Content uploaded by Michael Manville
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Michael Manville on Apr 09, 2018
Content may be subject to copyright.
104 Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018
Not If, but When: Autonomous Driving and the Future of Transit
Transit in the 2000s:
Where Does It Stand and
Where Is It Headed?
Michael Manville, Brian D. Taylor, and Evelyn Blumenberg
UCLA Luskin School of Public Affairs
Abstract
U.S. public transit has experienced something of a renaissance in the 2000s, with per capita service
levels increasing nationwide and public investment growing even faster—particularly expenditures
on rail transit. Despite this expansion, overall transit patronage has been relatively flat, and has
declined significantly since 2014. What is behind these trends, and what do they portend for the
future of transit? In this paper we consider three challenges shaping transit today and in the years
ahead: (1) the asymmetry of transit supply and use make it especially vulnerable to changes and
disruptions; (2) many of the factors that determine transit ridership, such as levels of private vehicle
ownership and use, are largely beyond the control of transit agencies; and (3) there remains no
consensus about what purpose transit should serve—politically the industry thrives on the idea
that it will reduce congestion or clean the air, while in practice it primarily moves poor people, a
very different and sometimes conflicting role. How successfully transit systems manage each of
these challenges will shape their future roles and significance.
Overview
Public support for transit investment, along with transit investment itself, is strong in the
United States. But patronage is faltering and the recent decline in transit use has stirred
considerable concern in the media and among transportation professionals. Figure 1 shows
the indexed trends since 2000 in ridership, ridership per capita, inflation-adjusted public
investment, and service hours. Following steady growth in ridership through the mid-2000s,
transit use slipped during the Great Recession beginning in 2008. Like the economy, transit
patronage gradually recovered between 2010 and 2014. But unlike the U.S. economy, which
has continued to slowly recover, transit use—and particularly per capita transit use—began
falling again in 2014. Observers point to all manner of culprits for these trends, ranging from
falling gasoline prices to the rise of transportation network companies like Uber and more.
Journal of Public Transportation | scholarcommons.usf.edu/jpt
Vol. 21 No. 1 [2018] pp. 104-118
SPECIAL ISSUE
The Future of Public Transportation
© 2018 Michael Manville, Brian D. Taylor, and Evelyn Blumenberg
http//dx.doi.org/10.5038/2375-0901.21.1.11
ISSN: 1077-291X | Licenced under Creative Commons License Attribution - Noncommercial 4.0
e Journal of Public Transportaion is published by the Center for Urban Transportation Research
at the University of South Florida
Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018 105
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
FIGURE 1.
Indexed Trends in Transit Ridership, Ridership per Capita, Inflation-Adjusted Public Investment, and
Service Hours since 2000
Figure 1 also shows the indexed trends in inflation-adjusted public transit investment
(operating expenditures plus a 10-year moving average of capital expenditures) and transit
vehicle service hours. ese trends paint both an auspicious picture of an industry that has
attracted significant public support and largesse, and a sobering picture of an industry that
attracts funding more easily than customers. Inflation-adjusted expenditures are increasing
considerably faster than service, while service is increasing considerably faster than overall
patronage, while per capita ridership is down since 2000. Although this figure plots investment
in and service provided by all transit modes, rail transit (subways, commuter rail, and especially
light rail) has proven especially popular in recent years with public officials and the people who
elect them. In 2000 light rail transit accounted for 6.3% of all transit investment nationwide
and carried 3.6% of all transit trips, but by 2015 these shares had increased to 9.1% of all public
transit investment and 5.1% of trips (National Transit Database 2000 & 2016). 1
Transit’s ridership issues are not confined to the past few years. Figure 2 shows a longer time
trend in both per capita transit trips and transit service supply, the latter measured by per
1 Transit investment is comprised of operating expenditures for a given year plus a 10-year inflation-adjusted
moving average of capital expenses leading up to that year. e 10-year moving average takes the given year as the
midpoint (5 years before, current year, 4 years after). For years 2011 and after, the 10 years shrink down to 9, 8, 7, 6,
and finally to a 5-year moving average, because 2015 is the endpoint.
106 Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
capita vehicle hours of service. Here we see a troubling pattern: a steady increase in transit
service supply (which has tripled since 1970) matched by an at-best flat trend in per capita
ridership. is pattern of rising service levels and generally flat patronage is not simply an
artifact of aggregating to the national level. Places that have aggressively added transit service
have not necessarily seen surges in ridership. Since 1985, for example, Los Angeles County has
spent billions of dollars to go from having no rail service to having over 100 miles of rail lines
today. But ridership on LA Metro, the agency that made these investments and that accounts
for the vast majority of county transit use, peaked absolutely in 1985, when the county had
almost two million fewer people. From 1985 to 2015, LA Metro ridership fell 25% per capita
(National Transit Database 2017; U.S. Census Bureau 2016). is combination of rising supply
and relatively flat ridership has made transit steadily less productive over time as people have
been using it less per inflation-adjusted dollar spent on it (Taylor and Morris 2015).
FIGURE 2.
Indexed Trends since 1990 in Per Capita Vehicle Hours (through 2014) and Per Capita Ridership
(through 2016)
What explains these worrisome trends and what do they mean for transit’s future? In this
paper we highlight three challenges confronting American public transportation and consider
their implications for the future. First, the asymmetry of transit supply and use make it
especially vulnerable to changes and disruptions. Second, many of the factors importantly
determining transit ridership today, such as private vehicle ownership and use, are largely
beyond the control of transit agencies. And third, the political success of the industry is often
at odds with its use, which reflects a lack of consensus on its purpose.
Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018 107
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
An Asymmetric Industry
One characteristic of American public transportation is that most people in most places do
not use it. e average U.S. resident made 32.2 transit trips in 2016 (Neff and Dickens 2017; U.S.
Census Bureau 2016), but the “average resident” is in this case an elusive creature, an artifact
of many people never using transit, some using it occasionally, and a few riding a great deal.
Chu (2012), for instance, shows that 20% of the U.S. population lives in neighborhoods where
transit is not available, while 60% lives in a neighborhood with transit service but has not used
it in the previous month. Another 11% of the population takes fewer than 10 transit trips per
month, while 8% takes 10 or more trips. In short, the share of people never using transit was
10 times larger than the share that rode transit 10 times or more per month.
is skewed distribution of transit users and non-users is compounded by their uneven
location across space. Most transit service and especially use are found in the nation’s
oldest and largest metropolitan areas. e 10 largest U.S. transit operators, concentrated
overwhelmingly in “legacy” cities like New York, Chicago, Boston, Washington, and San
Francisco, carried nearly two-thirds (65%) of all U.S. transit trips in 2016. e transit operators
in the New York urbanized area alone collectively accounted for 41% of all U.S. transit trips
(National Transit Database 2016). Within these transit-rich metropolitan areas, transit
provision and use is asymmetric as well—many more trips occur in dense urban areas than
in the suburbs. More than half (54%) of transit users live in neighborhoods with population
densities of 10,000 persons per square mile or higher (U.S. Department of Transportation
2009), compared to an overall 2016 U.S. population density of 85 persons per square mile.
Finally, transit service provision is temporally asymmetric as well. Compared to automobile
travel, transit service and trips are more likely to be made in the peak hour and peak direction
than at other times and in other directions (Taylor et al. 2000).
So who are the heavy transit users? Many travel demand analyses over the years have shown
that the single largest predictor of public transit use is access to a private vehicle. Put simply,
those unable to drive or be driven are far more likely to use transit. is implies two types of
transit riders. e first group includes people with higher socioeconomic status who live or
work in the small number of American locations where driving is difficult and expensive—
typically legacy cities where development densities are high, parking is scarce and priced, and
streets are narrow and congested. ese people have higher incomes but face high time and
monetary costs for driving.
e second group of transit riders may confront the same low price of driving that most
Americans face, but cannot drive because they have low incomes or because they have
other conditions, be they medical or legal, that prevent them from using automobiles. Of
course these two groups overlap: low-income people in places where driving is expensive are
particularly likely to ride transit. So even within legacy cities, but especially outside them,
transit draws its customers disproportionately from among those too poor, young, or disabled
to drive. In practice this has meant that many transit riders are low-income and immigrants
from developing countries (discussed further below). Figure 3 compares U.S. transit users with
the overall population across a range of socioeconomic and geographic dimensions.
108 Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
FIGURE 3.
Comparing Transit Users to the U.S. Population across Six Dimensions
e upshot is that transit use nationwide depends heavily on a relatively small number of
frequent transit users in a relatively small number of central cities located in a handful of the
largest U.S. metropolitan areas. Given these compounding asymmetries of transit provision
and use—among metropolitan areas, within metropolitan areas, by time-of-day and direction,
and among travelers—traditional fixed-route, fixed-schedule public transit ridership is
especially vulnerable to disruptions to its concentrated base of customers. Even as new, high-
quality transit services are implemented and transit oriented developments become more
common, the demand for transit travel will likely fall if population grows disproportionately
outside the largest metropolitan areas or on the suburban fringes within these areas; if
households that traditionally drive little get more access to automobiles; if fuel costs dip,
cars become more reliable, or other costs of driving decline; or if affordable and convenient
chauffeuring and ridesharing services emerge.
Evolving Environments, Markets, and Customers
Observers have proffered three general explanations for the fall in transit’s ridership even as
its demand has risen: (1) changes to transit service and pricing, (2) changes in the composition
and location of people likely to ride, and (3) changes in competing travel modes. While these
reasons are not mutually exclusive, it is important to note that the latter two are largely
outside the control of transit managers.
Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018 109
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
Changes in the Composition and Location of Likely Transit Riders
As the long, slow economic recovery trundles along nearly a decade after the 2008 economic
crash, job stability and incomes have finally begun to creep up among the poorest U.S.
residents, many of whom are among transit’s best customers. After years of decline, the mean
household incomes in the bottom income quintile have started to rise, an increase nationally
of more than 9% between 2014 and 2016 (U.S. Census Bureau 2017). Current research on
transit use in Southern California suggests that auto ownership and access among the poorest
quintile of the population has increased substantially since the mid-2000s, and the easier
availability of autos could be shifting many of transit’s heaviest users to ride less or even
abandon transit altogether. If this shift in auto access among poorer households is manifesting
nationwide, the effects on ridership could be substantial.
Relatedly, transit is heavily used by immigrants, particularly during their first years in the
United States. But immigration has slowed and shifted in recent years (U.S. Department of
Homeland Security 2000; 2015), which may be reducing the supply of new transit riders. As
immigrants assimilate, they are more likely to move from transit to driving (Blumenberg and
Evans 2010; Chatman and Klein 2009; Myers 1996). In addition, more recent immigrants to the
United States tend to be more affluent than those who arrived in the late 20th century, and
therefore less likely to be heavy transit users on arrival (Pew Research Center 2015). Further,
California and some other high-immigrant states have made it easier for undocumented
immigrants to obtain driver’s licenses (NCSL 2015), which may accelerate transitions from
transit to automobiles among immigrants.
Transit ridership is influenced not only by poverty levels, but also by the location of the poor,
and it possible that many heavy transit users no longer live close to transit. Cities and suburbs
around the United States have promoted transit oriented development (TOD) around bus
and particularly rail stations in order to locate more people within walking distance of high-
quality transit service (Shinkle 2012). TODs have proven popular with high-income workers
and may help contribute to the larger back-to-the-city movement among more affluent
residents (Baum-Snow and Hartley 2016; Pollack et al. 2010). But this influx of higher-income
residents might reduce rather than increase overall ridership. Newer, more affluent residents
who arrive in gentrifying transit oriented areas may use transit more than they did previously
(and more than if they lived elsewhere), but they may use transit less than the lower-income
residents they replace (Dominie 2012). And if the residents they replace end up living farther
from quality transit and ride less as a result, then TODs might be successful (in that they will
be popular and reduce driving), but also cause a net loss of transit ridership.
Finally, if higher-income residents are more likely over time to live in high-amenity, central-city
neighborhoods (Baum-Snow and Hartley 2016; Glaeser and Gottlieb 2006), it also appears that
lower-income households may be shifting to more suburban locales. Less than half of the poor
now live in central cities, down from 54% in 2000 (U.S. Census Bureau 2017). So even if poverty
has not fallen much, we know that it has suburbanized, meaning poor people now live farther
from transit on average (Kneebone and Garr 2010; Kneebone 2014; Zimmerman et al. 2015). So
in concert these shifts in the location of wealthier and poorer households may be putting the
demography of transit use at odds with its geography. Poor people ride more and people ride
more in dense central areas, but poor people are now less likely to be in dense central areas.
110 Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
Changes in Competing Travel Modes
Transit use is sensitive to gasoline prices, with some research showing that gas prices affect transit
use more than transit fares do (Cervero 1990). While gas prices have been volatile in recent years,
they have generally fallen since the late 2000s and have tended to fall more than rise. However,
while falling gas prices may explain part of the recent decline in transit use, we would note that
per capita declines in transit ridership began while gas prices were high and climbing.
Despite the best efforts of many transit officials, investments in keeping vehicle travel cheap have
likely outpaced investments in making transit travel easier. Los Angeles (LA), for example, has
spent a substantial amount on rail since 1990. In many other ways, however, its planning policies
continue to subsidize driving. From 1990 to 2009, the city never increased its street parking rates,
meaning that the real price of metered street parking fell by more than a third. LA still requires
almost every new development to provide parking, and regularly widens roads (Manville et al.
2013; Manville 2017). Nationwide, many TODs are built with abundant parking, meaning that
while transit operators are channeling resources into services that work best with relatively
higher densities, the surrounding land uses are auto-oriented and may encourage people to drive
for most trips (Chatman 2013). In combination these efforts have both contributed to heavy
private investments in private vehicle use and inhibited the sort of densities where traditional
transit works best.
Finally, over the past decade carshare and bikeshare services have been established in many of
the most transit-rich cities in the United States, while transportation network companies (TNCs)
have become ubiquitous competitors to both taxis and public transit (National Academies
of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine 2016). e market value of these new companies,
particularly Uber, is astonishing, suggesting that venture capitalists envision them as leaders
of a technology-driven transformation of urban transportation. TNC use in low-income
neighborhoods may be especially relevant for the future of public transit. Assuming they have
a smartphone and a credit account (which not all low-income travelers do), users can now
purchase automobile trips one at a time—in close to real time and typically at costs well below
those charged by taxicabs, particularly for shared ride options. e TNCS in essence allow people
to enjoy auto access without the high upfront costs of auto ownership. While these companies,
particularly Lyft, have partnered with several transit operators around the United States to
offer first mile/last mile connections to line-haul transit service, their net effect on transit use
remains uncertain. (To be clear, the effects are certainly knowable but the TNCs have been loath
to publicly release their ridership data.) But while TNCs may be taking customers away from
public transit today, we note that per capita transit use began falling before the TNCs began
aggressively expanding.
All the changes discussed here lie largely outside the control of transit agencies. ese agencies
can, of course, do much to attract or retain riders: they can improve service frequency and
reliability, insure that transit vehicles are clean and safe, provide accurate real-time service
information, and price services adroitly. But transit agencies cannot make gas prices, Uber
fares, or urban densities go up. ey cannot make parking less abundant or immigration more
common, and they cannot make poverty more prevalent (nor would we want them to). is
means that public transit agencies are in many ways beholden to larger economic and social
circumstances that will significantly shape their fate in the years ahead.
Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018 111
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
What Purpose Should Public Transit Serve?
e public transit industry in the United States began as private institutions serving a mostly
private purpose. At its height, American public transit was a series of privately owned but
publicly regulated monopolies, sometimes operated as loss-leading real estate enterprises. e
rise and fall of private transit was dramatic. Transit companies made fortunes for their owners;
were decried as sources of urban congestion; helped suburbanize and decentralize American
cities; became emblematic (to their detractors) of corrupt cartel capitalism; and ultimately
spiraled into insolvency as people abandoned them for cars (Jones 1985; Jackson 1985).
Transit’s decline was slowed in the quarter century after the Second World War when
municipal agencies resurrected struggling or defunct transit lines and put them under public
ownership. Governments have invested heavily in transit since the 1970s and, as shown in
Figure 1, support for public transit service has been particularly strong in the 2000s. But these
public entities faced a difficult challenge in taking over transit systems that were designed to
make a private profit (and often only indirectly through real estate development) and graft
onto them a public purpose (Jones 1985). In some places—Boston, New York, the other legacy
cities—this task was not hard. ese central cities remained largely built around transit, and
transit was essential to how they functioned. Transit in these locations remains essential to the
functioning of urban economic agglomerations, and there is a clear public interest in making
sure the transit network is extensive and service is frequent. ese cities could never rely solely
or even largely upon private vehicles and function effectively because they grew up around
transit; they retain built environments that simultaneously reward transit use and penalize
driving.
In other places, however, transit’s role was and still is unclear. Postwar America was defined by
falling population densities and rising auto use. In those locations the public sector inserted
transit into a world almost uniquely unsuited to it. Operating in mostly dispersed, auto-
oriented environments, transit cannot be the vital cog it once was, or still is in the prewar
built environments of legacy cities. In such dispersed, auto-oriented places, transit plays a
diminished role; with sparse route networks, long headways, and small mode shares it serves
as a back-up transportation system—the public option where the overwhelming majority of
people travel and access opportunity privately.
ere are inherent limitations to transit’s role as a social service. It is difficult for a system that
carries mostly low-income people to be extensive and frequent enough to serve riders well,
simply because most metropolitan areas do not have that many low-income people who lack
auto access. Moreover, in many parts of the United States a transit system that successfully
serves low-income riders might be self-undermining as it may allow them to get jobs and
money, which they might then use to buy cars. Such a development (which fragmentary
evidence suggests may be occurring now) would cause transit ridership to fall, although it is
difficult to lament disadvantaged people gaining income.
While transit in many places has defaulted into a social service, many people aspire for transit
to be more than that—although what exactly it should be depends on who is being asked.
Transit’s postwar growth has occurred despite and perhaps because the question of transit’s
purpose has never quite been settled, especially outside the legacy cities. An impressive
112 Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
political coalition has been built upon transit being many things to many people. is
approach has made public transit politically stronger and more fiscally solvent than it may
have been otherwise, but trying to be so many things to so many interests has also deprived it
of a clear mission or comparative advantage.
Consider what transit today is asked to do. Public transportation is variously charged with
the missions of reducing traffic congestion, air pollution, and greenhouse gas emissions; of
promoting economic revitalization and creating jobs; of reorganizing land use patterns and
creating denser, more attractive urban environments; of providing mobility for those without
it; and more (Taylor and Morris 2015). is is an ambitious agenda to be sure, and one with the
rare ability to win support from environmentalists, labor unions, businesses, and even drivers.
But trouble lurks. Little historical evidence supports the idea that transit can solve these
diverse problems. At its height public transportation was criticized as a cause of congestion,
not a salve for it. Similarly, where some proponents argue that transit will revitalize urban
areas, historically it was an engine of decentralization, pushing population outward into
streetcar suburbs. Even if we think that transit today can accomplish different goals than it did
in the past, the fact remains that for most of these problems transit is not the best or most
cost-effective solution. If we are worried about greenhouse gases, we should tax carbon. If
tackling congestion is our priority, we should price peak-hour driving. Income supplements
are proven to reduce poverty and in a nation organized around the car, buying poor people
automobiles increases mobility far more than building suburban light rail. Transit’s advantage
is political: it offers a way to solve problems that many people can agree on. Its disadvantage is
practical: it may not be a good way to solve those problems.
Of course, the perfect need not be the enemy of the good. Transit may not be the best
way to solve these problems, but it is a tool we have that voters are willing to deploy. Here,
however, we come full-circle: even if we assume transit can help solve these many social and
environmental problems, it can only do so if people ride it. And despite funding transit heavily
so it can solve these problems, it has not been gaining riders for decades and has recently been
losing them.
It is thus possible, and perhaps likely, that at least some of the longer-term declines in transit
productivity and more recent declines in patronage result from a tension between transit’s
politically popular environmental and economics purposes and its less popular but more
tractable social service mission. Put simply, many voters who do not ride transit have strong
influence over it, and they may have different ideas for what transit should be than do the
many riders who are numerically smaller and often cannot vote. Investments that please the
first group may not deliver ridership, while investments that please the second may deliver
ridership but be less likely to win funding support. If the second group is also shrinking, the
result could explain recent trends in increasing transit supply and falling ridership.
Looking Ahead
Given these three challenges of demand and service asymmetry, buffeting by exogenous urban
and societal changes, and a disconnect between transit politics and transit use, will transit
Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018 113
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
patronage continue its recent slide or rebound in the coming years? It depends, both on
factors under the purview of transit managers and policy makers as well as those outside of it
(Taylor and Fink 2013).
First and perhaps most importantly, ridership will depend on whether we find the political
will to intelligently manage private vehicle use by pricing driving at its marginal social cost. If
congestion charges, parking charges, emissions charges, and the like become more common,
cars will no longer automatically be the default mode for almost all trips in almost all places—
particularly for trips that drivers value less than it costs society to accommodate. is would
make public transit considerably more attractive to car owners for some trips, especially in
congested areas with limited parking. In addition, adopting these same principles to pricing
transit so that fares reflect, even if they do not fully cover, the marginal cost of service would
encourage more effective utilization of transit service capacity, increasing productivity (Yoh et
al. 2015).
e mode-shifting effects of such pricing policies will be enhanced if transit systems succeed
in better integrating real-time information about their services with increasingly popular
multi-modal navigation applications on mobile devices, making transit information simple
and easy particularly for the majority of the population that currently never rides transit.
Such improvements will reduce uncertainty about and the perceived time cost of waiting and
transferring for regular riders as well, which would boost ridership (Iseki and Taylor 2009; Yoh
et al. 2012).
Second, future transit ridership will depend on whether we focus transit investments in the
handful of places where most transit riders currently live. If ridership is transit’s primary goal,
one could argue that more transit investment should be devoted to shoring up and improving
service in the legacy cities rather than expanding new rail services in (for example) places
like Arizona or Florida. For this decidedly asymmetric industry, the New York Metropolitan
Transportation Authority (MTA) needs enormous sums of money to rebuild and upgrade its
aging infrastructure, which moves more than 35% of the nation’s transit passengers each day
(National Transit Database 2017). How effectively this industry behemoth rebuilds itself will
go a long way toward determining the future of American public transit. Big city rail systems
in Boston, Chicago, Washington, and elsewhere will need to similarly upgrade. And heavily
patronized bus systems in places like New York, Los Angeles, Philadelphia, and Seattle will
need to maintain and modernize their vehicle stocks as well.
ere are significant political obstacles to focusing public transit investments so narrowly,
as public finance politics favor spreading expenditures across many voters rather than
concentrating them geographically on a few beneficiaries. In addition, while transit might
work best in legacy cities, it remains a vital social service for disadvantaged households with
little or no access to automobiles in cities large and small nationwide, which both politically
and morally militates against concentrating transit service in a few locations. In other words,
there is an argument that ridership isn’t everything and that in the name of helping vulnerable
people we may need to continue heavily subsidizing some low-productivity systems.
ird, ridership will depend on whether thriving, densely developed, congested places can
continue to flourish while becoming denser, more congested, and transit friendly. It will
114 Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
also depend on whether service increases and improves in these expanding transit-friendly
locations where patronage is already high, or whether political pressure will instead steer
resources toward adding relatively unproductive transit service in far-flung, low-density, auto-
friendly, transit-hostile suburbs where most population growth is occurring.
From one perspective, the odds here seem long. Transit-friendly environments in the United
States are relatively scarce and continue to decline in relative terms, notwithstanding the
growing popularity of transit oriented developments. A recent study of population change
in urban, suburban, and rural neighborhood types (based on built form and transportation
system characteristics) across the United States found that over half of all U.S. population
growth since 2000 has been in the most sprawling, least transit-friendly suburban
developments (Voulgaris et al. 2017). Given this seemingly relentless suburbanization, the
relative role of traditional fixed-route, fixed-schedule public transit will likely continue to
diminish over time, even if absolute patronage levels rebound in the coming decade.
But transit need not be conceived of so narrowly. Traditional transit can also be viewed as one
of the oldest and highest capacity forms of shared mobility, part of a larger constellation of
options that range from shared ride vehicle services in far-flung suburbs to bus and rail modes
in built-up urban areas. If we view transit in this more holistic way, the role of transit in urban
mobility may well wax in the decades ahead.
Finally, the future of transit patronage will also depend on whether incomes and auto access
in low-income households continue to climb and whether immigration from poor countries
remains relatively low. is factor is obviously beyond the purview of transit officials and it
is far from clear that increased ridership through this channel is desirable. Given a choice
between more transit use and less poverty, most people prefer the latter. At the same time,
immigration from poorer countries could increase in the coming years depending on political
and economic circumstances both at home and abroad. An influx of lower-income people
seeking opportunity could breathe new life into transit use.
In summary, the future of public transit depends on many factors. Some of these are directly
controlled by transit agencies, others are more broadly within the purview of elected
officials and transportation policy makers, while still others are largely beyond the reach
of transportation policy. Regardless, popular and political aspirations for transit exceed
both realistic expectations for the mode and our willingness to make the difficult choices
needed to see it thrive. We aspire for transit to be an engine of change, but it is more often
a recipient of circumstances. is fact suggests that we need to fundamentally change those
circumstances in order to change transit, not the other way around. When we want transit to
change our economy, environment, or landscape, we misunderstand both the source of our
transportation problems and transit’s potential as a solution. e contemporary United States
is designed for and dominated by automobiles. is arrangement has caused undeniable
problems, but expecting transit to solve these problems on its own is quixotic. Excess driving
is not a result of people failing to take transit; it is a result of people driving. erefore, the
problems of the car will not be solved by transit. ey will be solved when public policy
confronts the car. If and when that happens, transit can once again play a vital role in
American urban transportation.
Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018 115
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
Acknowledgement
e authors thank UCLA Master of Public Policy student Tiffany Chu for her collection and
analysis of some of the data presented in this paper.
References
American Public Transportation Association. Various dates. Quarterly Ridership Reports.
Baum-Snow, N., and D. Hartley. 2016. Causes and Consequences of Central Neighborhood
Change, 1970-2010. Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Blumenberg, E., and A. E. Evans. 2010. “Planning for Demographic Diversity: e Case of
Immigrants and Public Transit.” Journal of Public Transportation, 13(2): 23-45. doi:
10.5038/2375-0901.13.2.2.
Cervero, R. 1990. “Transit pricing research: A review and synthesis.” Transportation, 17(2): 117-
139.
Chatman, D. 2013. “Does TOD Need the T? On the Importance of Factors Other
an Rail Access.” Journal of the American Planning Association, 79(1): 17-31. doi:
10.1080/01944363.2013.791008.
Chatman, D. G., and N. Klein. 2009. “Immigrants and Travel Demand in the United States:
Implications for Transportation Policy and Future Research.” Public Works Management &
Policy, 13(4): 312-327. doi: 10.1177/1087724X09334633.
Chu, X. 2012. An Assessment of Public Transportation Markets Using NHTS Data. Final Report.
National Center for Transit Research at CUTR, University of South Florida, Tampa.
Dominie, W. 2012. Is Just Growth Smarter Growth? e Effects of Gentrification on Transit
Ridership and Driving in Los Angeles’ Transit Station Area Neighborhoods. University of
California, Los Angeles.
Glaeser, E. L., and J. D. Gottlieb. 2006. “Urban Resurgence and the Consumer City.” Urban
Studies, 43(8): 1275–99. doi: 10.1080/00420980600775683.
Iseki, H., and B. D. Taylor. 2009. “Not all transfers are created equal: towards a framework
relating transfer connectivity to travel behavior.” Transport Reviews, 29(6): 777-800.
Jackson, K. 1985. Crabgrass Frontier: e Suburbanization of the United States. Oxford, UK:
Oxford University Press.
Jones, D. W., Jr. 1985. Urban Public Transit: An Economic and Political History. Englewood Cliffs,
NJ: Prentice Hall.
Kneebone, E. 2014. e Growth and Spread of Concentrated Poverty, 2000 to 2008-2012.
Washington, DC: e Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/interactives/the-
growth-and-spread-of-concentrated-poverty-2000-to-2008-2012/#/M10420.
116 Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
Kneebone, E., and E. Garr. 2010. e Suburbanization of Poverty: Trends in Metropolitan
America, 2000 to 2008. Washington, DC: e Brookings Institution. https://www.
brookings.edu/research/the-suburbanization-of-poverty-trends-in-metropolitan-america-
2000-to-2008/.
Manville, M. 2017. “Automatic street widening: Evidence from a highway dedication law.”
Journal of Transport and Land Use, 10(1): 375–393 .
Manville, M., and B. Cummins. 2015. “Why do voters support public transportation? Public
choices and private behavior.” Transportation, 42(2): 303–332.
Manville, M., A. Beata, and D. Shoup. 2013. “Turning Housing Into Driving: Parking
Requirements and Density in Los Angeles and New York.” Housing Policy Debate,
23 (2):350-375. do i: 10.10 8 0/10511482.2013 .767851.
Myers, D. 1996. “Changes over Time in Transportation Mode for Journey to Work: Effects of
Aging and Immigration.” Decennial Census Data for Transportation Planning: Case Studies
and Strategies for 2000, 2(13): 84-99. Washington, DC: Transportation Research Board.
National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine. 2016. Between Public and Private
Mobility: Examining the Rise of Technology-Enabled Transportation Services. Transportation
Research Board Special Report 319. Washington, DC: e National Academies Press. doi:
10.17 226/21875.
National Transit Database. Various years. Washington, DC: Federal Transit Administration.
NCSL. 2015. “States Offering Driver’s Licenses to Immigrants.” Washington, DC: National
Conference of State Legislatures. http://www.ncsl.org/research/immigration/states-
offering-driver-s-licenses-to-immigrants.aspx.
Neff, J., and M. Dickens. 2017. 2016 Public Transportation Fact Book, 67th Edition. Washington,
DC: American Public Transportation Association.
Pew Research Center. 2015. Modern Immigration Wave Brings 59 Million to U.S., Driving
Population Growth and Change rough 2065: Views of Immigration's Impact on
U.S. Society Mixed. Hispanic Trends, September 28. http://www.pewhispanic.org/
files/2015/09/2015-09-28_modern-immigration-wave_REPORT.pdf.
Pollack, S., B. Bluestone, and C. Billingham. 2010. Maintaining Diversity In America’s Transit-
Rich Neighborhoods: Tools for Equitable Neighborhood Change. Dukakis Center for Urban
and Regional Policy, Northeastern University.
Shinkle, D. 2012. Transit-Oriented Development in the States. Washington, DC: National
Conference of State Legislatures. http://www.ncsl.org/Documents/transportation/TOD_
Final.pdf.
Taylor, B. D., and C. N. Y. Fink. 2013. “Explaining transit ridership: What has the evidence
shown?” Transportation Letters: e International Journal of Transportation Research, 5(1):
15-26. doi: 10.1179/1942786712Z.0000000003.
Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018 117
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
Taylor, B. D., M. Garrett, and H. Iseki. 2000. “Measuring cost variability in provision of transit
service.” Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board,
1735: 101-112. doi: 10.3141/1735-13.
Taylor, B. D., D. Miller, H. Iseki, and C. Fink. 2009. “Nature and/or nurture? Analyzing the
determinants of transit ridership across US urbanized areas.” Transportation Research Part
A: Policy and Practice, 43(1): 60-77. doi: 10.1016/j.tra.2008.06.007.
Taylor, B. D., and E. A. Morris. 2015. “Public transportation objectives and rider demographics:
are transit’s priorities poor public policy?” Transportation, 42(2): 347-367. doi: 10.1007/
s11116-014-9547- 0 .
U.S. Census Bureau. 2011. Table 1. Intercensal Estimates of the Resident Population by Sex
and Age for the United States: April 1, 2000 to July 1, 2010 (US-EST00INT-01). Population
Division.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2016. Table 1. Annual Estimates of the Resident Population for the United
States, Regions, States, and Puerto Rico: April 1, 2010 to July 1, 2016 (NST-EST2016-01).
Population Division.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2017. Current Population Survey, Annual Social and Economic Supplement.
U.S. Department of Homeland Security. 2000. 2000 Yearbook of Immigration Statistics.
Washington, DC: Office of Immigration Statistics.
U.S. Department of Homeland Security. 2015. 2015 Yearbook of Immigration Statistics.
Washington, DC: Office of Immigration Statistics.
U.S. Department of Transportation. 2009. Summary of Travel Trends: 2009 National Household
Travel Survey. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Highway
Administration. http://nhts.ornl.gov/2009/pub/stt.pdf.
Voulgaris, C. T., B. D. Taylor, E. Blumenberg, A. Brown, and K. Ralph. 2017. “Synergistic
neighborhood relationships with travel behavior: An analysis of travel in 30,000 US
neighborhoods.” Journal of Transport and Land Use, 10(1): 437-461. doi: 10.5198/
jtlu.2016.840.
Yoh, A., B. D. Taylor, and J. Gahbauer. 2015. “Does Transit Mean Business? Reconciling
Economic, Organizational, and Political Perspectives on Variable Transit Fares.” Public
Works Management & Policy, 21(2): 157-172. doi: 10.1177/1087724X15616816.
Yoh, A., H. Iseki, M. Smart, and B. D. Taylor. 2012. “Hate to Wait: Effects of Wait Time on
Public Transit Travelers’ Perceptions.” Transportation Research Record: Journal of the
Transportation Research Board, 2216: 116-124. doi: 10.3141/2216-13.
Zimmerman, R., C. E. Restrepo, H. B. Kates, and R. Joseph. 2015. Suburban Poverty, Public
Transit, Economic Opportunities and Social Mobility. Final Report. Robert F. Wagner
Graduate School of Public Service, New York University.
118 Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2018
Transit in the 2000s: Where Does It Stand and Where Is It Headed?
About the Authors
Michael Manville, Ph.D. (mmanvill@ucla.edu) is assistant professor of Urban Planning
at the UCLA Luskin School of Public Affairs, and a faculty affiliate of the UCLA Institute of
Transportation Studies. His research focuses on the relationships between transportation and
land use, as well as on local public finance.
Brian D. Taylor, Ph.D. (btaylor@ucla.edu) is professor of Urban Planning, director of
the Institute of Transportation Studies, and director of the Lewis Center for Regional Policy
Studies at the UCLA Luskin School of Public Affairs. His research and teaching center on travel
behavior as well as transportation equity, finance, history, and politics.
Evelyn Blumenberg, Ph.D. (eblumenb@ucla.edu) is professor of Urban Planning at the
UCLA Luskin School of Public Affairs. Her research focuses on the effects of urban structure—
the spatial location of residents, employment, and services—on economic outcomes for
immigrants and low-wage workers.