ResearchPDF Available

An evaluation of both the 'rational' and the 'incremental' approaches to policy-making.

Authors:

Abstract

An evaluation of the rational and incrementalist approaches to policymaking, a piece I wrote in the course of my masters in public policy.
An evaluation of both the ‘rational’ and the ‘incremental’
approaches to policy-making.
Introduction:
Policy making can be understood as the process whereby government commit to taking action.
Through this lens we must further examine the approaches used in developing policy. There are a
number of theories related to how policies can be approached but through the course of this essay
we will seek to examine the ways in which the rational approach alongside the incremental approach
function in formulating and their use as approaches to policy development. We will explore what are
the constituent components of these approaches, how they function in the real world, alongside
criticisms of both approaches and cross-comparisons to effectively evaluate both approaches. When
evaluating policy making and the approaches related to the process of making policies it’s important
to take account of the policy cycle. This is a model through which we can evaluate approaches and
contextualise them within the policy cycle. The policy cycle we will use throughout this essay and
which serves as the effective frame in which we can view the approaches is that which is proposed
by (Anderson, 2015)
-
this includes analysing policy making through 5 stages, that of;
Agenda Setting - identifying the problem that the proposed policy(s) will seek to address,
Policy formulation - the approach to be taken to address the problem identified in the agenda
setting stage of the policy cycle
Decision-making - the process of deciding which approach to take or whether an approach
will be taken at all
Implementation - putting the policy into practice
Evaluation - evaluating the performance of the policy and establishing whether it was a
success or failure by examining its impact and outcomes ultimately
In line with (Wegrich and Jann, 2006) we will evaluate the approaches according to how they
function alongside how they work in relation to the policy cycle outlined above.
Rational Policy making.
The rational approach to policy making can be viewed as stated in (Cairney, 2012) as the
commonsense way in which a democracy should function. (Cairney, 2012) goes on to state that it
may be better viewed as an ideal in which one should aim for “a process in which elected
policymakers identify problems, clarify their aims and carefully weigh up solutions before making a
choice (based on perfect information and no resistance from unelected implementing officials)
”. This
however may be viewed as an ideal but it is commonly stated by critics that it is an ideal which
simply can’t be reached, due to the difficulty of having perfect information and in making decisions
where the factors that are considered can be ranked in a fair and impartial manner. It is because of
this that many scholars are increasingly seeing the rational approach to policy making requiring
significant interaction with the more incrementalist approach. By incorporating rational approaches
over a prolonged period of time that are responsive to changes and utilising the best available
evidence over a given time period. There are a number of ways in which this debate permeates
modern discussions on what constitutes modern political and policy approaches. however we can
evaluate this policy as described in (Cairney, 2012),namely to evaluate whether elected
policymakers can effectively seek to translate their values into policy supported by groups and
organisations that behave in a ‘logical, reasoned and neutral way’.
There are a number of primary assumptions that must be made to provide creedence to whether the
comprehensive rational approach to policy making can function effectively. These look at whether it
is possible for organisations to separate facts from theories and values in an artificial manner,
whether policymakers can rank their objectives in any meaningful way that supports policy making.
There are a host of reasons why this policy approach can face significant challenges, specifically if
we look at for example contrictatory objectives. This is where there is divergence between two
particular policies and how to address these contradictions alongside how one can go about
conducting a fair and effective ranking of the relevant factors to consider. We must also look at how
the rational approach fits in with the policy cycle outlined above and whether it is possible for the
rational approach to mirror this model in a linear fashion, namely is it possible for the rational
approach to follow a linear process. There is also the consideration that rational policy making
assumes that a policy maker can understand and interpret all possible outcomes which is not
possible, which many authors cite as down to a variety of factors, not least including cognitive
limitations. However if we look at bounded rationality, which as stated in (Cairney, 2012) which
doesn’t seek to simply maximise one’s utility but instead seeks to follow a course of action that is
‘good enough’. This approach within the rational approach would also explore using ‘rules of thumb’
to consider the relevant factors in making policy decisions. Within this context we can view rational
policy making as a process where we are seeking to make the best possible decision as far as
possible by using administrative science to support that decision, however this has its limitations as
we will explore below.
The Incremental Approach to Policy Making
In Charles Lindblom’s work (Lindblom, 1959),
he critiques the role of comprehensive rationality in
the policymaking process and instead speaks about the challenge this approach faces, specifically
the opportunity cost of comprehensive research, within this we can see an interesting understanding
of the limits of truly rational policy making. The limitations of using the best available evidence
requires research to develop the recommendations necessary to make rational policy making.
However when viewed through the lens of an opportunity cost where we instead look at how the
time and resources necessary for such research to be conducted could instead be used, alongside
the greater role of politics afforded to policymaking we can see many aspects contained within the
incrementalist approach which take a more nuanced view of the process of policymaking and the
relevant approaches in the process. (Cairney, 2012)
talks about policymakers considering not only
their own values but a more general view of other policymakers views on policy. this is to take
account of the balance of power that typically exists and the impact this balance of power can have
on policy making in general, in this regard we can view the incrementalist approach as more
cognisant of the political challenges inherent in policymaking.
Incrementalism according to (Lindblom, 1979) however does not simply mean change occuring in
small increments, it can be large increments that take place in the policy making process. however a
primary factor of incrementalism is whether the change is radical or non-radical, in that does the
policy change that occurs fit in line with more general trends or is it a more radical departure from
typical policy making. We can see between rational (in this case bounded rational) and
incrementalism there is a tendency for significant overlap in use of these approaches. for example
(Cairney, 2012) states that “Boundedly rational policymakers are much more likely to introduce
incremental policy changes - based on learning from past experience and addressing the
unintended consequences of previous decisions
it is here where we can see not only the overlap
but also how both approaches to policy making can intersect for a much more dynamic and adjusted
approach to making policy.
(Lindblom, 1959) views incrementalist approaches to policy making as a more efficient, sensible and
democratic approach. This is in contrast to the approaches to boundedly rational policy making as
put forward by (Simon, 1976) where we can view governments focusing on improving previous
policies as a more efficient way for policymaking to take place. alongside this we can view
policymaking that occurs through stages or over time as more sensible as there is a reduced
likelihood of making large lasting changes that were poorly thought out and not evaluated along a
process, and wide reaching changes can also be considered undemocratic according to (Cairney,
2012). this can come down to mandates and whether policymakers for example have a mandate to
implement such wide-reaching reforms. We can see this in (White and Lindblom, 1965) analysis
which looks at pluralistic democratic systems - we can see where there can be parties which engage
in “partisan mutual adjustment
a process that constitutes a large part of how an incrementalist
approach functions in a multi-party democracy as we can see policies over time being tweaked and
adjusted to more accurately achieve the intended outcome of a particular policy. (Hayes, 2017)
states that policies are made through a pluralistic process in which a number of participants can
instead focus on proposals that seek to incrementally alter the status quo, and that for the process of
incrementalism to yield defensible policy outcomes it must seek to satisfy three primary conditions;
that all or most social interests should be represented, political resources must be sufficiently
balanced so as one actor does not centrally control or dominate and that political parties must be
moderate and pragmatic. These three conditions fit in line with the process of incrementalism,
indeed being more democratic as the aim is to incorporate in the largest number of stakeholders,
however with regards to the point on pragmatism and moderate parties being involved being a
central critique that the policy of incrementalism fails to incorporate in idealism and the requirement
for radical change, specifically in response to major crises.
Compare & Contrast.
We can see from the readings provided above that there is significant overlap in terms of use of
these approaches in the process of policymaking. however when we begin to examine the relative
strengths and weaknesses of the approaches we can see that within either incrementalism or the
rational approach to policy making that there is a wide variation in terms of how these approaches
can be used. (Hayes, 2017) states that nonincremental policy changes occur during a period of
crises or during mass public arousal and that a departure from incrementalism to a more rational
approach to policy making would typically occur after a number of years of experience with policy
implementation and that rational approaches can occur in a punctuated equilibrium. We can see that
incremental approaches typically occur over a longer period of time and that the main point of
departure would typically occur in bursts of public pressure or engagement on a particular issue, for
example the issue of healthcare in the U.K with a gradual and incrementalist approach being
pursued until an institution such as the NHS is established, which would be a radical departure from
the norm only to lead to a punctuated equilibrium where incrementalist changes then re-occur on a
more radical approach such as the establishment of such an institution as the National Health
Service.
We can see that a radical departure from the norm, only to be followed by a more incrementalist
approach can be observed in (Cairney, 2012) where he states “if a previous policy commanded
widespread respect then policymakers will (and should) recognise the costs (analytical & political) of
a significant departure from it.
This fits in line with the inverse of this argument where external
pressures such as technological change, or if there is a sea change in attitudes on a particular issue
that there contains fertile ground in which a radical departure from incrementalist policy making can
occur. However (Lindblom, 1964) approaches this with the defence that incrementalism is not
necessarily about continuity and stability but moreover is the most logically coherent process to
make changes within a social structure is through a series of stages.
However when comparing the policy making approaches it is important to note the significant
overlap between both approaches. Most notably (Lindblom, 1979) assertion that opting for an
approach other than comprehensive rationality does not instead mean that one has to reject the
approach that favours better decision making in favour of a more gradual process but instead an
approach that can incorporate both the thoroughness of the comprehensive rationality approach to
policy making with the more tried and tested approach of the incrementalist approach which allows
for checks on the progress of policy initiatives to reach a particular desired policy outcome. This can
become an approach that allows policy to reach its more desired outcome that blends the strengths
of both approaches. This however faces the challenge of where power to make policy should be
concentrated or if it should be concentrated at all?
The rational approach, with its subsections can mean that power is centralised and that
organisations and policy makers seek to make use of ‘administrative science’ as stated by (Simon,
1976) and that organisations should seek to evaluate the possible outcomes and decide the best
possible policy solution with the available evidence. While this approach seeks to incorporate the
relevant evidence it requires that “an assumption that power is held centrally by policymakers and
carried out by neutral bureaucrats or other organisations
as stated within (Cairney, 2012). This
assumption that policy and policy making should be controlled centrally and in a hierarchical fashion,
can lead to the disenfranchisement from the policymaking process of lower ranking staff, clients and
patients. Such centralised control of policy making may hold important considerations for the
implementation of such rational policy making, with those trusted to implement a particular policy
being excluded from the making of the policy they are tasked with implementing. This contains within
it a contraction of sorts where the rational approach to policy making may take account of the best
available evidence while neglecting to include those who are responsible for its implementation
which may encounter the problem of being well developed in its scope and objectives but failing due
to poor implementation.
We can observe similar contradictions occuring in the incrementalist approach to policy making, with
the nature of partisanship which is a strong component of the incrementalist approach leading to
unbalanced power structures pursuing mutually negative policy approaches and with a situation of
duopolistic power brokers for example pursuing policies that don’t seek to improve the situation. We
can see this where there is consensus within a political structure on an approach that is not in the
best interests of addressing particular areas of concern. This can be seen in (Lindblom, 1977) where
he notes the particular failures of the incrementalist system with regards to business (particularly
large firms) in a market system, where they accrue large swathes of power and exert significant
influence to the determinant of small firms competing in a market economy and where policies are
created that reinforce this imbalance of power. While we can see that (Lindblom, 1979) identifies
that this is not a sufficient reason to reject the incremental policy approach, we can however see that
the contradiction in terms of the incrementalist approach assuming there will be policy corrections to
policies that are not adequately addressing particular problems that there is a flaw in this approach
due to the assumption of the political will to correct mistakes or flaws in the policy cycle.We can see
in the policy cycle that there are 3 primary options available, that of positive action, negative action
and neutral or no action, within the incremental approach we assume the approach will be to
gradually take positive action which supports addressing the particular policy problem, however we
can also see evidence of incrementally negative policy action being taken where the system doesn’t
correct itself and continues down a path of gradual worsening of the original problem. The work of
(Weiss and Woodhouse, 1992) seeks to address the concerns around the main critiques of
Lindblom’s original work by addressing some common misconceptions around the approach of
incrementalist policy making. They take the approach that in lieu of “ time, cognitive capacity,
resources, or theoretical understanding required for envisioning all conceivable options or for
analyzing all the consequences of those options that do get considered
.” that the incrementalist
approach to policy making afford the best possible solution to addressing these shortcomings.
We can also observe that a major deficiency in the work of Lindblom and the incrementalist
approach is that which is proposed within (Atkinson, 2011) that inherent within the incrementalist
approach is an assumption that a policy change is forthcoming and that there is a desire to move
away from the status quo, but this fails to take account of the “ persistent pull of the status quo
.” This
also flies in contradiction to a common critique that the incrementalist approach is one which is
inherently conservative, but that instead we can see that the will to do nothing, or in terms of the
policy cycle for no action to be taken is a consideration that bares heavily on the approaches of both
incrementalism and rational policy making.
Again inherent within both approaches and as mentioned by (Cairney, 2012) is the impact the
systems of governance has on the policy approach to be taken. (Cairney, 2012) specifically
mentions the divergence between the Westminster model of government with much more
centralised control and two parties which are conflicting in their aims, as opposed to the systems of
government in the US which contains within it more checks and balances, this can also be seen in
countries such as Japan where political inertia makes the arguments around policy making
approaches much more nuanced and conditional on government structure.
Conclusion
With regards to which approach can best aid the policymaking process, and through a
comprehensive analysis of the literature on the topic, I believe that it is clear that while both have
major concerns and considerations with regards to their applicability, it could be understood that
both rational and incrementalist approaches to policy making can have sufficient cross-over in terms
of their applicability. Indeed we can see from one of the main proponents of the incrementalist
approach Charles Lindblom that he believes there is scope to incorporate the incrementalist
approach with the rational approach. However throughout this essay I have sought to compare and
contrast both approaches with regards to their integrations with the policy cycle and how they can
best aid in the development of policy that is logically coherent and is focused on achieving the stated
objective and outcome desired at the identification stage of the policy cycle. It is due to this
alongside the considerations with bearing too heavily on one side I would understand that it is highly
contextual which policy approach to favour and to where possible incorporate the gradual, tried and
test aspects of incrementalist policy making with the incorporation of using the best available
evidence of the rational approach to policy making that is too be favoured.
References
Anderson, J. (2015). Public policymaking
. Stamford: Cengage Learning.
Atkinson, M. (2011). Lindblom’s lament: Incrementalism and the persistent pull of the status quo.
Policy and Society
, [online] 30(1), pp.9-18. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.polsoc.2010.12.002
[Accessed 10 Dec. 2017].
Cairney, P. (2012). Understanding public policy
. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp.95 - 111.
Hayes, M. (2017). Incrementalism and Public Policy-Making. Oxford Research Encyclopedia of
Politics
, [online] p.abstract. Available at:
http://politics.oxfordre.com/view/10.1093/acrefore/9780190228637.001.0001/acrefore-97801902286
37-e-133 [Accessed 10 Dec. 2017].
Lindblom, C. (1959). The science of "muddling through"
. New York, N.Y.: Irvington Publishers,
pp.79–88.
Lindblom, C. (1964). Contexts for Change and Strategy: A Reply. Public Administration Review
,
24(3), p.157.
Lindblom, C. (1977). Politics and markets
. New York, N.Y.: Basic Books.
Lindblom, C. (1979). Still muddling, not yet through
. [Place of publication not identified]: [publisher
not identified], pp.517–25.
Simon, H. (1976). Administrative behavior
. 3rd ed.
Wegrich, K. and Jann, W. (2006). Theories of the Policy Cycle. Handbook of Public Policy Analysis
,
pp.43-62.
Weiss, A. and Woodhouse, E. (1992). Reframing incrementalism: A constructive response to the
critics. Policy Sciences
, [online] 25(3), pp.255-273. Available at:
https://page-one.live.cf.public.springer.com/pdf/preview/10.1007/BF00138785.
White, O. and Lindblom, C. (1965). The Intelligence of Democracy: Decision Making through Mutual
Adjustment. The Western Political Quarterly
, 18(4), p.934.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
The scrutiny of governmental decision making and policy judgments is unceasing. A recent National Academy of Sciences report, for example, criticized the government for technological decisions that did not take cognizance of their impact on the deployment and utilization of scientists and engineers. The total issue is again joined in this symposium which presents some sharply contrasting viewpoints on administration, politics, and social change. Yehezkel Dror of the Hebrew University reexamines the decision making theory of Charles Lindblom's 1959 Review article, finds it wanting where rapid social change is occurring, and presents a new "normative" model for policy makers. Lindblom, now with the Department of State, defends his thesis in the context of American political change. Examining both the original Lindblom thesis and the Dror critique, Roger Jones of the Budget Bureau finds practicing administrators to be extremely skeptical of models and "other prescribed methodology as a road to administrative salvation." Placing the Lindblom essay in the perspective of public administration as a continuing study, Mickey McCleery of Antioch College finds in it an insightful contrast to the traditional theory of responsible bureaucracy. However, he joins with Jones in doubting the utility of models, and with Heydebrand in noting the philosophical difficulty of accepting what is as what ought to be. A University of Chicago sociologist, Wolf Heydebrand critiques the Dror model and the "essentially conservative framework" of Lindblom's argument.
Article
Charles Lindblom never abandoned the incremental version of decision-making he introduced in 1959, but as his work progressed he increasingly lamented the impaired quality of inquiry that characterizes public (and private) decision-making. Lindblom did not identify the precise origins of socially created incompetence, but he made it clear that incrementalism is not the source. This article suggests that two lines of intellectual inquiry—one based on institutionalism, one on behavioral economics—provide persuasive accounts of the reasons for Lindblom's lament. In each case the status quo is a central concept and its persistent hold over decision-makers is the reason for less than timely responses to policy deficiencies. Neither line of inquiry is inconsistent with incrementalism, but each improves on Lindblom's original formula.
Article
Short courses, books, and articles exhort administrators to make decisions more methodically, but there has been little analysis of the decision-making process now used by public administrators. The usual process is investigated here-and generally defended against proposals for more "scientific" methods. Decisions of individual administrators, of course, must be integrated with decisions of others to form the mosaic of public policy. This integration of individual decisions has become the major concern of organization theory, and the way individuals make decisions necessarily affects the way those decisions are best meshed with others'. In addition, decision-making method relates to allocation of decision-making responsibility-who should make what decision. More "scientific" decision-making also is discussed in this issue: "Tools for Decision-Making in Resources Planning."
Article
The concept of incrementalism has been widely cited over the past three decades, yet it has not served as the basis for a cumulatively developing line of empirical and theoretical inquiry. As a result, the highly promising incrementalist framework has contributed surprisingly little to improving our understanding of how decision-making processes can better adapt to humans' cognitive limitations. One indicator of the lack of progress is that policy scholars have never made a sustained attempt to explain how practitioners can become better incrementalists. To see whether the concept's original formulation may be obscuring the way to further progress, we summarize and appraise four enduring criticisms of incrementalism: its alleged lack of goal orientation, conservatism, limited range of applicability, and negative stance toward analysis. While questioning the validity of the critics' claims, we nevertheless propose a way to reframe the incrementalist endeavor, with the intention of stimulating both its critics and defenders to get on with the task of learning more about how individuals, organizations, and societies can proceed relatively intelligently despite the fact that humans rarely have a good understanding of complex social problems and policy options.
Understanding public policy
  • P Cairney
Cairney, P. (2012). Understanding public policy. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp.95 -111.
Incrementalism and Public Policy-Making
  • M Hayes
Hayes, M. (2017). Incrementalism and Public Policy-Making. Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics, [online] p.abstract. Available at:
Politics and markets
  • C Lindblom
Lindblom, C. (1977). Politics and markets. New York, N.Y.: Basic Books.