PreprintPDF Available

CECL Procyclicality: It Depends on the Model

Authors:
  • Deep Future Analytics LLC
Preprints and early-stage research may not have been peer reviewed yet.

Abstract and Figures

The new guidelines for loan loss reserves, CECL (Current Expected Credit Loss), were initially proposed so that lenders' loss reserves would be forward-looking. Under the previous guidance, loss reserves might only increase after a crisis had already ravaged a lender's portfolio. The goal of being forward-looking was for lenders to accumulate reserves in advance of the crisis, to be prepared. As the industry starts to implement CECL, questions have been raised about whether CECL will be forward-looking enough. Some preliminary studies have suggested that CECL could be procyclical, meaning that loss reserves would peak at the peak of a crisis. Although better than seeing failure only after it has happened, being required to raise liquidity at the peak of a crisis could still fail to save the lender from collapse, or even facilitate it. However, CECL is built on models, and the modeling details are important. These preliminary studies appeared to correlate losses directly to macroeconomic factors, equivalent to the time series models that we tested in Living with CECL: Mortgage Modeling Alternatives. As we saw in that study, time series models fail to capture the credit cycle and thus are among the least accurate models in the study. Our recent blog post (Breeden, 8 Aug 2018) showed that the credit cycle is very strong in mortgage and always leads the economic cycle. Earlier research showed that the credit cycle is partly driven by underwriting practices, but also strongly influenced by consumer loan demand (Breeden, J.L. and J.J. Canals-Cerdá, 2018). That is why Age-Period-Cohort (vintage) and survival models were the winners on long-range accuracy. We did not, however, test for procyclicality. The study tests a range of models for procyclicality. The scenarios were obtained by purchasing reports from Consensus Economics published in the month preceding each quarter's forecast, so these CECL estimates use the real economic assumptions available at the time.
Content may be subject to copyright.
CECL Procyclicality: It Depends on the Model
Joseph L Breeden
Prescient Models LLC
breeden@prescientmodels.com
September 6, 2018
Abstract
The new guidelines for loan loss reserves, CECL (Current Expected
Credit Loss), were initially proposed so that lenders’ loss reserves would
be forward-looking. Some recent studies have suggested that CECL could
be procyclical, meaning that loss reserves would peak at the peak of a
crisis. Although better than seeing failure only after it has happened,
being required to raise liquidity at the peak of a crisis could still fail to
save the lender from collapse, or even facilitate it.
However, previous procyclicality studies explained all losses with macroe-
conomic factors, ignoring the changes in credit risk and other portfolio
drivers that preceded the recession. The current work tests a wide range of
models to test the degree to which CECL is procyclical for different types
of models. The tests were also run using either real historical macroe-
conomic scenarios , flat scenarios, or mean reverting scenarios. All tests
were conducted on publicly available data from Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac using publicly disclosed models.
This study found that the CECL lifetime loss estimates were only
marginally sensitive to the quality of the economic scenario but changed
dramatically with different modeling techniques. Some methods predicted
increased loss reserve requirements as early as 2006 while others only saw
the recession as it happened or even afterward. Therefore, procyclicality
under CECL will be strongly influenced by the choices of the lender.
Keywords: Current expected credit loss approach, loan loss provisions,
procyclicality, vintage models, roll rate models, state transition models,
survival models
JEL Classifications: G18, G21, G28,
1 Introduction
Following the 2009 US recession and global financial crisis (GFC), the FASB
(Financial Accounting Standards Board) and IASB (International Accounting
1
2
Standards Board) sought new loan loss reserve rules that would allow lenders to
reserve for losses that could be reasonably anticipated given what is knowable in
their portfolio and the economy. This was intended as an improvement over the
previous rules which were inherently backward looking, considering only losses
after a default was believed to have occurred. Furthermore to this goal, loss
reserves were to look further into the future. In the US, the new rules adopted
in June 2016, the current expected credit loss (CECL), set all loss reserves to
cover the full lifetime of the loan [15]. The international standard, IFRS 9,
uses a 12-month loss reserve for stage 1 accounts (performing as expected), but
also adopts a lifetime loss calculation for stage 2 accounts (increased risk) [23].
The primary motivation for the divergence in the standards was the need to
accommodate the thousands of smaller lenders in the US. Therefore, CECL is
essentially IFRS 9 stage 2 for everyone.
Given the goal of anticipating and reserving for future loss events, the 2009
US recession and GFC serve as good test cases of whether loss reserves under
these rules would lead, lag, or be coincidence with the crisis. Although provi-
sions that lag the crisis serve little purpose, as was true under the old rules,
provision requirements that peak coincident with the crisis can also cause sig-
nificant financial stress because of the difficulty raising capital during a crisis.
When loss provision requirements are coincident with the underlying losses, this
is referred to as procylicality.
To prepare for future macroeconomic stresses, we should determine how we
can reasonably expect CECL estimates to behave. By applying CECL to the
2009 US recession in the case of mortgage and considering what was knowable
at the time, we seek to determine the degree to which CECL would be pro-
cyclical. Most importantly, prior experience has shown that different modeling
approaches can provide different degrees of foresight, so we tested time series,
vintage, roll rate, state transition, and survival models, all of which are sta-
tistical techniques. In addition, we considered some simple, spreadsheet-based
methods that have been recently proposed for use by smaller organizations to
comply with CECL. These are loss timing, vintage copy forward, and weighted
average remaining maturity (WARM).
To capture what was knowable at each forecast point, we purchased his-
toric publications of macroeconomic scenarios from Consensus Economics cor-
responding to the month before each forecast date. Those scenarios were for
the following two years. Using that as the ”foreseeable” period, we applied a
mean-reverting algorithm to the scenarios in order to forecast the remainder of
the term of the 30-year fixed rate conforming mortgages from Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac. We also considered a flat macroeconomic extrapolation for two
years followed by mean reversion. The third option was immediate mean rever-
sion. Any of these approaches would have been realizable through the economic
cycle.
The results of this study show the extreme importance of which model is cho-
sen for CECL. Also, once we abandon perfect foresight, the differences between
realistic economic scenarios are minor.
This study was inspired by the results of previous studies. An early study
3
on procyclicality argued on largely theoretical grounds that CECL would re-
duce procyclicality [10]. However, these conclusions made several assumptions
about what lenders would be able to estimate. A more recent analysis showed
that CECL estimates for mortgage would have been countercyclical if the future
macroeconomic conditions were known [9]. Neither of these studies addressed
the question of the real-world timing of CECL provisions given what was know-
able at the time.
Most recently, a study by Covas and Nelson [11] created a vector autoregres-
sion model to generate macroeconomic scenarios at each forecast point. These
were fed into a time series model similar to what is included in the current
work. Their result was that CECL estimates are highly procyclical and would
have caused a worsening of the crisis through reduced liquidity and subsequent
lending by banks. Their study did not consider any other model types.
In fact, previously published work on the mortgage crisis has shown that
losses did not peak purely due to deterioration in the economic environment.
Several authors have explored the impact of the moral hazard of securitization
as driving risky lending [13, 28, 30]. Levitin, Pavlov, and Wachter [29] argued
that securitization was the sole cause of the crisis, although this is rebutted by
Foote, Gerardi, and Willen [18].
Breeden [5] used a dataset back to 1990 to identify credit cycle peaks in
1991, 1995, and 2001 to argue that although securitization played a deleterious
roll in the 2009 crisis, this loss peak also corresponded to a credit risk cycle. A
subsequent analysis by Breeden and Canals-Cerda used a richer, more recent
data set to show that half of the mortgage crisis was explainable by typical scor-
ing factors. Although some part of the residual could have been attributable to
unseen underwriting changes, it again correlates strongly to drivers of consumer
risk appetite as measurable from the FRB Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey
(SLOOS).
Regardless of the exact mix of effects identified by these authors, the message
from all of them is that mortgage losses were more than an economic crisis. One
could assume that economic crises are unpredictable, but credit cycles are a
different matter. This leaves the possibility that losses are not as unpredictable
as some have assumed, if the correct model is used.
2 Data
This test was performed on publicly available data from Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac. Specifically, 30-year conforming fixed rate mortgages were analyzed. Loan-
level information from 2001 through 2017 from both sources was normalized and
combined. In addition to monthly loan status, the database contains a number
of attributes suitable for loan-level credit risk estimation. The full list of data
fields for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac appears in Table 1.
For the models developed in the study, the following definitions were used:
Default: current loan delinquency status >= 3, i.e. 90+ days past due
(DPD)
4
Origination fields Performance fields
Loan sequence number Loan sequence number
Credit score Monthly reporting period
First payment date Current actual UPB
First time homebuyer flag Current loan delinquency status
Maturity date Loan age
Metropolitan statistical area Remaining months to legal maturity
Mortgage insurance Repurchase flag
percentage
Number of units Modification flag
Occupancy status Zero balance code
CLTV – cumulative loan Zero balance effective date
to value
DTI – debt to income Current interest rate
Original UPB (unpaid balance) Current deferred UPB
LTV – loan to value DOLPI – Date of last paid installment
Original interest rate Mortgage insurance (MI) recoveries
Channel Net sales proceeds
PPM flag Non MI recoveries
Product type Expenses
Property state
Property type
Postal code
Loan purpose
Original loan term
Number of borrowers
Seller name
Servicer name
Table 1: Origination and performance data fields available in the Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac datasets.
5
Active: non-default and current actual UPB>0
Attrition: zero balance code=1 (prepaid)
Outstanding balance: current actual UPB if status = Active
Default balance: current actual UPB if status = default
Origination balance: current actual UPB if Current Date = Vintage
Loss: Default balance + Accrued Interest + Total Costs Total Proceeds
Accrued interest: Default balance*((Current Interest Rate/ 100-0.0035)/12)*(Months
between Last Principal and Interest Paid Date and Zero Balance Date)
Total costs: Foreclosure Costs + Property Preservation and Repair Costs
+ Asset Recovery Costs + Miscellaneous Holding Expenses and Credits
+ Associated Taxes for Holding Property
Total proceeds: Net Sales Proceeds + Credit Enhancement Proceeds +
Repurchase Make Whole Proceeds + Other Foreclosure Proceeds
The data analyzed in this study represents more than $2 trillion of con-
forming mortgages. All models were segmented by risk grade: Subprime is less
than 660 FICO, Prime is 660 to 780, and Superprime is 780 and above. Al-
though data was available by zip code, only nationwide models were created in
alignment with the available macroeconomic scenarios.
2.1 Macroeconomic Scenarios
The macroeconomic scenarios in this study were obtained by purchasing reports
from Consensus Economics published in the month preceding each quarter’s
forecast, so these CECL estimates use the real economic assumptions available
at the time. Consensus Economics provides quarterly scenarios for the follow-
ing two year period. From the factors provided, the following were considered
for mortgage modeling: real gross domestic product, real disposable personal
income, unemployment rate, 3-month treasury bill rate, and 10 year treasury
bond yield. These scenarios represent the average predictions of 24 prominent
economists or economic forecasting institutions.
Figure 2.1 shows that the consensus economic scenarios follow a rational
pattern. In any quarter, they follow recent trends and then begin to revert to
loan run averages.
The models tested here were originally developed as part of a more extensive
CECL mortgage study [7]. In that study, the selection of macroeconomic factors
was chosen from mortgage-related factors that are available in the government’s
Dodd-Frank Stress Test Act (DFAST) scenarios. in order to maintain repro-
ducibility of the results, Among the factors considered in the models, house price
index (HPI) and Dow Jones Total Stock Market Index were missing from the
Consensus Economics list. The Dow Jones index rarely appears in the models,
6
4"
5"
6"
7"
8"
9"
10"
11"
2004-01" 2005-01" 2006-01" 2007-01" 2008-01" 2009-01" 2010-01" 2011-01" 2012-01" 2013-01" 2014-01" 2015-01" 2016-01" 2017-01"
Unemployment*Rate*
Consensus*Economics*****Scenarios*
Figure 1: Quarterly unemployment rate scenarios from Consensus Economics
Inc. for the following two years. A mean-reverting scenario is applied thereafter
to complete the CECL forecast.
but HPI is quite important. To run the models, a simple vector auto-regression
model was created to predict the values of the missing variables from the avail-
able data of all macroeconomic factors. This modeling was training on data
preceding each forecast date. Accuracy was not a primary concern, only that
the models could be run out-of-sample.
3 Models
CECL is built on models. To study procyclicality, the models developed in the
CECL mortgage study by Breeden [7] were employed along with some recent
additions: WARM, Vintage Copy-Forward, and Loss Timing. The following
sections provide summary descriptions of each model. The complete descriptions
are available in the original study details.
3.1 Time Series
The simplest forward-looking model in this study requires creating macroeco-
nomic time series models of the balance default and pay-down rates. Lifetime
losses can then be simulated by projecting forward under a mean-reverting base
macroeconomic scenario until all currently outstanding balances are either paid
or charged off. Transformation of the macroeconomic data and model estimation
are primary considerations [26, 25, 14, 36, 20].
The time series model used macroeconomic factors to predict the balance
loss rate and balance payment rate, segmented by subprime, prime, and super-
prime. These models use lagged transforms of the economic factors described
in Section 2.1.
7
Pay-off rate(t) = Pay-off balance(t)
Outstanding balance(t1) (1)
Default rate(t) = Default balance(t)
Outstanding balance(t1) (2)
Pure macroeconomic time series models necessarily assume that all portfolio
dynamics are explainable by the economy without regard to changes in under-
writing or other policies. As mentioned in the introduction, many other factors
may have contributed to the mortgage crisis. In this time series model, those
factors will either be absorbed indirectly via possibly spurious correlations to
macroeconomic factors, or missed entirely.
3.2 Roll Rate
For the last 40 years, the two most common kinds of models for retail lending
portfolios are credit scores and roll rates. Roll rate models are similar in spirit
to a state transition model, but estimated on aggregate monthly balance flows
from one delinquency bucket to the next. [16]
Ri(t) = Balancei(t)
Balancei1(t1) (3)
Historically roll rate models have used moving averages of past rolls. For
CECL estimation, Ri(t) is modeled with macroeconomic factors. In addition,
the balance pay-down rate for non-delinquent accounts is modeled with macroe-
conomic data so that both charge-off and pay-off end states are included. Thus,
the roll rate model is like the time series model, but with intermediate delin-
quency transitions added. The final lifetime loss is calculated by summing the
monthly losses until all existing loans reach zero balance.
3.3 Age-Period-Cohort (Vintage)
Vintage models naturally capture the timing of losses and attrition versus age
of the loan, and therefore are an obvious choice for lifetime loss calculations.
An Age-Period-Cohort approach is commonly used to estimate such models
[19, 21, 4, 8]. Using rates for probability of default (PD), exposure at default
(EAD), loss given default (LGD), and probability of attrition (PA), monthly
loss forecasts are created and aggregated to a lifetime loss estimate.
When modeling default rate (PD), this takes the following form:
log-odds(PD) = lifecycle(age) + credit risk(vintage) + environment(date) (4)
Age is the age of the vintage. Vintage is the origination date. The lifecycle is also
known as the hazard function or the loss timing function. Credit risk measures
the relative risk of each vintage. Environment captures macroeconomic impacts
and account management changes through time.
8
The lifecycle, environment, and vintage functions can be represented with
splines or nonparametrically. The coefficients for those functions are typically
estimated with logistic regression or with a Bayesian estimator [31]. To obtain
a solution, a constraint must be set on the linear trends, as described in the
APC literature [22].
Macroeconomic scenarios are used to project the future value of the environ-
ment function, which is then combined with the vintage and lifecycle functions
to produce monthly forecasts for each vintage. The lifetime loss forecast sums
across both vintages and calendar date to the end of the loans’ terms or until
the outstanding balances reach zero.
3.4 State Transition
State transition models are the loan-level equivalent of roll rate models. Rather
than modeling aggregate movements between delinquency states, the probability
of transition is computed for each account. The states considered are current,
delinquent up to a maximum of six months delinquent, charge-off, and pay-off.
Account transition probabilities are modeled rather than the dollar transitions
in the roll rate model.
They derive from Markov models, though in practice they may not satisfy
the Markov criteria that no history other than the current state is used in
the model. They were used first and most heavily for corporate ratings and
commercial lending, where most of the literature is still to be found [24, 35, 33].
However, they are often used for retail lending, most often for mortgages [32, 2].
The method used here is most like that of Berteloot, et. al. [3].
For modeling, a recommended approach would be to create a multinomial
regression model from each non-terminal state, predicting all of the other states
the account can transition to. The regression model would consider external
macroeconomic drivers as well as internal factors for the accounts, such as FICO,
loan-to-value (LTV), etc. Functions of age may also be included in order to
capture lifecycle effects.
To make forecasts, if the input variables to the transition probability models
satisfy the Markov condition of having no memory prior to the current state,
then the forecasts may be created via a series of matrix multiplies as in the
Markov chain approach. However, if the input factors do have memory, such
as number of times delinquent in the previous six months (a common predic-
tive factor), then a Monte Carlo approach must be applied to a sample of the
accounts to simulate possible portfolio performance. At each time step each
account is assigned a specific state based upon the probability of that transition
and a drawn random number.
In all cases the probabilities are functions of time, because the macroeco-
nomic scenarios will change with time using the same mean-reverting scenarios
described earlier. The accounts will be simulated until they reach a terminal
state such as charge-off or pay-off, or they reach the end of term.
EAD and LGD are modeled separately as functions of the age of the loan to
capture balance pay-down with time.
9
3.5 Multihorizon Discrete Time Survival Model
Conceptually, discrete time survival models are the loan-level enhancement to
vintage models, usually with the implication of creating loan-level models with
scoring attributes. They did not evolve from survival models, but the relation-
ship is fair. Because lending performance data is generally recorded in monthly
increments, the discrete time approach is appropriate, in which case a discrete
time survival model is identical to logistic regression with a hazard function as
a fixed input.
For the present study, the lifecycle and macroeconomic correlations from the
APC vintage model estimation are used as fixed inputs to a logistic regression
panel data model with scoring attributes. This two-step process is done to avoid
multicolinearity problems when trying to estimate everything simultaneously.
PD, PA, and EAD are estimated with this process.
Separate origination and behavioral models are built, the former using only
factors available at origination and the latter using both origination factors and
behavioral factors such as recent delinquency. The multihorizon aspect comes
from the fact that a separate regression is estimated for each forecast horizon.
This is done because the coefficients for delinquency are highly nonlinear with
forecast horizon. However, by horizon 12, the coefficients stabilize and can
be used for all future values. Because any delinquent account will have either
cured or charged-off within six to twelve months, the remainder of the forecast
is dominated by persistent factors like FICO score and LTV.
The final lifetime loss forecasts are created by aggregating the loan-level
monthly loss estimates.
3.6 Weighted Average Remaining Maturity (WARM)
Popularized in FASB webinars on simple CECL approaches [17], WARM is just
the multiplication of the recent average loss rate and the average expected life
of the loan. Average expected life could be defined as the age at which half the
loans have paid-off or charged-off, or it could be defined as the age at which the
average outstanding balance will be half of the initial balance, which would be
shorter than the former. If one were to multiply the loss rate by the outstanding
balance in each month of the loan, adjusted for prepayment risk, the result would
be equivalent to the age at which the outstanding balance is half of the initial
balance. That is the approach used here.
Most notably with WARM, the loss rate used in the calculation is not depen-
dent upon the age of the account, economic conditions, current delinquency or
any credit risk factors. This is a steady-state model where all such changes are
assumed to be introduced manually via quantitative adjustments (Q-factors).
3.7 Vintage Copy-Forward
One simple method proposed for complying with CECL is to apply the annual
loss rate of the previous vintage in the previous year to the current vintage in
10
the current year. This has the affect of aligning vintages by age and potentially
capturing some recent credit quality changes.
Loss Rate(v, t +h) = Loss Rate(vh, t 1) (5)
To create the lifetime loss forecasts required by CECL, each successive fore-
cast year must look to an older vintage. If credit quality is not a constant
across vintages, this will create a bias in the approximation versus age. Also,
this approach does not include any explicit macroeconomic correlations.
3.8 Loss Timing
Lastly, the loss timing approach is conceptually the same as a balance-based haz-
ard function [12], but computed simply in a spreadsheet as the average monthly
loss rate versus age of the vintage. The vintages are aligned by age and an
average balance loss rate is computed relative to the origination balance. To
create forecasts, the loss timing function is applied for all forecast horizons for
active vintages.
Because this is a simple spreadsheet average rather than a statistical estimate
of a hazard function [27, 1], it will be subject to a number of biases. Again, this
is being proposed as a CECL solution, but would not normally be considered a
model suitable for forecasting.
4 Results
The goal of the study is to simulate how these models might perform out-of-
sample. To achieve that, one would ideally estimate all of the coefficients only
on data prior to the start of each quarter’s forecast. The challenge is that this
data does not have enough history prior to the recession to fully estimate these
models. Further, when we apply these models to the next recession, we will have
this past recession to model against. Although no future recession is expected
to be a replay of the previous recession, having one to train on is better than
no historic data.
With all this in mind, it would be overly harsh to run the models with no
history, and yet we don’t want to give perfect foresight. The compromise used is
that the full history was used to estimate economic sensitivity and product life-
cycles, but not scoring coefficients. It has been the author’s personal experience
that lifecycles for a specific product like 30-year mortgage are stable through
time and across lenders.
Macroeconomic sensitivities, when the correlations are restricted to variables
close to the consumers’ finances, are also reasonably stable. Unemployment
and change in house prices are always the dominant effects for mortgages. The
biggest change between the 2009 recession and the 2001 recession was the length-
ening of unemployment benefits to 99 weeks. This was significantly greater than
previous recessions and appears to have caused the optimal lag between unem-
ployment and mortgage default to have increased.
11
For the time series and roll rate models, estimating macroeconomic factors
across the full data set means that they are fully in-sample. For all other models,
the macroeconomic sensitivities were taken from a model over the full data and
other coefficients were re-estimated each quarter using only the preceding data.
As will be seen later in the scenario comparison results, using partially out-of-
sample models probably makes no difference in the comparison.
4.1 Comparing Models
The models described above were run each quarter using the corresponding
macroeconomic scenario as illustrated in Figure 2.1 for the first 24 months.
Then a mean-reverting algorithm was applied to the optimally transformed
macroeconomic factors using a second order Ornstein-Uhlenbeck algorithm [34,
6]. Each point along the time series in Figure 4.1 represents the CECL lifetime
loss estimate at that point for the Fannie Mae / Freddie Mac mortgage portfolio.
A CECL estimate was run for each quarter from 2005 Q1 through 2015 Q4.
The black line in Figure 4.1 is the actual future lifetime loss for loans out-
standing at that forecast point. The actual performance data runs through 2017,
so the tail losses beyond 2017 were filled in with a vintage model, because that
was one of the most accurate in our previous study. The actual forward-looking
lifetime losses rise steadily between 2005 and mid-2008, because new higher-risk
loans were being originated at a rapid pace.
The Actual line is an unobtainable ideal, but at the far opposite extreme
is the light green line for WARM. The graph shows that WARM is really no
different from the moving average loss rate typically used previously for ALLL
calculations, just with a lifetime multiplier. As such, it peaks well after the
crisis is over at a time that all other models correctly predict decreasing loss
reserves. Regulatory expectation is that users would apply quantitative fac-
tors (Q-factors) to manually adjust the WARM baseline to expectations about
the economic and credit cycles. However, because WARM is so out-of-phase
with actual reserve needs, lenders would be better off using a completely flat
(through-the-cycle) average loss rate than to try to back out the post-peak be-
havior of WARM. In short, WARM should not be used for CECL.
Between these extremes of perfect foresight and pure hindsight, things get
much more interesting. The most important question is not when reserves will
peak. In any recession scenario, reserves will peak when the macroeconomic
peak is known. However, not all losses are driven by macroeconomic factors.
When large volumes of new loans are booked, the hazard function or APC
lifecycle will predict when those losses should occur in the future. Similarly, a
strong credit cycle exists in mortgage, which can also be incorporated in the
forecast. Therefore, the question is whether any of the models give a warning
or simply jump to peak levels at the last moment. Figure 4.1 shows the change
in quarterly CECL estimates as a percentage of the outstanding loan balance.
The time series model that other studies suggest would be procyclical is,
in fact, procyclical. Loss reserves do not begin to rise until late 2008. In the
period between 2005 and late 2008 when large volumes of risky loans were being
12
0.0%$
0.5%$
1.0%$
1.5%$
2.0%$
2.5%$
3.0%$
3.5%$
4.0%$
4.5%$
5.0%$
2004-01$ 2005-01$ 2006-01$ 2007-01$ 2008-01$ 2009-01$ 2010-01$ 2011-01$ 2012-01$ 2013-01$ 2014-01$ 2015-01$
CECL$Loss$Rate$
CECL$Loss$Reserve$Estimates$
Actual$ APC$(Vintage)$ Multihorizon$DTS$ Roll$Rate$
State$Transition$ Time$Series$ WARM,$5yr$
Figure 2: CECL lifetime loss estimates between 2005 and 2015 for a range
of models using Consensus Economics scenarios the month before the forecast
quarter.
13
booked, the time series model shows no increase in reserves. If this were the only
basis upon which CECL was judged, it would be considered a failure. However,
that is a failure of the model, not the guidance.
-0.3%&
-0.2%&
-0.1%&
0.0%&
0.1%&
0.2%&
0.3%&
0.4%&
0.5%&
2004-01& 2005-01& 2006-01& 2007-01& 2008-01& 2009-01& 2010-01& 2011-01& 2012-01& 2013-01& 2014-01& 2015-01&
Provision(/(Outstanding(Balance(
Quarterly(Change(in(Reserves(by(Model(Type(
Actual& APC&(Vintage)& Multihorizon&DTS& Roll&Rate& State&Transition& Time&Series& WARM,&5yr&
Figure 3: Change in quarterly reserves by each model type using the Consensus
Economics scenarios.
The best two models from the perspective of anticipating the crisis are the
Age-Period-Cohort (vintage) model and the multihorizon discrete time survival
model. Both the APC and survival models start increasing reserve estimates
in 2005 and accelerate provisioning through 2009. Notably, these models are
adding reserves when the consensus economic scenario suggests that nothing is
wrong economically. Rather, the models are responding to shifts in credit quality
and applying the loss timing to the new originations. Although only halfway
to the perfect foresight result, they would have provided an early warning to
lenders as early as 2006 that risks were increasing significantly. This should be
the stated goal of CECL not to predict the economic cycle, which is unlikely,
but to accurately forecast the risk already in the portfolio.
The roll rate is better than nothing, but only halfway to the vintage and
survival models. This roll rate model used time series models of the net roll
rates to incorporate the economic cycle. A more simplistic model that only
uses moving averages of the rolls, as is common practice, would give much less
warning.
Also shown is the state transition model. As seen in Figure 4.1, the state
transition model showed rather little response to the recession. Unlike the roll
rate model which fits directly to the economic cycle, the state transition predicts
14
Model 2005-2007 2005-2008 2005-2009
APC (Vintage) 42.0% 52.7% 82.9%
Multihorizon DTS 36.3% 48.1% 83.8%
State Transition 28.3% 35.0% 47.9%
Roll Rate 24.3% 31.4% 49.3%
Vintage Copy-Forward 18.9% 69.4% 231.1%
Time Series 13.5% 17.2% 38.6%
WARM, 5yr 5.3% 12.3% 35.4%
Loss Timing 0.9% 1.3% 0.3%
Table 2: Changes in quarterly CECL estimates as a percentage of outstanding
balance.
only one step ahead (one month). Therefore, it’s coefficients are optimized for
short term accuracy, not accuracy through the economic cycle.
Table 2 summarizes the change in CECL reserves as estimated by each
model. The values shown are as a fraction of the ideal reserve level that would
have been maintained with perfect foresight. The results are ranked by which
models gave the most advance warning during the critical period of 2005 through
2007.
The results in Figure 4.1 and Table 2 are not the actual quarterly provi-
sions required, because provisions also must include replacement of charge-off
expenses in the previous quarter, Equation 6.
Provisions(t) = Reserves(t)Reserves(t1) + Losses(t1) (6)
Figure 4.1 shows the quarterly provisions that would be required under each
model as a percentage of outstanding balances in that quarter. Comparing
provisions makes the models look more similar, because they all add in the re-
placement of charge-off balances, even when the CECL calculation is unchanged.
We distinguish here between a statistically-based vintage model and some
simplistic spreadsheet-based vintage models, because the latter are in the same
league as WARM and serve only to clutter the earlier graphs. Figure 4.1 shows
the reserves for the other spreadsheet-based methods in context of a few statis-
tical methods. Of these, the Loss Timing model comes the closest to providing
a stable baseline against which to add intuitive Q-factors by management. The
Vintage Copy-Forward and WARM methods are essentially unusable.
That fact that APC, Loss Timing, and Vintage Copy-Forward are all ”vin-
tage” models has greatly confused the discussions around how to implement
CECL. Clearly, not all vintage models are the same.
4.2 Comparing Scenarios
In the preceding analysis, we used real macroeconomic scenarios from the fore-
cast periods, but how important is it to obtain the best possible scenarios?
Figure 4.2 shows the sensitivity of the APC CECL estimates to macroeconomic
15
-0.1%&
0.0%&
0.1%&
0.2%&
0.3%&
0.4%&
0.5%&
0.6%&
0.7%&
0.8%&
0.9%&
2004-01& 2005-01& 2006-01& 2007-01& 2008-01& 2009-01& 2010-01& 2011-01& 2012-01& 2013-01& 2014-01& 2015-01&
Provision(/(Outstanding(Balance(
Quarterly(Provisions(by(Model(Type(
Actual& APC&(Vintage)& Multihorizon&DTS& Roll&Rate& State&Transition& Time&Series& WARM,&5yr&
Figure 4: Quarterly provisions required by each model type using the Consensus
Economics scenarios.
0.0%$
1.0%$
2.0%$
3.0%$
4.0%$
5.0%$
6.0%$
7.0%$
8.0%$
9.0%$
10.0%$
2004-01$ 2005-01$ 2006-01$ 2007-01$ 2008-01$ 2009-01$ 2010-01$ 2011-01$ 2012-01$ 2013-01$ 2014-01$ 2015-01$
CECL$Loss$Rate$
CECL$Loss$Reserve$Estimates$
Actual$ APC$(Vintage)$ Loss$Timing$ Vintage$Copy-Forward$ WARM,$5yr$
Figure 5: CECL lifetime loss estimates between 2005 and 2015 for the spread-
sheet models compared to some key statistical methods using Consensus Eco-
nomics scenarios the month before the forecast quarter.
16
scenarios. The blue line is the forecast with perfect foresight for the full life of
the loans. The red line uses perfect foresight for the first two years, but then
applies a mean-reverting algorithm for the remainder of the forecast. Therefore,
the red line is the best possible CECL estimate, because it complies with the
CECL rules about reverting to long-run averages beyond a ”reasonable and sup-
portable” period. The two-year reasonable and supportable period used here
appears to be the most common value chosen in the industry.
The other lines use either consensus, flat, or mean reverting for the first
two years, and then continue with mean reverting for the remaining life of the
loan. Other than the Actual and Actual, 2yr scenarios, all other scenarios are
plausible CECL approaches.
0.0%$
0.5%$
1.0%$
1.5%$
2.0%$
2.5%$
3.0%$
3.5%$
4.0%$
2004-01$ 2005-01$ 2006-01$ 2007-01$ 2008-01$ 2009-01$ 2010-01$ 2011-01$ 2012-01$ 2013-01$ 2014-01$ 2015-01$
CECL$Loss$Rate$$
CECL$Loss$Estimates$by$Economic$Scenario,$APC$(Vintage)$
Actual$ Actual,$2yr$ Consensus$ Flat$ Mean$Reverting$
Figure 6: CECL lifetime loss estimates using various macroeconomic scenarios
in the APC vintage model.
Until January 2007, the Actual, 2yr and all realistic scenarios are equivalent.
All of the realistic scenarios diverge from perfect foresight between January 2007
and January 2009. However, all of the realistic scenarios are roughly equivalent
during this period and provide the early warning shown in Figure 4.1, because
that early warning is not dependent upon economic cycle. The consensus eco-
nomic scenario is more accurate and one quarter earlier than the flat scenario,
but the difference is minor. This result suggests that creating a good forecasting
model is more important than finding an optimal macroeconomic scenario.
17
5 Conclusion
During the initial adoption phase for CECL, the biggest step for lenders will
be to establish appropriate risk management practices for loss reserves, gather
necessary data, and create the necessary systems. During this time, any model
will probably be acceptable so long as overall progress is shown.
However, the purpose of CECL is to help lenders survive crises. Simple
models appear to offer little help in surviving crises and may actually be harmful.
To be useful in the period leading up to a crisis, having an effective model will
be important.
The current results also demonstrate that the model is more important than
the economic scenario. We accept that perfect macroeconomic foresight would
be useful, but is unobtainable. After that, the difference between the best and
the worst realistic macroeconomic scenarios is slight, but the difference between
the best and worst models is dramatic.
Acknowledgements
The author wishes to thank Maxim Vaskouski for this assistance in conducting
tests for this paper.
Also, Deep Future Analytics LLC (www.deepfutureanalytics.com) was an
important sponsor of this work.
References
[1] O. Aalen. Nonparametric inference for a family of counting processes.
Annals of Statistics, 6:701–726, 1978.
[2] A. Bangia, F. X. Diebold, A. Kronimus, C. Schagen, and T. Schuermann.
Ratings migration and the business cycle, with application to credit port-
folio stress testing. Journal of Banking & Finance, 26(2):445 – 474, 2002.
[3] K. Berteloot, W. Verbeke, G. Castermans, T. V. Gestel, D. Martens, and
B. Baesens. A novel credit rating migration approach using macroeconomic
indicators. Journal of Forecasting, 32:654–672, 2013.
[4] J. L. Breeden. Modeling data with multiple time dimensions. Computa-
tional Statistics & Data Analysis, 51:4761 – 4785, May 17 2007.
[5] J. L. Breeden. Macroeconomic adverse selection: How consumer demand
drives credit quality. In Credit Scoring and Credit Control XII Conference,
Edinburgh, August 2011.
[6] J. L. Breeden. Living with CECL: Mortgage Alternatives Study, chapter
10. Mean-Reverting Scenarios. Prescient Publshing, 2018.
18
[7] J. L. Breeden. Living with CECL: Mortgage Modeling Alternatives. Pre-
scient Models LLC, 2018.
[8] J. L. Breeden and L. C. Thomas. The relationship between default and
economic cycle for retail portfolios across countries: identifying the drivers
of economic downturn. Journal of Risk Model Validation, 2(3):11 – 44,
2008.
[9] S. Chae, R. Sarama, C. Vojtech, and J. Wang. The impact of the current
expected credit loss standard (cecl) on the timing and comparability of
reserves. Technical report, Bank Policy Institute, 2018.
[10] B. Cohen and G. Edwards. The new era of expected credit loss provisioning.
Technical report, Bank for International Settlements, March 2017.
[11] F. Covas and W. Nelson. Current expected credit loss: Lessons from 2007-
2009. Technical report, Bank Policy Institute, July 2018.
[12] D. R. Cox and D. O. Oakes. Analysis of Survival Data. Chapman and Hall,
London, 1984.
[13] R. Elul. Securitization and mortgage default. Journal of Financial Services
Research, 49:281– 309, 2015.
[14] W. Enders. Applied Econometric Time Series, Second Edition. John Wiley
& Sons, 2004.
[15] FASB. Financial Instruments Credit Losses (Subtopic 825-15). Financial
Accounting Series, December 20 2012.
[16] FDIC. Credit card activities manual.
https://www.fdic.gov/regulations/examinations/credit card/ch12.html,
2007.
[17] FDIC. Community bank webinar: Implementation examples for the cur-
rent expected credit losses methodology (CECL). Technical report, Federal
Deposit Insurance Corp, 2018.
[18] C. Foote, K. Gerardi, and P. S. Willen. Why did so many people make so
many ex post bad decisions? the causes of the foreclosure crisis. Technical
report, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 2012.
[19] N. D. Glenn. Cohort Analysis, 2nd Edition. Sage, London, 2005.
[20] T. J. Hastie, R. J. Tibshirani, and J. Friedman. The Elements of Statistical
Learning: Data Mining, Inference and Prediction. Springer, 2009.
[21] T. Holford. Encyclopedia of Statistics in Behavioral Science, chapter Age-
Period-Cohort Analysis. Wiley, 2005.
19
[22] T. R. Holford. The estimation of age, period and cohort effects for vital
rates. Biometrics, 39(2):311–324, 1983.
[23] IASB. IFRS 9 financial instruments. Technical report, IFRS Foundation,
2014.
[24] R. Israel, J. Rosenthal, and J. Wei. Finding generators for markov chains
via empirical transition matrices, with application to credit ratings. Math-
ematical Finance, 11:245–265, 2000.
[25] I. Jolliffe. Principal Component Analysis, second edition. Springer, 2002.
[26] G. Judge, W. E. Griffiths, R. C. Hill, H. L¨utkepohl, and T.-C. Lee. The
Theory and Practice of Econometrics. Wiley Publications, 1985.
[27] E. L. Kaplan and P. Meier. Nonparametric estimation from incomplete
observations. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 53(282):457–
481, 1958.
[28] B. Keys, T. Mukherjee, A. Seru, and V. Vig. Did securitization lead to lax
screening? evidence from subprime loans. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
125(1):307–362, 2010.
[29] A. Levitin, A. Pavlov, and S. Wachter. Securitization: Cause or remedy
of the financial crisis? Technical report, Institute for Law and Economics,
University of Pennsylvania Law School, 2009.
[30] T. Nadauld and S. Sherlund. The impact of securitization on the expansion
of subprime credit. Journal of Financial Economics, 107(2):454–476, 2013.
[31] V. Schmid and L. Held. Bayesian age-period-cohort modeling and predic-
tion - bamp. Journal of Statistical Software, Articles, 21(8):1–15, 2007.
[32] L. C. Thomas, J. Ho, and W. T. Scherer. Time will tell: behavioural
scoring and the dynamics of consumer credit assessment. IMA Journal of
Management Mathematics, 12(1):89–103, 2001.
[33] S. Truck. Forecasting credit migrations matrices with business cycle effects
p model comparison. The European Journal of Finance, pages 359–379,
May 2014.
[34] G. E. Uhlenbeck and L. S. Ornstein. On the theory of brownian motion.
Physical Review, 38:823 – 841, 1930.
[35] J. Wei. A multi-factor, credit migration model for sovereign and corporate
debts. Journal of International Money and Finance, 22:709–735, 2003.
[36] W. W. S. Wei. Time Series Analysis: Univariate and Multivariate Models,
2nd Edition. Addison-Wesley Pub Co, 1990.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Conference Paper
Full-text available
Using the credit quality estimates from a study of US mortgage performance , we investigated the drivers of credit quality beyond standard underwriting criteria such as score and LTV. Using the Federal Reserve Bank's Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey (SLOOS), we found that industry-wide variations in credit quality by vintage show no correlation to the loan officers' stated intend to tighten or loosen underwriting criteria. However, the measure of consumer demand for mortgages as take from the same survey correlated extremely well to credit quality by vintage. This correlation to consumer demand is also captured by comparing credit quality to macroeconomic drivers that appear to influence consumer appetite for credit. Using changes in mortgage interest rates and house prices we were able to provide an even better explanation of credit quality by vintage over the historical data set. Both the SLOOS and macroeconomic models were extrapolated forward to show how credit quality should have changed since the initial study and predict the credit quality of future originations. We refer to this process as Macroeconomic Adverse Selection, since the macroeconomic environment is having a clear impact on the distribution of consumers applying for loans in ways that are not reflected in their credit scores.
Article
Full-text available
The software package BAMP provides a method of analyzing incidence or mortality data on the Lexis diagram, using a Bayesian version of an age-period-cohort model. A hierarchical model is assumed with a binomial model in the first-stage. As smoothing priors for the age, period and cohort parameters random walks of first and second order, with and without an additional unstructured component are available. Unstructured heterogeneity can also be included in the model. In order to evaluate the model fit, posterior deviance, DIC and predictive deviances are computed. By projecting the random walk prior into the future, future death rates can be predicted.
Book
The new loan loss accounting rules for CECL and IFRS 9 require thousands of organizations to learn about modeling. Likewise, accountants and others in finance are now required to learn about statistical modeling concepts. This book is intended to define terms in a manner consistent with decades of academic literature on statistical modeling and hopefully reduce some of the noise and confusion just around definition of terms. It may also serve as a useful guide to analysts new to the field tasked with IFRS 9 compliance, the international loss accounting rules, and credit risk modeling in general. Each chapter of this book is a term that one might encounter when discussing creating lifetime loss forecasting models for CECL or IFRS 9. Not every term is a model, and some models listed are being mentioned only to explain why they are not likely to be used for loss forecasting. The CECL guidelines and subsequent FAQs have given examples of modeling techniques. Some people new to loss forecasting have assumed that those are all the available or applicable methods. This book is meant in part to dispel that misconception. The definitions and descriptions provided here are meant to provide an intuitive understanding across a range of modeling techniques. Mathematical derivations are kept to a minimum. The references listed will provide all the necessary details for an eager analyst.
Article
In this paper, we explore the role of consumer risk appetite in the initiation of credit cycles and as an early trigger of the US mortgage crisis. We analyze a panel data set of mortgages originated between 2000 and 2009 and follow their performance up to 2014. After controlling for all of the usual observable effects, we show that a strong residual vintage effect remains. This vintage effect correlates well with consumer mortgage demand, as measured by the Federal Reserve Board’s Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey, and with changes in mortgage pricing at the time the loan was originated. Our findings are consistent with an economic environment in which the incentives of low-risk consumers to obtain a mortgage decrease when the cost of obtaining a loan rises. As a result, mortgage originators generate mortgages from a pool of consumers with changing risk profiles over the credit cycle. The unobservable component of the shift in credit risk, relative to the usual underwriting criteria, may be thought of as macroeconomic adverse selection.
Article
The turmoil in the capital markets in 1997 and 1998 has highlighted the need for systematic stress testing of banks' portfolios, including both their trading and lending books. We propose that underlying macroeconomic volatility is a key part of a useful conceptual framework for stress testing credit portfolios, and that credit migration matrices provide the specific linkages between underlying macroeconomic conditions and asset quality. Credit migration matrices, which characterize the expected changes in credit quality of obligors, are cardinal inputs to many applications, including portfolio risk assessment, modeling the term structure of credit risk premia, and pricing of credit derivatives. They are also an integral part of many of the credit portfolio models used by financial institutions. By separating the economy into two states or regimes, expansion and contraction, and conditioning the migration matrix on these states, we show that the loss distribution of credit portfolios can differ greatly, as can the concomitant level of economic capital to be assigned.
Article
In this paper, we collect consumer delinquency data from several economic shocks in order to study the creation of stress-testing models. We leverage the dual-time dynamics modeling technique to better isolate macroeconomic impacts whenever vintage-level performance data is available. The stress-testing models follow a framework described here of focusing on consumer-centric macroeconomic variables so that the models are as robust as possible when predicting the impacts of future shocks.