ArticlePublisher preview available

Voluntary Export Restraints in a Trade Model with Sticky Price: Linear and Nonlinear Feedback Solutions

Authors:
To read the full-text of this research, you can request a copy directly from the authors.

Abstract and Figures

We revisit the adoption of voluntary export restraints (VERS) in the differential Cournot game with sticky price and intraindustry trade by Dockner and Haug (Can J Econ 3:679–685, 1991). The analysis relies on linear and nonlinear feedback strategies, to encompass the special cases considered in Fujiwara (Aust Econ Pap 49:101–110, 2010). We show that a VER may arise in correspondence of any free trade equilibrium generated by feedback information, when the intensity of competition is at least as strong as under open-loop information. The adoption of a VER by a foreign firm also benefits the domestic firm, yielding an outcome which has a definite collusive flavour. The foreign firm’s incentive to adopt the VER can be interpreted in the light of the dynamic formulation of conjectural variations due to Dockner (J Ind Econ 40:377–395, 2010).
This content is subject to copyright. Terms and conditions apply.
Dyn Games Appl (2018) 8:507–518
https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-018-0251-0
Voluntary Export Restraints in a Trade Model with
Sticky Price: Linear and Nonlinear Feedback Solutions
Luca Lambertini1·Arsen Palestini2
Published online: 15 March 2018
© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2018
Abstract We revisit the adoption of voluntary export restraints (VERS) in the differential
Cournot game with sticky price and intraindustry trade by Dockner and Haug (Can J Econ
3:679–685, 1991). The analysis relies on linear and nonlinear feedback strategies, to encom-
pass the special cases considered in Fujiwara (Aust Econ Pap 49:101–110, 2010). We show
that a VER may arise in correspondence of any free trade equilibrium generated by feedback
information, when the intensity of competition is at least as strong as under open-loop infor-
mation. The adoption of a VER by a foreign firm also benefits the domestic firm, yielding
an outcome which has a definite collusive flavour. The foreign firm’s incentive to adopt the
VER can be interpreted in the light of the dynamic formulation of conjectural variations due
to Dockner (J Ind Econ 40:377–395, 2010).
Keywords Differential games ·Intraindustry trade ·VER ·Conjectural variations
JEL Classification C73 ·D43 ·F12 ·L13
1 Introduction
The impact and desirability of output restrictions has been lively discussed in the literature
on intraindustry trade, from two main standpoints. The first, at least since Bhagwati [2]and
Shibata [26], considers the equivalence between tariffs and quotas (see also [17,18]; and
We would like to thank two anonymous referees for precious comments and suggestions. The usual
disclaimer applies.
BLuca Lambertini
luca.lambertini@unibo.it
Arsen Palestini
arsen.palestini@uniroma1.it
1Department of Economics, University of Bologna, Strada Maggiore 45, 40125 Bologna, Italy
2MEMOTEF, University of Rome “La Sapienza”, Via del Castro Laurenziano 9, 00161 Rome, Italy
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
... Cellini and Lambertini (2007) considered the duopoly market with different commodities and sticky prices, and established a differential game model competing in the quantities with each other, and further analyze the difference between the feedback and open-loop Nash equilibrium under steady state. Lambertini and Palestini (2018) investigated the adoption of voluntary export restraints (VERSs) in the differential Cournot game with sticky price. The primary difference between this stream of literature and our paper is that we investigate the impacts of players' myopic and farsighted behavior on the pricing strategy and R&D strategy. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper investigates the impacts of sticky price and behavioral choices on the operation decisions, firm's profits, and social welfare. Each player has either myopic behavior or farsighted behavior. Results show that (i) players prefer farsighted behavior , which can achieve the Pareto optimality, and (ii) when both players are farsighted, they will set a higher price but will have an insufficient-effort problem in process innovation. Furthermore, by comparing the social welfare in four different scenarios, we find that the social welfare is the highest when both players are myopic.
Article
The present study seeks to answer the question of whether acting non‐strategically can benefit firms. In a static Cournot framework, if a subset of firms are constrained to the equilibrium level of output, being non‐strategic will have no impact on profits of neither constrained nor strategic firms and provided that sufficiently large number of firms are restricted, a marginal quantity contraction can be to their benefit. In contrast, using a dynamic Cournot framework, we find that the constraint set at the equilibrium level or moderately deviated from it, leads to increased profits for all firms irrespective of the number of non‐strategic ones.
Article
The equivalence of price-modifying and quantity-fixing trade policies is investigated in a differential game. Two capital accumulation rules are employed, by Nerlove and Arrow and by Ramsey, respectively. In both cases, open-loop and closed-loop equilibria coincide and the domestic price equivalence holds at the subgame perfect equilibrium.
Chapter
I propose a differential oligopoly game of resource extraction under linear and nonlinear feedback strategies, where firms are managerial and delegation contract are based on output levels. The model shows that delegation expands the set of stable nonlinear feedback equilibria as well as the residual steady state resource stock. Additionally, the separation between ownership and control mitigates the voracity effect associated with high values of the reproduction rate of the resource.
Article
We revisit Fujiwara’s (2008) linear–quadratic differential duopoly game to show that the degenerate nonlinear feedback identified by the tangency point with the stationary state line is indeed unstable, given the dynamics of the natural resource exploited by firms. To do so, we fully characterise the continuum of nonlinear feedback solution via Rowat’s (2007) method, thereby identifying the infinitely many stable nonlinear feedback equilibria. This entails that Rowat’s method can be used in games where each player’s instantaneous payoff depends quadratically on all players’ controls.
Article
We revisit a recent literature on productive asset exploitation describing a differential oligopoly game of resource extraction under static, linear feedback and nonlinear feedback strategies, where we explicitly allow for the possibility of resource exhaustion. We show that (i) feedback rules entail resource exhaustion for a finite number of firms; and (ii) feedback strategies are more aggressive than static ones as long as the resource stock is large enough, in accordance with the acquired view based on the traditional pre-emption argument associated with feedback information.
Article
International pollution control involving two neighboring countries is modeled as a simple two-player dynamic game. Each country produces a good that is consumed by domestic households. Production of each consumption good results in emissions of pollutants. Households in each country derive utility from the consumption of the domestically produced good but incur costs through the total stock of pollution (stock externality). In this setting we characterize cooperative as well as noncooperative pollution control strategies of the governments of the two countries that maximize the discounted stream of net benefits of a representative consumer. It turns out that when the governments are restricted to use linear strategies noncooperative behavior results in overall losses for both countries. If, on the contrary, governments use nonlinear Markov-perfect strategies and the discount rate is small enough a Pareto-efficient steady-state pollution stock can be supported as a differentiable subgame-perfect equilibrium. Thus, the emergence of first-best solutions (cooperative outcomes) does not require any institutional arrangements (threats, retaliation, etc.) but can be brought about through the use of nonlinear Markov-perfect equilibrium strategies. 20 refs., 1 tab.
Article
In this paper an application of differential game theory in the area of microeconomics is presented. The problem considered is that of a dynamic duopoly where two firms each limited by a maximum capacity of production, share the same market, and try simultaneously but independently to maximize their profits over a certain planning horizon. While the static duopoly theory does not address itself to the question of the process by which changes in the price are brought about, but only compares the prices before and after the change takes place, the dynamic market theory, considered in this paper, allows for an analysis of how the price changes with time and what trajectory it follows. Necessary conditions for the existence of a Nash equilibrium solution in the general case are discussed and more specific results for the special case of linear demand and quadratic cost functions are developed.
Book
Preface 1. From Keynesian to New Keynesian economics. 2. Keynesian microfoundations in historical perspectives. Part I Real Rigidities 3. The labour market and real wage rigiditry. 4. Credit rationing and imperfect capital markets. 5. Real rigidities in the goods market. Part II Nominal Rigidities Introduction 6. Rational models of irrational behaviour. 7. Price setting with adjustment cost. 8. Real and nominal price rigidity: further issues. Part III Coordination Failures and Hysteresis 9. Coordination failures 10. Hysteresis Conclusions.