PreprintPDF Available

Differences in Regional Productivity and Imbalance in Regional Growth

Authors:
Preprints and early-stage research may not have been peer reviewed yet.

Abstract and Figures

This paper focuses on the relationships between regional productivity and regional economic growth. Historical data show the difference in regional productivity in both geographical and sectoral dimensions. Using a modelling approach, the paper tests the regional spillover effects among three types of municipalities in two selected sectors. The results show that, firstly, there are different impacts on different types of regions; secondly, the spillover of impacts differ with respect to regional spillovers and sectoral spillovers; thirdly, the economic structure and the linkage between the regions also play a role in regional spillovers. Imbalanced growth between the regions is revealed.
Content may be subject to copyright.
1
{Preprint version, 2019}
Title: Differences in Regional Productivity and Imbalance in Regional Growth
Corresponding author: Nino Javakhishvili-Larsen, E-mail: ninojl4@gmail.com
And co-author: Jie Zhang, E-mail: Jie.Zhang@crt.dk
Abstract
This paper focuses on the relationships between regional productivity and regional economic
growth. Historical data show the difference in regional productivity in both geographical and
sectoral dimensions. Using a modelling approach, the paper tests the regional spillover effects
among three types of municipalities in two selected sectors. The results show that, firstly, there are
different impacts on different types of regions; secondly, the spillover of impacts differ with respect
to regional spillovers and sectoral spillovers; thirdly, the economic structure and the linkage
between the regions also play a role in regional spillovers. Imbalanced growth between the regions
is revealed.
Keywords: Regional Productivity, Urban-Rural, Spillover Effects, Regional Growth
JEL: C68, O11, O14, O18
2
Introduction
The aim of this paper is to investigate the relationship between changes in labour productivity and
economic growth in Danish regions at the municipal level. Using historical data, we compare the
changes in labour productivity in selected economic sectors before and after the financial crisis of
2008. The study shows that there is a difference in the sector productivity across different types of
regions; that is, the productivity in the new and creative economic sectors in the urban regions has
increased, but that in the traditional sectors, such as agriculture and some of the industrial sectors,
has decreased.
Various studies have been conducted in the fields of new economic geography and regional and
urban economics in relation to labour productivity and the relevant factors that explain the
differences in regional labour productivity. Most research has focused on the explanation of and
correlations between productivity and other economic factors by using econometric approaches.
The differences in human capital, capital stocks and public investment in different regions can
explain some of the causes of different labour productivity levels. Other studies have found that
agglomeration, externalities, technology changes, R&D inputs and so on have also contributed to
the changes in productivity.
Unlike other researchers, we apply a model approach to test and identify the contribution of changes
in labour productivity to regional economic growth. Historical data show the differences in regional
labour productivity and economic growth, which lead to increases in regional commuting and
labour migration; these in turn influence in the long-term changes in labour productivity both in the
region in focus and in the neighbouring regions. The scenario analysis in this paper aims to identify
how the changing trends in productivity within the selected sectors have direct and spillover effects
on regional growth.
3
Literature Review
A considerable amount of research has focused on regional productivity and attempts to understand
the relationship between labour productivity and other economic factors, such as the growth of total
factor productivity (TFP), capital stock, different education backgrounds in the labour force, human
capital, R&D inputs, and technology changes. Besides these economic factors, some research has
explored the relationship between productivity and agglomeration effects, externalities, and
localization.
Total factor productivity seems to be a significant factor that affects both the level and the growth
rates of productivity. Baier, Dwyer and Tamura (2006) found, using a long-time span data set
covering 145 countries, that 14% of economic growth is directly contributed by the growth of TFP.
The variance is larger across country groups; specifically, TFP growth accounted for 34% of the
average growth in Western countries and 26% in Southern Europe and the newly industrialized
countries (NICs). Their evidence shows that, over long periods of time, the growth of output per
worker is associated with the accumulation of physical and human capital and technology changes.
Beugelsdijk, Klasing and Milionis (2018) determined, using the 257 regions in the 21 EU countries,
that 75% of the differences in regional economic development can be attributed to differences in
TFP. They suggested that the analysis could be extended to the regional level in each country and to
the sectoral level, as this could reveal more about the TFP differences related to regional economic
growth and local dimensions of technology and knowledge.
Bronzini and Piselli (2009) investigated the long-run relationship between total factor productivity,
human capital, and public infrastructure between 1980 and 2001 across the Italian regions. Their
findings showed that the R&D associated with productivity expansion is rather small; on the other
hand, human capital and infrastructure seem to play an important role in explaining regional
productivity dynamics. Both have a positive and quite remarkable effect on productivity. They
found from their model simulation that, with an increase of 1% in human capital and public
4
infrastructure, productivity will increase by 0.38% and 0.11%, respectively. They also discovered
through causality tests that both human capital and public capital are exogenous in the long run.
Ciccone (2002) wrote that “two of the main explanations for special differences in average labour
productivity within countries are spatial externalities and increasing returns at the firm level
combined with non-tradability or transportation costs. Ciccone (2002) estimated the regional
agglomeration effect for the five large EU countries, that is, France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and the
UK. The empirical results suggest that the agglomeration effects in these European countries are
only slightly lower than those in the United States and do not vary significantly across countries.
Brulhart and Mathys (2008) extended Ciccone’s (2002) method by applying dynamic panel
estimation and using sector-level data. Their results demonstrated that agglomeration contributes
significantly to economic growth, with long-term elasticity of 13%.
Azaeri et al. (2016) focused their study on the relationship between agglomeration effects and
manufacturing productivity in urban cities. Their results showed that labour density has a negative
impact on a country’s economic growth due to the population congestion in large cities; however,
output density has a positive effect on urban manufacturing productivity.
Cohen (2010) obtained similar results by applying the econometric method to estimate the effects of
public investment in infrastructure and found that investment in public infrastructure has a positive
impact on regional productivity. Schutzs (2017) research explored distinct patterns of innovative
activities within three territories in Australia. The proposed analysis was able to discover the key
actors of innovative activities in each region by concentrating on the industry linkage structure.
Arbia, Battisti and Vaio (2010) implemented a modelling approach to confirm that institutions and
geography play a strong and positive role in regional productivity growth.
Whether the contribution is from TFP, human capital and public infrastructure or from externalities,
innovative activities, and agglomeration economies, regional spillovers produce changes in regional
productivity, causing differences in regional growth. According to the previous studies, there is a
5
positive correlation between productivity growth and economic growth at either the spatial level or
the sectoral level. In this paper, we investigate further how changing productivity assumptions in a
regional economy can have both inter-sectoral and inter-regional spillover effects. Using regional
IO-CGE modelling techniques and Danish regional multitudinous data, we attempt to demonstrate
whether there are any spatial variations in the spillover effect size considering the regional typology
(urban versus rural/peripheral) and whether there are varied effects on the future course of
economic development in the selected sectors considering the regional typology. Naveed et al
(2017) argue that agglomeration economies and accessibility to the human capital pool varies across
the regions within the country. The urban areas characterise with the large pools of labour, skills
and accessibility to knowledge and services therefore, the exogenous shock (for example, labour
inflows) do not play important role on the local labour markets and local economy. While, the rural
and peripheral areas, characterised by scarce supply of labour and services and an absence of the
agglomeration economies, therefore the exogenous shock (for example, labour inflow) play
significant role on local economic growth (for example, job creation). Considering the Myrdal’s
(1957) and Krugman’s (1991) studies and extended various research by economists and
geographers in the last decades, geographical analysis become essential to understand how
economic impacts differ based on socioeconomic characteristics of different localities for adopting
the urban and rural development policies. This paper employs the urban-rural typology and
compares the spillover effects of the productivity increase in rural, urban, and peripheral areas of
Denmark. Based on the scenario experiments, the paper will contribute to the previous literature by
explaining the spillover variations of labour productivity across sectors, time, and geography.
Spatiality, Trends and Data
Previous studies have emphasized that labour productivity varies due to socio-economic and
demographic differences within regions. Broersma and Oosterhaven (2009) found that the causes of
the regional differences in labour productivity are diversification, urbanization, and localization
effects. Urbanization and localization are subdivisions of agglomeration effects. Their results
6
showed that high job density in a particular region leads to higher regional productivity growth. The
positive agglomeration effect is, however, mitigated by the effect of the job density in neighbouring
regions. If a region is surrounded by regions with high job density, then positive spillover effects
will spread to its neighbours. Hence, the agglomeration effect of that region will be less without
considering the effects of the neighbouring regions.
Our study takes regional heterogeneity into account by grouping 98 Danish municipalities into
spatialeconomic types, namely urban, rural, and peripheral. The grouping method is based on
Hansen et al. (2012) and is widely used in policy practice (e.g., reporting to the Danish parliament)
as well as in research (Naveed et al., 2017). This typology groups municipalities by their socio-
economic functionality using 14 socio-economic indicators to identify urban versus rural areas.
These indicators cover issues of economy, education, demography, development, rural importance,
centreperiphery and urbanization. They are grouped into 3 types of municipalities. The Urban
Municipalities type includes 35 municipalities that are socio-economically connected to the 5
largest cities in Denmark, such as the capital city metropolis (Copenhagen), Aarhus city area,
Aalborg, Odense and Kolding and the urban catchment type municipalities (17 municipalities) that
are also socio-economically connected to the city municipalities. These 52 municipalities are
strongly connected to each other and have urban characteristics. Therefore, they comprise the Urban
Municipalities type group. The Rural type includes 30 municipalities, and they play a considerable
role in the creation of ruralurban balance. These municipalities are less connected to the 5 largest
cities and have strong rural activities. The last type, the Peripheral type, consists of 17
municipalities, which are mainly characterized by remote rurality, are less connected to other
municipalities. These municipalities are in remote areas, such as small island or those on the far
edge of the western coastline. We investigate the peripheral type separately from the rural type, as,
both structurally and demographically, peripheral-type municipalities are quite different from rural-
type municipalities.
7
Copenhagen metropole is the largest agglomeration in Denmark and encompasses one-third of the
Danish population and nearly half of the Danish employment and production. Copenhagen
metropole is a gravity centre and creates a clear centreperiphery structure in Denmark. The rest of
the production and population are scattered across other municipalities of Denmark. Four other big
cities are located on the Jutland Peninsula and Fyn, but none of them are big enough to create
gravity field and strong leakages; however, they have spillover effects on a few of the neighbouring
municipalities. This spatial typology is demonstrated in Figure 1a in the appendix, in which the
Urban, the Rural and the Peripheral type municipalities have clear spatial distribution patterns.
Due to the tadpolestructure of the Danish economy, with the Copenhagen metropole as the head,
national-level processes of economic growth or restructuring have mainly been observed in the
Copenhagen metropole. Since 2000, labour productivity has been increasing rapidly in all the
municipality types; however, in 2008 and 2009, labour productivity dropped in the whole country
due to the global financial crisis. In 2007, the Danish economy reached its peak (OECD, 2008). At
the end of 2008, the global financial crisis was also reflected in the Danish economy. The crisis
became the foundation for the economic restructuring. Between 2008 and 2010, approximately 140
thousand jobs disappeared. Skills and higher competences became the key factors to survive and
compete on the labour market (www.fm.dk/publikationer). Until the end of 2011, the employment
figures did not change much; however, the economic situation showed some signs of improvement
at the end of 2011 and later. Labour productivity had already reached the 2008 level in 2010, with
rapid growth until 2012 and continued steady growth until 2016 (see Figure 2a in the appendix).
Figure 2a shows that, from 2000 to 2008, labour productivity was increasing at about 4% annually
in all the types of municipalities, and, after the financial crisis (from 2009), the productivity trend
continued to grow but with a lower annual growth rate of about 2%. Figure 2a also shows that the
urban and rural regions followed the national productivity trend after 2009; however, the peripheral
regions had a slower recovery after the crisis. In the peripheral regions, we observe that the
productivity growth started a couple of years later, and they managed to catch up with the other
8
regions with about 7% annual growth from 2010 to 2012. After 2012, all the regions continued to
grow more slowly, by about 1% annually, until 2016. In 2016, the regional gap of labour
productivity was low, with only a few thousand Danish kroner. According to Figure 2a, the labour
productivity level in the peripheral regions in 2016 was about 36 thousand kroner higher than that
in the urban and rural regions, respectively.
According to the analyses of economic structure and the trends of each municipality type, it is
found that knowledge-based business services are mainly concentrated in urban municipalities and
machine industry is more representative for the rural and peripheral regions.
Description of SectorsSelection for Experiment
The overall development trends of labour productivity clearly point to few possible explanations. It
is possible that, due to the financial crisis, there were some structural changes in the Danish
economy, and it is also possible that there were changes in the spatial distribution of economic
activities, especially in the peripheral regions. Figures 1, 2 and 3 show the regional sectoral
concentration in comparison with productivity growth in each type of region.
By calculating the location quotient (LQ) of each sector in each region, we identify the regional
concentration of each sector by using the standard LQ equation:
LQi
= (ei/e) / (Ei/E)
were,
LQi
= location quotient for sector i in the region
ei
= employment in sector i in the region
e
= total employment in the local region
Ei
= employment in industry i in the nation
economy
E
= total employment in the nation
Based on the LQ, the regions differ not only by the socio-economic conditions (such as urban, rural,
and peripheral) but also by the distribution of economic activities. Figure 1 illustrates the sectors
9
that are concentrated in urban regions. As in many other Western European countries, the urban
types of areas in Denmark have high locational concentration of service sectors, which are
knowledge intensive, such as IT and information, R&D, financial and insurance services, trade and
transport, public services, and other business services. In almost all sectors, productivity increased
rapidly during the period 20002008, while it started to slow down during and after the financial
crisis, from 2009 to 2016.
Among these locally concentrated sectors, most of the sectors experienced a fluctuating annual
growth rate of productivity of about 12% before and after the financial crisis. A few sectors, such
as telecommunications, R&D and some public sectors and services faced a rapid productivity
decline of about 4% annually during the period 20092016, while only a couple of sectors, the
medicine industry and knowledge-based business services, achieved rapid productivity growth after
the crisis. The medicine industry is a large cluster located primarily in the Copenhagen metropole
area; therefore, we do not include this sector in further analyses in this paper, as it fails to reflect the
economic activities in other urban municipalities. However, knowledge-based business services
seem to be the sector with the fastest-growing productivity before and especially after the crisis,
from 2009 to 2016, and the gross value added (GVA) in this sector increased continuously by about
2% annually during the whole period from 2000 to 2016.
[…Insert Figure 1 here]
Figure 1. Regional concentration by sector and productivity annual growth rate in urban municipalities
Source: CRT database and own calculation
Note: CAGR is Compound Annual Growth Rate. LQ is Location Quotient
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
1,00
1,05
1,10
1,15
1,20
1,25
1,30
1,35
1,40
1,45
Productivity Annual Growth
Rate
Location Quotient
CAGR (2000-2008) CAGR (2009-2016)
10
The local concentration of economic activities differs between the rural areas and the urban areas.
Rural regions have concentrated mainly on industries and primary sectors. Oil refineries are the
most concentrated and emerging sector; however, we do not analyse this sector further in this paper,
as oil refineries are only located in a couple of municipalities in Denmark and therefore do not
reflect other rural municipalities in Denmark. Figure 2 illustrates the regional concentration of the
sectors and the annual productivity growth before and after the crisis in rural-type municipalities.
According to Figure 2, the machine industry was emerging before the crisis by rapidly increasing its
productivity by about 6% annually. The financial crisis slowed down the productivity growth by
4%, and from 2009 to 2016 productivity increased annually only by a 2% growth rate. The GVA in
the machine industry has been increasing by about 3% annually.
According to Figure 2, a few regionally concentrated sectors increased their productivity after the
finance crisis in the rural areas. For example, the furniture industry, which expanded its productivity
by 5% annually before the crisis between 2000 and 2008, continued with even more rapid annual
productivity growth of 9% between 2009 and 2016. Such a trend in productivity is also apparent in
the GVA in this sector, with an annual growth rate of more than 7% from 2000 to 2016.
[…Insert Figure 2 here]
Figure 2. Regional concentration by sector and productivity annual growth rate in rural municipalities
11
Source: CRT database and own calculation
Note: CAGR is Compound Annual Growth Rate. LQ is Location Quotient
Peripheral municipalities have a similar economic concentration to rural municipalities, as mainly
primary and industrial sectors are concentrated there; however, the rapid growth in productivity in
some sectors affected their LQ index after the crisis, causing their increasing concentration in those
municipalities. For example, the chemical and leather industries had high productivity growth
during 2009 and 2016 and the LQ index changed from LQ<1 in 2000 to LQ>1 in 2016. Some
sectors experienced a rapid decrease in productivity after the crisis, and their LQ index changed
from concentrated in 2000 to non-concentrated in 2016 (e.g., mining). (Figure 3)
[…Insert Figure 3 here]
Figure 3. Regional concentration by sector and productivity annual growth rate in peripheral municipalities
Source: CRT database and own calculation
Note: CAGR is Compound Annual Growth Rate. LQ is Location Quotient
Overall, as in the rural municipalities, the machine industry was one of the most rapidly growing
sectors in the peripheral municipalities. Even though the productivity growth dropped from 10%
annual growth before the crisis to 2% annual growth after the crisis, the GVA of the machine
industry in the peripheral municipalities increased by about 5% annually from 2000 to 2016.
Despite the slowing down of the productivity growth after the crisis, the LQ index of the machine
industry increased from 1.41 in 2000 to 1.68 in 2016.
-8%
-6%
-4%
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
0,00
0,50
1,00
1,50
2,00
2,50
3,00
Agriculture,…
Electronic…
Furniture…
Metal…
Tree and…
Food,…
Machine…
Mining
Construction
Plastic,…
Water…
Other…
All Sectors
Education
Chemical…
Energy Supply
Social…
Transport
Real Estate…
Textile and…
Hotels and…
Public…
Trade
Healthcare
Travel…
Financial…
Transportati…
Productivity Annual Growth Rate
Location Quotient
CAGR (2000-2008) CAGR (2009-2016) LQ-2000 (LQ>1 = Regional Concentration)
12
According to the analyses of economic structure and the trends of each municipality type, the
selection of sectors a and b, is relatively clear. Sector a should represent the knowledge-based
economy and sector b the industrial economy. According to the analyses in the urban areas, it is
obvious that either R&D or knowledge-based business services can be selected. The R&D sector in
Denmark is mainly a publicly owned sector (i.e., universities, research institutions, etc.); therefore,
the development processes within this sector are strongly bound to the political decisions of the
welfare system rather than the free market. The knowledge-based business services sector, on the
other hand, is privately owned and therefore the productivity changes in this sector reflect the
changes in the free market. Even though knowledge-based business services are mainly
concentrated in urban municipalities, their rapid growth in rural and peripheral municipalities,
especially after the crisis, implies that this sector is emerging outside the cities.
Based on the analysis of rural and peripheral municipalities, sector b is the machine industry. The
machine industry is one of the largest industries in Danish rural areas, and the trends have shown
rapid growth of production value both in the rural municipalities and in the peripheries since 2000.
Although the machine industry is not regionally concentrated in the urban municipalities, both
productivity and gross value added have been increasing by about 2%, especially between 2009 and
2016.
Methods and Assumptions
The scenario experiment is implemented in the SAM-K/LINE model, which is a Danish inter-
regional macroeconomic model with frameworks of computable general equilibrium (CGE) and the
social accounting matrix (SAM) by municipality, model is hereafter called LINE (Madsen &
Jensen-Butler, 2004 & 2005; Madsen & Zhang, 2010). The main purpose of this paper is to
investigate the relationship between changes in productivity and economic growth in Danish
regions. In accordance with this target, a scenario experiment is set up as follows.
13
Scenario 1 We assume that the productivity in the selected sector a a knowledge-based sector
will increase by 10% in 2020 compared with the baseline.
Scenario 1 is expressed in the following formular:
         (eq. 1)
were,
 is the difference in production value between the baseline production and the altered
production by given sectors i (a or b) and given municipalities j (urban, rural, and peripheral).
 is the number of employees in the given sectors i (a or b) and municipalities j (urban,
rural, and peripheral).
 is the labour content in the production by given sectors i and municipalities j.
Here    
 is the baseline production by the given sectors i and municipalities j.
As shown in equation (1) in the scenario 1 experiment, we calculate the difference in the production
value between the baseline production in the given sector and municipality and the production with
10% lower labour content (as the labour content is multiplied by 0.90), that is, a 10% increase in
productivity. Analysing this scenario, we can observe how much the productivity gain in sector a
will contribute to the regional economy (GVA) and employment in the urban and ruralperipheral
types of municipalities in Denmark.
Scenario 2 We assume that the productivity in selected sector b the machine industrial sector
will increase by 10% in 2020 compared with the baseline.
Same as in equation (1), in scenario 2, we calculate the difference in the production between the
baseline production in the given sector and municipality and the production with 10% lower labour
content, that is, a 10% increase in productivity in the machine industry.
14
By analysing this scenario, we can observe how much the productivity gain in sector b will affect
the regional economy (GVA) and employment in the urban and ruralperipheral types of
municipalities in Denmark.
Considering the regional heterogeneity, we set up each scenario experiment for each type of
municipality separately. Therefore, in each scenario, we include six experiments (Table 1).
[…Insert Table 1 here…]
Table 1. Structure of the scenario experiments
Scenario 1 10% increase in knowledge-based services
Scenario2 10% increase in the machine industry
Scenario 1A in urban municipalities
Scenario 2A in urban municipalities
Scenario 1B in rural municipalities
Scenario 2B in rural municipalities
Scenario 1C in peripheral municipalities
Scenario 2C in peripheral municipalities
There are two fixed pre-assumptions in the SAM-K/LINE model, which do not affect the results of
the scenario experiments. 1) The SAM-K/LINE baseline model assumptions built on the forecast
itself. These assumptions are based on the Aggregated Danish Annual Model (ADAM), which is the
Danish official macroeconomic model projecting economic and demographic trends at the national
level. These projections are developed at the Danish Ministry of Finance and incorporate future
political reforms and expected changes in the country. 2) Even though SAM-K/LINE is a dynamic
model that covers the Danish regional economy at the municipality level during the period 1996
2040, we employ only a one-year experiment, that is, a short-term experiment with the fixed
assumption that the unemployment is constant and that the labour force is elastic. As these
assumptions do not affect the results from each scenario, we do not describe them further.
In the next section, we analyse the results from the two sets of scenarios and try to explain how the
productivity change affects the regional economy through the inter-regional and inter-sectoral
spillovers and further compare the size of changes in the knowledge-based service sector and the
machine industrial sector.
15
Results from the Scenario Experiments
As presented above, the two sets of scenarios are designed to investigate the productivity changes in
two sectors, that is, the knowledge-based service sector (1A1C in Table 1) and the machine
industrial sector (2A2C in Table 1), and three types of municipalities, specifically ‘urban’, ‘rural’
and ‘peripheral/outskirts. In the following sections, the results are organized so that we first look at
the impacts of these six experiments on the overall economy in the different types of municipalities
and then describe the inter-regional and inter-sectoral spillovers in more detail.
Overall results
Based on the scenario assumptions, whereby we assume that the productivity in the selected sectors
a (a knowledge-based sector) and b (the machine industrial sector) will increase by 10% in 2020,
the overall results show how great an impact each experiment has on the employment in different
types of municipalities. Figure 4 shows the job growth in Danish municipalities in the baseline
scenario since 2000. According to the figure, the number of total jobs increased in all the
municipality types until 2008 and then decreased due to the financial crisis in 20082009. The
urban type of municipalities appears to have been quite resilient to the economic recovery after the
crisis, and the number of jobs has continuously increased, especially after 2013. The rural and
peripheral municipalities show a slight increase in the number of jobs until 2013, and, in the
baseline scenario, they are expected to grow more in 2020; however, these types of municipalities
remain far below the national average.
[…Insert Figure 4 here]
Figure 4. Job growth in Denmark by municipality types between 2000 and 2020 (2000=100 index)
16
Source: SAM-K/LINE®_version0218
After applying the scenario experiments in the model, in which we assume that the productivity in
the two different types of sectors is 10% higher in 2020 than in the baseline scenario, we can see the
overall impact in experiments 1C and 2C. Figure 5 shows the overall results regarding the impact
on employment and the comparison between the experiments. The horizontal line in Figure 5 is the
baseline employment index (=100). The changes in employment in each experiment will be
compared with the baseline employment, which will reveal the changes in the index. Figure 5 also
shows that the total effects of experiment 2C are the highest across the municipality types. Such
overall impacts of the increasing productivity in the machine industry in peripheral areas indicate
that the peripheral areas are generally characterized by strong inter-regional linkages to other
neighbouring localities, due to the “thin pool” of labour and the lack of availability of suppliers for
the production.
[…Insert Figure 5 here]
Figure 5. Comparison of the impacts of the experiments in municipality types. 2020_Base is index 100.
100
91
98
100
114
108
85
90
95
100
105
110
115
120
Periphery Rural Urban Denmark
17
Source: SAM-K/LINE®_version0218
Note: 1A, 1B, 1C refers to scenarios 10 % increase in productivity in knowledge-based services in urban, rural and
peripheral areas respectively. 2A, 2B, 2C, refers to scenarios 10% increase in productivity in machine industry in
urban, rural and peripheral areas respectively.
The economic sector, such as the machine industry, is also characterized as the sector with higher
intermediate consumption than the knowledge-based sector, which explains why there is a larger
overall spillover effect from the increased productivity in the machine industry in the peripheral
type of municipalities internally as well as inter-regionally. The figure also shows that the impacts
are relatively smaller in urban and rural areas, which is more explainable as such localities have a
better capacity to absorb (Naveed et al., 2017) the various shocks and changes. The detailed inter-
regional and inter-sectoral spillover effects are described in the following sections.
Intra- and inter-regional spillovers: Spatial analysis
In this section, the results are shown from the viewpoint of inter-regional spillover effects. Inter-
regional spillovers are defined as the extent to which economic exogenous shocks affect the
neighbouring localities (Dietzenbacher, 2002). The spillover values differ depending on the strength
of the geographical linkages among the municipality types. This section focuses on the creation of
gross value added (GVA). Based on the definition of productivity in this study, we assume that
increasing productivity will happen at the expense of the number of jobs in the sector and therefore
that the added employment effects cannot be high. However, we can observe the extent to which the
productivity increase affects the value creation in the local and the national economy. Table 2
99,900
100,000
100,100
100,200
100,300
100,400
100,500
100,600
Periphery Rural Urban Denmark
Index
2020_1A
2020_1B
2020_1C
2020_2A
2020_2B
2020_2C
2020_Base (100)
18
shows the changes in gross value added (GVA) due to implementing scenarios 1A to 1C, which
refer to the 10% productivity increase in the knowledge-based service sector in the three types of
regions: A urban; B rural; and C peripheral.
[…Insert Table 2 here]
Table 2. Regional changes in GVA due to experiments 1A1C (10% productivity increase in the knowledge-
based service sector) (in million DKK)
Type of regions
Periphery (1C)
Rural (1B)
Urban (1A)
Total
Periphery (1C)
109
12
31
152
(%)
0.72
0.08
0.20
1.00
Rural (1B)
9
408
106
523
(%)
0.02
0.78
0.20
1.00
Urban (1A)
28
99
3.565
3,692
(%)
0.01
0.03
0.97
1.00
Total
147
520
3,702
4,369
(%)
0.03
0.12
0.85
1.00
Source: SAM-K/LINE®_version0218
Note: 1A, 1B, 1C refers to scenarios 10 % increase in productivity in knowledge-based services in urban, rural and
peripheral areas respectively.
As is apparent from the table, a 10% increase in productivity in the knowledge-based service sector
in the peripheral municipalities creates in total 152 m DKK
1
(approximately 20 m EUR) GVA,
while 72% of the gain remains in the peripheral municipalities (app. 109 m DKK (app. 14 m EUR))
and 28% of the generated value spills over to the rural and urban types of municipalities (which
altogether equal app. 43 m. DKK or 5.6 m EUR). According to the same experiment, increasing
productivity in the knowledge-based service sector in rural types of municipalities creates in total an
additional 523 m DKK (70 m EUR) in the whole country, from which 78% of the economic gain
remains in the rural municipalities (app. 408 m DKK, =55 m EUR) and the remaining 22% spills
over to the other municipality types. The third experiment in the urban municipalities, however,
shows that 97% of the additional total gain of 3.692 m DKK (=500 m EUR) GVA remains within
the urban localities and only 3% spills over to the other municipality types. Overall, after summing
the results from these three experiments (1A1C), the urban municipalities gain 85% of the total
1
The exchange rate for 100 DKK=13.4 EUR in 2019.
19
effects, while only a 12% gain is observed in the rural municipalities. The size of the economic gain
in urban areas is naturally large, as the concentration of knowledge-based services is mainly in the
urban type of municipalities in comparison with the rural and peripheral types of municipalities.
However, nearly all the economic gains from the increased productivity in such a sector remain in
the urban areas with a unidirectional link from rural to urban as well as from peripheral to urban,
and not the reverse.
Table 3 shows the results from the second set of experiments, 2A2C, which refer to the 10%
productivity increase in the machine industrial sector in the three types of regions. As the table
shows, the 10% productivity increase in the machine industry in the peripheral municipalities
affects the increase in the total GVA by 1,615 million DKK (=200 m EUR), from which only 73%
of the added value remains intra-regionally and the rest spills over to the other municipalities,
especially to the urban types, with app. 18% of the total value. The same assumption in the rural
municipalities leads to an increase in the total GVA of 3,496 million DKK (=468 m EUR). 86% of
the added value remains in the rural municipalities (app. 3,009 million DKK) and the rest spills over
to the urban municipalities. Both experiments, in peripheral areas and in rural areas, show strong
relations to the urban areas, albeit with only unidirectional linkages. This proves that the same
assumption for the experiment in the urban municipalities causes an increase in the total GVA of
3,657 million DKK and that 93% of the added value remains intra-regionally, while only 6% of the
added value spills over to the rural municipalities.
[…Insert Table 3 here]
Table 3. Regional changes in GVA due to experiments 2A2C (10% productivity increase in the machine
industrial sector) (in millions of DKK)
Type of regions
Periphery (2C)
Rural (2B)
Urban (2A)
Total
Periphery (2C)
1,186
141
288
1,615
(%)
0.73
0.09
0.18
1.00
Rural (2B)
49
3,009
438
3,496
(%)
0.01
0.86
0.13
1.00
Urban (2A)
49
203
3,405
3,657
(%)
0.01
0.06
0.93
1.00
20
Total
1,285
3,354
4,131
8,770
(%)
0.15
0.38
0.47
1.00
Source: SAM-K/LINE®_version0218
Note: 2A, 2B, 2C, refers to scenarios 10% increase in productivity in machine industry in urban, rural and peripheral
areas respectively.
In general, to sum up the results from these three experiments, 2A2C, the primary winner is
observed to be the urban municipalities, which gain 47% of the total effects caused by the
experiments, while 38% of the total gain is observed in the rural municipalities and only 15% in the
outskirts. It is also clear that the total effects from the experiments in the knowledge-based sector
are concentrated within the urban areas (85%; see Table 2), while the total effects from the
experiments in the machine industry are closely distributed between rural and urban municipalities.
The size of the effects in the rural areas is due to the concentration of the machine industrial sector
in such areas. In total, these three experiments indicate similar distribution patterns of the effects, as
in the case of GVA (Table 3), for which the effects are distributed mainly between the urban and
rural municipalities and the peripheries gain only 12% of the total.
In summary, these results indicate that the machine industrial sector has stronger backward linkages
than the knowledge-based service sectors. The spillover effects, however, are unidirectional in both
sectors, that is, from rural to urban, from peripheral to urban and from peripheral to rural. The
results also indicate that the exogenous changes in the peripheral municipalities have stronger
positive effects on the urban and rural municipalities, while the urban municipalities demonstrate
the opposite pattern, whereby all the positive effects from the exogenous changes in the economy
remain primarily intra-regionally within the urban municipalities. This phenomenon can
demonstrate how the gap between the urban and the rural municipalities is constantly widening in
both the local economy and the demography.
Inter- and intra-sectoral spillovers: Multiplier analysis
This section focuses on the inter- and intra-sectoral linkages based on the results of the six
experiments (1A1C and 2A2C). The goal of the analysis is to understand and compare the size of
21
the multipliers and inter-sectoral linkages in knowledge-based services and the machine industrial
sector in different geographical settings.
The multiplier effect shows how much the final demand should increase after creating an exogenous
shock/alteration in the specific economic condition. For this aspect, we calculate the direct, derived,
and total effects. The direct effect is the shock or alteration in the specific condition; that is, in this
study, the direct effect is the value from the 10% productivity increase in the given sector. The
derived effect is measured as the sum of the indirect effect, which is the measure of sector-to-sector
activity/trade, and the induced effect, which is the measure of the wages/income created due to the
shock/alteration in the specific economic condition. The total effect is the sum of the direct and
derived effects, whereby the derived effect is the sum of the indirect and induced effects. The
multiplier is therefore calculated as the total effect divided by the direct effect. This can explain
how much the change in the final demand due to the shock/alteration in the economic condition
affects the total economy.
As it was clear from the previous section, spillover effects differ by the geographical type of the
location where the economic activity is present. This section takes the geographical characteristics
into account and studies the size and types of multipliers considering the experiments in urban,
rural, or peripheral municipalities.
Table 4 shows the inter- and intra-regional spillover effects from experiments 1A1C, referring to
the 10% productivity increase in the knowledge-based service sector in three types of
municipalities. According to the table, the multipliers in the urban regions are the largest, which can
be explained by the concentration of knowledge-based services, the pool of required competences
and the wide range of trade partners in the urban municipalities.
According to the table, experiment 1A’s results show a direct value gain of 1.6 billion DKK with a
multiplier of 2.31, which can be interpreted as indicating that, for each additional million DKK of
GVA, 1.31 million DKK is gained. That shows that the total derived effects in the urban
22
municipalities are app. 2 billion DKK, from which app. 24.4% (511 m. DKK) is an intra-sectoral
derived effect within the knowledge-based services, while app. 75% of the derived gain spills over
to other sectors in the Danish economy. The table also confirms that the smallest multiplier effect is
observable when the same experiment is conducted in the peripheral regions (1C). According to the
results, each additional million DKK GVA in the knowledge-based services in peripheral
municipalities spills over only 0.88 million DKK, which equals about 71 million DKK. From the
derived effects, 24% (17 m. DKK) is generated internally in the knowledge-based services, while
76% of the gain is from sector-to-sector activities (inter-sectoral derived effect). In the rural
municipalities, the results of the 1B experiment follow the same pattern as the other two
experiments. In addition, the intra-sectoral derived effects are similarly 24.2% (61 m. DKK), while
the inter-sectoral derived effects are about 75.8%. In summary, the intra-sectoral and inter-sectoral
spillover effects of knowledge-based services are nearly the same in all the types of municipalities
and do not change by location, while the multiplier size clearly differs by the geographical
characteristics of the location, that is, the knowledge-based services have larger derived effects the
closer they are to the urban municipalities.
[…Insert Table 4 here]
Table 4. Changes in the final GVA due to experiments 1A1C (a 10% productivity increase in the knowledge-
based service sector) (in millions of DKK)
Periphery (1C)
Rural (1B)
Urban (1A)
Total
Direct effect
81
271
1,602
1,954
Total effect
152
523
3,693
4,368
Derived effect
71 (100%)
252 (100%)
2,091 (100%)
2,414
Intra-sector derived effect
17 (24%)
61 (24.2%)
511 (24.4%)
589
Inter-sector derived effect
54 (76%)
191 (75.8%)
1,580 (75.6%)
1,825
Multipliers
1.88
1.93
2.31
Source: SAM-K/LINE®_version2018
Table 5 shows the results from the second set of experiments 2A2C, referring to the 10%
productivity increase in the machine industrial sector in the three types of municipalities. This
experiment shows different results regarding the multiplier effects and the intra- and inter-sectoral
23
spillover effects. As mentioned earlier, the machine industrial sector is a manufacturing industry,
which requires high intermediate consumption and raw materials to produce the output; therefore,
we expected high-level inter-sectoral spillover effects connected to this sector.
[…Insert Table 5 here]
Table 5. Changes in GVA due to experiments 2A2C (a 10% productivity increase in the machine industry
sector) (in millions of DKK)
Periphery (2C)
Rural (2B)
Urban (2A)
Total
Direct effect
900
2,269
2,211
5,380
Total effect
1,615
3,495
3,658
8,768
Derived effect
715 (100%)
1,226 (100%)
1,447 (100%)
3,388
Intra-sector derived effect
106 (14.8%)
165 (13.5%)
184 (12.7%)
455
Inter-sector derived effect
609 (85.2%)
1,061 (86.5%)
1,263 (87.3%)
2,933
Multipliers
1.79
1.54
1.65
Source: SAM-K/LINE®_version0218
It is interesting to notice in the table that experiment 2C, referring to the 10% productivity increase
in this sector in peripheral municipalities, has the largest multiplier effect of 1.79 compared with
experiments 2B (rural) and 2A (urban). This can be interpreted as indicating that, if experiment 2C
caused the additional direct effect of GVA of 900 m. DKK, then the derived effects were 715 m.
DKK. From the derived effects, 14.8% were intra-sectoral derived effects and 85.2% inter-sectoral
spillovers, which are much higher figures than in the previous experiments for knowledge-based
services and can be explained by the higher intermediate consumption in the production of
machinery. The other two experiments, 2B in rural municipalities and 2A in urban municipalities,
have similar intra- and inter-sectoral spillover effects, although the inter-sectoral derived effects
increase with closeness to the urban municipalities. According to Table 5, experiment 2A produces
a smaller multiplier effect than in peripheral areas, which equals app. 1.65 and can be interpreted as
showing that each additional 1 million DKK GVA derives 0.65 million DKK GVA. At the same
time, app. 87.3% (1,263 m. DKK) of the derived effects are inter-sectoral.
In summary, the 10% productivity increase in the machine industrial sector in peripheral
municipalities has larger spillover effects geographically but lower inter-sectoral linkages than that
24
in urban areas, which has lower spillover effects geographically but higher inter-sectoral linkages.
We assume that the results in these experiments indicate that different types of activities within the
machine industrial sector could be in urban, rural, and peripheral areas; for example, production
plants could be in peripheral municipalities, while service, research or similar activities within the
machine industry could be in the urban municipalities. Unfortunately, we cannot undertake more
detailed analyses of the sector at the plant level.
As explained above, each experiment has different economic and employment effects, and even
though the productivity increase means that the number of jobs is assumed to decrease while the
gross output increases, then the employment effects in these experiments are due to the additional
gain in gross output after the 10% productivity increase in the knowledge-based service sector and
the machine industrial sector in the three different types of municipalities.
In summary, the location matters regarding the spillover effects from the changes in the gross
output, especially in the machine industrial sectors. The productivity increase in the peripheral
municipalities in this sector creates large spillover effects not only by geography but also
intersectoral, in terms of both GVA and employment. Meanwhile, in urban and rural municipalities,
the derived effects are mainly due to the sector-to-sector interaction and activities.
On the other hand, the productivity increase in knowledge-based services generates higher
economic and employment returns in the urban municipalities. Even though more than half of the
spillover effects are inter-sectoral, the intra-sectoral spillover effects are also considerable in terms
of both economic (GVA) and employment (FTE) returns.
Discussion and Conclusion
This paper provides evidence that an increase of productivity in some sectors positively affect the
regional economic growth. Moreover, the inter-regional effects increase by the distance from the
central and urban areas. The paper observes and compares the effects of exogenous shock (a 10%
productivity increase) in two selected sectors in three types of regions. There are selected to study
25
the effects of productivity change in knowledge-based services, on the one hand, and machine
manufacturing sector in three types of geographical settings, i.e., urban, rural, and peripheral areas.
The study has shown that regional productivity grows unevenly with respect to time, sector, and
geography. There is a tendency for R&D, the knowledge-based service sector, and the creative
economies in urban areas to show faster growth rates than the traditional sectors, such as agriculture
and manufacturing. It is obvious that the urban municipalities have an advantage in knowledge-
based services; on the other hand, due to relatively cheap labour, the rural municipalities have a
relative advantage in the machine industry. The purpose of the scenario analysis is to identify the
regional consequences of the modelling calculations and compare the inter-regional and inter-
sectoral spillovers of these two sectors in urban, rural, and peripheral municipalities.
Scenario experiment shows from a regional spillover effect point of view, the machine industry has
a deep backward linkage and has a greater impact on the other regions than knowledge-based
services. The other side of story is that the knowledge-based service sector is more concentrated in
the urban areas, as they have a labour force with relatively higher competence than the rural
regions. However, the regional spillover effects are not so large, as 97% of activities remain in the
urban municipalities. From the geographic perspective, the urban regions gain the most; therefore,
they have the highest economic growth.
Regarding sectoral spillovers, even though the urban regions create the most GVA and
employment, the municipalities on the outskirts have the highest multiplier. This manifests in the
dependence of the peripheral municipalities on the other regions. There are two aspects to consider
in this conclusion: 1. The machine industry has, in general, high intermediate consumption, i.e., raw
materials, energy, transport, services. This means that the inter-sectoral trade is also high, which
proves that any exogenous change in this sector will have impact on other sectors as well. 2. The
machine industry plants are mainly located in the peripheral areas in Denmark. As mentioned
previously, the peripheral areas are characterised by the scarce labour, skills and even services
(Naveed, et al., 2017), therefore, the industry has stronger inter-regional trade links with the areas
26
with bigger pool of labour and services, which in its term explains the higher backward linkages
and spillover effects of an exogenous change.
This conclusion could be considered in the regional policy perspective, in terms of promoting the
regional cohesion and balanced economic growth. The level and growth rates of regional
productivity, the regional economy and the explanation for regional inequality are always the top
issues in regional policies. The EU regional policy has mainly focused on business competitiveness,
regional economic growth, job creation, sustainable development, and the improvement of citizens’
quality of life. The Danish Government has recently stressed the education effort in training the
potential labour force; the Government has also put effort into the regional balance and has more
recently decided to move the nearly 4,000 state jobs (i.e., 4,000 working places) from the capital
region to the rural and peripheral municipalities. Previous research has shown that public
investment in infrastructure, the improvement of human capital, heavy inputs in R&D and
encouraging innovation in enterprises, along with other factors, will help in improving regional
productivity, enabling regions to maintain high economic growth. However, often policy initiatives
affect the economic activities in the urban areas (for example, cluster policies, smart specialisation
policies, etc), which benefit to the further economic growth of the urban areas, while ignore the
economic activities in the peripheral and rural regions, and furthermore, creating further imbalance
in regional economic growth. This study provides the evidence to consider different policy
approaches to maintain the balanced economic growth, both in urban and rural/peripheral areas in a
country.
27
References
Arbia, G., Battisti, M. & Vaio, G. D. 2010. Institutions and geography: Empirical test of spatial
growth models for European regions. Economic Modelling, 27, 1221.
Azaeri, M., Kim, H., Kim, J. Y. & Ryu, D. 2016. The effect of agglomeration on the productivity of
urban manufacturing sectors in a leading emerging economy. Economic System, 40, 422432.
Baier, S. L., Dwyer, G. P. & Tamura, R. 2006. How important are capital and total factor
productivity for economic growth? Economic Inquiry, 44 (1), 2349. DOI: 10.1093/ei/ebj003.
Beugelsdijk, S., Klasing, M. J. & Milionis, P. 2018. Regional economic development in Europe:
The role of total factor productivity. Regional Studies, 52 (4), 461476. DOI:
10.1080/00343404.2017.1334118.
Broersma, L. & Oosterhaven, J. 2009. Regional labour productivity in the Netherlands: Evidence of
agglomeration and congestion effects. Journal of Regional Science, 49 (3), 483511.
Bronzini, R. & Piselli, P. 2009. Determinants of long-run regional productivity with geographical
spillovers: The role of R&D, human capital, and public infrastructure. Regional Science and Urban
Economics, 39, 187199.
Brulhart, M. & Mathys, N. A. 2008. Sectoral agglomeration economies in a panel of European
regions. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 38, 348362.
Ciccone, A. 2002. Agglomeration effects in Europe. European Economic Review, 46, 213227.
Cohen, J. 2010. The broader effects of transportation infrastructure: Spatial econometrics and
productivity approaches. Transportation Research Part E, 46, 317326.
Dietzenbacher, E. 2002. Interregional multipliers: Looking backward, looking forward. Regional
Studies, 36 (2), 125136.
28
Hansen, I. W., Larsen, N., Andreasen, S. A. L., Larsen, M. B., Andreasen, S. A. L. & Neumann, C.
2012. Herfra min verden går. Landdistriktsredegørelse. Indenrigs og Sundhedsministeriet.
Ministeriet for Fødevarer, Landbrug og Fiskeri.
Krugman, P. 1991. Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy,
99(3), 483499. doi:10.1086/261763
Madsen, B and Jensen-Butler C. 2004. Theoretical and operational issues in sub-regional modelling,
illustrated through the development and application of the LINE model, Economic Modelling,
Volume 21, Issue 3, 471-508.
Madsen, B. and Jensen-Butler C. 2005. Spatial Accounting Methods and the Construction of Spatial
Accounting Matrices. Economic Systems Research, vol 17, 2005.
Madsen, B. and Zhang J. 2010. Towards a New Framework for Accounting and Modelling the
Regional Impacts of Tourism and Culture, Economic Systems Research, 2010, Vol. 22(4), 313340.
Myrdal, G. 1957. Economic theory and underdeveloped regions. London: University
Paperbacks/Methuen.
Naveed, A., Javakhishvili-Larsen, N. & Schmidt, T. D. 2017. Labour mobility and local
employment: Building a local employment base from labour mobility? Regional Studies, 51 (11),
16221634. DOI: 10.1080/00343404.2016.1223284.
OECD (2008): Economic Survey of Denmark 2008. OECD. Paris, France.
Schutz, M. H. (2017): Australia’s regional innovation systems: Inter-industry interaction in
innovative activities in three Australian territories. Economic System Research, 29 (3), 357384.
DOI: 10.1080/09535314.2017.1301886.
29
Appendices
Figure 1a. Municipality Types in Denmark
Source: CRT Database and own calculation
Copenhagen
Aalborg
Aarhus
Odense
Kolding
30
Figure 2a. Labour productivity trend between 2000 and 2016 by spatial typology
Source: CRT database and own calculation
700.000
800.000
900.000
1.000.000
1.100.000
1.200.000
1.300.000
1.400.000
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
Urban Rural Peripheral whole country
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
Regional economic development in Europe: the role of total factor productivity. Regional Studies. This paper documents the fact that the large and persistent differences in economic development across subnational regions in European Union countries can largely be attributed to differences in total factor productivity (TFP). Applying the technique of development accounting, the paper decomposes differences in output per worker across 257 European Union regions into a component due to the local availability of production factors and a component due to TFP. As the analysis reveals, TFP differences are large even within countries, and are strongly related to economic geography and historical development paths. This suggests limited interregional diffusion of technology and of efficient production practices.
Article
Full-text available
Regional specifics reveal in differences in economic activity and structure, the institutional, socio-economic and cultural environment and not least in the capability of regions to create new knowledge and to generate innovations. Focusing on the regional level, this paper for three Australian territories (New South Wales, Victoria and Queensland) explores patterns of innovative activities in their private business sectors. Furthermore, these patterns are compared to specifics of each region's economic structure. We make use of input–output-based innovation flow networks, which are directed and weighted instead of binary. The value added of the proposed analysis is that we are able to trace a variety of different aspects related to the structure of innovative activities for each territory. It gets evident that mostly innovative activities in each territory are not strong in ‘niche’ branches but in fields of intense economic activity, signalising the high path-dependency of innovative activities in a specific geographical environment.
Article
Full-text available
We identify four different approaches to estimate the regional and local impacts of tourism based on national accounts and economic modelling: The supply approach, the simple demand or commodity approach, the simple satellite account approach involving tourism satellite accounts based on social accounting, and the extended satellite account approach. Based upon a general interregional quantity model for tourism, empirical evidence on the impacts of tourism on 98 Danish municipalities is presented. We conclude that the four approaches give very different results, both in absolute and in relative terms.
Article
Labour mobility and local employment: building a local employment base from labour mobility? Regional Studies. Do labour inflows contribute to job opportunities for local residents? This question is analysed based on a three-step instrumental variables (IV) estimation procedure including two-way fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity by using unique panel data for the period 2006–11 in Denmark. The results show that labour inflows are crucial for employment opportunities in peripheral areas, but appear to have no effects closer to urban centres. Furthermore, the findings highlight the importance of inflows of specific skills and cross-sectoral dependencies in skill dynamics. This stresses the importance of considering policies promoting mobility to ensure the employment basis in peripheral areas.
Article
The importance of "broader" economic effects of transportation infrastructure has recently become apparent. "Broader" refers to impacts beyond the geographic boundaries within which the infrastructure investments are undertaken. Approaches to estimate "broader" impacts in production and cost function models are evaluated. A contribution of this paper is the empirical demonstration with a cross-section of US states' manufacturing data that ignoring broader effects of a spatially lagged dependent variable can lead to mis-statements of the overall productive impacts of public infrastructure. These inaccuracies can arise because of missing indirect effects and from specification bias that may directly impact the infrastructure elasticity.
Article
This article provides an empirical assessment of the growth experiences of European regions, during the period 1991–2004, by taking into account the spatial effects due to both institutions and geography. These effects have been modelled by means of specific controls and by using a non-conventional spatial weight matrix. Results favour a model dealing with substantive spatial externalities. Within this framework, the country-specific institutions are strongly and positively related to the regional productivity's growth rate. In addition, the geo-institutional proximity increases the spatial dependence of the regional output per worker and raises the speed of convergence. By contrast, the pure geographical metrics is underperforming, while underestimating the convergence dynamics.
Article
The paper estimates agglomeration effects for France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and the UK. Estimation takes into account endogeneity of the spatial distribution of employment and spatial fixed effects. Empirical results suggest that agglomeration effects in these European countries are only slightly smaller than agglomeration effects in the US: the estimated elasticity of (average) labor productivity with respect to employment density is 4.5 percent compared to 5 percent in the US.
Article
This paper develops a simple model that shows how a country can endogenously become differentiated into an industrialized "core" and an agricultural "periphery. " In order to realize scale economies while minimizing transport costs, manufacturing firms tend to locate in the region with larger demand, but the location of demand itself depends on the distribution of manufacturing. Emergence of a core-periphery pattern depends on transportation costs, economies of scale, and the share of manufacturing in national income. The study of economic geography-of the location of factors of production in space-occupies a relatively small part of standard economic analysis. International trade theory, in particular, conventionally treats nations as dimensionless points (and frequently assumes zero transportation costs between countries as well). Admittedly, models descended from von Thunen (1826) play an important role in urban studies, while Hotelling-type models of locational competition get a reasonable degree of attention in industrial organization. On the whole, however, it seems fair to say that the study of economic geography plays at best a marginal role in economic theory. On the face of it, this neglect is surprising. The facts of economic geography are surely among the most striking features of real-world economies, at least to laymen. For example, one of the most remarkable things about the United States is that in a generally sparsely populated country, much of whose land is fertile, the bulk of the population resides in a few clusters of metropolitan areas; a quarter of the inhabitants are crowded into a not especially inviting section of the East Coast. It has often been noted that nighttime satellite