ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

Tipping points in social convention Once a population has converged on a consensus, how can a group with a minority viewpoint overturn it? Theoretical models have emphasized tipping points, whereby a sufficiently large minority can change the societal norm. Centola et al. devised a system to study this in controlled experiments. Groups of people who had achieved a consensus about the name of a person shown in a picture were individually exposed to a confederate who promoted a different name. The only incentive was to coordinate. When the number of confederates was roughly 25% of the group, the opinion of the majority could be tipped to that of the minority. Science , this issue p. 1116
Content may be subject to copyright.
SOCIAL SCIENCE
Experimental evidence for tipping
points in social convention
Damon Centola
1,2
*, Joshua Becker
1
, Devon Brackbill
1
, Andrea Baronchelli
3
Theoretical models of critical mass have shown how minority groups can initiate
social change dynamics in the emergence of new social conventions. Here, we study
an artificial system of social conventions in which human subjects interact to establish
a new coordination equilibrium. The findings provide direct empirical demonstration
of the existence of a tipping point in the dynamics of changing social conventions.
When minority groups reached the critical massthat is, the critical group size for
initiating social changethey were consistently able to overturn the established
behavior. The size of the required critical mass is expected to vary based on
theoretically identifiable features of a social setting. Our results show that the
theoretically predicted dynamics of critical mass do in fact emerge as expected
within an empirical system of social coordination.
Observational accounts of rapid changes in
social conventions have suggested that ap-
parently stable societal norms can be ef-
fectively overturned by the efforts of small
but committed minorities (13). From social
expectations about gender roles in the workplace
(4) to the popular acceptance of (or intolerance
toward) tobacco use and marijuana use (5), ac-
counts of changing social conventions have hy-
pothesized that minority groups can trigger a
shift in the conventions held by the majority of
the population (13,5,6). Although this hypoth-
esis presents a striking contrast to the expecta-
tions of classical equilibrium stability analysis
from economic theory (7,8), it can nevertheless
be well explained by the theory of critical mass
as posited by evolutionary game theory (911).
This theory argues that when a committed mi-
nority reaches a critical group sizecommonly
referred to as a critical mass”—the social system
crosses a tipping point. Once the tipping point is
reached, the actions of a minority group trigger a
cascade of behavior change that rapidly increases
the acceptance of a minority view (1214).
The simplest formulation of critical mass
theory maintains that small groups of regular
individualsthat is, with the same amount of
social power and resources as everyone else
can successfully initiate a change in social con-
ventions. According to this view, the power of
small groups comes not from their authority or
wealth but from their commitment to the cause
(14,15).
Thus far, evidence for critical mass dynamics
in changing social conventions has been limited
to formal theoretical models and observations
from qualitative studies. These studies have pro-
posed a wide range of possible thresholds for
the size of an effective critical mass, rangingfrom
10% of the population up to 40%. For instance,
theoretical simulations of linguistic conventions
have argued that a critical mass composed of 10%
of the population is sufficient to overturn an
established social equilibrium (14). By contrast,
qualitative studies of gender conventions in
corporate leadership roles have hypothesized
that tipping points are only likely to emerge
when a critical mass of 30% of the population
is reached (3,16). Related observational work
on gender conventions (17)hasbuiltonthisline
of research, speculating that effective critical
mass sizes are likely to be even higher, ap-
proaching 40% of the population. Despite the
broad practical (18,19) and scientific (1,12)
importance of understanding the dynamics of
critical mass in collective behavior, it has not
been possible to identify whether there are in
fact tipping points in empirical systems because
such a test requires the ability to independently
vary the size of minority groups within an evolv-
ing system of social coordination.
We addressed this problem by adopting an
experimental approach to studying tipping-
point dynamics within an artificially created
system of evolving social conventions. Following
the literature on social conventions (9,20,21),
we study a system of coordination in which a
minority group of actors attempt to disrupt an
established equilibrium behavior. In both our
theoretical framework and the empirical setting,
we adopt the canonical approach of using co-
ordination on a naming convention as a general
model for conventional behavior (2124). Our
experimental approach is designed to test a
broad range of theoretical predictions derived
from the existing literature on critical mass
dynamics in social conventions.
We first synthesized these diverse theoret-
ical and observational accounts of tipping-point
dynamics to derive theoretical predictions for
the size of an effective critical mass (25). Based on
earlier theoretical (9,26) and qualitative studies
of social convention (20,23), we propose a simple
model of strategic choice in which actors decide
which social conventions to follow by choosing
the option that yields the greatest expected in-
dividual reward given their history of social in-
teractions (9). In this individual learning model,
people coordinate with their peers so long as
they benefit individually from coordinating. The
RESEARCH
Centola et al., Science 360, 11161119 (2018) 8 June 2018 1of4
1
Annenberg School for Communication, University of
Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, USA.
2
School of Engineering,
University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, USA.
3
Department of Mathematics, City, University of London,
London, UK.
*Corresponding author. Email: dcentola@asc.upenn.edu
Fig. 1. Predicted tipping points in social stability. (A) Theoretical modeling of the proportion
of outcomes in which the alternative behavior is adopted by 100% of the population. In this
system, the number of agents (N) = 1000, the number of interactions (T) = 1000, the number of past
interactions used in agent decisions (M) = 12. (B) The size of the predicted critical mass point is
shown as a function of individualsaverage memory length, M,where(N= 1000, T= 1000).
The dashed lines indicate the range enclosed by our experimental trials, showing the largest
unsuccessful minority (21%) and the smallest successful minority (25%). Although the expected size
of the critical mass point increases with M, this relationship is concave, allowing the predicted
tipping point to remain well below 50% as Mgets large (>100). (Inset) Effect of increasing population size
on the precision of the size of the committed minority (C)prediction(M=12,T= 1000). For N<1000,
small variations in the predicted tipping point emerge due to stochastic variations in individual
behavior. Shaded region indicates Csizes where success was observed frequently but without
certainty. Above this region, for larger Csizes, the probability of success reaches 1; for Csizes below
this region, the likelihood of success goes to 0.
on June 21, 2018 http://science.sciencemag.org/Downloaded from
model predicts a sharp transition in the collec-
tive dynamics of social convention as the size of
the committed minority reaches a critical frac-
tion of the population (Fig. 1). When the size of
the committed minority is below this predicted
tipping point, the dominant social convention is
expected to remain stable, whereas above this
size it is expected to change (25).
Our theoretical predictions for the size of the
critical mass were determined by two parame-
ters: individual memory length (M) and popu-
lation size (N). Explorations of these parameters
(Fig. 1) show that the predicted size of the tipping
point changes with individualsexpected memory
length (M). When participants have shorter
memories (M< 5 interactions), the size of the
critical mass is smaller. Even under the assump-
tion that people have very long memories (M>
100 interactions), the predicted critical mass size
remains well below 50% of the population (25),
indicating that critical mass dynamics may be
possible even in systems with long histories.
Variations in population size were explored com-
putationally in the range 20 < N< 100,000 and
were not found to significantly affect the pre-
dicted criticalmass size (25). Figure 1 shows that
for populations in the range 20 < N< 1000,
stochastic fluctuations introduce a small uncer-
tainty into the estimate of the critical mass size.
However, for population sizes N> 1000, the
predicted tipping point for social change is con-
stant and independent of N[complete details
in (25)].
We recruited 194 subjects from the World
Wide Web and placed them into online com-
munities where they participated in a social
coordination process (27,28). Upon arrival to
the study, participants were randomly assigned
to participate in one of 10 independent online
groups, which varied in size from 20 to 30
people. In a given round of the study, the mem-
bers of each group were matched at random
into pairs to interact with one another. Within
each pair, both subjects simultaneously assigned
names to a pictured object (i.e., a face), attempt-
ing to coordinate in the real-time exchange of
linguistic alternatives (20,25). If the players
entered the same name (i.e., coordinated), they
were rewarded with a successful payment; if
they entered different names (i.e., failed to co-
ordinate), they were penalized. In each commu-
nity, individuals interacted with each other
over repeated rounds of randomly assigned pair-
ings, with the goal of coordinating with one
another (25). Participants were not incentiv-
ized to reach a globalconsensus but only to
coordinate in a pairwise manner with their part-
ner on each round. Participants were financially
rewarded for coordinating and financially pun-
ished each time they failed to coordinate with
each other (25). Once a convention was estab-
lished for the entire population, the incentives
strongly favored coordinating on the equilib-
rium behavior.
After each round, the participants could see
only the choices that they and their partner had
made, and their cumulative pay was updated
accordingly. They were then randomly assigned
to interact with a new member of their group,
and a new round would begin. These dynamics
reflect common types of online exchanges, in
which community members directly interact with
the other members of a large, often anonymous
populationusing, for instance, chat interfaces
or messaging technologiesleading them to
adopt linguistic and behavioral conventions that
allow them to effectively coordinate their actions
with other participantsexpectations (20,29 30).
Consistent with these types of settings, partic-
ipants in the study did not have any informa-
tion about the size of the population that was
attempting to coordinate nor about the number
ofindividualstowhomtheywereconnected
Centola et al., Science 360, 11161119 (2018) 8 June 2018 2of4
Fig. 2. T ime s eries showing adoption of the al ternative convent ion by noncom mitted
subjects (i.e., experimental subjects). Gray lines indicate the popularity of the established
convention; black lines show the adoption of the alternative convention. Success was
achieved when more than 50% of the noncommitted population adopted the new social
convention. Trials in the left column show failed mobilization, whereas trials in the right
column show successful mobilization. A transition in the collective dynamics happens when
Creaches ~25% of the population. Each round is measured as N/2 pairwise interactions,
such that each player has one interaction per round on average.
RESEARCH |REPORT
on June 21, 2018 http://science.sciencemag.org/Downloaded from
(9,20,23). In every group, this interaction pro-
cess quickly led to the establishment of a group-
wide social convention, in which all players in
the network consistently coordinated on the
same naming behavior (20,25). Once a con-
vention was established among all experimental
participants, we introduced a small number of
confederates (that is, a committed minority)
into each group, who attempted to overturn
the established convention by advancing a novel
alternative (25).
Trials varied according to the size of the com-
mitted minority (C) that attempted to overturn
the established convention. In total, we studied
the dynamics of critical mass in 10 independent
groups, each with a committed minority of a
fixed size. Across all 10 groups, the sizes of the
committed minorities were in the range (15% <
C< 35%).
Figures 2 and 3 report tipping-point dynamics
in the collective process of overturning an
established equilibrium. Consistent with the
expectations of our theoretical model (using
empirically parameterized values of Nand M),
when the size of the committed minority reached
~25% of the population, a tipping point was
triggered, and the minority group succeeded in
changing the established social convention.
Five trials were conducted. Each trial was
composed of two communitiesone with the
committed minority below the expected critical
size (C< 25%) and one with it equal to or above
(C25%). In every trial, the community with C<
25% had only small numbers of converts to the
minority view. Over the course of these trials,
each of these converts eventually reverted to the
dominant norm. Continuous interactions led to
occasional switching by subjects throughout the
study. However, over all the trials, in the condi-
tion where the minority group was smaller than
25% of the population, on average only 6% of th e
noncommitted population adopted the alternative
behavior by the final round of the study.
For each of these unsuccessful trials, we
conducted a corresponding trial using another
population of the same size but with a larger
committed minority (25% C31%). In all
these groups, the alternative norm reached
the majority of the population within the ex-
perimental window of observation (Figs. 2
and 3). Over all trials, populations with C25%
were significantly more likely to overturn the
dominant convention than populations with
acommittedminoritybelow25%(P=.01,
Wilcoxon rank sum). We found that in one case
(Trial 1) this transition from failure to success
was the result of increasing the size of the com-
mitted minority by only one person.
Figure 3 shows a summary of final adoption
levels across all trials, along with expectations
from our empirically parameterized theoretical
model, with 95% confidence intervals. Popula-
tions with committed minorities ranging from
25% C27% achieved uptake levels between
72 and 100% within the empirical observation
window. At C= 31%, the committed minority
achieved consensus within the window of em-
pirical observation. Figure 3 compares these
observations to numerical simulations of the
theoretical model using population sizes and ob-
servation windows (Trounds of interaction) com-
parable to the experimental study (N= 24, T=
100, M= 12). Memory length for these simulations
was calibrated using subjectsempirical memory
lengths in this study based on their observed
behavior over all 10 groups. A memory length
in the range 9 M13 provides a good ap-
proximation of subjectsobserved behavior, cor-
rectly predicting 80% of subjectschoices across
all trials (25). The theoretically predicted critical
mass size from this model fit the experimental
findings well (Fig 3). Numerical analyses indicate
that with larger population sizes, the critical mass
point becomes more exact (See Figs. 1 and 3),
approaching 24.3% of the population.
Our experimental results do not show agree-
ment with theoretical predictions from models
of social convention that predict low critical
mass thresholds, at 10% of the population. How-
ever, our findings show good agreement with
qualitative studies of gender conventions within
organizational settings (3), which hypothesized
that a critical mass of ~30% could be sufficient to
overturn established norms (16). Our results may
suggest that in organizational contextswhere
population boundaries are relatively well defined
and there are clear expectations and rewards for
social coordination among peersthe process of
normative changes in social conventions may be
well described by the dynamics of critical mass.
The design choices that aided our control of
the study also put constraints on the behaviors
that we could test. Our experimental design pro-
vided subjects with social and financial incen-
tives that strongly favored coordinating on an
established social convention (25). However, in
the real world, individualsemotional and psy-
chological commitments to established behav-
iors can create additional resistance to behavior
change (31). To further explore these expecta-
tions, supplementary analyses of our theoretical
model (fig. S7) (25) extend our basic predictions
to consider how the critical mass size may differ
under conditions of greater social entrenchment.
When actors are more conservativeexhibiting an
explicit bias in favor of the established convention
(based on a skewed best-response calculation
favoring the equilibrium behavior)tipping-point
dynamics were still predicted to be achievable by
committed minorities with only marginally larger
group sizes.
In delimiting the scope of our findings, we
emphasize that the critical mass value of 25%
is not expected to be a universal value for chang-
ing social conventions. Our results demonstrate
that within an endogenous system of social co-
ordination, tipping-point dynamics emerged con-
sistent with theoretical expectations. Further
work is required to determine the applicabil-
ity of our findings to specific social settings. In
particular, alternative empi rical parameter-
izations of our model can result in alternative
predictions for the expected size of the critical
mass. We expect that the findings from our
study can be considerably expanded by future
empirical work studying the dynamics of tipping
points within other empirical systems of so-
cial convention.
For instance, an important setting in which
these results might be usefully applied concerns
the growing ability of organizations and govern-
ments to use confederate actors within online
spaces to influence conventional behaviors and
beliefs. Recent work on the 50 Cent Party in
China (32,33) has argued that the Chinese
government has incentivized small groups of
motivated individuals to anonymously infiltrate
social media communities such as Weibo with
the intention of subtly shifting the tone of the
collective dialogue to focus on topics that cel-
ebrate national pride and distract from collec-
tive grievances (32). We anticipate that social
media spaces of this kind will be an increasingly
important setting for extending the findings of
our study to understand the role of committed
minorities in shifting social conventions. Sim-
ilarly, the results from our study may also be
usefully applied to the dynamics of critical mass
in other online settings, such as changing social
expectations regarding (i) the standards of ci-
vility on Facebook and other online discussion
forums (19,34), (ii) the acceptability of bullying
behavior in adolescent chat groups (35), and
Centola et al., Science 360, 11161119 (2018) 8 June 2018 3of4
Fig. 3. Final success levels from
all trials (gray points indicate trials
with C< 25%; black points indicate
trials with C25%. Also shown
is the theoretically predicted critical
mass point (solid line) with 95%
confidence intervals (N=24,T= 45,
M=12; gray area indicates 95% con-
fidence intervals from 1000 replications).
The dotted line indicates C=25%.
The theoretical model of critical mass
provides a good approximation of the
empirical findings. For short time periods
(T< 100 interactions), the critical mass
prediction is not exact (ranging from 20%
<C< 30% of the population); however,
over longer time periods (T> 1000) the transition dynamics become more precise (solid line, 25).
RESEARCH |REPORT
on June 21, 2018 http://science.sciencemag.org/Downloaded from
(iii) the appropriate kinds of content to share
with strangers over social media (36), all of
which have been suggested to exhibit suscep-
tibility to shifts in conventional behavior as a
result of the activity of a small fraction of the
population (19,34,36).
REFERENCES AND NOTES
1. T. Kuran, Am. J. Sociol. 100, 15281551 (1995).
2. K. D. Opp, C. Gern, Am. Sociol. Rev. 58, 659680 (1993).
3. R. M. Kante r, Am.J.Sociol.82,965990 (1977).
4. D. Dahlerup, L. Freidenvall, Int. Fem. J. Polit. 7,2648
(2005).
5. S. Bikhchandani, D. Hirshleifer, I. Welch, J. Polit. Econ. 100,
9921026 (1992).
6. T. Kuran , Private Truths, Public Lies: The Social
Consequences of Preference Falsification (Harvard Univ.
Press, 1997).
7. J. C. Harsanyi, R. Selten, A General Theory of Equilibrium
Selection in Games (MIT Press, Cambridge, 1988).
8. J. F. Nash, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 36,4849 (1950).
9. H. P. Young, Econometrica J. Econom. Soc. 61,5784
(1993).
10. M. Kandori, G. J. Mailath, R. Rob, Econometrica J. Econom. Soc.
61,2956 (1993).
11. G. Ellison, Econometrica J. Econom. Soc. 61,10471071
(1993).
12. T. Schelling, Micromotives and Macrobehavior (Norton,
New York, 1978).
13. M. Granovetter, Am. J. Sociol. 83, 14201443 (1978).
14. J. Xie et al., Phys. Rev. E Stat. Nonlin. Soft Matter Phys. 84,
011130 (2011).
15. D. M. Centola, Ration. Soc. 25,340 (2013).
16. D. Dahlerup, Scand. Polit. Stud. 11, 275298 (1988).
17. S. Grey, Polit. Gend. 2, 492502 (2006).
18. G. Marwell, P. Oliver, The Critical Mass in Collective Action
(Cambridge Univ. Press, 1993).
19. K. Nyborg et al., Science 354,4243 (2016).
20. D. Centola, A. Baronchelli, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 112,
19891994 (2015).
21. D. Lewis, Convention: A Philosophical Study (Harvard Univ.
Press, Cambridge, 1969).
22. C. Castellano, S. Fortunato, V. Loreto, Rev. Mod. Phys. 81, 591
(2009).
23. S. Garrod, G. Doherty, Cognition 53, 181215 (1994).
24. L. Wittgenstein, Philosophical Investigations (John Wiley & Sons,
2009).
25. Materials and methods are available as supplementary
materials.
26. A. Baronchelli, M. Felici, V. Loreto, E. Caglioti, L. Steels, J. Stat.
Mech. Theory Exp. 2006, P06014 (2006).
27. D. Centola, Science 334, 12691272 (2011).
28. D. Centola, Science 329, 11941197 (2010).
29. L. Backstrom, D. Huttenlocher, J. Kleinberg, X. Lan, Group
formation in large social networks: membership, growth, and
evolution. Proc. 12th ACM SIGKDD Int. Conf. Knowl. Discov.
Data Min., 4454 (2006).
30.F.Kooti,H.Yang,M.Cha,P.K.Gummadi,W.A.Mason,The
Emergence of Conventions in Online Social Networks. Proc.
Sixth Int. AAAI Conf. Weblogs Soc. Media ICWSM 2012
(2012).
31. C. Tilly, S. Tarrow, Contentious Politics (Oxford Univ. Press,
New York, ed. 2, 2015).
32. G. King, J. Pan, M. E. Roberts, Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 111, 484501
(2017).
33.G.King,J.Pan,M.E.Roberts,Science 345, 1251722
(2014).
34. A. Antoci, A. Delfino, F. Paglieri, F. Panebianco, F. Sabatini,
PLOS ONE 11, e0164286 (2016).
35. E. L. Paluck, H. Shepherd, P. M. Aronow, Proc. Natl. Acad.
Sci. U.S.A. 113, 566571 (2016).
36. C. Shih, The Facebook Era: Tapping Online Social Networks to
Market, Sell, and Innovate (Pearson Education, 2010).
ACKNO WLED GME NTS
We gratefully acknowledge research assistance from S. Kim
and N. Herbert, helpful suggestions from P. S tarr and
A. van de Rijt, and programming assistance from A. Wagner
and R. Overbey. This research was approved by the Institutional
Review Board at the University of Pennsylvania, where the
study was conducted, and it included informed consent by all
participants in the study. Funding: The authors received
no external funding in support of this research. Author
contributions: D.C. and A.B. designe d the study. J.B. and
D.B. collected the data. D.C., J.B., D.B., and A.B. analyzed
the data. D.C. wrote the manuscript. All authors commented
on and approved the final manuscript. Competing interests:
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
Data and materials availability: The datasets are available
upon request and upo n publication wil l be publicly availa ble
for download from the university Web site: http://ndg.asc.upenn.
edu/exp eriment s/crea ting-c ritical -mass. Upon publication,
the data will be available at Dataverse, doi:10.7910/DVN/11HUAG.
The code in R is available on GitHub at https://github.com/
NetworkDynamicsGroup/BestResponseNameGame.
SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIALS
www.sciencemag.org/content/360/6393/1116/suppl/DC1
Materials and Methods
Supplementary Text
Figs. S1 to S7
References (37)
3 January 2018; accepted 20 April 2018
10.1126/science.aas8827
Centola et al., Science 360, 11161119 (2018) 8 June 2018 4of4
RESEARCH |REPORT
on June 21, 2018 http://science.sciencemag.org/Downloaded from
Experimental evidence for tipping points in social convention
Damon Centola, Joshua Becker, Devon Brackbill and Andrea Baronchelli
DOI: 10.1126/science.aas8827
(6393), 1116-1119.360Science
, this issue p. 1116Science
opinion of the majority could be tipped to that of the minority.
name. The only incentive was to coordinate. When the number of confederates was roughly 25% of the group, the
about the name of a person shown in a picture were individually exposed to a confederate who promoted a different
devised a system to study this in controlled experiments. Groups of people who had achieved a consensuset al.Centola
Theoretical models have emphasized tipping points, whereby a sufficiently large minority can change the societal norm.
Once a population has converged on a consensus, how can a group with a minority viewpoint overturn it?
Tipping points in social convention
ARTICLE TOOLS http://science.sciencemag.org/content/360/6393/1116
MATERIALS
SUPPLEMENTARY http://science.sciencemag.org/content/suppl/2018/06/06/360.6393.1116.DC1
REFERENCES http://science.sciencemag.org/content/360/6393/1116#BIBL
This article cites 25 articles, 7 of which you can access for free
PERMISSIONS http://www.sciencemag.org/help/reprints-and-permissions
Terms of ServiceUse of this article is subject to the
is a registered trademark of AAAS.Science
licensee American Association for the Advancement of Science. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. The title
Science, 1200 New York Avenue NW, Washington, DC 20005. 2017 © The Authors, some rights reserved; exclusive
(print ISSN 0036-8075; online ISSN 1095-9203) is published by the American Association for the Advancement ofScience
on June 21, 2018 http://science.sciencemag.org/Downloaded from
... Baronchelli's study with the NG model has demonstrated that when allies constitute approximately 25 percent of the population, the opinions of the majority may converge toward those of the minority. 29 He also found, through the evolution of the NG model in different community sizes and real-world social data, that higher-order interactions can lead to a critical threshold, enabling minority groups to overturn established norms, which contrasts with previous patterns. 30 The study of the NG is not limited to individual influence 31 but also involves external environmental feedback 32 and network structures such as static, 33,34 higher-order, 30 dynamic, 35 and empirically complex networks. ...
Article
Full-text available
The phenomenon where a committed minority overturns established social norms, frequently witnessed in revolutions and elections, has drawn extensive attention as it powerfully showcases the profound influence of strong personal convictions. In order to unravel the underlying mechanisms of the crucial role of public opinion within the dynamic process where a committed minority can leverage negative public opinion to challenge the status and even overturn established norms when a critical threshold is reached, we investigated the effects of negative public opinion by integrating it into the well-established traditional naming game model. It was found that there exists an optimal range of negative public opinion influence, which facilitates the minority’s ability to gain power and achieve social consensus. Notably, our results show that a smaller critical mass of committed individuals could trigger consensus behavior under this mechanism. The introduction of negative public influence into opinion propagation has yielded intriguing results, offering a new perspective on expanding consensus formation in opinion dynamics, particularly in diverse environments.
... Only two decades after the development of the SIR model in 1927 [53], mathematicians realized the potential for the mathematics of epidemics to describe not only the transmission of diseases, but also the spread of information [62, 23] and more recently, misinformation [67,29,31,30]. Since its inception, research in this arena has focused on the development and empirical testing [79,80,13,11,10] of modifications to the SIR model [69,18,24] which apply to the spread of information and rumors on homogeneous [61, 62], heterogeneous [79, 5, 9, 74], and community-structured [80, 19, 51, 78] populations. Despite these changes, these models all hold at their core the key assumption of "particle-like" information spread [61]. ...
Preprint
Many of today's most pressing issues require a more robust understanding of how information spreads in populations. Current models of information spread can be thought of as falling into one of two varieties: epidemiologically-inspired rumor spreading models, which do not account for the noisy nature of communication, or information theory-inspired communication models, which do not account for spreading dynamics in populations. The viral proliferation of misinformation and harmful messages seen both online and offline, however, suggests the need for a model that accounts for both noise in the communication process, as well as disease-like spreading dynamics. In this work, we leverage communication theory to meaningfully synthesize models of rumor spreading with models of noisy communication to develop a model for the noisy spread of structurally encoded messages. Furthermore, we use this model to develop a framework that allows us to consider not only the dynamics of messages, but the amount of information in the average message received by members of the population at any point in time. We find that spreading models and noisy communication models constitute the upper and lower bounds for the amount of information received, while our model fills the space in between. We conclude by considering our model and findings with respect to both modern communication theory and the current information landscape to glean important insights for the development of communication-based interventions to fight rising threats to democracy, public health, and social justice.
... In this work, we lift the assumption of requiring a single actor (such as the platform) to act as an adversary to induce polarization or disagreement and consider the case of several decentralized actors. It is known that empirically, a very small percentage (25%) of the users in a network need to disagree to sway consensus (Centola et al., 2018). Moreover, real-world social networks involve multiple malicious actors, who use different levels of manipulation and hate speech based on their individual goals (Bjork-James and Donovan, 2024). ...
Preprint
Full-text available
Opinion dynamics model how the publicly expressed opinions of users in a social network coevolve according to their neighbors as well as their own intrinsic opinion. Motivated by the real-world manipulation of social networks during the 2016 US elections and the 2019 Hong Kong protests, a growing body of work models the effects of a strategic actor who interferes with the network to induce disagreement or polarization. We lift the assumption of a single strategic actor by introducing a model in which any subset of network users can manipulate network outcomes. They do so by acting according to a fictitious intrinsic opinion. Strategic actors can have conflicting goals, and push competing narratives. We characterize the Nash Equilibrium of the resulting meta-game played by the strategic actors. Experiments on real-world social network datasets from Twitter, Reddit, and Political Blogs show that strategic agents can significantly increase polarization and disagreement, as well as increase the "cost" of the equilibrium. To this end, we give worst-case upper bounds on the Price of Misreporting (analogous to the Price of Anarchy). Finally, we give efficient learning algorithms for the platform to (i) detect whether strategic manipulation has occurred, and (ii) learn who the strategic actors are. Our algorithms are accurate on the same real-world datasets, suggesting how platforms can take steps to mitigate the effects of strategic behavior.
... Another way to use behavioural interventions is to support the communication of traditional policies that may be already in place, with the objective of making them more transparent and acceptable (Box 6). While behavioural interventions target individuals, changes in individual behaviour can trigger a cascade of effects, leading to more systemic changes (Centola, 2010;Centola et al., 2018). ...
Technical Report
Full-text available
This report examines the transformative role of behavioural insights (BI) in EU policymaking, advocating for integrating BI early in the policy cycle to enhance policy effectiveness. It challenges the misconception that BI is limited to designing behavioural interventions with marginal impacts and demonstrates its potential to guide the development of both traditional policy instruments and behavioural interventions. The report underscores the importance of BI in identifying synergies and conflicts between policies across different areas, thereby improving policy coherence. It advocates for the use of BI in combination with systems analysis to achieve systemic changes. The policy relevance of this work lies in its timely contribution to evidence-based approaches, particularly in areas where the human dimension is key to policy success.
Chapter
The Cambridge Handbook of Moral Psychology is an essential guide to the study of moral cognition and behavior. Originating as a philosophical exploration of values and virtues, moral psychology has evolved into a robust empirical science intersecting psychology, philosophy, anthropology, sociology, and neuroscience. Contributors to this interdisciplinary handbook explore a diverse set of topics, including moral judgment and decision making, altruism and empathy, and blame and punishment. Tailored for graduate students and researchers across psychology, philosophy, anthropology, neuroscience, political science, and economics, it offers a comprehensive survey of the latest research in moral psychology, illuminating both foundational concepts and cutting-edge developments.
Article
Full-text available
Extant theory proposes that stakeholders reward organizations that behave ethically and punish those that don’t. Taken at face value, this dynamic implies that organizations prioritizing ethical concerns should have competitive advantages augmenting performance. Unfortunately, hoped-for advantages often fail to materialize. Examining this difficult reality, we explore how pluralistic ethical standards manifest in ways that are not obvious because they are often locally and temporally attached to stakeholder groups. Further, we adopt a resource-based view of organizations and draw on literature related to dynamic capabilities and stakeholder theories to argue that ethics-related organization-level behavior can only lead to sustainable competitive advantages when there is continued competence across present and future-oriented systems. As a whole, our work provides a useful theoretical framework for addressing the pragmatic difficulties associated with enacting universal ethical principles in unique situations.
Article
Full-text available
Outcomes in the cultural arena are due to many factors but are there general rules that can suggest what makes some cultural traits successful and others not? Research in cultural evolution theory distinguishes factors related to social influence (such as copying from the majority, or from certain individuals) from factors related to individual, nonsocially influenced, propensities such as evolved cognitive predispositions, or physical, biological, and environmental constraints. Here, we show, using analytical and individual-based models, that individual preferences, even when weak, determine the equilibrium point of cultural dynamics when acting together with nondirectional social influence in three out of four cases we study. The results have implications regarding the importance of keeping into account individual-level, nonsocial, factors, when studying cultural evolution, as well as regarding the interpretation of cross-cultural regularities, that must be expected, but can be product of weak directional forces, intensified by social influence.
Article
A significant amount of punishment that happens in society is state punishment, that is, third‐party punishment carried out by an organized political community in response to a rule violation. We argue that a complete psychology of punishment must consider state punishment as a distinct form. State punishment is a unique type of punishment because it is a special case of third‐party punishment, pre‐specified to occur after the violation of official rules and policies, carried out by people acting on behalf of a nation or government. State punishment, especially as compared to interpersonal punishment, is regarded as a legitimate form of violence, which communicates not just disapproval but information about procedures and power. Moreover, state punishment is made possible by state rules, which, unlike norms, are formalized, can be fully articulated and are perfectly transmissible across generations. We end the paper with implications for the psychology of punishment more broadly and future directions for better understanding the unique psychology of state punishment.
Article
Dr Hannah Godrey explores how workplace culture and team dynamics impact veterinary teams, sharing practical steps for nurses to foster a positive, supportive environment that enhances wellbeing, teamwork and patient care.
Chapter
This chapter evaluates the validity of social psychology, sociology and behavioural psychology theories in relation to media studies and climate change discourse; it identifies the mechanisms that can assist the media in ensuring public attention to climate change and free-riding mitigation. It provides pathways for the creation of the social proof narrative as well as proposing action points, behavioural change directions and building consistent interest to climate events and people’s role in addressing them.
Article
Full-text available
Climate change, biodiversity loss, antibiotic resistance, and other global challenges pose major collective action problems: A group benefits from a certain action, but no individual has sufficient incentive to act alone. Formal institutions, e.g., laws and treaties, have helped address issues like ozone depletion, lead pollution, and acid rain. However, formal institutions are not always able to enforce collectively desirable outcomes. In such cases, informal institutions, such as social norms, can be important. If conditions are right, policy can support social norm changes, helping address even global problems. To judge when this is realistic, and what role policy can play, we discuss three crucial questions: Is a tipping point likely to exist, such that vicious cycles of socially damaging behavior can potentially be turned into virtuous ones? Can policy create tipping points where none exist? Can policy push the system past the tipping point?
Article
Full-text available
Evidence is growing that forms of incivility–e.g. aggressive and disrespectful behaviors, harassment, hate speech and outrageous claims–are spreading in the population of social networking sites’ (SNS) users. Online social networks such as Facebook allow users to regularly interact with known and unknown others, who can behave either politely or rudely. This leads individuals not only to learn and adopt successful strategies for using the site, but also to condition their own behavior on that of others. Using a mean field approach, we define anevolutionary game framework to analyse the dynamics of civil and uncivil ways of interaction in online social networks and their consequences for collective welfare. Agents can choose to interact with others–politely or rudely–in SNS, or to opt out from online social networks to protect themselves from incivility. We find that, when the initial share of the population of polite users reaches a critical level, civility becomes generalized if its payoff increases more than that of incivility with the spreading of politeness in online interactions. Otherwise, the spreading of self-protective behaviors to cope with online incivility can lead the economyto non-socially optimal stationary states. JEL Codes: C61, C73, D85, O33, Z13. PsycINFO Codes: 2240, 2750.
Book
The problem of collective action is that each member of a group wants other members to make necessary sacrifices while he or she 'free rides', reaping the benefits of collective action without doing the work. Inevitably the end result is that no one does the work and the common interest is not realized. This book analyses the social pressure whereby groups solve the problem of collective action. The authors show that the problem of collective action requires a model of group process and cannot be deduced from simple models of individual behaviour. They employ formal mathematical models to emphasize the role of small subgroups of especially motivated individuals who form the 'critical mass' that sets collective action in motion. The book will be read with special interest by sociologists, social psychologists, economists and political scientists. It will also be of concern to those in industrial relations and communications research working on issues in collective action and rational choice.
Article
The Chinese government has long been suspected of hiring as many as 2 million people to surreptitiously insert huge numbers of pseudonymous and other deceptive writings into the stream of real social media posts, as if they were the genuine opinions of ordinary people. Many academics, and most journalists and activists, claim that these so-called 50c party posts vociferously argue for the government’s side in political and policy debates. As we show, this is also true of most posts openly accused on social media of being 50c. Yet almost no systematic empirical evidence exists for this claim or, more importantly, for the Chinese regime’s strategic objective in pursuing this activity. In the first large-scale empirical analysis of this operation, we show how to identify the secretive authors of these posts, the posts written by them, and their content. We estimate that the government fabricates and posts about 448 million social media comments a year. In contrast to prior claims, we show that the Chinese regime’s strategy is to avoid arguing with skeptics of the party and the government, and to not even discuss controversial issues. We show that the goal of this massive secretive operation is instead to distract the public and change the subject, as most of these posts involve cheerleading for China, the revolutionary history of the Communist Party, or other symbols of the regime. We discuss how these results fit with what is known about the Chinese censorship program and suggest how they may change our broader theoretical understanding of “common knowledge” and information control in authoritarian regimes.
Article
Significance Despite a surge in policy and research attention to conflict and bullying among adolescents, there is little evidence to suggest that current interventions reduce school conflict. Using a large-scale field experiment, we show that it is possible to reduce conflict with a student-driven intervention. By encouraging a small set of students to take a public stance against typical forms of conflict at their school, our intervention reduced overall levels of conflict by an estimated 30%. Network analyses reveal that certain kinds of students (called “social referents”) have an outsized influence over social norms and behavior at the school. The study demonstrates the power of peer influence for changing climates of conflict, and suggests which students to involve in those efforts.
Article
Formal theories of collective action face the problem that in large groups a single actor makes such a small impact on the collective good that cooperation is irrational. Critical mass theorists argue that this 'large group problem' can be solved by an initial critical mass of contributors, whose efforts can produce a 'bandwagon' effect, making cooperation rational for the remaining members of the population. However, critical mass theory requires an explanation of how a critical mass can form in the first place. I present a model of collective action that solves this problem by showing how aspects of social structure - including network topology, homophily, and local coalition formation - can allow rational actors to endogenously form a critical mass. The findings indicate that as the mobilization effort becomes more 'complex', clustered networks and homophily become increasingly important for critical mass collective action.
Article
Significance Social conventions shape every aspect of our lives, from how we greet each other to the languages we speak. Yet their origins have been a topic of theoretical speculation since the time of Aristotle. Most approaches assume that institutions are necessary to organize large populations, but the simplest explanation is that universally accepted conventions are the unintended consequence of individuals’ efforts to coordinate locally with one another. Although this hypothesis is compelling, it lacks conclusive empirical support. Here, we present results from controlled experiments demonstrating that changes in network connectivity can cause global social conventions to spontaneously emerge from local interactions, even though people have no knowledge about the population, or that they are coordinating at a global scale.
Article
We focus on the roles of groups and personal networks in demonstrations in the repressive setting of East Germany between May and October 1989. We first propose a micro-model specifying a broad set of individual incentives to participate; then we contend that political events and changes in the social context together with existing coordinating mechanisms produced the large-scale demonstrations in 1989. Most of our hypotheses are tested using a representative survey of Leipzig's population in the fall of 1990 that focuses on the 1989 protests. Among the incentives, only political discontent, weighted by perceived personal political influence, has a major impact on participation in the demonstrations. The expectation of repression was irrelevant. Opposition groups were unable to shape the incentives of the population, and incentives for their members to participate were weak, whereas negative incentives prevailed for members of the Socialist Party. Incentives to participate were concentrated in personal networks of friends. Thus, personal networks were the most important contexts for mobilizing citizens. A "spontaneous coordination model" explains how discontented citizens met at particular times and places, and why few incentives were necessary to prompt participation in the demonstrations.