ChapterPDF Available

Abstract

The study of political institutions has moved back into center stage in political science. The study of political institutions and their consequences for political choice and development has moved to center stage in the study of politics. The article first surveys the history of institutionalist thought, then explores several different types of institutionalist theory, and, finally, suggests the central analytical agendas of modern institutionalist theory. The article examines how and why both history and institutions matter for politics and emphasizes the importance of 'ideas' for understanding political change.
Institutionalism
Sven Steinmo
European University Institute, Florence, Italy
June 27, 2013
The study of political institutions has moved back into center stage in political science.
Whereas only a few years ago, institutions were mostly casually mentioned in most political
science research, today they are a central focus of attention. This change is not simply a
change of language or the catching on of a new popular phrase or academic fad. Instead these
changes represent an important development in evolution of political science theory and
intellectual focus.
The following essay surveys the history of institutionalist thought, explores several different
types of institutionalist theory and suggest the central analytical agendas of modern
institutionalist theory.
1 What are Institutions?
In the broadest sense, institutions are simply rules. As such, they are a foundation for all
political behavior. Some are formal (as in constitutional rules) some are informal (as in
cultural norms), but without institutions there could be no organized politics. Indeed absent
institutions there could be no organization at all. To understand this point, simply attempt to
consider a world in which there were no rules: In this Hobbesian hell, individuals would be
forced to ‘invent’ communication every time they encountered another individual. In this
sense, then, if we study social interaction, we study institutions. This does not suggest,
however, that all social scientists are ‘Institutionalists.’
2 Institutionalism
The ‘Institutionalism’ specifically examines the ways in which institutions structure social
and political behavior (North 1990). This burgeoning body of literature argues that policy,
politics, and behavior can only be understood in the context of the institutions in which they
take place. Thus, for example, Ellen Immergut argues that variations in National Health
Insurance (NHI) systems are best explained by variations in national political institutions
(Immergut 1998). Similarly, Bo Rothstein shows that Sweden's high union density is best
explained by the ‘Ghent’ unemployment insurance system which gives workers powerful
incentives to join Swedish unions (Rothstein 1992). Even more broadly, Douglas North
suggests that the very success of Western political economic model is rooted in the peculiar
institutions developed in these societies (North 1990).
The central tenet of this New Institutionalism is that institutions are not neutral to policy
outcomes. As Peter Hall has suggested, ‘On the one hand, the organization of policy-making
affects the degree of power that any one set of actors has over policy outcomes. On the
other hand, organizational position also influences an actor's definition of his own
interestsin this way, organizational factors affect both the degree of pressure an actor can
bring to bear on policy and the likely direction of that pressure’ (Hall 1986) p. 12..
In sum, institutions define the rules of the political game and as such they define who can
play and how they play. Consequently, they ultimately can shape who wins and who loses. If
politics is the study of who gets what, when and why, then institutionalists argue that
institutions should be at the heart of that study.
3 A Brief History of Institutionalism
Institutionalism has a long established tradition among those interested in politics and
political outcomes. Plato's Republic is a comparative study of institutions. Similarly,
Aristotle's central concern in Politics is which kinds of political institutions will produce the
best outcomes. James Madison must clearly also be seen as an early American
‘Institutionalist’ in that he was specifically concerned with which kinds of institutions would
produce the best political outcomes and how the specific design of institutions would shape
political outcomes.
Political scientists have also long been interested in institutions. Indeed, in its early years
political science meant the study of political institutions (Wilson 1891). But, with some
important exceptions (Herring 1940; Key 1947), early political science was often more
descriptive than analytical. ‘Comparative politics,’ in particular, consisted mostly of detailed
configurative studies of different legal, administrative, and political structures. In the
immediate postwar years a new generation of political scientists attempted to make the study
of politics more ‘scientific.’ For many this effectively meant that political science ought to
model itself on the ‘hard sciences’ which they believed was fundamentally a deductive
process. Thus rather than studying the details of political life and inductively uncover the
patterns of behavior and action, political ‘science’ should be a deductive science that seeks to
discover of the general laws and fundamental forces that lay behind political action. Focusing
on particular institutions, proponents this intellectual agenda implied, was ‘a-theoretical.’
Concomitant with the push for more abstract laws, political scientists were disillusioned by
the failure of parliamentary institutions in Inter-war Weimar Germany (and later in post-
colonial Africa) to prevent these polities from devolving into authoritarianism. Clearly, many
argued, there were bigger, more important, indeed more fundamental, forces at work in
politics and development than political institutions. These forces, they argued, should be the
focus of political science.
Thus, behavioralist, functionalist and Marxist perspectives took leading roles in political
science theory building through most of the 1960s and 1970s. As a consequence, institutional
analysis diminished in prominenceparticularly in comparative politics. For Functionalists,
political institutions were simply seen as organizations created to fulfill the systemic needs of
society. As such, political institutions were neither important nor interesting. For
Behavioralists and Marxists, political institutions were simply arenas in which political battles
were fought out. While Marxists saw the relevant groups as classes and Pluralists saw them as
more narrowly defined, neither theoretical perspective played particular attention to the
structure or character of the institutions themselves. The real meat of politics, they argued
and the keys to understanding political outcomeswas found in the articulation of group
interests. Though this was rarely explicitly stated, implicit in these theories was the assertion
that if politics or policies differed between societies, this difference was surely the result of
different constellations of group and class interests or preferences (Almond and Verba 1963;
Verba 1967; Miliband 1969).
It was not the case, however, that all political scientists had abandoned the study of
institutions. Indeed, many of the most widely read scholars in American Politics maintained
an explicitly institutional emphasis (Schattschnieder 1960) (Greenstein 1963). In
Comparative Politics, as well, several political scientists continued to examine political
institutions and their effects on political outcomes (Ekstein 1960; Bendix 1964; Huntington
1968), even while they sometimes had to defend their ‘inductive’ approach from the challenge
that it was not ‘scientific’ (Przeworski and Teune 1970). For these scholars it was self-evident
that if one wanted to understand what government does, one needs to specifically study the
institutions through which it acts.
It was probably in Comparative Politics that the search for ‘Grand Theory’ had its most
significant impact. It may be for this reason that a self-conscious return to ‘Institutionalism’
was most forcefully articulated here. Among the first group of scholars to move in this
direction was Peter Katzenstein and his colleagues who sought to explain why several
advanced capitalist states responded so differently to the oil shock of the 1970s. The answer,
they concluded, was found in the differing institutional structures in these polities and the
consequent patterns of economic policy pursued in each nation (Katzenstein 1978).
Similarly, Theda Skocpol's study of social revolutions also concluded that one could not
explain the course of a country's revolution without examining the nature and structure of the
state against at which these revolutions were aimed (Skocpol 1979).
Soon a new ‘state centered’ approach emerged in comparative political inquiry. These
scholars forcefully argued against the behavioralist and Marxist ‘grand theory’ emphasis then
dominant in the study of comparative politics. Instead, they suggested, political outcomes
were shaped and structured by the specific actors and their position in the state. One should
not treat the state as a neutral ‘black box’ through which group or class interest was simply
translated (Evans, Rueschemeyer et al. 1985). Instead, the state had independent interests and
agendas which were separate and different from the interests and preferences of classes and
interest groups that made up society.
Of course it did not take long for these scholars to discover that ‘the state’ is too broad a
concept and too varied a set of institutions to be ‘taken seriously’ without being broken down.
To make analytic sense out of the insights, scholars began examining institutions more
carefully. If state institutions ‘matter,’ they argued, then why should this not be equally true
of institutions outside the boundaries of the executive state? With these questions ‘The New
Institutionalism’ was born.
4 Three Types of Institutionalism
Today three different intellectual approaches lay claim to the term ‘Institutionalist’ (Hall and
Taylor 1996). Each grows out of a different academic discipline and attempts to integrate
these different analytic traditions into the understanding of politics. Sociological
Institutionalism, as its name implies, grows out of sociology and the study of organizations
(Selznick 1949). These scholars have been centrally interested in understanding culture and
norms, as institutions. These scholars emphasize ‘folkways,’ ‘patterns of behavior,’ and
‘cognitive maps’ and argue that these social institutions are critical for understanding the
structure of social, political, and economic interactions (March and Olsen 1989; DiMaggio
and Powell 1991). Building on upon their analyses of complex organizations, these scholars
show the relationship between formal institutions and the structure or patterns of behavior and
beliefs. They argue that these informal institutions are core to any understanding of the
nonrational aspects human communication and exchange.
‘Rational Choice Institutionalism,’ taking its lead from economics, emphasizes quite different
sets of institutions and their effects. Rational Choice (RC) scholars attempt to apply the
formal logic and methods to the study of politics and history and often explicitly eschew the
more ‘mushy’ or less precise variables such as norms and beliefs. Instead, basic assumptions
are made about human behavior and motivation in order to uncover and examine the basic
laws of political behavior and action. Scholars in this tradition argue that once these laws are
discovered, models can be constructed that will help us understand and predict political
behavior (Levi 1988). In their deductive model, Rational Choice scholars look to the real
world to see if their model is right (test the model). For these scholars, understanding real
outcomes is not the first pointcreating, elaborating, refining a theory of politics is
(Weingast 1996).
The implications of this scientific orientation are substantial. Morris Fiorina, a highly
regarded RC scholar at Harvard, put the issue in the following way: ‘most PTI scholars are
not as interested in a comprehensive understanding of some real institution or historical
phenomenon, so much as in a deeper understanding of some theoretical principle or
logic[F]or most PTI scholars, breadth trumps depth; understanding 90 percent of the
variance in one case is not as significant an achievement as understanding 10 percent of each
of nine cases, especially if the cases vary across time and place’ (Fiorina 1995) p. 110-1.
The third ‘New Institutionalist’ approach emerges out of what might be considered a more
traditional political science. Consequently, it has a quite different aim: Historical
Institutionalists are primarily interested in understanding and explaining real world events and
outcomes. As with the other approaches noted above, scholars working in this tradition also
argue that one cannot explain particular historical outcomes without specifically examining
the way in which the political institutions have shaped or structured the political process
(Steinmo, Thelen et al. 1992). But, unlike RC scholars in particular, Historical Institutionalists
came about their ‘institutional’ arguments inductively after testing a variety of alternative
theories (i.e., Marxist, structural functionalist, culturalist, and rationalist) against the
outcomes they observed. In other words, Historical Institutionalists are first interested in
explaining an outcome (say, for example, why France and Britain have pursued such different
styles of industrial Policy (Hall 1986) or why some welfare states generate more popular
support than others (Rothstein 1998); they then proceed to explore alternative explanations
for the outcomes they observe.
Historical Institutionalists do not argue that institutions are the only important variables for
understanding political outcomes. Quite the contrary, these scholars generally see institutions
as intervening variables (or structuring variables) through which battles over interest, ideas,
and power are fought. Institutions are thus the focal points in critical junctures in a historical
path analysis because political battles are fought inside institutions and over the design of
future institutions.
5. Taking History Seriously
These insights had important implications, both for what we study and for how we study it.
Historical institutionalists study history because they believe history matters, not merely to
increase the reference points for analysis (as is done in time series analysis). There are at least
three important ways in which history matters. First, political events happen within a
historical context, which has a direct consequence on the decisions or events. An early
example of this is the seminal work of Alexander Gershenkron, who argued that when a
country industrializes necessarily affects how it industrializes. He shows us why latecomers
cannot go through the same long trial-and-error process followed by early developers.1 In
other words, the process of industrialization is essentially different for late developers than for
early developers. This is a huge insight that is easily missed in large scale quantitative, cross
national comparisons, which very often pool data across continents and time periods and treat
the time/place as inconsequential (or assume that it will ‘wash out’ of the analysis).
The second reason history matters is that actors or agents can learn from experience.
Historical institutionalists understand that behaviour, attitudes and strategic choices take place
inside particular social, political, economic and even cultural contexts. Rather than treating all
political action as if fundamentally the same irrespective of time, place or context, historical
institutionalists explicitly and intentionally attempt to situate their variables in the appropriate
context. Thus, by deepening and enriching their understanding of the historical moment and
the actors within it, they are able to offer more accurate explanations for the specific events
that they explore than had they treated their variables outside the temporal dimension.
E.E. Schattschneider’s early work on tariff policy showed how political choices made
1 An example outside politics may prove illustrative. Many of us recognize that firstborn
children have a very different developmental experience than second (or later) children. Not
only are the parents more experienced after the first child, they are also taking care of more
than one child at a time. Finally, and equally importantly, subsequent children grow up in a
home where there are older siblings – something the first child, by definition, cannot do.
at time A have important consequences for time B. In this work he famously argued that ‘new
policies create new politics’. Following Schattschneider, Paul Pierson has shown in several
important works how and why policy choices at one point in time affect choices at subsequent
points in time. Similarly, Esping-Anderson pointed out in his seminal Three Worlds of
Welfare Capitalism how, given the fact that we live in modern welfare states with
unemployment insurance, health insurance, pension programs and the like: The existence of
the welfare state is a fact of modern political life that itself shapes politics, expectations and
policy in the countries that have developed it (Esping-Andersen 1990).
Finally, again as Pierson has shown, expectations are also moulded by the past
(Pierson 2004). While some might point to America’s adventure in Iraq as a simple product of
power politics and/or the demand for oil, a historical institutionalist would more likely look to
the patterns of past victories for an understanding of why this country reacted in the way it did
to the 9/11 bombings. Certainly they were mistaken, but there should be little doubt that
America’s past successes in Germany and Japan – to say nothing of their perceived victory
over Communism at century’s end – led policy makers in the administration to believe that
they could assert American power and bring successful capitalism and democracy to a former
dictatorship.
In sum, for historical institutionalists, history is not a chain of independent events.
There is more than the temporal dimension implied in this basic point. Taking history
seriously ultimately means that the scholar is sceptical of the very notion of variable
independence. Instead, acknowledging the importance of history suggests an explicit
awareness that important variables can and often do shape one another. Historical
institutionalists, more than political scientists in some other traditions, are explicitly interested
in these interactive effects on the interdependence of multiple causal variables.
Historical institutionalists are something like the environmental biologist who believes
that in order to understand the specific fate of a particular organism or behaviour, she must
explicitly examine that organism or behaviour in the ecology or context in which it lives. This
implies a different scientific ontology than that commonly found in the hard sciences of
physics and chemistry. At the root of evolutionary biology is the assumption that the objects
of analysis – living organisms – are fundamentally different from inanimate matter. While
objects in the physical world often adhere to constant ‘laws’ of nature, biological organisms
often defy attempts to reduce them to their essential components because of their complexity.
Thus, as eminent evolutionary biologist Ernst Mayer points out, the development of biology
as a science has required an investigation of ‘additional principles’ that applied only to living
organisms. He argues, ‘This required a restructuring of the conceptual world of science that
was far more fundamental than anyone had imagined at the time’ (Mayr 2004) p. 26.
Historical institutionalism represents something like this ontological move in social
science. In order to understand historically specific events and long term political outcomes,
one could not strictly apply methods and epistemologies drawn from the study of invariant
variables that have fixed relationships across space and time. This, of courses, does not mean
that it is not science – unless one’s definition of science would exclude biology as well;
rather, it implies that the scientific methods applied should fit the subject being studied.
6. Ideas, Institutions and Change
To argue that “institutions matter” is by now taken as common sense. Today it is
widely recognized that institutions provide stability in political life because they structure
political choices. This is because when we know the rules, we are more likely to know how to
interact and how to behave. Indeed, when we know the rules we adapt our behavior
accordingly. The more difficult and interesting questions arise when we ask: 1) Why do
people follow rules? 2) How do we explain institutional change? And, 3) if institutions are so
important, what role is left for human agency and ideas?
Early institutionalist scholars drew insights from evolutionary theory of "punctuated
equilibrium" to explain institutional change (Steinmo, Thelen et al. 1992). In recent years,
however, there has been growing interest in explaining the endogenous sources of
institutional change. A number of scholars have mapped out different types of institutional
change in different contexts (Streeck and Thelen 2005; Mahoney and Thelen 2009). These
efforts have led to considerable refinement of our understanding of different types of
institutional change, but are insufficient for explaining why institutions change.
The most important contributions to Institutionalist theorizing on change have come
from those scholars who specifically have tried to examine relationship between human
agency and ideas (Campbell 2002; Lieberman 2002; Blyth 2008; North 2008). Traditionally,
(especially those in the rational choice school) institutions are created by individuals seeking
maximize their individual interests. Ideas, in this view, were simply epiphenomenal or
justification for people’s ‘real’ motivation. But such an approach is unsatisfactory; both at the
common sense level (we know that human beliefs and ideas matter for our choices) and
because these approaches fail to explain how we move from one equilibrium to another.
The interesting questions arise when we look at the interdependent relationships
between ideas, institutions and interests over time. Since none of these factors are static, then
only through an historical analysis can we learn how they develop, how they change and why
they are so different in different contexts (Lieberman 2002). Building on the work of social
psychologist such as Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman (Kahneman, Slovic et al. 1982;
Kahneman 2011), institutionalist scholarship is moving toward a more nuanced understanding
of the ‘social foundations’ of human rule following behavior and are attempting to better
understand the ways in which human cognitive biases’ shape interact with institutional
structures to influence human behavior. Social psychologists have long understood that
human beings are social creatures who are not normally individualistic in a meaningful sense.
Instead we are driven to follow social rules and look for social approval. Human beings are
more likely to be normative actors, possessing significant cognitive biases,’ than rational self-
interested utility maximizers. Appreciating human motivations in this way forces us to
consider the interaction of institutional rules, human choices and eventually, differences in
cultural systems.
Finally, institutionalists have begun to argue that we can understand change in
evolutionary terms and thus bring some of the insights from evolutionary theory into the
study of institutional evolution (Lewis and Steinmo 2012). Whereas traditional political
science has taken a mechanical approach to the study of politics and human affairs (Hall
2003) an evolutionary approach to institutional change allows one to integrate contingency
into the study as well be more honest with the fact that there are no truly independent
variables of interest in human affairs . Almost everything that is really interesting and
important is instead the product of the complex interaction of multiple factors that interact
with each other over time (Streeck 2010).
See also:
Institutionalization; Institutions; Law: New Institutionalism; Norms; Political Science:
Overview; Political Sociology; Rational Choice in Politics
Bibliography
4314 words
References
Almond, G. A. and S. Verba (1963). The civic culture; political attitudes and democracy in
five nations. Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Bendix, R. (1964). Nation-building and citizenship. Berkeley, University of California Press.
Blyth, M. (2008). ELEN degenerates: Four (Plus Two) reasons to Take Ideas Very Seriously
Indeed. Ideas and Politics in Social Sciences. D. Beland and R. Cox, forthcoming.
Campbell, J. (2002). "Ideas, politics and public policy." Annual Review of Sociology 28: 21-
38.
DiMaggio, P. J. and W. W. Powell (1991). Introduction. The new institutionalism in
organizational analysis. W. W. Powell and P. J. DiMaggio. Chicago, The University of
Chicago Press: 1-38.
Ekstein, H. (1960). Pressure group politics: the case of the medical association. Stanford, CA,
Stanford University Press.
Esping-Andersen, G. s. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge, Polity.
Evans, P., D. Rueschemeyer, et al. (1985). Bringing The State Back In. New York,
Cambridge University Press.
Fiorina, M. (1995). "Rational Choice and the New (?) Institutionalism." Polity XXXVIII(1
(Fall)): 107-115.
Greenstein, F. I. (1963). The American party system and the American people. Englewood
Cliffs, Prentice-Hall.
Hall, P. (1986). Governing the Economy. New York, Oxford University Press.
Hall, P. (2003). Aligning Ontology and Methodology in Comparative Research. Comparative
historical analysis in the social sciences. J. Mahoney and D. Rueschmeyer. Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press: 373-404.
Hall, P. and R. Taylor (1996). "Political science and the three new institutionalisms." Political
Studies 44: 936-957.
Herring, P. (1940). The politics of democracy; American parties in action. New York, W. W.
Norton & Company.
Huntington, S. (1968). Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, Yale University
Press.
Immergut, E. (1998). "The Theoretical Core of the New Institutionalism." Politics and Society
26(1): 5-34.
Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. London, Penguin.
Kahneman, D., P. Slovic, et al., Eds. (1982). Judgement under uncertainty: Heuristics and
biases. New York, Cambridge University Press.
Katzenstein, P. J. (1978). Between power and plenty : foreign economic policies of advanced
industrial states. Madison, University of Wisconsin Press.
Key, V. O. (1947). Politics, parties and pressure groups. New York, Thomas Y. Crowell
company.
Levi, M. (1988). Of rule and revenue. Berkeley, University of California Press.
Lewis, O. and S. Steinmo (2012). "How Institutions Evolve: Evolutionary Theory and
Institutional Change." Polity 44(3): 314-339.
Lieberman, R. (2002). Political institutions and the politics of race in the development of the
modern welfare state. Restructuring the Welfare State-Political Institutions and Policy
Change-. B. Rothstein and S. Steinmo. New York, Palgrave Macmillan: 102-129.
Lieberman, R. C. (2002). "Ideas, Institutions, and Political Order: Explaining Political
Change." The American Political Science Review 96(4): 697.
Mahoney, J. and K. Thelen (2009). How Historical Institutionalists explain change.
Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power in Historical
Institutionalism. J. Mahoney and K. Thelen. New York, Cambridge University Press.
March, J. and J. Olsen (1989). Rediscovering Institutions. New York, Free Press.
Mayr, E. (2004). What makes biology unique? : considerations on the autonomy of a
scientific discipline. Cambridge, UK ; New York, Cambridge University Press.
Miliband, R. (1969). The state in capitalist society. London, Weidenfeld & Nicolson.
North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
North, D. C. (2008). What is Missing from Political Economy. The Oxford handbook of
political economy. B. R. Weingast and D. A. Wittman. Oxford, Oxford University Press:
1003-1009.
Pierson, P. (2004). Politics in time: History, institutions, and social analysis. Princeton,
Princeton University Press.
Przeworski, A. and H. Teune (1970). The logic of comparative social inquiry. New York,,
Wiley-Interscience.
Rothstein, B. (1992). Labor market institutions and working class strength. Structuring
Politics: Historical institutionalism in comparative politics. S. Steinmo, K. Thelen and F.
Longstreth. New York, Cambridge University Press: 33-56.
Rothstein, B. (1998). Just Institutions Matter: The Moral and Political Logic of the Universal
Welfare State. New York, Cambridge University Press.
Schattschnieder, E. E. (1960). The semi-sovereign people. New York, Holt Reinhart.
Selznick, P. (1949). TVA and the grass roots : a study in the sociology of formal organization.
Berkeley, University of California Press.
Skocpol, T. (1979). States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France,
Russia and China. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Steinmo, S., K. A. Thelen, et al. (1992). Structuring politics : historical institutionalism in
comparative analysis. Cambridge [England] ; New York, Cambridge University Press.
Streeck, W. (2010). Epilogue. Institutions in History: Bringing Capitalism Back In. Handbook
of Comparative Institutional Analysis, , Ox-ford: Oxford University Press, 2010. J. Campbell,
C. Crouch, P. H. Kristensenet al. Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Streeck, W. and K. A. Thelen (2005). Introduction: Institutional change in advanced political
economies. Beyond Continuity. W. Streeck and K. Thelen. Oxford, Oxford University Press:
1-39.
Verba, S. (1967). "Some Dilemmas in Comparative Research." World Politics 20: 111-127.
Weingast, B. (1996). Political Institutions: Rational Choice Perspectives. A New Handbook
of Political Science. H. D. K. R.E. Goodin. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 167-190.
Wilson, W. (1891). Congressional government : a study in American politics. Boston,
Houghton.
... The formation of an institutional collective relies upon the (a) resources brought to a situation, (b) value assigned to actions, (c) way knowledge and information are acquired and used, and (d) processes and justification for particular courses of action (76). In turn, the realisation of a collective accelerates the concept of an institution (79)(80)(81), particularly when considering the institutional nature of sport, both globally (82)(83)(84)(85)(86)(87) and in Australia (66,(88)(89)(90). ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper reviews some mainstream meso-level policy analysis frameworks widely applied in sport. There is, however, an absence of consensus for an established framework for analysing sport policy in general and, instead, techniques emanating from other fields of study have been relied upon. The resultant approach to sport policy analysis is inconsistent, multidimensional, and lacks unanimity, leading to calls for a sport-specific framework. This research outlines how meso-level frameworks have been applied in sport policy and issues linked to sustainability from a grassroots policy perspective. A narrative literature review provides an overview of prevalent approaches, namely Institutional Analysis, the Multiple Streams Framework, Policy Network Theory, and the Advocacy Coalition Framework. Aspects of applying these models to sport policy—including some key advantages and disadvantages—are outlined, especially the issue of conventional top-policy processes, the impact on policy implementers at grassroots level, and the potential for bottom-up policy influence. The article examines the four frameworks in the context of praxes in sport, noting the overall importance of a meso-level approach to sport policy analysis and that arriving at an holistic and inclusive accord has merit.
... This research is grounded in a historical institutionalist (HI) approach wherein actions are understood as being structured through institutional resources that constrain and shape behaviour and outcomes (Mahoney & Thelen, 2010;March & Olsen, 1989, 2006Steinmo & Thelen, 1992;Steinmo, 2001;Thelen, 1999Thelen, , 2000Thelen, , 2002Thelen, , 2003. This approach stresses that institutional rules and practices inform and guide actor behavior, while 'structures of meaning' or common purposes "explain, justify and legitimate behavioural codes" (March & Olsen, 2006, p. 3). ...
Article
Full-text available
In rural development literature, subsidiarity and the merits of local community participation are increasingly extolled. Targeted, nationally-derived sectoral (e.g., agricultural) policies and subsidies are increasingly rejected for a more inclusive, place-based, partnership-driven, community-led, and investment-oriented approach to rural development. This shift can be seen across OECD countries and has been lauded by the organization as 'a new paradigm for rural development.' As such, rural development is conceptualized as a process that emanates from the local level, involving a variety of stakeholders in decision making, such that policy development is viewed as more participatory, reflective of and responsive to community needs. Given this, what role (and capacity) might there be for municipalities to meaningfully engage in rural development activities? This paper examines this question through a case study of two rural Atlantic Canadian communities. In doing so, it finds that these two rural municipalities are institutionally constrained from engaging in rural development initiatives and that provincial and federal funders are focused on economic, rather than community, development. It is argued that municipal capacity needs to be greatly enhanced through institutionalized mechanisms in order for them to become meaningful partners in the development process.
... Relevant studies include those highlighting political processes, political and social institutions, contexts, actors, rules, disputes, interests, and political arenas and systems. The following types of studies will also be considered for inclusion: studies discussing political and (inter) governmental relations, power relations and fiscal federalism; policy analyses and studies investigating policy-making and implementation; studies adopting the political determinants of health approach [40][41][42]; studies focusing on political science and health [43,44]; studies adopting institutionalist approaches [45][46][47]; and studies involving the political economy of health [48,49]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Introduction Primary health care is a key element in the structuring and coordination of health systems, contributing to overall coverage and performance. PHC financing is therefore central in this context, with variations in sufficiency and regularity depending on the “political dimension” of health systems. Research that systematically examines the political factors and arrangements influencing PHC financing is justified from a global and multidisciplinary perspective. The scoping review proposed here aims to systematically map the evidence on this topic in the current literature, identifying groups, institutions, priorities and gaps in the research. Methods and analysis A scoping review will be conducted following the method proposed by Arksey and O’Malley to answer the following question: What is known from the literature about political factors and arrangements and their influence on and repercussions for primary health care financing and resource allocation models? The review will include peer-reviewed papers in Portuguese, English or Spanish published between 1978 and 2023. Searches will be performed of the following databases: Medline (PubMed), Embase, BVS Salud, Web of Science, Scopus and Science Direct. The review will follow the Preferred Reporting Items for Systematic Reviews and Meta-Analyses extension for Scoping Reviews checklist. Inclusion and exclusion criteria will be used for literature screening and mapping. Screening and data charting will be conducted by a team of four reviewers. Registration This protocol is registered on the Open Science Framework (OSF) platform, available at https://doi.org/10.17605/OSF.IO/Q9W3P
... The urbanization process in cities around the world particularly in Africa is greatly structured by and gives rise to a dense, often impenetrable, meshwork of institutions. Consequently, an HI approach is apt for studying urbanization and its discontents in Abuja as it provides historical explanations on how institutions structure and shape political actors, behaviours, rules of engagement, and outcomes of interests across time (Steinmo, 2008(Steinmo, , 2015. Exploring how historical antecedents shape the current dynamics around the governance of informal settlements can provide fundamental insights into the persistent problems and contentions around informal settlements. ...
Article
Full-text available
History matters. Yet, explanations about the contemporary dynamics around informal settlements in global South cities are often divorced from their historical antecedents. We argue that a retrospective approach is important in analyzing and understanding the current dynamics around informal settlements. Applying the historical institutionalism approach and the concepts of critical junctures and path dependency, this paper develops an institutionalist approach to exploring the messy and complex dynamics of urban informal settlements in Abuja, Nigeria. Using interviews, focus group discussions, document analysis, and participant observations, we identify four key critical junctures: the Federal Capital Territory (FCT) ACT of 1976; the Land Use ACT of 1978, the 1979 master plan of Abuja, and the attempted demolition of Mpape in 2012 and the resulting 5-year court case that ended in 2017. These critical junctures have created path dependencies that explain the contemporary state of the urban informal settlements in Abuja, particularly in relation to land rights and tenure (in)security. This study shows how inconsistencies in the formulation of policies and their implementation in the planning of cities are a result of historically embedded problems. Insights into such historical legacies are the first step to a comprehensive understanding and future planning of urban informal settlements.
Article
Full-text available
El estudio de las instituciones cobró impulso como enfoque de análisis de la sociedad a través del estudio de la interacción de los individuos. Douglas North (1995:13) impulsó este tipo de análisis al considerar a las instituciones como las limitaciones creadas por el hombre para dar forma a la interacción. El presente artículo presenta algunos de los criterios que sirven para explicar la conducta de los individuos en sociedad, es decir en su interacción con otros individuos, usados en los enfoques llamados institucionales. Los diversos enfoques institucionales consideran a las instituciones como reglas de funcionamiento de la sociedad, aunque cada enfoque centra su atención en aspectos diferentes. El institucionalismo histórico se ocupa de analizar estructuras y procesos políticos de largo plazo en donde las instituciones (y las ideas que las sustentan)
Thesis
Full-text available
The study focuses on how informal institutions affect public policy implementation. Specifically, the focus is on whether informal practices involved during the distribution of agricultural inputs namely; the Starter Pack Scheme (SP), Targeted Input Programme (TIP) and Agricultural Input Subsidy Programme (AISP) had impacted food security programme implementations. The main argument is that politics exhibited by these informal practices contribute to the maladministration of the agricultural input programmes and violates the fundamental notion of public accountability. The study seeks to expose the effects of these tendencies on the distribution of the agricultural inputs in the light of effectiveness and accountability. The study is based on the theoretical underpinnings of Helmke and Levitsky’s conceptualization of the impact of informal institutions, and Thomas’ conceptualization of Public Accountability to assess the effects of patronage politics manifested in the distribution. The study adopts a combined research design to evaluate the breadth and depth of the effects of these practices. Machinga and Thyolo districts are used as applicable case areas in the study. Despite the success stories which the agricultural input subsidy programmes registered, the findings indicate that patronage politics, as an informal institution, is a vice against effective distribution and public accountability, and produce many repercussions in public policy implementation. From the findings, rules and regulations were violated, coupons and packs were sold out and some was used to woo political supporters. The study concludes that patronage politics manifested in the distribution of agricultural input programmes undermines public accountability and works against the purpose of the food security programmes.
Article
Purpose of the research . This paper presents the results of research on methods and tools of state regulation reflected in schools of economic theory, which originated in the early 16th century and continue to develop to the present day. The aim of the study is to examine the main approaches to state participation in the economic life of a country, in different periods of the history of the world economy. State regulation of the economy is an important aspect of modern economic policy and generates many discussions. Methodology. This research provides an overview of various schools of economic thought and their views on state regulation in schools of economic theory. It includes a discussion of regulatory tools and methods, such as taxes, subsidies, monetary policy, fiscal policy, and market regulation. Findings. The paper also addresses issues of regulatory efficiency, the balance between state intervention and market freedom, and social justice. Understanding these ideas and concepts allows for a conscious analysis and discussion of current problems of state regulation in the modern economy. Recommendations are aimed at studying the effectiveness of state intervention in various economic conditions. This includes assessing the impact of regulation on economic growth, market stability, and social justice.
Article
Full-text available
The pace of reforms in young democracies frequently depends not only on the political will of state authorities, but also on how strongly domestic civil society organizations (CSOs) make a stand for democratic change. This study examines the coalescing practices of Ukrainian CSOs, which come together to propel issues of public importance onto the agendas of the national government or local governments. The paper develops a typology of diverse coalitions and provides examples of the impact of different types of CSO alliances on democratic developments in Ukraine over the last two decades. The article concludes that CSO coalitions in Ukraine might be seen as informal institutions with functional and problem-solving roles due to their ability to restore the balance of power between state and civil society and benefit participatory decision-making.
Article
Full-text available
This scientific work examines the role of political institutions in the formation of the state’s social policy, with a focus on the part that concerns issues of protecting public health. Next, politics on protection of health of population (or health policy) is considered in the prism of global processes. Purpose. The purpose of this work is to study issues of social policy, in particular, its part relating to health care, in the context of global politics and to analyze the role of political institutions in the process of its formation and implementation. Methods. During the research, works devoted to the issues covered in the topic of the work were studied, in particular, the very concept of political institutions and the meaning of social policy were analyzed. A literature review was conducted and results were generated based on methods of generalization and comparative analysis. Main results and conclusions. Based on the materials studied, a conclusion is made about the key role of political institutions in the development and implementation of social policy, which on a global scale influences global health issue. The conclusion is made about the need for a more detailed study of the importance of the involvement of political institutions in the formation of policies to protect public health.
Article
Full-text available
Standards developed by standard-setting organisations (SSOs) – sometimes labelled private rulemaking – are part of larger practices of governance in most societies yet are underinvestigated from a policy process perspective. Utilising and developing the multiple streams approach (MSA), this article investigates a policy process moving between government and the SSO Standards Norway (SN). The study finds standardisation by SSOs to be an ambiguous institutional arrangement. Strong institutional barriers in theory did not work as such in the case investigated. This article argues that the differentiation between responsibility for process (SN) and content (committee) makes the standardisation process vulnerable. The concept of “institutional deficit” is introduced to describe a potential mismatch between SSOs producing policy in a government-like institution, but where the SSOs are not capable of taking responsibility for policies in a government-like way. This article finds the adjusted MSA useful in this potentially least likely case.
Article
Full-text available
Scholars have become acutely interested in how behavior driven by ideas rather than self-interest determines policy-making outcomes. This review examines the literature on this subject. It differentiates among the types of ideas that may affect policy making (i.e., cognitive paradigms, world views, norms, frames, and policy programs) and identifies some of the persistent difficulties associated with studying how ideas shape policy. In particular, studies often do a poor job pinpointing the causal mechanisms that link ideas to policy-making outcomes. More attention needs to be paid to articulating the causal processes through which ideas exert effects. Suggestions for future scholarship that might improve this situation are offered. These include identifying the actors who seek to influence policy making with their ideas, ascertaining the institutional conditions under which these actors have more or less influence, and understanding how political discourse affects the degree to which policy ideas are communicated and translated into practice.
Book
In this book Bo Rothstein seeks to defend the universal welfare state against a number of important criticisms which it has faced in recent years. He combines genuine philosophical analysis of normative issues concerning what the state ought to do with empirical political scientific research in public policy examining what the state can do. Issues discussed include the relationship between welfare state and civil society, the privatization of social services, and changing values within society. His analysis centres around the importance of political institutions as both normative and empirical entities, and Rothstein argues that the choice of such institutions at certain formative moments in a country's history is what determines the political support for different types of social policy. He thus explains the great variation among contemporary welfare states in terms of differing moral and political logics which have been set in motion by the deliberate choices of political institutions. The book is an important contribution to both philosophical and political debates about the future of the welfare state.
Chapter
Long one of the central features of American politics, racial inequality is increasingly an important feature of the European political landscape. Across Europe, countries traditionally considered racially and ethnically homogeneous are struggling with racial diversity to an unprecedented degree. This new diversity in Europe has spawned a grimly familiar litany of problems: racism, discrimination, inequality, isolation, political powerlessness, and even racial violence. To Americans, these are the common disorders of a society long divided by race. Although France and Britain, as well as other European countries, ruled for centuries over multiracial colonial empires, it is only since the dissolution of those empires in the wake of World War II that these countries have confronted significant problems of racial diversity within their own borders.1 The political construction of racial conflict in Europe is in many ways a newer phenomenon than in North America, but it seems to be following the same trajectory, creating an entrenched racial hierarchy that structures society and politics, in which “whites” of European descent are at the top and “blacks” of African and Asian descent are at the bottom. As one commentator writes, “the European experience [shows] that it does not require the particular history of Afro-Americans to account for severe economic disadvantage among ethnic minorities” (Gordon 1995, p. 540).
Chapter
This article discusses what is missing from the literature on political economy. The first section discusses the need for a dynamic theory, which is illustrated in three examples provided in the latter portion of the article. It then examines the centrality of beliefs and argues that the failure to understand some fundamental questions reflects that social science fails to have a truly dynamic theory that considers the non-ergodic nature of the world.
Article
This now-classic examination of the development of viable political institutions in emerging nations is a major and enduring contribution to modern political analysis. In a new Foreword, Francis Fukuyama assesses Huntington's achievement, examining the context of the book's original publication as well as its lasting importance. "This pioneering volume, examining as it does the relation between development and stability, is an interesting and exciting addition to the literature."-American Political Science Review. "'Must' reading for all those interested in comparative politics or in the study of development."-Dankwart A. Rustow, Journal of International Affairs.