
Age of Exceptions and Limitations (New York 2017), 60, 66–68.
11
See e.g. W. Patry, Moral Panics and the Copyright Wars (Oxford 2009), 117–19; D. Gervais, “User-
Generated Content and Music File-Sharing: A Look at Some of the More Interesting Aspects of Bill
C-32”in M. Geist (ed.), From “Radical Extremism”to “Balanced Copyright”: Canadian Copyright
And The Digital Agenda (Toronto 2010 ), 447, 450; R. Giblin, “Reimagining Copyright’s Duration”
C.L.J. 3What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
Second, I’ll try to offer an answer to the question why we’ve devoted so lit-
tle ink to the paltry nature of authors’real-world copyright benefits. This
issue, after all, is deeply important on both a practical and theoretical
level, so why don’t we write about it more? At least part of the answer,
I’ll suggest, lies in the ways that we, as lawyers, think about property rights.
II. DISEMPOWERED AUTHORS
Let me acknowledge my priors. Twenty-first-century copyright law is a
complex system with a bunch of interlocking and sometimes inconsistent
purposes, but I believe that the most important of those purposes are
these: first, copyright law should encourage authors to create and widely
disseminate works of authorship; second, it should give them meaningful
opportunities to earn money from doing so; and, third, copyright law should
encourage readers, listeners, viewers, and other users to encounter, enjoy
and learn from those works of authorship.
12
There are other purposes,
but they’re subsidiary. To hijack a turn of phrase popularised by
Amazon.com’s vice president Russ Grandinetti, the only essential players
in the copyright system are the author and the audience.
13
Of course, the copyright system needs intermediaries to convey the
works of authorship to their audiences and to channel the revenues
flowing from the enjoyment of those works back to authors, but we can,
and I think should, be agnostic as to whether the law should favour any
of the competing intermediaries over the others. The most important con-
sideration is how well they accomplish their tasks of disseminating works
to audiences and paying money to authors.
14
So, let’s look at how they’re doing at those tasks. How well is the current
global copyright system working out for authors and for readers? I’ve spent
much of my career arguing that the copyright interests of readers and other
consumers are receiving too little attention.
15
The problems the copyright
in R. Giblin and K. Weatherall (eds.), What If We Could Reimagine Copyright? (2017) 177, 193–96;
Ginsburg, “The Place of the Author in Copyright”; P.B. Hugenholtz, “The Great Copyright Robbery:
Rights Allocation in a Digital Environment”(2000), available at <https://www.ivir.nl/publicaties/down-
load/thegreatcopyrightrobbery.pdf>; M. Van Houweling, “Authors vs Owners”(2016) 54 Hous.L.R.
371; M. Van Houweling, “Distributive Values in Copyright”(2004) 83 Tex.L.Rev. 1535.
12
J. Litman, “Real Copyright Reform”(2010) 96 Iowa L.Rev. 1. See also e.g. Doctorow, Information
Doesn’t Want to Be Free, pp. 153–54.
13
See D. Streatfield, “Amazon Signs Up Authors, Writing Publishers Out of Deal”,New York Times,17
October 2011, p. A1 (quoting Grandinetti as having said: “The only really necessary people in the pub-
lishing process now are the writer and reader”).
14
Many intermediaries, whether they are book publishers, online marketplaces or social media platforms,
reasonably view their efforts at market analysis, strategy and design to involve great creativity.
Comparable creativity is, of course, often required to sell products, like wheelbarrows or hot sauce,
that are not works of authorship. The fact that intermediaries make creative and valuable contributions
to the copyright ecosystem doesn’t, without more, make them its indispensable beneficiaries.
15
See e.g. J. Litman, “Copyright Noncompliance (Or Why we Can’t‘Just Say Yes’to Licensing)”(1997)
29 N.Y.U. Journal of International Law & Policy 237; J. Litman, “The Exclusive Right to Read”(1994)
13 Cardozo Arts & Ent.L.J. 29; J. Litman, “Lawful Personal Use”(2007) 85 Tex.L.Rev. 1871.
4 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
law poses for readers haven’t evaporated. For one thing, at least in the US,
readers are paying for access to the works they encounter by giving up mas-
sive chunks of personal privacy.
16
US policymakers are beginning to appre-
ciate the risks of that approach, but it may already be too late to mend them.
For another, many copyright owners have succeeded, at least so far, in their
efforts to nullify the legal rights that the copyright law gives to users, by
purporting to bind consumers to overreaching end user license agree-
ments.
17
I’m concerned that that will end up severely undermining the
copyright system in the long term. Still, even with those problems, to the
extent that one goal of copyright is to give members of the public many
opportunities to enjoy a large variety of different works, in different formats
and at different price points, the current system is fabulously successful.
The situation for authors, on the other hand, is more depressing. The
copyright system, in truth, has never been very good at either giving
authors their choice of myriad channels for distributing their works to the
public, or enabling them to earn meaningful amounts of money from
doing so.
18
If an author’s goals are to communicate her works to their
best audience and to earn an income from doing so, her choices end up
being narrowly limited. Even if she succeeds in disseminating her work
through the most suitable channel, she needs to accept that the intermediary
who operates that channel will likely both control the distribution of her
works and keep most of the money those works earn.
19
In the eighteenth, nineteenth and twentieth centuries, this bargain prob-
ably seemed pretty reasonable. Paper was expensive.
20
Mass distribution
required paper, along with printing presses, bookstores, warehouses, trucks,
movie cameras and movie theatres, broadcast towers and communications
satellites –required, in other words, a significant capital investment.
21
It
made sense in that context to expect that as the revenues from works of
authorship flowed from users to authors, most of the money would be
diverted along the way to pay for expensive reproduction and distribution
solutions.
16
See e.g. J.M. Newman, “The Myth of Free”(2018) 86 G.W. Law Rev. 513, at 551–55; G.A. Fowler,
“Your Data Is Way More Exposed than You Think”,Wall Street Journal, 24 May 2017, available at
<https://www.wsj.com/articles/your-data-is-way-more-exposed-than-you-realize-1495657390>;
S. Schechner and N. Kostove, “Google and Facebook Likely to Benefit from Europe’s Privacy
Crackdown”,Wall Street Journal, 23 April 2017, available at <https://www.wsj.com/articles/how-eur-
opes-new-privacy-rules-favor-google-and-facebook-1524536324>.
17
See A. Perzanowski and J. Schultz, The End of Ownership (Cambridge, MA 2016), 15–101; M.J.
Radin, Boilerplate (Princeton 2013), 33–51, 168–76; see e.g. L. Hyde, Common as Air: Revolution,
Art, and Ownership (New York 2010), 66–68.
18
See e.g. Doctorow, Information Doesn’t Want to Be Free, pp. xxii–xxv.
19
See Litman, “Real Copyright Reform”, pp. 8–12.
20
See M.A. Carroll, “Whose Music Is it Anyway? How We Came to View Musical Expression as a Form
of Property”(2004) 72 U.Cin.L.Rev. 1405, at 1471.
21
See e.g. J. Litman, “Sharing and Stealing”(2004) 26 Hastings Communication & Entertainment Law
Journal 1, at 2.
C.L.J. 5What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
In the twenty-first century, that explanation doesn’t seem so reasonable.
At least some popular reproduction and distribution alternatives are much
less expensive than the older sorts.
22
Digital reproduction, digital down-
loads and online streaming can be downright cheap –the fact that anyone
can afford to do it is said to be a primary driver of increasing consumer pir-
acy.
23
By all accounts, moreover, the money attributable to the distribution
and enjoyment of works of authorship is at an all-time high.
24
Yet creators
report that they are being paid much less than they used to be paid.
25
Some of the explanation for that might relate to the winner-take-all struc-
ture of many of the copyright intensive industries. J.K. Rowling,
26
Damien
Hirst,
27
Beyoncé Knowles,
28
George Lucas
29
and Lin Manual Miranda
30
have earned a bunch of money from their works of authorship. The majority
of creators, in contrast, regularly face the choice of living perilously close to
22
See e.g. Hyde, Common as Air, pp. 64–65; M.A. Lemley, “IP in a World Without Scarcity”(2015) 90
N.Y.U.L.Rev. 460, at 482–94.
23
See e.g. O. Kerr, “A Lukewarm Defense of the Digital Millennium Copyright Act”in A. Thierer and C.
W. Crews (eds.), CopyFights: The Future of Intellectual Property in the Information Age (Washington
2002), 163, 165–67; F. Von Lohmann, “Measuring the Digital Millennium Copyright Act Against the
Darknet: Implications for the Regulation of Technological Protection Measures”(2004) 24 Loy.L.A.
Ent.L.Rev. 635, at 638–43.
24
See e.g. J.P. Friedlander, “RIAA Year-End Music Industry Revenue Report”, 22 March 2018, available
at <http://www.riaa.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/RIAA-Year-End-2017-News-and-Notes.pdf>;
Siwek, “Copyright Industries in the US Economy”; A. Szamosszegi and M.A. McCleary, “Fair Use
in the US Economy”(2017), available at <https://www.ccianet.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/06/Fair-
Use-in-the-U.S.-Economy-2017.pdf>. Reports focusing on particular income streams earned by some
legacy intermediaries don’t count all of the revenue that new-fangled intermediaries are collecting as
a result of the online dissemination of works of authorship. See e.g. Statista, “Dossier: Film Industry
in the U.S.”(2018), available at <https://www.statista.com/study/11472/film-industry-in-the-united-
states-statista-dossier/>. That money is of course part of the total that should be available for author
compensation. Moreover, those industry sector-specific reports indicate that legacy intermediaries are
earning impressive profits, despite the large amounts of money paid to platforms and other new-fangled
intermediaries. See e.g. ibid.; Friedlander, “RIAA Year-End Music Industry Revenue Report”,p.1.
25
See e.g. K. Cowdray, “ALCS Survey Finds 15% Drop in Average Author Earnings since 2013”,The
Bookseller, 27 June 2018, available at <https://www.thebookseller.com/news/alcs-reveals-average-
author-earnings-even-lower-four-years-ago-818891>; D. Dupont, “Composer Maria Schneider Warns
Students about the Future of the Music Industry”,Bowling Green Independent News, 31 March
2018, available at <http://bgindependentmedia.org/composer-maria-schneider-warns-students-about-
the-future-of-the-music-industry/>; M. Harris, “How Much Is a Word Worth?”,Medium, 16 April
2018, available at <https://medium.com/s/story/how-much-is-a-word-worth-7fcd131a341c>;
D. Preston, “Why Is it So God damned Hard to Make a L iving as a Writer Today ?”,Authors
Guild Bulletin 63, Summer 2017.
26
See J.B. Stewart, “In the Chamber of Secrets: J.K. Rowling’s Net Worth”,New York Times,24
November 2016, available at <https://www.nytimes.com/2016/11/24/business/in-the-chamber-of-
secrets-jk-rowlings-net-worth.html>.
27
See E. Kinsella, “Damien Hirst and Anish Kapoor Land on UK Rich List (Again)”,Artnet News, 8 May
2017, available at <https://news.artnet.com/art-world/artists-on-sunday-times-rich-list-952055>.
28
See Z. O’Malley Greenburg, “The World’s Highest Paid Women in Music 2017”,Forbes, 20 November
2017, available at <https://www.forbes.com/sites/zackomalleygreenburg/2017/11/20/the-worlds-high-
est-paid-women-in-music-2017/>.
29
See Z. O’Malley Greenburg, “America’s Wealthiest Celebrities: The Top 10 by Net Worth”,Forbes,18
December 2017, available at <https://www.forbes.com/sites/zackomalleygreenburg/2017/12/18/ameri-
cas-wealthiest-celebrities-2017-the-top-ten-by-net-worth/>.
30
See M. Paulson and D. Gelles, “Hamilton, Inc.: The Path to a Billion-Dollar Broadway Show”, 8 June
2016, available at <https://www.nytimes.com/2016/06/12/theater/hamilton-inc-the-path-to-a-billion-
dollar-show.html>.
6 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
the poverty line or working at a day job to support their families.
31
But that
isn’t a new thing.
32
If creators are earning even less than they used to, there
are other factors at work.
This is a complicated problem with multiple causes, but one of the causes
is that many of the intermediaries in our story have recently figured out
ways to earn more but pay authors less. I alluded earlier to the conflict
between old-fangled and new-fangled intermediaries. The legacy intermedi-
aries seem to be incensed that service providers and platforms are collecting
a large share of the revenues earned by copyrighted works. They’ve
invented a catch phrase, the “value gap”, to describe their complaint,
which is that the new-fangled intermediaries have too much bargaining
power and are able to use that bargaining power to negotiate lower license
fees than the legacy intermediaries believe that they should pay.
33
Publishers, record labels, and motion picture studios argue that lawmakers
should change the law to tilt the playing field in their favour, so that they
can bargain for higher fees.
34
Meanwhile, though, they are making up for
what they believe are pitifully inadequate licensing fees by structuring the
licensing deals to minimise their own obligation to pay royalties to crea-
tors.
35
If Spotify or YouTube pays copyright owners for the use of
music, for example, by giving music publishers and record labels an equity
stake in the company, or by paying an annual up-front blanket license fee,
none of that money needs to be passed on to composers or musicians.
36
31
See e.g. T. London and B. Pesner, Outrageous Fortune: The Life and Times of the New American Play
(New York 2009), 50–96; R. Deahl, “New Guild Survey Reveals Majority of Authors Earn Below
Poverty Line”,Publishers Weekly, 11 September 2015, available at <https://www.publishersweekly.
com/pw/by-topic/industry-news/publisher-news/article/68008-new-guild-survey-reveals-majority-of-
authors-earn-below-poverty-line.html>; J. Gibson, P. Johnson and G. Dimita, “The Business of Being an
Author: A Survey of Authors’Earnings and Contracts”, April 2015, available at <https://orca.cf.ac.uk/
72431/1/Final%20Report%20-%20For%20Web%20Publication.pdf>; M. Kretschmer, “Does Copyright
Law Matter? An Empirical Analysis of Creators Earnings”, 21 May 2012, available at SSRN: <https://
ssrn.com/abstract=2063735>; M. Kretschmer, S. Singh, L. Bently and E. Cooper, “2011 Copyright
Contracts and Earnings of Visual Creators: A Survey of 5800 British Designers, Fine Artists,
Illustrators and Photographers”, 2011, available at <https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/4899875.pdf>.
32
See e.g. H. Finklestein, “The Copyright Law: A Reappraisal”(1956) 104 U.Pa.L.Rev. 1025, at 1051;
M. O’Rourke, “Bargaining in the Shadow of Copyright Law After Tasini”(2003) 53 Case W.Res.L.
Rev. 605, at 613–14.
33
See G. Peoples, “War of Words: Labels and Trade Groups Target YouTube’s‘Value Gap’”,Billboard,
13 April 2016, available at <https://www.billboard.com/articles/business/7333110/war-of-words-labels-
trade-groups-youtube-value-gap>; see e.g. Joint Comments of the American Association of Independent
Music et. al., In re: Section 512 Study, 31 March 2016, available at <https://www.riaa.com/wp-content/
uploads/2016/03/Music-Community-Submission-in-re-DMCA-512-FINAL-7559445.pdf>; International
Federation of the Phonographic Industry, “Europe’s Creators, Cultural and Creative Industries’Call
to the European Council: Secure the Aims of the Proposed Copyright Directive in the DSM”,12
April 2018, available at <http://www.ifpi.org/downloads/EU_Creators_Cultural_and_Creative_
Industries_Call_to_European_Council.pdf>.
34
See e.g. IFPI, “Rewarding Creativity: Fixing the Value Gap”, available at <http://www.ifpi.org/value_-
gap.php> (visited 19 April 2018).
35
See e.g. K. Garcia, “Private Copyright Reform”(2013) 20 Mich. Telecom. & Technology Law Review
1, at 22–23, 27–29.
36
See e.g. 19 Recordings v Sony Music Entertainment, No. 14-CV-1056 (SDNY filed 24 June 2015);
Z. O’Malley Greenburg, “Revenge of the Record Labels: How the Majors Renewed Their Grip on
Music”,Forbes, 15 April 2015, available at <https://www.forbes.com/sites/zackomalleygreenburg/
C.L.J. 7What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
In a similar vein, publishers have reinterpreted extant contracts and
redrafted new contracts to reduce the royalty rates for digital distribution
of the works they control. In standard 20
th
century book and music publish-
ing and recording contracts, authors were paid a small percentage of rev-
enue for the manufacture and distribution of hard copies and a larger
share of the income from licensing the work to another business.
37
That
made sense; the smaller royalty for hard copies reflected the expense of
manufacturing and distributing the copies, neither of which were implicated
by licensing deals. When publishers and record labels licensed works to
music and eBook distribution services to enable the services to make the
works available for paid digital downloads, though, they insisted that
they need only pay the lower royalty rate designated for the sale of hard
copies, and that’s the rate that they paid.
38
On one level, none of this should surprise us. Of course, the people who
control the terms and conditions of use will structure those terms and con-
ditions in ways that best advance their own interests. What I find notable is
how little attention these recent moves have attracted from legal scholars.
Indeed, even though we are all likely aware of these developments (because
we live in the world), if you read most of what American copyright scholars
have written about copyright revision, you’d conclude we don’t think that
these developments should worry us as much as other problems.
39
2015/04/15/revenge-of-the-record-labels-how-the-majors-renewed-their-grip-on-music>. In 2016,
major record labels in the US announced that musicians would eventually be paid a share of the
profits that the labels earned from selling their equity stakes in Spotify, but have been slow to disclose
specifics. Z. O’Malley Greenburg, “Spotify Goes Public at $30 Billion: When Will Artists See Any of
That?”,Forbes, 3 April 2018, available at <https://www.forbes.com/sites/zackomalleygreenburg/2018/
04/03/spotify-ipo-goes-public-at-30-billion-when-will-artists-see-any-of-that>. Sony Music
Entertainment sold half of its equity stake in Spotify in April of 2018, earning an estimated $761 mil-
lion. In June of 2018, the company promised that it would pass along a portion of the proceeds from the
sale to artists and independent labels beginning in August. See M. Newman, “Sony Music
Entertainment to Start Paying Indie Artists and Labels Spotify Sale Proceeds as Early as August”,
Billboard, 14 June 2018, available at <https://www.billboard.com/articles/business/8461117/sony-
music-canada-spotify-pay-indie-artists-labels>. Warner Music sold 75% of its stake in Spotify in
May of 2018, but, as of this writing, has not revealed its plans for sharing the money with creators.
37
See e.g. R. Curtis, How to Be Your Own Literary Agent: An Insider ’s Guide to Getting Your Book
Published (New York 2003), 62–76, 295–97; N. Aragon, “Note: Calculating Artists’Royalties: An
Analysis of the Courts’Dualistic Interpretations of Recording Contracts Negotiated in a Pre-Digital
Age”(2017) 2017 Cardozo Law Review De Novo 180, at 184–88; L. Blake and D.K. Stuart,
“Analysis of a Recording Contract”in M. Halloran (ed.), The Musician’s Business and Legal Guide
(Upper Saddle River 2008), 282, 312–13.
38
See e.g. FBT Productions v Aftermath Records, 621 F.3d 958 (9th Cir 2010); Tavares v Capitol
Records, LLC, 2013 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 34317 (ND Cal. 2013); cf. Keiler v Harlequin Enters., 751
F.3d 64 (2d Cir. 2013) (book publisher evaded 50% license royalty by sublicensing to its own subsid-
iary for an artificially low price). There’s been some litigation over this, with mixed results. One court
concluded that the plain language of particular contracts obliges record labels to pay the larger licensing
royalty for digital downloads. FBT Productions, 621 F.3d 958 (9th Cir 2010), 964–66. A different court
held that the plain language of an essentially similar contract supports the argument that royalties for
digital download licenses should be the same as royalties for the sale of hard copies. Malmsteen v
Universal Music Group, 940 F. Supp. 2D 123, 132–33 (SDNY 2013).
39
This assertion is controversial. Indeed, some scholars will find it offensive. Everyone who writes copy-
right scholarship views her work as pro-creator and pro-creativity, and believes that her proposals will
improve the way the system works for the ultimate benefit of creators, however defined. I’m not sug-
gesting that scholars have not cared about creators, or have failed to produce proposals designed to
8 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
European scholars have recently paid somewhat more attention to this col-
lection of issues as part of a contentious effort to revise the European
Directive on Copyright in the Digital Single Market,
40
and their reports
have been dismaying. Real-world creators encounter significant obstacles
to enjoying the rights and receiving the compensation that the law in theory
affords them.
41
Yet proposed solutions seem both modest and unlikely to
effect significant improvement.
42
Meanwhile, even those small correctives
seem as if they would be unthinkable additions to current American
efforts at copyright reform.
If all of us can see these issues, at least in broad outline, and if at least
some of us believe that these problems undermine the value and legitimacy
of the copyright system, why have we not come up with better suggestions
for addressing it?
One possibility is that many of us have concluded that it’s hopeless: the
problem seems insoluble. Copyright intermediaries have too many oppor-
tunities to take advantage of creators and too few reasons to refrain from
exploiting them. Over the past three hundred years, copyright laws have
incorporated a variety of provisions intended to protect creators from over-
reaching intermediaries; none of them has been particularly effective. In the
US, our copyright history is teeming with court decisions that gutted statu-
tory safeguards for authors’rights.
Although US copyright law has always required that transfers of copy-
right be made only by a signed writing,
43
nineteenth-century publishers
benefit them. I’m urging, rather, that our scholarship has paid too little attention the practical obstacles
many creators face in taking advantage of the rights conferred by copyright law on copyright owners.
Almost all of us (and I don’t exclude myself) have failed to examine the ways that recent copyright
practices and proposals give creators even less money and control than past practices and proposals.
To the extent that we have an imperfect understanding of the mechanics of the copyright system in prac-
tice, our ideas for fixing it are likely to fall short.
40
See European Commission, “Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on
Copyright in the Digital Single Market”, 14 September 2016, available at <http://ec.europa.eu/transpar-
ency/regdoc/rep/1/2016/EN/1-2016-593-EN-F1-1.PDF>. Most of the controversy centres on whether
proposals to rebalance the law to provide more robust rights to publishers and impose more onerous
obligations on platforms are good or bad policy. See e.g. P. Samuelson, “Legally Speaking: The
EU’s Controversial Digital Single Market Directive”,61Communications of the ACM, forthcoming
November 2018; “Google Criticized for Push Against EU Copyright Reform”,Financial Times,26
June 2018, available at <https://www.ft.com/content/a8031d7a-78a0-11e8-bc55-50daf11b720d>;
M. Banks, “MEPs Rally against Planned EU Copyright Reform”,The Parliament, 8 June 2018, avail-
able at <https://www.theparliamentmagazine.eu/articles/news/meps-rally-against-planned-eu-copyright-
reform>; K.G. Orphanides, “The EU’s Bizarre War on Memes is Totally Unwinnable”,Wired, 18 June
2018, available at <http://www.wired.co.uk/article/eu-meme-war-article-13-regulation>.
41
See e.g. L. Bently, “Between a Rock and a Hard Place: The Problems Facing Freelance Creators in the
UK Media Marketplace, A Briefing Document on Behalf of the Creators Rights Alliance”, 29 June
2009, available at <http://www.creatorsrights.org.uk/media/between.pdf>; Gibson, “The Business of
Being an Author”; Kretschmer, “Does Copyright Law Matter?”.
42
Chapter 3 of the current draft EU directive would oblige member states to ensure that authors and per-
formers receive regular reports on the revenue generated by their works and the remuneration to which
they are entitled, and to provide mechanisms for authors and performers to request additional remuner-
ation when the revenues earned from their works are grossly disproportionate to the revenues anticipated
when a copyright assignment or licensing agreement was negotiated. See note 40 above.
43
See e.g. Copyright Act of 1790, § 2, 1 Stat. 124, 1st Cong. 2d Sess. (1790); Act. of February 3, 1831, §
§ 6, 7, 21stCong. 2d Sess. (1831); Rev. Stat. § § 4964, 4965.
C.L.J. 9What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
persuaded courts that that prerequisite did not limit their ability to secure
ownership of the copyrights in works that had not yet been published
and registered.
44
The copyright renewal term was intended to enable
an author who had assigned her copyright in the first term to renegotiate
the terms of any licenses or assignments.
45
In 1943, however, music
publisher M. Witmark & Sons persuaded a divided Supreme Court
that an assignment of the renewal term during the initial term was
enforceable against the author.
46
In the 1976 Copyright Act, Congress
replaced the renewal term with an inalienable right to terminate any
assignment, grant, or license, and provided expressly that an author
was entitled to terminate “notwithstanding any agreement to the con-
trary”.
47
The House Report explained that, in contrast to the ownership
of the renewal term, “the right to take this action cannot be waived in
advance or contracted away”.
48
Yet, assignees of copyright have devised
strategies for undermining the supposed inalienable termination right,
and have largely succeeded in persuading courts of their effectiveness.
49
44
See e.g. Parton v Prang, 18 F. Cas. 1273, 1278 (C.C.D. Mass. 1872); Lawrence v Dana, 15 F. Cas. 26
(C.C.D. Mass 1869); Pulte v Derby, 20 F. Cas. 51 (C.C. D. Ohio 1852). See generally J. Litman, “What
Notice Did”(2016) 96 B.U.L.Rev. 717, at 724–31.
45
H.R. Rep. No. 2222, 60th Cong. 14 (1909). See J.J. Guinan, Jr., “Duration of Copyright: Study No. 30”
(1957), 77–79, reprinted in Copyright Society of the USA, Studies on Copyright, vol. 1 (1963), 495–97;
B.A. Ringer, “Renewal of Copyright: Study No. 31”(1960), 121–22, reprinted in Copyright Society of
the USA, Studies on Copyright, vol. 2 (1963), 503, 517–18.
46
Fred Fisher Music Co. v M. Witmark & Sons, 318 U.S. 643 (1943). The majority rejected the argument
that the statute should be construed to preserve the author’s opportunity to renegotiate the terms of
licenses or assignments:
The policy of the copyright law, we are told, is to protect the author –if need be, from himself
–and a construction under which the author is powerless to assign his renewal interest
furthers this policy. We are asked to recognize that authors are congenitally irresponsible,
that frequently they are so sorely pressed for funds that they are willing to sell their work
for a mere pittance, and therefore assignments made by them shou ld not be upheld....
It is not for courts to judge whether the interests of authors clearly lie upon one side of this
question rather than the other. If an author cannot make an effective assignment of his
renewal, it may be worthless to him when he is most in need. Nobody would pay an author
for something he cannot sell. We cannot draw a principle of law from the familiar stories of
garret-poverty of some men of literary genius. Even if we could do so, we cannot say that
such men would regard with favour a rule of law preventing them from realizing on their
assets when they are most in need of funds. ...
We conclude, therefore, that the Copyright Act of 1909 does not nullify agreements by
authors to assign their renewal interests (ibid., at 656–57).
47
17 USC § 203(a)(5). See generally R.A. Reese, “Termination Formalities and Notice”(2016) 96 B.U.L.
Rev. 895; Authors Alliance, “Termination of Transfers”(2017), available at <https://www.authorsalli-
ance.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/20180315-ToT-Templates.pdf>.
48
H.R. Rep. No. 1476, 94th Cong. 125 (1976).
49
E.g. Larson v Warner Brothers, 640 Fed. Appx. (9th Cir. 2016); Marvel Characters v Kirby, 726 F. 3d
119 (2d Cir. 2013); DC Comics v Pacific Pictures Corp., 545 Fed, Appx. 678 (9th Cir. 2013); Penguin
Group (USA) Inc. v Steinbeck, 537 F.3d 193, 196 (2d Cir. 2008), cert. denied, 129 S. Ct. 2383 (2009);
Milne v Stephen Slesinger, Inc., 430 F.3d 1036, 1039 (9th Cir. 2005). See e.g. L.P. Loren,
“Renegotiating the Copyright Deal in the Shadow of the Inalienable Right to Terminate”(2010) 62
Fla.L.Rev. 1329; P. Menell and D. Nimmer, “Judicial Resistance to Copyright’s Inalienable Right to
Terminate Transfers”(2010) 33 Columbia Journal of Law & the Arts 227.
10 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
Thus, authors’ability to recapture copyright rights has, in practice, been
narrowly limited.
50
Also in the 1976 Act, Congress narrowed the circumstances under
which an independent contractor’s work could be deemed a work made
for hire, legally authored by the creator’s employer. Under the current
copyright act, works created by employees are works made for hire.
Works created by independent contractors, however, can be works
made for hire only if the creator signs a work made for hire contract.
51
That hasn’t prevented courts from concluding that works created by indi-
viduals who are not treated as employees for the purposes of labour and
tax laws should nonetheless be deemed to be employee-created works
made for hire,
52
or that works created by independent contractors who
have not signed a work made for hire agreement should be considered
to have been authored by the entity that paid for their creation, because
that entity’s decision-making authority made it the “dominant author”
of the work.
53
Even when the courts construe the statute in authors’favour, moreover,
those interpretations have little practical effect on authors’opportunities to
control or earn money from their works. In 1993, freelance journalists
filed suit against the New York Times, claiming that the Times’licensing
of their contributions to electronic and online databases infringed their
reproduction, distribution and public display rights. Their initial permis-
sion to the Times to print their articles in its newspaper, they insisted,
did not allow the Times to resell those articles to electronic database ser-
vices. The Times argued that a privilege in the statute permitting the pub-
lisher of a collective work to reprint contributions to the collective work
only as “part of the collective work, any revision of that collective
work, or any later collective work in the same series”,
54
authorised it to
license full issues of its newspaper to digital publishers. The trial court
50
Nor do copyright owners appear to be willing to allow the new or enhanced copyright rights they are
seeking to be subject to comparable recapture provisions. Congress is currently considering the
CLASSICS Act, a Bill that would establish an entitlement to royalties for the digital transmission of
sound recordings that were recorded before US law extended copyright protection to sound recordings.
See S. 2334, title 2, 115th Cong. (2018). Although the Bill is described by the recording industry asso-
ciation as a measure to “finally ensure that musicians and vocalists who made those timeless songs
finally get their due”, see Recording Industry Association of America, “Press Release: Historic
Coalition of 213 Musical Artists Calls on Congress to Pass CLASSICS Act, Fix the ‘Pre-1972’
Loophole for Legacy Artists”, 13 February 2018, available at <https://www.riaa.com/historic-
coalition-213-musical-artists-calls-congress-pass-classics-act-fix-pre-1972-loophole-legacy-artists/>, it
includes no provisions that would allow the original authors of the sound recordings to recapture the
ownership of rights they assigned to record labels.
51
17 USC §§ 101, 201. See Community for Creative Non Violence v Reid, 490 US 730 (1989). In addition
to imposing the requirement of a signed writing, section 101 limits the category of commissioned works
made for hire to nine specific subject matter categories. See United States Copyright Office, Circular
No. 9: Works Made for Hire (2012), available at <https://www.copyright.gov/circs/circ09.pdf>.
52
See e.g. JustMed v Byce, 600 F.3d 1118 (9th Cir. 2010); JAH IP Holdings v Mascio, 2014 US Dist
LEXIS 16246 (D. Colo. 2014).
53
See 16 Casa Duse v Merkin, 791 F.3d 247, 260 (2d Cir. 2015).
54
17 USC § 201(c).
C.L.J. 11What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
agreed.
55
In 2001, the US Supreme Court concluded that the purpose of
the statutory privilege was to protect authors’abilities to license their
works to other publishers, while enabling the publisher of the initial col-
lective work to print revised editions without again securing permission
from every contributor. That purpose would be frustrated if the publishers
could license the individual contributions to electronic databases.
56
In response to the Supreme Court’s ruling, the New York Times
announced that rather than compensating 27,000 freelance authors for the
unauthorised licensing of their works to digital databases, it would instead
permit individual authors to request that the Times continue to make all
their works digitally available, without any additional payment, on the con-
dition that the authors release all legal claims against the Times and its data-
base licensees. Otherwise, the newspaper would purge all of those
freelancers’contributions from its database.
57
Further, in response to the
lawsuit, the New York Times and other large publishers insisted, going for-
ward, that all freelance journalists sign work made for hire or all rights con-
tracts authorising publishers to exploit the works in future as well as
existing media for no additional payment.
58
As Maureen O’Rourke noted:
“Although the holding in the case ostensibly gave freelancers a bargaining
chip, a lack of bargaining power precludes their obtaining additional con-
sideration for licensing their judicially vindicated rights.”
59
Nor have authors outside of the US fared significantly better. Recent
studies of the effectiveness of copyright law reforms in the EU designed
to improve the lot of creators have concluded that the reforms enacted so
far have been ineffective, primarily because authors lack the bargaining
power to take advantage of them.
60
55
Tasini v NY Times, 972 F. Supp. 804 (SDNY 2007), rev’d 206 F.3d 161 (2d Cir. 2000), aff’d 533 U.S.
483 (2001).
56
NY Times v Tasini, 533 U.S. 483, 499–506 (2001).
57
See F. Barringer, “Freelancers Suing Again on Copyright”,New York Times, 6 July 2001, available at
<https://www.nytimes.com/2001/07/06/business/freelancers-suing-again-on-copyright.html>:
The Times’s current offer to freelancers –about 27,000 are affected, the newspaper estimates
–allows them to request that their material remain available electronically. It contains a pro-
vision that “should you opt to have your work restored, you agree that you will not be com-
pensated and that you will release The Times from any claims relating to your work appearing
in electronic archives such as Nexis.”
Any request must cover all of a freelancer’s contributions to The Times; no freelancers can
pick and choose how much of their work can remain available.
(ibid.). See “Tasini v The New York Times: A Note on the Consequences”, 2 Complete Review Quarterly
#3, August 2001, available at <http://www.complete-review.com/quarterly/vol2/issue3/tasini.htm>.
58
See O’Rourke, “Bargaining in the Shadow”, pp. 605–13.
59
Ibid., at p. 606.
60
See e.g. J.C. Ginsburg and P. Sirinelli, “Private International Law Aspects of Authors’Contracts: The
Dutch and French Examples”(2015) 39 Columbia Journal of Law & the Arts 171; S. Dusollier, C. Ker,
M. Iglesias and Y. Smith, “Contractual Arrangements Applicable to Creators: Law and Practice of
Selected Member States”, study commissioned by the European Parliament Directorate-General for
Internal Policies (2014), available at <http://www.cross-innovation.eu/wp-content/uploads/2014/03/
IPOL-JURI_ET2014493041_EN.pdf>; Europe Economics IViR, “Remuneration of Authors of Books
12 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
Too often, copyright scholars’work neglects questions of money. Even
when we focus on authors’compensation, we don’talwayspayattentionto
whether the money actually makes its way into creators’pockets. Recently,
we’ve been asking collecting societies to do the hard work of managing remu-
neration for many small-change uses.
61
We’ve learned that collecting money
is easy, but figuring out how to divide it among worthy claimants is really
hard.
62
The statutory, regulatory, and contractual provisions that authorise col-
lective licensing call for the revenues to be distributed to creators and other
rights holders, but the mechanisms that we use for deciding how to allocate
and pay them are at best imperfect
63
and often deeply flawed.
64
Collecting
societies are themselves intermediaries who will seek to protect their own
positions in the copyright food chain.
65
We know that there are some collect-
ing entities that pay at least a share of their receipts directly to creators. There
are others who pay owners, and rely on the owners to pass the creators’share
on. Others dole out the money to organisations that represent creators and task
those organisations with figuring out whether and how to distribute the funds
to their members. Still others hold the money in an interest-bearing account
until prospective claimants can agree with each other on who receives what
share, and divide the money up according to their agreement. There are
still others who don’t disburse the royalties at all –they use the money to
pay administrative costs and fund good works.
66
and Scientific Journals, Translators, Journalists and Visual Artists for the Use of Their Works”, study
prepared for the European Commission (2016), available at <https://www.ivir.nl/publicaties/download/
remuneration_of_authors_final_report.pdf>.
61
See A. Katz, “Copyright Collectives: Good Solution but for Which Problem”in R.C. Dreyfuss,
D. Zimmerman and H. First (eds.), Working Within the Boundaries of Intellectual Property:
Innovation Policy for the Knowledge Society (New York 2010); see e.g. Music Modernization Act,
H.R. 5447, 115th Cong. § 102 (2018) (establishing a new music publisher-owned collective to receive
and distribute royalties for a new statutory blanket license for the reproduction of musical compositions
in the course of digital streaming). See generally D. Gervais (ed.), Collective Management of Copyright
and Related Rights, 3rd ed. (Frederick 2016).
62
See e.g. W. Fisher III, Promises to Keep: Technology, Law & the Future of Entertainment (Stanford,
CA 2004), 207–36; D. Gervais, (Re)structuring Copyright: A Comprehensive Path to International
Copyright Reform (Cheltenham 2017), 238–56; European Commission, “Directive on Collective
Management of Copyright”, 4 February 2014, available at <http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/copy-
right/management/>; European Commission StaffWorking Document Impact Assessment
Accompanying the Document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the
Council on collective management of copyright and related rights and multi-territorial licensing of
rights in musical works for online uses in the internal market 19–29, 11 July 2012, available at
<http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52012SC0204&from=EN> (herein-
after “Commission StaffWorking Document”).
63
See e.g. Litman, “Real Copyright Reform”, p. 50 and n. 229.
64
See e.g. Copyright Royalty Board New Developments, 10 March 2017, available at <https://www.crb.
gov/> (announcing suspension of royalty distribution proceedings required by 17 USC § 1007);
Commission StaffWorking Document, pp. 15–29.
65
See J. Band and B. Butler, “Some Cautionary Tales about Collective Licensing”(2013) 21 Michigan
State International Law Review 687; see e.g. M. Long, “Publishers Raise New Concerns over SGAE
Practices”,IQ Magazine, 11 June 2018, available at <https://www.iq-mag.net/2018/06/publishers-
new-concerns-sgae-practices/#.Wx_5t1Mvw74>.
66
See e.g. H. Wijminga, W. Klomp, M. van der Jagt and J. Poort, “World Intellectual Property
Association International Survey on Private Copying: Law and Practice 2016”(2017), available at
<http://www.wipo.int/edocs/pubdocs/en/wipo_pub_1037_2017.pdf>.
C.L.J. 13What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
Most legal scholars don’t spend much attention examining this problem,
or trying to ascertain what mechanisms different collecting entities use for
deciding how to disburse the money they collect. It’s as if, once we’ve pro-
vided that consumers and users must buy a ticket in order to enjoy a copy-
righted work, we’re done. There may be some policy justification for
charging fees as a purely expressive exercise, so that users will understand
that enjoyment of a copyrighted work has commercial value. It’s wasteful,
in the sense that some members of an author’s audience will miss encoun-
tering the work because they can’tafford or don’t want to pay the ticket
price, but we may make that choice nonetheless to send the message that
enjoying works of authorship should not be free.
67
If that’s why we’re
doing it, though, we should say so. If, on the other hand, our purported rea-
son for levying the charge is to put money into creators’pockets, it might
be a good idea to look to see how much of it actually gets there. At least in
the US, that question hasn’t been the focus of much legal scholarship.
68
Some copyright scholars have begun to ask the question whether and
when creators respond to the rewards promised by copyright, and to try
to harness the insights of disciplines other than the law –economics, psych-
ology, neurology, history –to see whether it might be possible to come up
with answers.
69
It’sdifficult, though, to evaluate whether the answers to
that question have real-world significance without knowing whether and
under what circumstances creators will actually collect those rewards.
If I’m right that most of us have given up on close scrutiny of author
compensation because we suspect that it’s a hopeless inquiry, this may
be a good time to re-examine that impulse. That, however, would require
us to confront the questions we no longer ask and the features of the copy-
right system that we seldom notice, because we’ve grown inured to the
67
Cf. J.C. Ginsburg, “Fair Use for Free, or Permitted-but-Paid?”(2015) 29 Berkeley Tech.L.J. 1383.
68
But see P. DiCola, “Money From Music: Survey Evidence on Musicians’Revenue and Lessons About
Copyright Incentives”(2013) 55 ACJ 301. There are a number of recent economic and legal studies
from Europe, with discouraging conclusions. See e.g. M. Kretschmer, “Copyright and Contracts:
Regulating Creator Contracts: The State of the Art and a Research Agenda”(2010) 18 J.Intell.Prop.
L. 141; R. Towse, “Economics of Copyright Collecting Societies and Digital Rights: Is there a Case
for a Centralised Digital Copyright Exchange?”(2012) 9 Review of Economic Research on
Copyright Issues 3; C. Handke and R. Towse, “Economics of Copyright Collecting Societies”
(2007) 38 International Review of Intellectual Property & Competition Law 937; R. Towse,
“Copyright and Artists: A View From Cultural Economics”(2006) 20 Journal Economic Surveys
567; Europe Economics IViR, “Remuneration of Authors”; M. Kretschmer, “Private Copying and
Fair Compensation: An Empirical Study of Copyright Levies in Europe”(2011), available at
<https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/
310183/ipresearch-faircomp-201110.pdf>.
69
E.g. G. Lunney, Copyright’s Excess: Money and Music in the US Recording Industry (Cambridge
2018); C. Sprigman, “Copyright and Creative Incentives: What We Know (and Don’t)”(2017) 55
Hous.L.R. 451; R. Tushnet, “Economies of Desire: Fair Use and Marketplace Assumptions”(2009)
51 William & Mary Law Review 513; D. Zimmerman, “Copyright As Incentives: Did We Just
Imagine That?”(2010) 12 Theo Inq Law 29; M. Senftleben, “Copyright, Creators, & Society’s Need
for Autonomous Art –the Blessing and Curse of Monetary Incentives”(2017) in Giblin and
Weatherall, What If We Could Reimagine Copyright?, p. 25. See also CREATe Copyright Research
Centre at the University of Glasgow, Copyright Evidence Wiki, available at <http://www.copyrightevi-
dence.org/evidence-wiki/index.php/Copyright_Evidence> (cataloguing empirical studies).
14 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
ways that the copyright system fails to deliver on the promises of copyright
theory.
III. COPYRIGHT AND PROPERTY
In the rest of this essay, I’ll argue that one reason we talk less than we
should about how the copyright system commonly fails to reward creators
is that our assumptions about legal property rights distort our perceptions of
the way the copyright laws operate. Copyright experts take a lot for granted
about the way the copyright system works and is supposed to work.
Copyright is a property right. We’re lawyers. The legal characteristics of
property rights are basic building blocks of our legal education.
One element of legal property rights is control, and most of the debates
over treating copyright as a form of property have focused on the control
that a property owner is able or should be able to exercise.
70
Control is
an important aspect of property, but it isn’t the only or even the most
important aspect. After all, we have lots of different ways to give an indi-
vidual legal control over something without giving her a property right.
What makes property rights special is that they are alienable.
71
Treating
something as property makes it easier to sell. We define a right as a prop-
erty right to encourage its transfer.
72
This intrinsic feature of legal property
is something that it’s easy for lawyers to take for granted. What makes it
possible for publishers, record labels, and other intermediaries to behave
the way they’ve been behaving is that the powers conferred by a copyright
belong to the copyright owner rather than the author.
73
That strikes non-
lawyers as odd, but it’s second nature to us. Our copyright system empow-
ers publishers and record labels to structure licensing deals for their own
benefit, since they own the copyrights, and set the terms and conditions
for copyright licenses.
Because we’re lawyers, we know that the grantee of a property right
stands in the shoes of the grantor and is entitled to exercise the powers
embodied in the property right. We assume that the original property
owner has had the opportunity to extract compensation for the value of
the right, because that’s just how property rights work. Indeed, copyright
lawyers and scholars sometimes use the words “author”and “copyright
70
See e.g. L. Lessig, Free Culture (New York 2004), 83–173; Patry, Moral Panics and the Copyright
Wars, pp. 109–32; S. Aistars, D. Hartline and M. Schultz, “Copyright Principles and Priorities to
Foster a Creative Digital Marketplace”(2016) 23 Geo. Mason L.Rev. 769; M. Grynberg, “Property
Is a Two-Way Street: Personal Copyright Use and Implied Authorization”(2010) 79 Fordham L.
Rev. 435; R.P. Merges, “The Concept of Property in the Digital Era”(2008) 45 Hous.L.R. 1239;
A. Mossoff,“Is Copyright Property?”(2005) 42 San Diego L.Rev. 29.
71
Accord, Ginsburg, “The Place of the Author in Copyright”, pp. 66–67.
72
See e.g. J. Litman, “Information Privacy/Information Property”(2000) 52 Stan.L.Rev. 1283, at 1295–
301.
73
See e.g. Fisher, Promises to Keep, pp. 47–70, 204–05; Bently, “Between a Rock and a Hard Place”,
pp. 15–21; Kretschmer, “Does Copyright Law Matter?”, pp. 32–33.
C.L.J. 15What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
owner”interchangeably, treating them as synonyms.
74
After all, the author
is the initial copyright owner, and the person to whom she transfers those
rights is entitled to step into her shoes. For most purposes, in the eyes of the
law, the owner is the author.
75
We could take a more nuanced look at how legal copyright property
rights actually behave in the world. We should examine our view of
legal property to identify the things that our assumptions may prevent us
from seeing.
IV. THE DAWES ACT AND THE STATUTE OF ANNE
I’m going to take a short detour to tell a story that, at least at first, isn’t
going to seem as if it has any bearing on copyright law. It begins about
400 years ago. In the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, European colo-
nists sailed to North America to develop new territories in the names of
their sovereigns.
76
Unfortunately, the new land already had occupants who had lived on that
land for centuries. The European settlers moved in anyway. Sometimes, it
was possible for the Europeans and the indigenous tribes to coexist, at least
initially; in other situations, though, the indigenous Indian tribes occupied
area that the Europeans wanted to control.
77
The Indians weren’t white,
weren’t Christian and weren’t farmers. They weren’t using the land for
what the Europeans believed to be the best and highest purpose.
78
Some
of the European settlements felt little compunction about seizing the land
from its occupants. Violence ensued.
79
Eventually, after enough people had been killed and enough property had
been damaged, the settlements and the tribes reached agreements, dividing
74
See e.g. J.C. Ginsburg, “Copyright Use and Excuse on the Internet”(2000) 24 Colum.-VLA J.L. & Arts
1, at 41; R. Oman, “Going Back to First Principles: The Exclusive Rights of Authors Reborn”(2008) 8
Journal of High Technology Law 169, at 176–77, 180.
75
See e.g. B. Viswanathan and A. Mossoff,“Open-Access Mandates and the Seductively False Promise of
‘Free’”, Center for the Protection of Intellectual Property Briefing Paper 4, April 2017, available at
<http://apo.org.au/node/93506>. Moral rights, of course, are an important exception to this rule.
Even in countries with robust moral rights protection, however, those rights appear to have negligible
economic value and restrain the exploitation of copyrighted works only in extreme cases.
76
See generally R.T. Anderson, B. Berger, S. Krakoffand P.E. Frickey, American Indian Law: Cases and
Commentary, 3rd ed. (St. Paul 2015), 22–25.
77
See generally e.g. N.J. Newton (ed.), Cohen’s Handbook of Federal Indian Law: 2005 Edition (Newark
2005).
78
See ibid.; E. Kades, “The Dark Side of Efficiency: Johnson v M’Intosh and the Expropriation of
American Indian Lands”(2000) 148 U.Pa.L.Rev. 1065, at 1076–77.
79
See B. Berger, “Red: Racism and the American Indian”(2009) 56 UCLA Law Review 591, at 603–07.
See e.g. E.A. Schmidt, The Divided Dominion: Social Conflict and Indian Hatred in Early Virginia
Boulder, CO (2014), 45–61 (Anglo-Powhatan wars between English settlers in the Virginia Colony
and the Powhatan tribe); S. Feeley, “‘Before Long to be Good Friends:’Diplomatic Perspectives of
the Tuscarora War”in M. LeMaster and B.J. Wood (eds.), Creating and Contesting Carolina
(Columbia 2013), 140 (Tuscarora war between Tuscarora tribe and British, German and Dutch settlers
in North Carolina); E. Haefeli, “Kieft’s War and the Cultures of Violence in Colonial America”in M.A.
Bellesiles (ed.), Lethal Imagination: Violence and Brutality in American History (New York 1999), 17
(war between Dutch settlers in the New Netherland colony and the Lenape tribe).
16 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
up the disputed territory between them.
80
Those agreements, though, turned
out to be unstable. The European-Americans kept seeking to expand their
territory. Over the next 200 or so years, they used money, persuasion,
threats, citizen violence, and military force to convince or compel Indian
tribes to relocate westward to more remote and less desirable land.
81
Along the way, more violence ensued.
82
The American army was busy con-
ducting one or another war with Indian tribes for most of the nineteenth
century.
83
American courts concluded that Indians had an enforceable legal right to
occupy tribal land, but that they didn’t actually own it.
84
The US federal
Government came under immense pressure to open Indian land for settle-
ment by white European-Americans.
85
It tried to use the tools at its disposal
(money and soldiers) to move the tribes out of the way of white homestea-
ders. Indian tribes who had agreed to resettle west of the Mississippi river,
only to be asked to move again, were increasingly reluctant to consent to be
uprooted.
86
Besides, the Government was running out of surplus land.
87
Yet more violence followed.
88
White Americans resented the tribes’control of land that they believed
should by rights be available to them. They pursued a variety of devices,
many of them unlawful, to wrest control of the land from the tribes.
89
What ended up doing the trick was a series of statutes of which the most
famous was the Dawes Act, also known as the General Allotment Act of
1887.
90
Instead of taking the land away from the tribes, the Dawes Act
gave title to the tribal land to individual Indians. The Act divided the
vast tracts of territory controlled by Indian tribes into many 160-acre
plots, and awarded each plot to an individual Indian head of household,
80
See S. Banner, How the Indians Lost Their Land (Cambridge, MA 2005), 85–111.
81
See e.g. Anderson et al., American Indian Law, p. 50; Banner, How the Indians Lost their Land,
pp. 191–227.
82
See e.g. Banner, How the Indians Lost Their Land, pp. 121–29; Newton, Cohen’s Handbook, pp. 35–
36, 39–40, 44; A. Deboe, A History of the Indians of the United States (Norman, OK 1970), 101–16;
A. Deboe, The Road to Disappearance: A History of the Creek Indians (Norman, OK 1966), 72–107.
83
See Banner, How the Indians Lost Their Land, pp. 237–47; see e.g. Newton, Cohen’s Handbook,
pp. 51–54, 71; E.A. Schwartz, The Rogue River Indian War and Its Aftermath: 1859–1980 (Norman,
OK 1997), 69–160.
84
E.g. Johnson’sLesseevM’Intosh, 21 US 543 (1923);see Banner, How the Indians Lost TheirLand, pp. 150–
90; L.G. Robinson, “The Judicial Conquest of Native America: The Story of Johnson v M’Intosh”in
C. Goldberg, K.K. Washburn and P.P. Frickey (eds.), Indian Law Stories (New York 2011),29.
85
See Banner, How the Indians Lost Their Land, pp. 195–226.
86
See ibid., at pp. 197–201, 212–17, 222–26; Newton, Cohen’s Handbook, pp. 51–54, 73.
87
See Banner, How the Indians Lost Their Land, pp. 228–36.
88
See e.g. Anderson et al., American Indian Law, pp. 74–77; Newton, Cohen’s Handbook, pp. 70–71, 73.
89
See Banner, How the Indians Lost Their Land, pp. 214–27, 237–45.
90
General Allotment Act of 8 February 1887, 24 Stat. 388, ch. 119. See also Act for the Protection of the
People of Indian Territory, Pub. L. 55-515, 30 Stat. 495 (1898) (“Curtis Act”); Dawes Act Amendment
of 1891, 26 Stat. 794 (1891); General Allotment Act Amendment of 1906, Pub. L. 59-149, 34 Stat. 182
(1906) (“Burke Act”); Act Authorizing the Secretary of the Interior to allot homesteads to the natives of
Alaska, Pub. L. 59-171, 34 Stat. 197 (1906). For historical background on the allotment policy and a
brief description of initial allotment efforts preceding the Dawes Act, see generally Newton, Cohen’s
Handbook, pp. 66–69, 75–78.
C.L.J. 17What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
in trust for a short period and then in fee simple. During the trust period, the
Indian owners were permitted to lease the plot to white Americans. After
the trust period expired, the Indian household that owned the land was
free to sell it to any buyer. Any unallocated plots were deemed “surplus
land”, and were purchased from the tribe by the federal Government and
made available for sale to non-Indians. At the time, I’m sure that some
of the supporters of the law believed it would empower individual
Indians to vest them with ownership of a plot of land; other supporters,
though, had more cynical motives. In any event, to the extent that one pur-
pose of the statutes was to encourage the transfer of land from Indian tribes
to white American citizens, it was a stunning success. Very quickly, the
majority of the land occupied by Indian tribes passed out of Indian hands
through sales to non-Indians. The winners were white settlers and land
speculators; the Indians ended up both impoverished and often displaced.
91
I want to draw a couple of parallels from that story to a statute that copy-
right lawyers are more familiar with. This story starts at about the same
time. In the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, the members of the
Stationers’Company had a monopoly on publishing, augmented by a
naked horizontal restraint of trade among the members.
92
After more
than a century controlling the business of publishing, the Stationers surely
felt entitled to continue to exercise that control. They had, after all, invested
significant money and efforts into printing and selling their texts. When
Parliament declined to re-enact the licensing act that gave the members
of the Stationers company their printing monopoly, the Stationers engaged
in strenuous lobbying to persuade the Government to restore it.
93
I don’t want to simplify the complex set of considerations that went into
enacting the Statute of Anne,
94
or to minimise the provisions included for
the protection of universities, readers and consumers,
95
or to suggest that
91
Banner, How the Indians Lost Their Land, pp. 257–93; see J.V. Royster, “The Legacy of Allotment”
(1995) 27 Ariz.St.L.J. 1, at 10–14. In 1934, Congress repudiated the allotment program. The Indian
Reorganization Act of 1934 prohibited further allotment of Indian land and sought to return to the tribes
some portion of the 90 million acres of Indian land that had passed into non-Indian ownership. Indian
Reorganization Act, Pub. L. No. 73-383, 48 Stat. 984 (1934) (codified as amended at 25 U.S.C. §§ 461-
479 (1976). See Blackfeet Tribe of Indians v State of Montana, 729 F.2d 1192 (9th Cir. 1984) (en banc),
aff’d 471 US 759 (1985).
92
See e.g. L.R. Patterson, Copyright in Historical Perspective (Nashville 1968), 28–77; I. Gadd, “The
Stationers Company in England before 1710”in I. Alexander and H.T. Gomez-Arostegui (eds.),
Research Handbook on the History of Copyright Law (Cheltenham 2018), 81, 88–92.
93
See C. Blagden, The Stationers Company: A History 1403–1959 (London 1960), 153–77; R. Deazley,
On the Origin of the Right to Copy (Oxford 2004), 1–50; I. Alexander, “All Change for the Digital
Economy: Copyright and Business Models in the Early Eighteenth Century”(2010) 25 Berkeley
Tech.L.J. 1351; Gadd, “The Stationers Company in England before 1710”, pp. 92–95.
94
Statute of Anne, 8. Anne, c. 19 (1710). See e.g. Deazley, On the Origin of the Right to Copy, pp. 31–50;
Alexander, “All Change for the Digital Economy”, pp. 1354–62; H.T. Gomez-Arostegui, “The Untold
Story of the First Copyright Suit under the Statute of Anne in 1710”(2010) 25 Berkeley Tech.L.J. 1247,
at 1251–58; J. Litman, “Readers’Copyright”(2011) 58 J. Copyright Soc’y U.S.A. 325, at 332–35.
95
See A. Katz, “Copyright, Exhaustion, and the Role of Libraries in the Ecosystem of Knowledge”(2016)
13 I/S Journal of Law & Policy for the Information Society 81, at 84–86; Litman, “Readers’Copyright”,
pp. 333–35.
18 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
some of the law’s supporters didn’t believe that it would empower authors.
Whatever the intention, the law ended up working out pretty well for the
members of the Stationers’company. By establishing an assignable prop-
erty right for authors and their assigns, the law encouraged authors to con-
vey their copyrights to printers and publishers (who, after all, were the folks
with the printing presses), where they have stayed pretty much for the next
300 years.
96
The rest of the world followed that model.
97
In almost every country,
authors receive copyright protection as an initial matter, but those copy-
rights are transferred to and then owned and controlled by publishers and
other intermediaries.
98
In the US, where capitalism is both our economic
system and our dominant religion, courts were especially eager to conclude
that authors had conveyed their copyrights to publishers, even in the
absence of any evidence, and that inclination has persisted.
99
When it
didn’t work to simply presume that the copyright had been transferred,
our courts invented the work made for hire doctrine out of whole cloth.
100
The moral of both of these stories is that deeming a resource to be a prop-
erty right is often an extremely effective way to gain control of that
resource, especially when you don’t have control of it at the outset.
When the law transforms something that was not formerly property into
a property right, the accompanying alienability will cause control of it to
flow to those with the most bargaining power. If you are looking to get
your hands on some arable land or to regain your control of the printing
of texts, creating new property rights turns out to be an excellent strategy.
Sometimes the original recipient of the property benefits, but not always.
Sometimes the world improves as a result; other times it doesn’t.
V. THE WAGES OF PROPERTY RIGHTS
So, here’s the upshot: immense sums of money slosh through the current
copyright system, but only a tiny share of that money ends up in authors’
pockets. By some accounts, that share has been decreasing. We all know
that, because, as I said, we live in the world and see the evidence all around
us, but we have tended to overlook it when we talk about copyright law
reform. Over the past 300 years, we’ve expanded and extended copyright
96
See Patterson, Copyright in Historical Perspective, pp. 143–50, 213–21.
97
See e.g. O. Bracha, “The Adventures of the Statute of Anne in the Land of Unlimited Possibilities: The
Life of a Legal Transplant”(2010) 25 Berkeley Tech.L.J. 1427.
98
See J.C. Ginsburg and E. Treppoz, International Copyright Law US and EU Perspectives: Text and
Cases (Cheltenham 2015); P. Goldstein and B. Hugenholz, International Copyright, 2nd ed. (Oxford
2010), 244–69; Ginsburg, “The Place of the Author in Copyright”, pp. 63–66.
99
See Litman, “What Notice Did”, pp. 732–34; see e.g. Bleistein v Donaldson Lithographing Co., 188 U.
S. 239, 248–49 (1903); Edward Thompson Co. Am. Law Book Co., 119 F. 217, 219 (C.C.S.D.N.Y.
1902); Colliery Eng’r Co. v United Correspondence Schs., 94 F. 152, 153 (C.C.S.D.N.Y. 1899).
100
See C. Fisk, “Authors at Work: The Origins of the Work-for-Hire Doctrine”(2003) 15 Yale J.L. &
Human. 1.
C.L.J. 19What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
repeatedly, and larded the law up with new licenses and payment obliga-
tions.
101
We’ve failed, however, to pay enough attention to how –or
whether –the intermediaries tasked with distributing the revenues actually
disburse them. We don’t look inside the black box surrounding the author’s
conveyance of her rights to a new owner. Because we understand how
property rights work, we trust and assume that the profits flowing from
copyright expansion redound to the benefit of authors.
But, because we live in the world, we know, or should know, that often
they don’t. If we believe that that’s a problem (and I happen to), we won’t
be able to figure out how to fix it without a careful examination of what is
inside the black box. That means asking some questions that we aren’tin
the habit of asking, and that copyright owners are not in the habit of
answering.
102
(Let me say, parenthetically, that if we decide that it isn’t a problem that
authors receive so small a share of the proceeds from their works, the fuss
about the so called “value gap”makes even less sense. If we believe that
economics and policy support the conclusion that authors’teeny-weeny
percentage of the vast sums generated by the enjoyment of works of enter-
tainment and information is the right amount to pay them, it’s hard to see
any justification for interfering in the negotiations among commercial dis-
tributors to dictate which of them gets the largest share of the very substan-
tial remainder.)
If the problem is worth addressing, though, we should have learned by
now that it isn’t a useful solution to throw more money and control at copy-
right owners and trust that, this time, they will share a larger part of it with
authors.
I want to emphasise the narrow limits of the argument that I’m making.
I’m not arguing that the alienability of copyrights is itself the problem, nor
that I believe that we could solve it simply by limiting copyright transfers or
making rights inalienable. After all, consider Germany. Germany treats
copyrights as inalienable, at least formally,
103
but German authors don’t
appear to enjoy significant financial advantages over authors from other
countries.
104
I think the role that the alienability of property rights plays
in my argument is twofold. First, whenever we have significant disparities
101
See e.g. N.W. Netanel, Copyright’s Paradox (Oxford 2008), 54–80.
102
I don’t mean to minimise the practical difficulties posed by intermediaries’insistence that contract terms
and payments are proprietary information that they are entitled to keep secret. See e.g. P. DiCola and
D. Touve, “Licensing in the Shadow of Copyright”(2014) 17 Stanford Technology Law Review 397, at
443–57.
103
See German Copyright Act §§ 29, 31.
104
See e.g. M. Kretschmer and P. Hardwick, “Authors’Earnings from Copyright and Non-Copyright
Sources: A Survey of 25,000 British and German Writers”(Dorset 2007), available at https://micro-
sites.bournemouth; Kretschmer, “Does Copyright Law Matter?”, pp. 12–15; Senftleben, “Copyright,
Creators, & Society’s Need for Autonomous Art”, p. 53. See also e.g. Ginsburg and Sirinelli,
“Private International Law Aspects of Authors’Contracts”(examining private international law obsta-
cles to implementing author-protective legislation enacted in France and the Netherlands).
20 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
in wealth and bargaining power, the distribution of freely alienable property
rights is almost always going to mirror and will often exacerbate those dis-
parities. Second, the legal dogma surrounding property rights, which, as
lawyers, we’ve inhaled since we were students, can keep us from appreci-
ating those disparities. We don’t pay enough attention to the use of alien-
able property rights as a device to allow powerful actors to appropriate
valuable items in the control of less powerful actors.
VI. SEEING WHAT WEDON’TSEE
Is the problem indeed as intractable at it sometimes seems, or is there some-
thing we could do to address it?
Copyright in the twenty-first century is a byzantine legal ecosystem. I
believe that there would be real value in our exploring that ecosystem, care-
fully and from the inside, in order to understand the reasons that it has per-
sistently given creators short shrift. That would involve our taking a
painstaking look at the way that authors and copyright owners structure
their interactions, to figure out where, if anywhere, an intervention might
be effective.
I don’t have an easy solution to propose. It’s possible, but unlikely, that
we could tweak copyright ownership law or revise copyright licensing rules
in ways that could significantly improve the world for at least some
authors.
105
Throwing more copyright rights at copyright owners
106
is
unlikely to trickle down to creators –at least unless and until we understand
more of the dynamic that results in their getting such a small share of the
proceeds from their creations. Adjusting the law to enhance the bargaining
power of publishers over platforms or platforms over publishers
107
isn’t
105
See e.g. J.E. Cohen, Configuring the Networked Self (New Haven 2012), 223–66; Gervais, Collective
Management of Copyright and Related Rights, pp. 191–215; W. Patry, How to Fix Copyright (Oxford
2011), 177–88; J. Silbey, The Eureka Myth: Creators, Innovators and Everyday Intellectual Property
(Stanford 2015), 274–85; Loren, “Renegotiating the Copyright Deal”; R.A. Reese, “Optional Copyright
Renewal: Lessons for Designing Copyright Systems, The 38 Annual Horace J. Manges Lecture”(2015)
39 Columbia Journal of Law & the Arts 145; M. Van Houweling, “Making Copyright Work for Authors
Who Write to Be Read”(2015) 38 Columbia Journal of Law & the Arts 381.
106
See e.g. H.R. 1836, Fair Play Fair Pay Act, 115th Cong. (2017) (giving sound recording copyright own-
ers new exclusive right to perform their sound recordings over AM and FM radio); C. Geiger,
O. Bulayenko and G. Frosio, “The Introduction of a Neighbouring Right for Press Publishers at EU
Level: The Unneeded (and Unwanted) Reform”(2017) 39 EIPR 202.
107
See e.g. Joint Comments of Amer. Ass’n of Independent Music et. al., U.S. Copyright Office: In re
Section 512 Study, Docket No. 2015-7, 31 March 2016, available at <https://www.riaa.com/wp-con-
tent/uploads/2016/03/Music-Community-Submission-in-re-DMCA-512-FINAL-7559445.pdf>; J. Chu
and T. Marino, “Victims of IP Theft Need Better Protection”,The Hill, 12 March 2014, available at
<http://thehill.com/opinion/op-ed/200630-victims-of-ip-theft-need-better-protection>; J. Taplin, “Is it
Time to Break Up Google?”,New York Times, 22 April 2017, available at <https://www.nytimes.
com/2017/04/22/opinion/sunday/is-it-time-to-break-up-google.html>; S. Carlisle, “DMCA
‘Takedown’Notices: Why ‘Takedown’Should Become ‘Takedown and Stay Down’and Why It’s
Good for Everyone”,Nova Southeastern University Copyright Office Blog, 23 July 2014, available
at <http://copyright.nova.edu/dmca-takedown-notices/>; E. Harmon, “‘Notice and Stay Down’Is
Really Filter Everything”,Electronic Frontier Foundation Deeplinks Blog, 21 January 2016, available
at <https://www.eff.org/deeplinks/2016/01/notice-and-stay-down-really-filter-everything>.
C.L.J. 21What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
calculated to make life better for creators. I don’t see much promise in any
of the pending statutory or treaty proposals currently on the table. It may be
that those proposals are the only proposals that have any practical chance of
adoption, precisely because Reed Elsevier, Vivendi, Disney or Google
won’t countenance any new law or treaty that leaves them no better off
than the current law. Copyright intermediaries have enough political
power to insist on watering down reform proposals until they will be of lit-
tle actual use to creators, and have recently exercised that power to revise
legislative and treaty proposals in their favour.
108
Over the past 20 years,
we’ve seen several unsuccessful efforts to reform national and international
copyright law-making processes to weaken the influence wielded by power-
ful copyright players.
109
Such efforts face obstacles that seem insurmount-
able. The firm hold that copyright intermediaries have on national and
international law-making processes, and their current preoccupation with
marshalling all available resources to vanquish each other, suggest that real-
istic opportunities for author-empowering copyright reforms may be scant.
I suspect that we may end up concluding that the more promising propo-
sals are only tangentially related to copyright law. Many creators lack the
bargaining power to exercise the rights theoretically afforded to them by
current law.
110
If the pivotal problem is a lack of bargaining power, though,
new or enhanced property rights are unlikely to solve it. It is just remotely
possible that we might make more headway by attacking the problem from
the other end. There may be interventions to address the bargaining power
deficit more directly. Catherine Fisk has argued that encouraging authors to
engage in collective bargaining may be the most practical solution, even if
the price of that bargaining would be the loss of copyright ownership.
111
I
can imagine requiring the collecting entities that don’t currently pay the
creators’share of royalties directly to creators to do so from now on.
112
Some scholars have suggested that self-publishing over the Internet may
allow creators to compete directly with intermediaries and to collect a larger
share of the proceeds from their works.
113
My colleague Jeremy Peters has
108
See e.g. R. Giblin, “Should It Be Copyright’s Role to Fill Houses with Books?”in S. Frankel and
D. Gervais (eds.), Intellectual Property and Regulation of the Internet: Th e Nexus with Human and
Economic Development (Wellington 2017); M.E. Kaminski, “The Capture of International
Intellectual Property Through the US Trade Regime”(2014) 87 S.Cal.L.Rev. 977.
109
See e.g. G. Krikorian and A. Kapczynski (eds.), Access to Knowledge in the Age of Intellectual
Property (New York 2010); L. Lessig, Republic, Lost: How Money Corrupts Congress –and a Plan
to Stop It (New York 2011).
110
See e.g. Bently, “Between a Rock and a Hard Place”; Ginsburg and Sirinelli, “Private International Law
Aspects of Authors’Contracts”;O’Rourke, “Bargaining in the Shadow”.
111
See C. Fisk, “Hollywood Writers and the Gig Economy”(2018) 2017 U.Chi. Legal F. 177.
112
See e.g. Future of Music Coalition, “Principles for Artist Compensation in New Business Models”,2
April 2009, available at <https://www.futureofmusic.org/article/article/principles-artist-compensation-
new-business-models>.
113
See e.g. J.M. Garon, “Digital Hollywood 2.0: Reimagining Film, Music, Television and Publishing
Distribution as a Global Artist Collaborative”(2013) 21 Michigan State International Law Review
563; O’Rourke, “Bargaining in the Shadow”, p. 638.
22 [2018]The Cambridge Law Journal
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of
suggested that we could get a lot of mileage from encouraging or requiring
copyright owners to adopt generally recognised accounting standards, along
with mandated, publicly-available annual audits. I suspect we might get
somewhere by imposing labelling rules that required purveyors of copies
of or access to copyrighted works to disclose the percentage of the purchase
price that will be paid directly to creators of the work.
114
It might be useful
to set up and fund government or non-profit organisations tasked with edu-
cating and supporting creators in appreciating and enforcing their current
legal rights against the entities to which they’ve transferred their
copyrights.
115
None of these approaches comes from the copyright scholar’s usual tool-
box. There’s value, though, in exploring the copyright system from
unaccustomed vantage points. If nothing else, it can help us to appreciate
what we tend not to see and why we don’t see it.
114
Cf. R. Giblin, “The Author Made 3p from the Sale of this Book”,The Author’s Interest Blog, 3 April
2018, available at <https://authorsinterest.org/2018/04/03/more-on-fair-trade-for-authors/>.
115
E.g. O’Rourke, “Bargaining in the Shadow”, pp. 637–38. See generally Bowker, “Self-Publishing in the
United States 2010–15”(2015), available at <http://media.bowker.com/documents/bowker-selfpublish-
ing-report2015.pdf>; R. Shapiro and S. Aneja, “Unlocking the Gates: America’s New Creative
Economy”(2018), available at <http://www.recreatecoalition.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/02/
ReCreate-Creative-Economy-Study-Report.pdf>.
C.L.J. 23What We Don’t See When We See Copyright as Property
use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008197318000600
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 139.81.157.28, on 23 Aug 2018 at 17:16:01, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of