ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

This article examines the impact of microfinance ‘plus’ (i.e. coordinated combination of financial and nonfinancial services) on the performance of microfinance institutions (MFIs). Using a global data set of MFIs in 77 countries, we find that the provision of nonfinancial services does not harm nor improve MFIs’ financial sustainability and efficiency. The results however suggest that the provision of social services is associated with improved loan quality and greater depth of outreach.
Do Microfinance Institutions Benefit from Integrating Financial and
Nonfinancial Services?
Running head: Effects of microfinance ‘plus’
Robert Lensink
Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Groningen, Development Economics Group,
Wageningen University, The Netherlands.
E-mail: B.W.Lensink@rug.nl; tel: +31503633712
Roy Mersland
School of Business and Law,
University of Agder, Kristiansand, Norway
E-mail: roy.mersland@uia.no
Nhung Thi Hong Vu
College of Economics, Can Tho University, Vietnam
Email: vthnhung@ctu.edu.vn
Stephen Zamore
School of Business and Law,
University of Agder, Kristiansand, Norway
E-mail: stephen.zamore@uia.no
1
Do Microfinance Institutions Benefit from Integrating Financial and Nonfinancial
Services?
Running head: Effects of microfinance ‘plus’
Abstract
This paper examines the impact of microfinance ‘plus’ (i.e., coordinated combination of
financial and nonfinancial services) on the performance of microfinance institutions (MFIs).
Using a global data set of MFIs in 77 countries, we find that the provision of nonfinancial
services does not harm nor improve MFIs’ financial sustainability and efficiency. The results
however suggest that the provision of social services is associated with improved loan quality
and greater depth of outreach.
Keywords: Microfinance ‘plus’; Business development services; Outreach; Financial
sustainability
JEL codes: G21; O16; C23.
1. Introduction
Microfinance aims at providing financial services to low income households and
microenterprises who have been excluded from traditional banking. The achievement of this goal
has been universally recognized (Biosca, Lenton, and Mosley 2014, Balkenhol and Hudon 2011).
Beside this primary social mission of financial inclusion, Microfinance Institutions (MFIs) also
seek to remain financially sustainable. According to Morduch (1999), this is the “win-win”
solution of microfinance. Thus, MFIs are hybrid organization pursuing both social and financial
objectives. Like banks MFIs should be profitable or at least break-even, and like social
2
organizations MFIs should reach out to unbanked clients and enhance their welfare.
In the late 1970s and early 1980s, the provision of financial services to microentrepreneurs
was often done alongside nonfinancial services (social and business development services)
(Goldmark 2006). The social services focused on improving clients’ welfare while the business
development services were offered to teach the clients basic financial management principles.
This was believed to enhance clients’ business success and thereby improve MFI’s loan quality.
This belief was however not supported by early studies such as Kilby and D'Zmura (1985) and
Boomgard (1989).
While some MFIs continue to deliver nonfinancial services in recent times, many others
have phased out the practice since the late 1990s (Goldmark 2006). The focus on only financial
services (minimalist model) could among other things be attributed to low impact of the training
programs and pressure to commercialize microfinance. Often the training programs are counter-
productive because they are either of low quality or do not meet the specific needs of the poor
(Goldmark 2006, Yunus 2007).
Moreover, proponents of the minimalist approach argue that access to credit alone is enough
for the poor to work themselves out of poverty. For instance, Dr Muhammad Yunus, a renowned
pioneer of microfinance, states that “rather than waste our time teaching them new skills, we try
to make maximum use of their existing skills. Giving the poor access to credit allows them to
immediately put into practice the skills they already know” (Yunus 2007, 225). Another
argument for the minimalist approach is that, including ‘‘plus’’ services will have a negative
influence on MFIs’ financial sustainability. This argument is related to the claimed trade-off
between social mission and financial sustainability (Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Morduch 2007,
2011, Hermes, Lensink, and Meesters 2011). This can be described as a “win-loss” situation for
3
the clients and MFIs respectively.
However, the minimalist approach has been reassessed (Lanao-Flores and Serres 2009) with
an increasing conclusion that the “microcredit, by itself, is usually not enough” (Reed 2011, 1).
To this end, some MFIs today still adopt the credit-plus model (what we call microfinance
‘plus’) by bundling financial and nonfinancial services to clients. A typical proponent of this
model is Freedom from Hunger, a U.S.- based village banking organization. Proponents argue
that, the credit-plus model maximizes MFIs’ social impact (Dunford 2001).
About 27 percent of MFIs in our sample adopt a ‘plus’ model while the remaining 73
percent follow the minimalist approach. The fact that some MFIs are specialized while others are
‘plus’ providers offers an interesting research setting. Thus, what we set out to study in this paper
is to investigate whether the microfinance ‘plus’ model is more beneficial than the minimalist
approach in terms of the achievement of MFIs’ social and financial objectives. This has not been
addressed in the academic literature to the best of our knowledge. Empirical literature on the
impact of microfinance ‘plus’ in general is very limited (Biosca, Lenton, and Mosley 2014). In
addition, we adopt several estimation methods to address potential endogeneity.
The relevance of this study is demonstrated by recent concerns that the client’s impact of
accessing stand-alone credit has been overstated (Angelucci, Karlan, and Zinman 2015, Banerjee
et al. 2015). These studies imply that providing only microcredit as a solution to poverty is
probably not adequate. According to Armendáriz and Morduch (2010), poor households benefit
from a combination of services, rather than the simple provision of credit. Similarly, Khandker
(2005) argues that because poverty is multidimensional, poor people need access to a
coordinated combination of both financial and nonfinancial services (e.g., business trainings) to
overcome poverty. Such developmental services are crucial for making credit more productive
4
and impactful for the clients.
The arguments for the importance of the microfinance ‘plus’ (maximalist) approach are
further supported by several studies documenting improved clients’ impact when accessing
credit in combination with nonfinancial services or ‘‘plus’’ services (Copestake, Bhalotra, and
Johnson 2001, Dunford 2001, Halder 2003, Karlan and Valdivia 2011, McKernan 2002,
Noponen and Kantor 2004, Smith 2002). A main problem with these studies, in addition to being
case studies with relatively little external validity, is that they focus on the impact of
microfinance ‘plus’ on clients, without considering the outcomes for the MFIs. In contrast, this
paper uses a global sample to investigate the potential influence of microfinance ‘plus’ on the
MFIs’ performance.
Since controversies persist between the minimalist and maximalist approaches (Bhatt and
Tang 2001, Morduch 2000), it is the aim of this paper to provide policymakers and practitioners
with informed information as to whether the provision of ‘‘plus’’ services influences the
financial and social performance of MFIs. To achieve this aim, the paper focuses on two main
questions: (1) do MFIs that combine financial and nonfinancial services achieve better financial
performance, in terms of financial sustainability, efficiency and portfolio quality, than MFIs that
deliver only financial services? and (2) do microfinance ‘plus’ providers attain better social
performance, in terms of outreach, than their specialist peers?
Using a unique sample of MFIs in 77 countries we find that there is no evidence of
microfinance ‘plus’ influence on financial sustainability and efficiency. The results however
indicate that MFIs that provide social services have higher repayment rates and greater depth of
outreach than those that do not. Thus, bundling financial services with nonfinancial further
enhance the outreach mission of MFIs (Dunford 2001).
5
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we discuss the concept of microfinance ‘plus’
and then provide a conceptual framework on the impact of such services on performance. This
precedes the hypothesis development. Section 3 presents the data and the specific variables used
in the estimation. Section 4 outlines the estimation procedure taking into account endogeneity
concerns. Section 5 presents and discusses the empirical results while Section 6 concludes the
paper with some remarks for practitioners and policymakers.
2. Conceptual Framework: Influence of Microfinance ‘Plus’ on MFI Performance
2.1 The Concept of Microfinance ‘plus’
Microfinance ‘plus’ services are any activities aside financial services (Goldmark 2006) targeted
at improving both the welfare of poor people and their businesses. An overall understanding of
the concept is relatively straightforward, but a more detailed explanation is also possible. For
example, an MFI that provides savings, insurance, or money transfers together with loans is not
involved in microfinance ‘plus’, because all its services are financial in nature. An MFI that
provides informational sessions to potential clients or trains existing clients in the use of credit or
the importance of repayment is not practicing microfinance ‘plus’, nor is an MFI that partners
with another organization that provides clients with ‘plus’ services. Rather, a ‘plus’ service refers
specifically to a nonfinancial service provided by the MFI itself.
Various MFIs offer a wide variety of ‘plus’ services, ranging from access to markets and
business development services (BDS) to health provision and literacy training (Goldmark 2006,
Maes and Foose 2006). In most cases, these ‘plus’ services are either BDS or social services
(Goldmark 2006). The former aims to boost competitiveness by improving productivity, product
design, service delivery or market access (Sievers and Vandenberg 2007). These services include
6
(but not limited to) management or vocational skills trainings, technical and marketing assistance
(Sievers and Vandenberg 2007, Goldmark 2006). Social services (e.g. health, nutrition,
education, etc.) on the other hand are intended to raise the general welfare of clients.
2.2 Conceptual Framework for the Effects of Microfinance ‘plus’
Empirical studies on the impact of microfinance ‘plus’ programs on microenterprises are limited
(Biosca, Lenton, and Mosley 2014). One of the earliest studies that evaluated the influence of
‘plus’ services in microfinance is McKernan (2002) who finds positive effect of such services on
clients’ profitability. Other impact studies include Smith ( 2002) Bjorvatn and Tungodden
(2010), Karlan and Valdivia (2011) McKenzie and Woodruff (2013), among others. The findings
of these and other studies range from no significant impact of microfinance ‘plus’ to mixed
effects. However, what seem not to be taken into account is that nonfinancial services have the
potential to influence not only the outcome for the clients but may also influence the
performance of the MFI (Sievers and Vandenberg 2007).
Thus, this study examines the influence of microfinance ‘plus’ on the institution itself and
not on the clients. Although no clear-cut theory exists on the link between microfinance ‘plus’
and performance, we can use different theories from extant literature to derive a framework that
demonstrates potential outcomes of microfinance ‘plus’ (Figure 1). Specifically, we argue that
microfinance ‘plus’ services may have both positive and negative outcomes on the performance
of MFIs. By providing ‘plus’ services, an MFI could benefit from client loyalty, potential
clients, high repayment rates, self-sustainability, better social outreach, and greater access to
client information (see top of Figure 1). On the other hand, the microfinance ‘plus’ model comes
with some challenges for the provider. Among other things, the MFI may suffer from increased
7
costs, resource constraints and lower client retention. (see bottom of Figure 1).
[Figure 1 near here]
Client loyalty. A key benefit of adding ‘plus’ services to microfinance is the stimulation of
client loyalty (Sievers and Vandenberg 2007). If the ‘plus’ services improve client satisfaction,
they should help increase retention rates. Such an increase in retention rate was confirmed by
Karlan and Valdivia (2011) in their randomized control trial study from Peru Another example
from Financiera Solucion, also shows that the institution benefits from including management
training because it can better retain clients (Sievers and Vandenberg 2007) which is of course
beneficial for the MFI (Reichheld 1996).
Potential clients. MFIs providing nonfinancial services have the opportunity to earn a
comparative advantage in terms of attracting new clients (Khandker 2005, Mosley and Hulme
1998) especially in the increasing competition in microfinance markets (McIntosh and Wydick
2005). Attracting more clients improves the financial sustainability of the MFI because of scale
economies (Hartarska, Shen, and Mersland 2013). And, obviously, having more clients could be
equated with greater breadth of microfinance outreach mission.
High repayment rates. Microfinance ‘plus’ can help reduce the risk of default. Relevant
training programs could for example increase the clients’ business success while trainings on
how to invest loans could help borrowers avoid using loans for consumption purpose rather than
productive activities (Marconi and Mosley 2006). For instance, Karlan and Valdivia (2011) find
some evidence of improved repayment rates arising from microfinance ‘plus’. Giné and Mansuri
(2014) however do not find evidence of improved repayment rates following clients’
participation in business training programs.
Self-sustainability. Since borrowers are often limited by their lack of knowledge they often
8
end up doing petty trade where even negative return on capital is a possible outcome (De Mel,
McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008). ‘Plus’ services may motivate better investments with higher
potential returns which could enhance loan repayment rates. Likewise, with improved human
capital the clients may be able to service bigger loans which enhances the financial performance
of MFIs (Hartarska, Shen, and Mersland 2013). Finally, ‘plus’ services might be offered for a
fee resulting in a positive profit margin for the MFI (Sievers and Vandenberg 2007).
Greater social outreach. By providing ‘plus’ services an MFI maximizes its social mission
with a wide range of social services such as health education (Dunford 2001). Although MFIs
aim to reach poor people, most of them access the ‘upper poor’ more than the ‘very poor’
(Mosley 2001). In addition, pressure from governments and donors to ensure financial
sustainability leads many MFIs to ignore social protection objectives and target less risky clients.
Therefore, a major argument in support of the microfinance ‘plus’ approach is that it might
enable MFIs to reach poorer and more vulnerable clients compared to the minimalist model
(Halder 2003, Maes and Foose 2006). After all, other antipoverty modalities including primary
health and education may be more effective than microfinance when wishing to enhance the
welfare of the poorest sectors (Mosley 2001). Of course, providing ‘plus’ services is not devoid
of potential disadvantages for the MFI as outlined in the following.
Increased costs. The microfinance ‘plus’ approach may come with additional operational
and administrative costs for the MFI. A study of four Freedom from Hunger affiliates reveals
that the direct cost of including learning sessions, related to family, health, nutrition, business
development and self-confidence, accounted for between 4.7 and 10 percent of each MFI’s
operational costs (Vor der Bruegge, Dickey, and Dunford 1999). Also Dunford (2001)
documents that combining financial and education services offers benefits for borrowers but
9
increases the costs for the MFI.
Additional resources required. The provision of ‘plus’ services requires additional resources
(e.g., time, money, staff, etc.) from the institution. It increases administrative burdens and may
distract managers and other staff from credit administration, which could decrease repayment
rates (Berger 1989). Since many MFIs are already struggling with being financially self-
sustainable, adopting the maximalist model may make them worse-off. Probably, the difficulty in
being self-sustainable makes some MFIs unwilling to incorporate nonfinancial services into their
business models.
Lower client retention. Just as the provision of specific and relevant ‘plus’ services could
lead to client loyalty, poor quality or irrelevance of such services could also lead to client
dissatisfaction. Some evidence shows that microfinance borrowers do not consider training
useful and do not retain or apply their acquired knowledge, such that time spent in training
appears to be an opportunity cost for credit (Goldmark 2006). In this regards, dissatisfied clients
are more likely to stop doing business with ‘plus’ providers (Sievers and Vandenberg 2007). On
the other hand, the positive outcomes of business training on clients’ business success may also
result in reduced client retention because successful microenterprises may progress to the formal
banking sector (Karlan and Valdivia 2011).
Based on the conceptual framework above, we formulate our testable hypotheses. Given that
providers of ‘plus’ services benefit from client loyalty, possibility to attract new clients, and
income realized from demand-driven ‘plus’ services, our first hypothesis is that MFIs providing
‘plus’ services are likely to perform financially better than specialized MFIs.
Second, there is some evidence that ‘plus’ services, especially BDS, may improve the
creditworthiness of borrowers resulting in higher repayment rates (e.g., Karlan and Valdivia
10
2011). Therefore, we hypothesize that repayment rates in MFIs providing ‘plus’ services are
higher than in specialized MFIs. Since the positive creditworthiness effect probably holds only
for BDS providers, and not for SS ‘plus’ providers, we hypothesize that BDS ‘plus’ providers are
more effective in improving financial performance than SS ‘plus’ providers.
Third, many studies (e.g., Vor der Bruegge et al. 1999, Dunford 2001) suggest that ‘plus’
services come with additional costs for the institutions. Therefore, we hypothesize that ‘plus’
providers will experience higher costs ratios than specialists.
Finally, we hypothesize that ‘plus’ providers perform better socially than MFIs providing
only financial services. Moreover, to distinguish which ‘plus’ services lead to higher social
performance, we hypothesize that the social performance of SS providers is better than for BDS
providers. However, we must highlight that there are potential trade-offs between social and
financial performance of MFIs (Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Morduch 2011) which could become
evident in our results.
3. Data and variables definitions
3.1 Data
The dataset is hand-collected from rating reports from the five leading rating agencies in the
microfinance industry; i.e. Microrate, Microfinanza, Planet Rating, Crisil and M-CRIL. The
rating reports are narratives consisting of contextual and MFI specific information including
accounting details, organizational features and benchmarks. The reports are not fully
standardized and therefore differ in their emphasis and in the amount of information available.
The result is that not all reports have information on all variables. When necessary, all numbers
in the dataset have been annualized and dollarized using the official exchange rates from the
11
given time. All together we used observations of 478 rated MFIs from 77 countries1 spanning the
period 1998–2012.
No dataset is perfectly representative of the microfinance field. Ours contains relatively
fewer mega-sized MFIs and does not cover all small savings and credit cooperatives. The former
are rated by agencies such as Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s; the latter are not rated. However,
our use of rating reports should be relevant for studying the effects of microfinance ‘plus’,
because MFIs that are rated have a common interest in accessing funding and increasing their
sustainability. The data set includes specialists and providers of ‘plus’ services, so it enables
meaningful comparisons. For a further description of the dataset please see Beisland and
Mersland (2012).
3.2 Variables definitions
Dependent variables
We focus on financial sustainability, efficiency and portfolio quality as measures of financial
performance and outreach as a measure of the social performance of MFIs.
Financial sustainability measures. We consider the operational self-sufficiency ratio (OSS)
as a main indicator of financial performance. This ratio demonstrates the ability of MFIs to be
fully sustainable in the long run, in the sense that they can cover all their operating costs and
maintain the value of their capital. As a robustness check, we include financial self-sufficiency
(FSS) and return on assets (ROA) measures. Operational self-sufficiency, financial self-
sufficiency and return on assets have been used widely to measure the financial sustainability of
MFIs (Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Morduch 2007, 2011, Mersland and Strøm 2009).
Efficiency measures. We use four indicators for efficiency. The operating expense ratio
1 The number of MFIs per country is avaiable from the authors upon request.
12
which measures the MFI’s operating expenses compared with the annual average loan portfolio.
A decrease in this ratio implies an increase in efficiency. Since MFIs offering small loans will
look worse than MFIs offering large loans we also include the cost per client variable
(Rosenberg 2009). Next, we employ the ratio of credit clients per loan officer as well as credit
clients per staff member to evaluate how ‘plus’ activities influence the employment of personnel
resources in the MFI.
Loan portfolio quality measures. We use two indicators of portfolio quality. First, the
portfolio at risk beyond 30 days (PAR30) reveals the potential for future losses based on the
current performance of the portfolio. Second, the write-off ratio measures the actual amount of
loans that have been written off as unrecoverable during a given period of time, in relation to the
outstanding loan portfolio. The variables have been used in previous studies (e.g., D'Espallier,
Guerin, and Mersland (2011)).
Social performance measures. To evaluate social performance, we use three indicators of
outreach: number of clients, average loan size and percentage of women clients. First, the
number of clients serves as a proxy for the ‘breadth of outreach’ (Rosenberg 2009, Schreiner
2002). For the ‘depth of outreach’, i.e. economic poverty level of the clients, we apply average
loan size and share of female borrowers. We recognize that average loan size and share of
female borrowers are rough proxies for ‘depth of outreach’ (for a discussion of their
shortcomings see Armendariz and Szafarz, 2011), though still the most commonly used variables
to measure clients poverty level (Hermes, Lensink, and Meesters 2011, Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt,
and Morduch 2009, 2007, Ahlin, Lin, and Maio 2011, Schreiner 2002, Mersland and Strøm
2009).
13
Independent variables
We distinguish three types of MFI services: (1) specialized financial services only, (2) financial
services and BDS and (3) financial services and social services (SS). We include BDS and SS
dummies, as well as a constant in our estimates. BDS equals 1 if the MFI provides business
development services and 0 otherwise. Similarly, SS equals 1 if the MFI provides social services
and 0 otherwise.
Control variables
To control for macroeconomic institutional differences we include annual percentage growth rate
of gross domestic product (GDP) (based on constant 2005 U.S. dollars) ( GDP growth) and
inflation (Claessens, Demirguc-Kunt, and Huizinga 2001, Lensink and Hermes 2004). To further
control for country influence we include the countries’ scores on the human development index
(HDI). HDI is a composite index that combines three dimensions of human development:
education, economy and life expectancy. Finally, we include regional as well time dummies in
all estimations.
To control for MFI-specific characteristics, we include number of credit officers since the
number of field officers may be driving the results and not the ‘plus’ service itself. We further
control for the size by including the total assets of the MFI. The lending methodology, either
group based or individual has the potential to influence efficiency levels, repayment as well as
outreach, thus we include group lending as a control variable regarding the repayment of credits
(Hulme and Mosley 1996, Morduch 1999). It enhances the repayment rates due to peer pressure
from other group members (Ledgerwood 1999). Furthermore, it is cost-efficient to offer group
loans due to scale economies. Group loans are less risky than are those to individuals because of
14
better screening, monitoring, auditing and enforcement (Ghatak and Guinnane 1999). Thus, we
expect MFIs offering group loans to have improved portfolio quality and high efficiency than
those offering individual loans. Also, in line with Mersland, Randøy, and Strøm (2011) and
Mersland, D’espallier, and Supphellen (2013), we control for MFI experience (age), whether the
MFI is a member of an international network, and whether it was initiated by a religious
organization. Finally, we control for the organizational form of the MFI (NGO, Bank,
Cooperative, and Non-Bank financial institution, and state banks). Table 1 presents a summary
of all the variables.
[Table 1 near here]
4. Estimation approach
We employ panel data modelling to examine the potential effects of microfinance ‘plus’ on the
financial and social performance of MFIs. Thus, we specify our panel model as follows:
yijt=β0+β1BDSijt +β2SSijt +γ M jt +τ MFijt +ci+εijt
(1)
where the dependent variable yijt is a measure of financial and social performance of the ith MFI
located in country jth at time t, and β0 is a constant term. BDSijt equals 1 if the ith MFI is a ‘plus’
provider that integrates BDS and 0 if it is a specialist or a ‘plus’ provider that integrates social
services in country j at time t; SSijt equals 1 if the ith MFI is a ‘plus’ provider of social services
and 0 if it is a specialist or ‘plus’ provider that integrates BDS in country j at time t. Furthermore,
Mjt is a vector of control variables describing the macroeconomic environment in country j at
time t; MFijt is a vector of control variables describing the features of the ith MFI in county jth at
time t;
i
c
is the MFI’s individual unobserved effects; and εijt is mean-zero errors.
First, we use the random effects model (RE) because our main variables of interest (i.e.,
15
BDS and SS) are time invariant and a fixed effects model (FE) is impossible. However, the
rejections of Hausman test null hypothesis in our results show that FE is consistent. Therefore,
our second estimator is the Hausman-Taylor’s (HT). This estimator distinguishes between
regressors that are uncorrelated with FEs and those that are potentially correlated with them.
Hausman and Taylor (1981) suggest using an economics intuition to determine which variables
should be treated as potentially correlated with the FE. The model also distinguishes time-
varying from time-invariant regressors. The model is as follows.
yijt=β0+X1ijt β1+X2ijt β2
+
W1ij γ1+W2ij γ2+ci+εijt
(2)
where the dependent variable yijt is a measure of performance of the ith MFI located in country j
at time t; β0 is a constant term; X denotes time-varying regressors: Inflation, GDP growth, MFI
size, MFI experience, Credit officers, HDI, and W denote time-invariant regressors; International
network, Religious organization, BDS, SS, Group lending, Coop, bank, NGO, non-bank and
i
c
are MFI-specific unobserved effects; and εijt is idiosyncratic errors. Regressors with subscripts 1
are uncorrelated with
i
c
, whereas those with subscripts 2 are specified as correlated with
i
c
. All
regressors are assumed uncorrelated with εijt .2
The MFI’s choice to integrate financial and ‘plus’ services depends substantially on its
specific characteristics. Therefore, we treat BDS and SS as endogenous. We similarly assume
that group lending is endogenous and must be instrumented. The same holds for the number of
credit officers. Group lending offers an excellent platform for the delivery of ‘plus’ services
alongside microfinance (MkNelly et al. 1996). The decision to provide individual or group
lending also depends on the presence of some MFI-specific characteristics. The remaining
2The Hausman and Taylor (1981) estimator assumes that the exogenous variables serve as their own instruments;
X2ijt
is instrumented by its deviation from individual means; and
W
2ij
is instrumented by
X
1ij
.
16
control variables are treated as exogenous.
The validity of instruments used in the Hausman-Taylor model is tested by Sargan-Hansen
test of overidentifying restrictions. The null hypothesis of this test is that the instruments are
valid. If the test results reject the null hypothesis (which is the case in this study), it suggests that
there are endogeneity problems other than fixed effects. This leads us to the use of Blundell and
Bond (1998) system GMM (generalised method of moments) estimator which uses lagged
differences of the dependent variable as instruments for equations in levels, in addition to lagged
levels of dependent variable for equations in the first differences (Baltagi 2013).
5. Results and discussions
5.1 Descriptive statistics and correlations
Table 2 presents descriptive statistics of all variables used in the estimations. On average, an
MFI can cover operational costs from revenue 1.13 times, indicating that the MFI is self-
sustainable. However, OSS does not depict the intrinsic self-sustainability of the MFI because of
the presence of subsidies and that is what FSS corrects for. The mean value for FSS is 0.95
which shows that on average, MFIs in our sample are not financially self-sustainable. Returns on
assets has a mean value of 2.4 percent. In terms of outreach, the average MFI has about 15000
clients of which 66 percent are women and the average loan amount disbursed (scaled by GDP
per capita) is USD 1.30. With respect to loan quality, on average, about 6 percent of the total
loan portfolio is in arrears over 30 days and 1.4 percent is written off as loan loss. Concerning
efficiency dimension, an MFI has on average, operational costs of 25 percent of gross loan
portfolio, cost per client of USD 118.65, 132 borrowers per staff, and 272 borrowers per loan
officer.
17
[Table 2 near here]
Furthermore, about 25 and 26 percent of MFIs offer business development and social
services respectively. The average MFI has about: USD 11.3 million of total assets, 10 years of
industry experience and 38 credit officers. Approximately 37 percent of the MFIs are members
of an international network, 17 percent of them (MFIs) were started by religious organisations
and 19 percent offer group loans only. In terms of legal status, about 51 percent of the MFIs are
NGOs, 29 percent are nonbank financial institutions, 13 percent are cooperatives and 5 percent
are banks. Finally, the mean values for GDP growth, inflation and HDI are 5.2 percent, 6.1
percent and 0.606 respectively3.
5.2 The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and MFI performance: random effects
First, we present the results of the RE estimator. Table 3 presents estimates of the effects of
microfinance ‘plus’ on financial sustainability. The statistics show that we pass the Hausman’s
test in models (1) and (2) as the p-values are greater than 0.05 but fail in model (3) because the
p-value is less than 0.05. The Wald’s chi-squared test is significant showing that our models are
correctly specified, and our regressors explain up to 27 percent of the variance of the outcome
variables (model 2) and as low as 17 percent (model 3). The results show that BDS and SS are
statistically insignificant suggesting that they have no effect on the financial sustainability of
MFIs.
As for the control variables we observe that HDI is negatively associated with the FSS while
MFI size significantly enhances financial sustainability. As expected, inflation reduces financial
self-sustainability of MFIs because it increases their cost of production. The results further
3 Testing (unreported) for multicollinearity problems indicates that none of the correlation values are above cut-off
point of 0.90 (Hair et al. 2010). The only correlation close to the cut-off point is that of BDS and SS (0.84)
indicating that if MFIs offer ‘plus’ services they often offer both BDS and SS.
18
indicate that MFIs with large number of loan officers tend to reduce financial sustainability in
terms of OSS, FSS and ROA. Similarly, MFIs with religious orientation have lower financial
sustainability compared to those without, while group lending is associated with increased ROA.
Finally we observe than any ownership type is better than being state owned when it comes to
financial sustainability. Finally, group lending is associated with increased returns on assets.
[Table 3 near here]
Table 4 also presents RE results on the link between microfinance ‘plus’ and efficiency.
Like in Table 3, BDS and SS are not significant and thus, have no effect on MFIs’ efficiency.4
[Table 4 near here]
Next, we provide the RE estimates on the link between microfinance ‘plus’ and loan quality.
Table 5 lists the results and it is clearly shown that BDS does not affect loan quality in terms of
portfolio at risk and write-offs but SS has positive outcome on the former suggesting that
providing social services enhances repayment rates. Our interpretation is that the provision of
social services enhances clients’ loyalty and therefore also their repayment of loans. Thus, clients
find the SS services relevant. The finding that MFIs do not improve repayment rates over time is
not necessarily surprising since more experienced MFIs can allow a larger share of their clients
to be in arrears.
[Table 5 near here]
Table 6 presents the last set of RE estimates on the link between microfinance ‘plus’ and
social performance. SS is significantly and positively related to women suggesting that the
provision of social services maximizes MFIs’ outreach efforts (Dunford 2001). BDS on the other
hand is insignificant and hence has no effect on social performance.
[Table 6 near here]
4 Because of space constraints we do not comment on the control variables included in tables 4, 5 and 6.
19
5.3 The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and MFI performance: fixed effects present
The results of the Hausman’s specification test presented in Tables 3-6 suggest that there are
fixed effects as we did not pass the test in some of the models (e.g.,3, 4, 5). To account for fixed
effects, we use the HT estimator which uses exogenous regressors as instruments. The results for
the financial sustainability are presented in Table 7 while the results for the efficiency,
repayment and outreach effects are available from authors upon request. We pass the Sargan-
Hansen test with p-values greater 0.05 in all models (Table 7) suggesting that our instruments are
valid. We however fail the test especially in three models for efficiency (unreported). Generally,
the results in the HT models mirror those of the random effects models reported in tables 3-6
the provision of ‘plus’ services does not have significant effect on the MFI’s performance.
However, the rejection of the null hypothesis of valid instruments suggests that the results may
be biased; there are real endogeneity problems aside fixed effects. Next, we employ the system
GMM to account for potential endogeneity issues.
[Table 7 near here]
5.4 The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and MFI performance: endogeneity present
Table 8 reports system GMM results on the link between microfinance ‘plus’ and financial
sustainability of MFIs. The statistics show that there is first-order serial correlation as the p-
values of AR(1) are all less than 0.05 but no second-order serial correlation (p-values>0.05). We
pass the Hansen’s test of overidentifying restrictions indicating joint validity of instruments set
(all p-values > 0.05). All the lags of the dependent variables are statistically significant at least at
the 5 percent level. Once again, neither BDS nor SS are significantly associated with the
20
financial sustainability confirming the results previously reported. Likewise, we find that the
GMM regressions do not result in significant findings for the effect of BDS or SS on the
efficiency, repayment or social outreach of the MFI (unreported).
[Table 8 near here]
A concern with the system GMM estimates relates primarily to our time-invariant regressors
(i.e., BDS and SS) as their lagged values cannot be used as instruments because their lagged first
differences are zero. This leaves us with first differences of time-varying variables which
unfortunately cannot be valid instruments either because they suffer from Nickell’s bias (Nickell
1981) and do not also correlate sufficiently with the observed BDS and SS. Thus, the estimates
of the system GMM are also problematic. Therefore, the random effects estimates are preferred
because of the nature of our variables of interests which get wiped out if the fixed effects model
is used and their estimation in the HT model is not appropriate due to invalidity of instruments.
In any case, results from the three estimators (RE, HT and system GMM) suggest that
microfinance ‘plus’ do not influence overall performance of MFIs. Only in few cases the RE
estimates provide some evidence of improved loan quality and outreach and thus support our
hypotheses on these dimensions of performance.
6. Conclusion
This paper set out to examine the potential impact of microfinance ‘plus’ on the financial and
social performance of microfinance institutions (MFIs). Impact studies of nonfinancial services
have always used the clients as their unit of analysis. In contrast, this paper focuses on the
providers of ‘plus’ services. Using a unique global sample of MFIs and an arsenal of estimation
methods, we find insignificant impact of business development services on MFIs’ financial and
social performance. Furthermore, we find only meagre evidence of improved loan quality and
21
outreach with the provision of social services. Specifically, providing social services comes
with lower portfolio at risk and more women clients though these findings are not stable across
estimation methods.
Thus, this paper provides a first-hand information on the outcome of microfinance ‘plus’
from the perspective of the providers. Overall, it appears there is no performance disparity for
those MFIs providing ‘plus’ services and those that do not. Perhaps, the benefits of microfinance
‘plus’ might have been neutralised by the disadvantages associated with it, hence, leaving a
negligible net impact on MIFs’ performance.
The no-results reported in this study actually offers important policy lessons for MFIs. With
this information, microfinance practitioners are informed that, adopting the maximalist approach
causes no harm on their overall financial and social performance. Thus, if the ‘plus’ services are
of value for the customers the provision of such does not harm the performance of the MFI. We
do however recognize that the design and the cost structure of the ‘plus’ service does of course
influence the outcome for the client as well as the MFI. Our study only shows that MFIs offering
‘plus’ services today have on average been able to design these in such a way that they do not
harm the performance of the MFIs. We thus recommend future studies to look deeper into how
the design and cost structure of ‘plus’ services have an influence on the MFI performance.
Likewise, an interesting area for future researchers could be an investigation of how “smart
subsidies” (Morduch 2007) might account for the additional costs of providing ‘plus’ services, as
well as how coordinated nonfinancial services provided by non-MFIs, in cooperation with MFIs,
might influence MFI performance. Finally, like Berge, Bjorvatn, and Tungodden (2014), studies
are much warranted on whether or not different ‘plus’ services actually enhance clients’
impacts.
22
References
Ahlin, C., J. Lin, and M. Maio. 2011. "Where does Microfinance Flourish? Microfinance Institution Performance in
Macroeconomic Context." Journal of Development Economics 95 (2):105–120.
Angelucci, Manuela, Dean Karlan, and Jonathan Zinman. 2015. "Microcredit impacts: Evidence from a randomized
microcredit program placement experiment by Compartamos Banco." American Economic Journal:
Applied Economics 7 (1):151-182.
Armendáriz, Beatriz, and Jonathan Morduch. 2010. The Economics of Microfinance. 2 ed. Cambridge, MA, USA:
The MIT Press.
Balkenhol, Bernd, and Marek Hudon. 2011. "Efficiency." In The Handbook of Microfinance, edited by Beatriz
Armendáriz and Marc Labie. Singapore: World Scientific Publishing Co.
Baltagi, Badi H. 2013. Econometric analysis of panel data 4ed. Chichester, England: John Wiley & Sons.
Banerjee, Abhijit, Esther Duflo, Rachel Glennerster, and Cynthia Kinnan. 2015. "The miracle of microfinance?
Evidence from a randomized evaluation." American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 7 (1):22-53.
Beisland, Leif A., and Roy Mersland. 2012. "Do microfinance rating assessments make sense? An analysis of the
drivers of the MFI ratings." Nonprofit & Voluntary Sector Quarterly 41 (2):213–231.
Berge, Lars Ivar Oppedal, Kjetil Bjorvatn, and Bertil Tungodden. 2014. "Human and financial capital for
microenterprise development: Evidence from a field and lab experiment." Management Science 61
(4):707-722.
Berger, Marguerite. 1989. "Giving women credit: The strengths and limitations of credit as a tool for alleviating
poverty." World development 17 (7):1017-1032.
Bhatt, N., and S. Y. Tang. 2001. "Delivering microfinance in developing countries: Controversies and policy
perspectives." Policy Studies Journal 29 (2):319-333.
Biosca, Olga, Pamela Lenton, and Paul Mosley. 2014. "Where is the ‘Plus’ in ‘Credit-Plus’? The Case of Chiapas,
Mexico." The Journal of Development Studies 50 (12):1700-1716.
Bjorvatn, Kjetil, and Bertil Tungodden. 2010. "Teaching business in Tanzania: Evaluating participation and
performance." Journal of the European Economic Association 8 (2‐3):561-570.
Boomgard, James J. 1989. AID microenterprise stock-taking: Synthesis report: Agency for International
Development.
Claessens, S., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and H. Huizinga. 2001. "How does foreign entry affect domestic banking
markets?" Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (5):891-911.
Copestake, J., S. Bhalotra, and S. Johnson. 2001. "Assessing the impact of microcredit: A Zambian case study."
Journal of Development Studies 37 (4):81-100.
Cull, Robert, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Jonathan Morduch. 2007. "Financial performance and outreach: A global
analysis of leading microbanks." Economic Journal 117 (517):F107-F133.
Cull, Robert, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Jonathan Morduch. 2009. "Microfinance meets the market." The Journal of
Economic Perspectives 23 (1):167-192.
Cull, Robert, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Jonathan Morduch. 2011. "Microfinance Trade-Offs: Regulation,
Competition and Financing." In, edited by B. Armendariz and M. Labie, 141-157. Washington, D.C: World
Scientific Publishing.
D'Espallier, Bert, Isabelle Guerin, and Roy Mersland. 2011. "Women and repayment in Microfinance." World
Development 39 (5):758-772.
De Mel, Suresh, David McKenzie, and Christopher Woodruff. 2008. "Returns to capital in microenterprises:
evidence from a field experiment." The Quarterly Journal of Economics:1329-1372.
Dunford, Christopher. 2001. "Building better lives: Sustainable integration of microfinance and education in child
survival, reproductive health, and HIV/AIDS prevention for the poorest entrepreneurs." Journal of
Microfinance/ESR Review 3 (2):1-25.
Ghatak, Maitreesh, and Timothy W Guinnane. 1999. "The economics of lending with joint liability: theory and
practice." Journal of development economics 60 (1):195-228.
Giné, Xavier, and Ghazala Mansuri. 2014. "Money or ideas? A field experiment on constraints to entrepreneurship
in rural Pakistan." A Field Experiment on Constraints to Entrepreneurship in Rural Pakistan (June 1,
2014). World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6959).
Goldmark, Lara. 2006. "Beyond Finance: Microfi nance and Business Development Services." In An inside view of
Latin American microfinance, edited by Marguerite Berger, Goldmark Lara and Miller Sanabria Tomás.
Washington DC: Inter-American Development Bank
23
Gulli, Hege. 1998. Microfinance and poverty: Questioning the conventional wisdom. Washington, D.C: Inter-
American Development Bank.
Halder, S.R. . 2003. "Poverty outreach and BRAC's microfinance interventions: Programme impact and
sustainability." IDS Bulletin 34:44–53.
Hartarska, Valentina, Xuan Shen, and Roy Mersland. 2013. "Scale economies and input price elasticities in
microfinance institutions." Journal of Banking & Finance 37:118-131.
Hausman, Jerry A, and William E Taylor. 1981. "Panel data and unobservable individual effects." Econometrica:
Journal of the Econometric Society:1377-1398.
Hermes, Niels, Robert Lensink, and Aljar Meesters. 2011. "Outreach and Efficiency of Microfinance Institutions."
World Development 39 (6):938-948. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.10.018.
Hulme, David , and Paul Mosley. 1996. Finance Against Poverty Vol. 1. London: Routledge
Jeans, A. , and O. Ruthven. 1996. Sarvodya: REDS Project Completion Report1993-96. London: ODA Joint
Funding Scheme.
Karlan, D., and M. Valdivia. 2011. "Teaching Entrepreneurship: Impact of Business Training on Microfinance
Institutions and Clients." The Review of Economics and Statistics 93 (2):510-527.
Khandker, Shahidur R. 2005. "Microfinance and poverty: Evidence using panel data from Bangladesh." The World
Bank Economic Review 19 (2):263-286.
Kilby, Peter, and David D'Zmura. 1985. Searching for benefits: US Agency for International Development.
Lanao-Flores, I, and P Serres. 2009. "Microfinance and non-financial services: An impossible marriage?" Private
Sector Development 3 (3):1-6.
Ledgerwood, Joana. 1999. Microfinance handbook: an institutional and financial perspective. Washington, D. C.:
World Bank.
Lensink, R., and N. Hermes. 2004. "The short-term effects of foreign bank entry on domestic bank behaviour: Does
economic development matter?" Journal of Banking & Finance 28 (3):553-568. doi: Doi 10.1016/S0378-
4266(02)00393-X.
Maes, Jan, and Laura Foose. 2006. "Microfinance and Non-Financial Services for the very Poor: Digging Deeper to
Find Keys to Success." Washington: Seep Network—Poverty Outreach Working Group.
Marconi, Reynaldo, and Paul Mosley. 2006. "Bolivia during the global crisis 1998–2004: towards a
‘macroeconomics of microfinance’." Journal of International Development 18 (2):237-261.
McIntosh, Craig, and Bruce Wydick. 2005. "Competition and microfinance." Journal of development economics 78
(2):271-298.
McKenzie, David, and Christopher Woodruff. 2013. "What are we learning from business training and
entrepreneurship evaluations around the developing world?" The World Bank Research Observer:lkt007.
McKernan, Signe-Mary. 2002. "The Impact of Microcredit Programs on Self-Employment Profits: Do Noncredit
Program Aspects Matter?" The Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (1):93-115. doi:
10.1162/003465302317331946.
Mersland, Roy, Bert D’espallier, and Magne Supphellen. 2013. "The effects of religion on development efforts:
Evidence from the microfinance industry and a research agenda." World Development 41:145-156.
Mersland, Roy, Trond Randøy, and Reidar Øystein Strøm. 2011. "The impact of international influence on
microbanks’ performance: A global survey." International Business Review 20 (2):163-176.
Mersland, Roy, and Øystein R. Strøm. 2009. "Performance and governance in microfinance institutions." Journal
of Banking & Finance 33 (4):662–669.
MkNelly, B., C. Watetip, C.A. Lassen, and C. Dunford. 1996. Preliminary evidence that integrated financial and
educational services can be effective against hunger and malnutrition. Research paper series 2.
Morduch, Jonathan. 1999. "The Microfinance Promise." Journal of Economic Literature XXXVII:1569–1614.
Morduch, Jonathan. 2000. "The Microfinance Schism." World Development 28 (4):617–629.
Morduch, Jonathan. 2007. "Smart subsidies." In Microfinance and Public Policy: Outreach, Performance and
Efficiency, edited by Bernd Balkenhol, 72-85. UK: Palgrave Macmillan
Mosley, P. 2001. "Microfinance and Poverty in Bolivia." The Journal of Development Studies 37 (4):101-132. doi:
10.1080/00220380412331322061.
Mosley, Paul, and David Hulme. 1998. "Microenterprise finance: is there a conflict between growth and poverty
alleviation?" World development 26 (5):783-790.
Nickell, Stephen. 1981. "Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects." Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric
Society:1417-1426.
Noponen, Helzi, and Paula Kantor. 2004. "Crises, setbacks and chronic problems—the determinants of economic
stress events among poor households in India." Journal of International Development 16 (4):529-545. doi:
24
10.1002/jid.1076.
Reed, Larry R. 2011. "State of the microcredit summit campaign report 2011." Microcredit Summit Campaign.
Washington DC.
Reichheld, Frederick F. 1996. The loyalty effect: The hidden force behind growth, profits and lasting value . Boston,
MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Roodman, David. 2009. "How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata." Stata
Journal 9 (1):86-136.
Rosenberg, Richard, ed. 2009. Measuring Results of Microfinance Institutions: Minimum Indicators That Donors
and Investors Should Track, A Technical Guide. Washington, DC 20433 USA: Consultative Group to
Assist the Poor/The World Bank.
Schreiner, Mark. 2002. "Aspects of outreach: a framework for discussion of the social benefits of microfinance."
Journal of International Development 14 (5):591-603. doi: 10.1002/jid.908.
Sievers, Merten, and Paul Vandenberg. 2007. "Synergies through linkages: Who benefits from linking micro-finance
and business development services?" World Development 35 (8):1341-1358.
Smith, Stephen C. 2002. "Village Banking and Maternal and Child Health: Evidence from Ecuador and Honduras "
World Development 30 (4):707-723 doi: 10.1016/S0305-750X(01)00128-0
Vor der Bruegge, Ellen, Joan E Dickey, and Christopher Dunford. 1999. "Cost of Education in the Freedom from
Hunger version of Credit with Education Implementation." Research Paper 6.
Yunus, Muhammad. 2007. Banker to the poor. India: Penguin Books.
Microfinance ‘plus’ outcomes
Figure 1: Effects of microfinance ‘plus’ on microfinance institutions’ performance
25
Increased costs
Additional resources required
Lower client retention
Customer loyalty
Potential customers
High repayment rates
Financial Self-sustainability
Greater social outreach
Access to client information
MFI nancial and
social performance
+
-
Variables Description
Operational self-sufficiency Operating revenue / (Financial expense + loan loss
provision expense + operating expense)
Financial self-sufficiency Adjusted operating revenue / adjusted (financial expense +
loan loss provision expense + operating expense)
Return on Assets Net operating income / average total assets
Portfolio at risk (PAR30) Portfolio at Risk > 30 days/ Gross portfolio
Write-off ratio Write-off of loans / Average gross portfolio
Clients Number of active clients
Average loan size Amount issued in the period / Number of issued loans
Women Percentage of female clients
Operating expense ratio Operating expenses/average gross loan portfolio
Cost per client ratio Operating expenses/ number of active clients
Staff productivity Number of active borrowers/ Number of staff
Loan officer productivity Number of active borrowers / Number of loan officers
BDS 1 if MFI provides business development services, 0
otherwise
SS 1 if MFI provides social services, 0 otherwise
Group lending 1 if MFI uses group lending methodology, 0 otherwise
MFI experience (age) Number of years the MFI has been in operation
Credit officers Number of credit officers an MFI has at the end of year
Assets Total assets of the MFI
Bank 1 if a MFI is registered as a bank, 0 otherwise
Nonbank 1 if a MFI is registered as a non-financial institution, 0
otherwise
NGO 1 if a MFI is registered as non-governmental organization,
0 otherwise
Coop 1 if a MFI is registered as a cooperative, 0 otherwise
International network 1 if the MFI is member of an international network, 0
otherwise
Religious organization 1 if the MFI was initiated by an organization with a
religious agenda, 0 otherwise
26
GDP growth Annual GDP growth (based on constant 2005 US dollars)
HDI Human Development Index
Inflation Annual inflation rate
Table 1: Variable descriptions
Table 2: Descriptive statistics
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
Operational self-sufficiency 1.128241 0.3678306 0.075 2.96
Financial self-sufficiency 0.9484163 0.3047077 0.063 3.469
Return on assets 0.0240719 0.0858322 -0.373 0.373
Number of clients 15008.51 18951.42 24 98639
Average loan size 1.296353 2.826229 0.027 35.72
Percentage of women 0.6646034 0.2601223 0.000 1.000
Portfolio at risk 0.0601583 0.0689986 0.001 0.39
Write-off ratio 0.0135395 0.0196164 0.000 0.099
Write-off ratio (log) -5.053952 1.616904 -6.907 0.948
Operating expense ratio 0.2458689 0.1269165 0.016 0.6
Cost per client 118.648 107.004 0.242 574.99
Borrowers per staff member 132.1854 111.304 1 1893
Borrowers per loan officer 272.4617 159.7607 3 989
Assets 11301397.26 24831411.
8
19288 279350816
MFI age 9.782793 5.828356 0 29
Group lending 0.1923767 0.3942558 0 1
Credit officers 38.10859 39.05367 1 199
International network 0.3729858 0.483713 0 1
Religious organization 0.1685289 0.3744224 0 1
BDS 0.2524664 0.4345248 0 1
SS 0.2699552 0.4440358 0 1
Bank 0.0483496 0.2145538 0 1
Nonbank 0.2924221 0.454981 0 1
NGO 0.5099954 0.5000163 0 1
Coop 0.1338912 0.3406146 0 1
GDP growth 5.206064 3.175086 -14.149 17.33
Inflation 0.0611677 0.0487948 -0.185 0.287
HDI 0.6060426 0.1358599 0.058 0.806
27
Table 3: The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and financial sustainability
(1) (2) (3)
Variables OSS FSS ROA
BDS 0.0089 -0.0214 -0.0067
(0.0333) (0.0270) (0.0095)
SS -0.0060 0.0030 0.0072
(0.0292) (0.0249) (0.0097)
HDI -0.2367 -0.2811** -0.0170
(0.1769) (0.1408) (0.0642)
GDP growth 0.0023 0.0057* 0.0013
(0.0046) (0.0035) (0.0010)
MFI size 0.1342*** 0.1075*** 0.0248***
(0.0207) (0.0159) (0.0038)
MFI experience -0.0069 -0.0072 0.0005
(0.0047) (0.0044) (0.0007)
Inflation -0.1548 -0.7004*** 0.0737
(0.2662) (0.2398) (0.0677)
Credit officers -0.0026*** -0.0017*** -0.0004***
(0.0007) (0.0005) (0.0001)
International network -0.0399 0.0109 0.0003
(0.0471) (0.0358) (0.0086)
Religious organization -0.0463 -0.0837* -0.0193*
(0.0534) (0.0430) (0.0100)
NGO 0.3541 0.3995*** 0.0346
(0.3560) (0.1318) (0.0457)
Non-bank 0.2093 0.3175** 0.0170
(0.3557) (0.1261) (0.0459)
Bank 0.3720 0.3933*** 0.0385
(0.3645) (0.1462) (0.0473)
Coop 0.3281 0.4057*** 0.0306
(0.3565) (0.1368) (0.0466)
Group lending 0.0447 0.0333 0.0187***
(0.0329) (0.0264) (0.0065)
Constant -0.8750* -0.7562*** -0.3634***
(0.4797) (0.2712) (0.0853)
Time dummies Yes Yes Yes
Regional dummies Yes Yes Yes
Observations 628 654 1,104
Number of MFIs 196 211 317
Hausman test (p-value) 0.7758 0.4205 0.0016
28
R-squared (overall) 0.2071 0.2658 0.1688
Chi-squared 142.12*** 306.36*** 133.38***
Notes: This table lists Random effects results of the link between microfinance ‘plus’ and financial sustainability
of MFIs. OSS is operational self-sustainability and measures the ability of MFI to cover its operational costs from
revenue, FSS is financial self-sustainability and measures the ability of MFI to cover operational costs from revenue
without subsidies and ROA is returns on assets. BDS=1 if MFI provides business development services,
0=otherwise, and SS=1 if MFI provides social services, 0=otherwise. MFI size is the natural logarithm of total
assets, MFI experience is the number of years the MFI has been in operation, and Credit officers is the number of
credit officers at the end of the year. Group lending=1 if MFI offers group loans, 0= otherwise, International
network=1 if MFI is a member of international network, 0=otherwise, Religious organisation=1 if MFI was started
by a religious organisation, 0=otherwise. NGO =1 if the MFI is registered as a nongovernmental organisation, 0
=otherwise, Non-bank =1 if the MFI is registered as a non-bank financial institution, 0 =otherwise, Bank =1 if the
MFI is registered as a bank, 0 =otherwise, and Coop =1 if the MFI is registered as a cooperative, 0 =otherwise. GDP
growth is the real annual Gross Domestic Product growth rate, Inflation is annual producer price index, and HDI is
human development index. In parentheses are robust standard errors.
*, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, 1% respectively.
29
Table 4: The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and MFI efficiency
(4) (5) (6) (7)
Variables Operating
expenses
Cost per
client
Staff
productivity
Credit officer
productivity
BDS 0.0046 -11.1686 -6.4027 -13.6241
(0.0092) (8.2730) (4.6786) (9.7459)
SS -0.0006 7.3049 1.8171 1.3546
(0.0102) (7.2725) (4.6595) (10.1066)
HDI -0.1051 100.1630 84.3848* 61.4425
(0.0999) (76.6951) (44.5177) (117.7688)
GDP growth 0.0010 -1.8255** 0.6072 0.8140
(0.0011) (0.7907) (0.6034) (1.3391)
MFI size -0.0551*** 12.6214* 16.3686*** 39.5467***
(0.0066) (6.7782) (3.6843) (7.1674)
MFI experience -0.0009 0.2095 0.7911 1.9210
(0.0015) (1.2514) (0.8511) (1.7786)
Inflation -0.0367 -6.5753 -82.5389** -165.1948*
(0.0876) (62.6171) (41.7542) (86.9073)
Credit officers 0.0006*** -0.3000** -0.2736** -1.2017***
(0.0002) (0.1443) (0.1184) (0.2305)
International network 0.0463*** -8.9624 21.2268** 58.0469***
(0.0147) (10.9173) (9.9890) (19.0053)
Religious organization -0.0235 -6.6840 26.6914* 17.3264
(0.0167) (13.1452) (15.0120) (23.1394)
NGO -0.0829** 4.1400 -31.1030 -28.3443
(0.0382) (37.1670) (18.9918) (37.8816)
Non-bank -0.0907** 31.7750 -40.0253** -39.4110
(0.0373) (36.5450) (18.8842) (35.8501)
Bank -0.0599 -16.4869 -76.2367** -19.1276
(0.0449) (47.5149) (30.9760) (57.5899)
Coop -0.1948*** -29.9296 -76.8696*** -69.6188
(0.0416) (39.1691) (22.6003) (42.7219)
Group lending -0.0137** -2.0071 0.4042 8.5278
(0.0067) (6.0482) (3.9206) (8.6970)
Constant 1.2140*** -152.1842 -135.6015** -334.4640**
(0.1207) (111.7720) (63.4283) (132.5162)
Time dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes
Regional dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 994 960 1,123 1,106
Number of MFIs 295 278 315 313
30
Hausman test (p-value) 0.0001 0.0002 0.9036 1.0000
R-squared (overall) 0.3410 0.2724 0.1924 0.2093
Chi-squared 334.69*** 266.08*** 172.43*** 154.27***
Notes: This table lists Random effects estimates of the link between microfinance ‘plus’ and MFI efficiency.
Operating expense is total operating expenses as a percentage of average gross loan portfolio, Cost per client is total
operating expenses as a percentage of number of active clients, Staff productivity is the number of active borrowers
per staff, and Credit officer productivity is the number of active borrowers per credit officer. Regressors are defined
previously. In parentheses are the robust standard errors.
*, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, 1% respectively.
31
Table 5: The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and loan quality
(8) (9)
Variables PAR30 Write-off
BDS 0.0038 0.1091
(0.0054) (0.2420)
SS -0.0110** -0.3611
(0.0055) (0.2361)
HDI 0.0330 -0.8982
(0.0504) (0.9150)
GDP growth -0.0023*** -0.0244
(0.0006) (0.0206)
MFI size -0.0055 0.0935
(0.0033) (0.0701)
MFI experience 0.0023*** 0.0169
(0.0007) (0.0159)
Inflation -0.0628 1.4634
(0.0431) (1.1286)
Credit officers 0.0001 -0.0008
(0.0001) (0.0021)
International network -0.0234*** -0.1109
(0.0073) (0.1565)
Religious organization 0.0082 0.1442
(0.0083) (0.1959)
NGO 0.0177 0.5172
(0.0332) (0.5032)
Non-bank 0.0221 0.2957
(0.0333) (0.5000)
Bank 0.0054 0.0621
(0.0357) (0.5943)
Coop 0.0327 -0.0124
(0.0347) (0.5327)
Group lending 0.0023 0.2515*
(0.0044) (0.1404)
Constant 0.0939 -7.0021***
(0.0698) (1.2779)
Time dummies Yes Yes
Regional dummies Yes Yes
Observations 1,001 1,087
Number of MFIs 298 301
32
Hausman test (p-value) chi2<0 0.4105
R-squared (overall) 0.1640 0.0913
Chi-squared 117.50*** 228.54***
Notes: This table lists Random effects estimates of the link between microfinance ‘plus’ and loan portfolio quality
of MFIs. PaR30 is nonperforming loans over 30 days, and Write-off is natural logarithm of the proportion of loans
portfolio that have been written off as loan loss. Regressors are defined previously. In parentheses are robust
standard errors.
*, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, 1% respectively.
Table 6: The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and social performance
(10) (11) (12)
Variables Clients Average loan size Women
BDS -602.9183 -0.0212 -0.0098
(777.4759) (0.1556) (0.0443)
SS 597.1599 0.0755 0.0899**
(699.2822) (0.1505) (0.0431)
HDI 3,861.4355 -1.6081 0.4286**
(5,486.8614) (1.4455) (0.2067)
GDP growth 110.2542 -0.0238 0.0143**
(83.0698) (0.0348) (0.0065)
MFI size 1,933.2793*** 0.1736* -0.0615***
(516.9265) (0.1006) (0.0202)
MFI experience 142.4659 -0.0321 0.0038
(115.0366) (0.0349) (0.0043)
Inflation -5,247.5854 -2.1151 -0.5878*
(6,821.1764) (2.8034) (0.3159)
Credit officers 222.4752*** -0.0022 0.0009**
(21.2049) (0.0038) (0.0004)
International network 2,452.8597* -0.3416 0.1434***
(1,290.6792) (0.4111) (0.0401)
Religious organization -1,606.7106 0.3312 -0.0466
(1,166.1896) (0.5857) (0.0602)
NGO -2,557.9972 0.7308** -0.0822
(2,521.8525) (0.3527) (0.0728)
Non-bank -1,930.1692 1.6658** -0.1872**
(2,504.2784) (0.6494) (0.0806)
Bank -2,524.7437 2.3336** -0.2099**
(3,992.8307) (1.0651) (0.1055)
Coop 3,843.7740 1.3902** -0.2162*
(3,551.6547) (0.5984) (0.1105)
Group lending 82.3783 -0.0524 0.0214
(525.3579) (0.2298) (0.0268)
Constant -32,712.4700*** -1.0653 1.2537***
(8,845.9372) (1.9017) (0.3633)
Time dummies Yes Yes Yes
Regional dummies Yes Yes Yes
Observations 976 645 176
Number of MFIs 277 201 139
33
Hausman test (p-value) 0.2034 0.0000 0.3599
R-squared (overall) 0.6376 0.1521 0.4716
Chi-squared 827.32*** 66.19*** 229.78***
Notes: This table lists Random effects estimates of the link between microfinance ‘plus’ and social performance of
MFIs. Clients is the number of active clients an MFI has, Average loan size is the amount of loan disbursed per
borrower scaled by gross domestic product per capita, and women is a percentage of female clients. Regressors are
defined previously. In parentheses are robust standard errors.
*, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, 1% respectively.
Table 7 The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and financial sustainability
(13) (14) (15)
Variables OSS FSS ROA
BDS -0.0114 -0.0302 -0.0099
(0.0514) (0.0339) (0.0106)
SS -0.0023 0.0017 0.0066
(0.0492) (0.0326) (0.0104)
HDI -0.0794 -0.0837 0.0598
(0.2881) (0.2324) (0.0592)
GDP growth 0.0030 0.0064* 0.0014
(0.0050) (0.0034) (0.0010)
MFI size 0.1507*** 0.1551*** 0.0350***
(0.0260) (0.0191) (0.0048)
MFI experience -0.0090 -0.0067 0.0003
(0.0056) (0.0056) (0.0009)
Inflation -0.1246 -0.6438*** 0.0731
(0.3045) (0.2235) (0.0591)
International network -0.0485 -0.0112 0.0007
(0.0563) (0.0573) (0.0104)
NGO 0.5578** 0.5296*** 0.0591*
(0.2845) (0.1549) (0.0355)
Non-bank 0.4077 0.4339*** 0.0363
(0.2826) (0.1422) (0.0348)
Credit officers -0.0025*** -0.0024*** -0.0007***
(0.0009) (0.0006) (0.0002)
Group lending 0.0611 0.0429* 0.0252***
(0.0386) (0.0242) (0.0074)
Religious organization -0.0386 -0.0808 -0.0208
(0.0630) (0.0653) (0.0129)
Bank 0.5090* 0.4489** 0.0549
(0.2963) (0.1986) (0.0402)
Coop 0.5225* 0.5182*** 0.0460
(0.2833) (0.1609) (0.0370)
Constant -1.4732** -1.7077*** -0.5844***
(0.6083) (0.3850) (0.1012)
Time dummies Yes Yes Yes
Regional dummies Yes Yes Yes
Observations 628 654 1,104
Number of MFIs 196 211 317
34
Chi-squared 106.24*** 262.62*** 199.78***
Sagran-Hansen (P-value) 0.6688 0.1783 0.2927
Notes: This table presents estimates of the Hausman-Taylor model. Our endogenous regressors are credit officers,
BDS, SS, and Group lending, of which credit officers is time varying and the rest are time-invariant. The remaining
regressors are considered exogenous. Time varying exogenous variables are HDI, GDP growth, MFI size, MFI
experience and inflation. The remaining exogenous regressors are time invariant. Variables are defined in Table 2.
Standard errors in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10.
Table 8: The link between microfinance ‘plus’ and financial sustainability
(16) (17) (18)
Variables OSS FSS ROA
OSSt-1 0.4490**
(0.1794)
FSSt-1 0.4881**
(0.2207)
ROAt-1 0.5066***
(0.0875)
BDS 0.1630 0.0109 0.0009
(0.1221) (0.1047) (0.0132)
SS -0.0864 0.0743 0.0011
(0.1477) (0.1745) (0.0131)
HDI -0.2846 0.3117 0.0236
(0.2883) (0.6601) (0.0646)
GDP growth -0.0007 0.0128 0.0012
(0.0060) (0.0124) (0.0008)
MFI size 0.0468* 0.0703 0.0025
(0.0266) (0.0725) (0.0031)
MFI experience 0.0019 -0.0201 -0.0009*
(0.0067) (0.0205) (0.0005)
Inflation 0.1433 -0.1500 0.0550
(0.5422) (0.6218) (0.0749)
Credit officers -0.0010 -0.0007 -0.0000
(0.0008) (0.0013) (0.0001)
International network 0.0518 -0.0541 0.0036
(0.0593) (0.1124) (0.0045)
Religious organization 0.0003 -0.0590 0.0085
(0.0464) (0.0993) (0.0075)
NGO -4.5378 4.1261 -0.1938
(5.3656) (6.0511) (0.3040)
Non-bank -4.7924 4.3736 -0.2106
(5.4818) (6.3937) (0.3170)
Bank -4.4579 4.0063 -0.1954
(5.3021) (5.9865) (0.3022)
Coop -4.5834 4.0857 -0.2145
(5.3237) (6.0198) (0.3056)
Group lending -0.0672 -0.0698 -0.0046
(0.0678) (0.0642) (0.0120)
35
Constant 4.7866 -4.7093 0.1909
(5.4758) (7.0737) (0.3576)
Time dummies Yes Yes Yes
Regional dummies Yes Yes Yes
Observations 466 472 844
Number of MFIs 187 201 305
Number of instruments 41 41 43
Chi-squared 229.83*** 210.41*** 321.87***
AR(1) test (P-value) 0.045 0.033 0.000
AR(2) test (P-value) 0.412 0.296 0.792
Hansen test (P-value) 0.800 0.284 0.176
Notes: This table lists system GMM (generalized methods of moments) results of the link between microfinance
‘plus’ and financial sustainability of MFIs. OSS is operational self-sustainability and measures the ability of MFI to
cover its operational costs from revenue, FSS is financial self-sustainability and measures the ability of MFI to cover
operational costs from revenue without subsidies and ROA is returns on assets. Regressors are defined previously.
AR (1) and AR (2) are tests for first-and second-order serial correlation in the first-differenced residuals, under the
null hypothesis of no serial correlation. The Hansen test of over-identification is under the null hypothesis that all
instruments are valid. In specifying the two-step System GMM model, we use lags of: dependent variables, BDS
and SS as GMM instruments allowing the default lags limits in Stata. “By default, gmmstyle() generates the
instruments appropriate for predetermined variables: lags 1 and earlier of the instrumenting variable for the
transformed equation and, for system GMM, lag 0 of the instrumenting variable in differences for the levels
equation” (Roodman 2009, 124). The exogenous regressors are also standard instrumental variables, and the
‘collapse’ option is used to limit instrument proliferation. In parentheses are robust standard errors.
*, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, 1% respectively.
36
... Incremental innovation in microfinance products, such as microfinance plus services and flexible products, engender a greater depth of outreach and social performance (e.g., Barboni, 2017;Barboni & Agarwal, 2023;Lensink et al., 2018;Roy & Pati, 2018). For instance, Lensink et al. (2018) investigate whether microfinance plus is more effective than credit alone in achieving MFIs' social objectives. ...
... Incremental innovation in microfinance products, such as microfinance plus services and flexible products, engender a greater depth of outreach and social performance (e.g., Barboni, 2017;Barboni & Agarwal, 2023;Lensink et al., 2018;Roy & Pati, 2018). For instance, Lensink et al. (2018) investigate whether microfinance plus is more effective than credit alone in achieving MFIs' social objectives. They find evidence that MFIs providing plus services exhibit greater depth of outreach than their counterparts. ...
... It improves clients' ability to repay loans, informed decision making, reduces financial stress, and increases client satisfaction, leading to a more meaningful and stable approach to risk management. Several studies verify that incrementally innovative products such as microfinance plus, combined products, and flexible credit positively affect MFIs risk management (Godquin, 2004;Hsu et al., 2021;Lensink et al., 2018;Pelka et al., 2015;Tedeschi, 2006). Lensink et al. (2018) discovered that bundling lending with nonfinancial services results in a lower level of portfolio at risk because of clients' enhanced knowledge and skills, which helped them make more informed financial decisions, manage their businesses, and reduce their likelihood of defaulting on loans, thereby lowering the overall portfolio at risk for the lender. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
In recent years, there has been a notable shift towards embracing innovative microfinance products. Yet, what do we know about the impact of these innovations on clients, MFIs, and their associated challenges? This systematic literature review (SLR) analyzes 105 articles to analyze the effects of so-called disruptive and incremental innovation in microfinance products. The findings reveal that these innovations elicit diverse outcomes for clients and MFIs, albeit through different pathways. Although the results are mixed, this SLR emphasizes the potential of these innovations to deepen the effects of microfinance. The study highlights a symmetry between the two types of innovations. Disruptive innovations prioritize the financial empowerment of clients, whereas incremental innovations focus more on socioeconomic development. Moreover, implementing innovative products enhances the financial and social performance of MFIs. Intriguingly, incremental innovation may reintroduce information asymmetry problems. Disruptive innovation raises concerns about client protection and exclusion of the most unprivileged, among other aspects. The analysis emphasizes that MFIs may use these innovations to maximize benefits for their clients while maintaining sustainable financial returns.
... Almost none of the extant research has looked at the impact of microcredit contracts on borrowers' welfare (Sett, 2020). Further, studies questioned whether or not different 'plus' services enhance beneficiaries' welfare (Lensink et al. 2018). Most previous studies don't deal 4 with the microfinance program design leading to the required outcome (social mission and women empowerment). ...
... The profit status of an MFI changes its decision-making process, its goals, and its mission. A study by Lensink et al. (2018) indicated that MFIs are hybrid organizations pursuing both social and financial objectives. Like banks, MFIs should be profitable or at least break-even, and like social organizations, MFIs should reach out to unbanked clients and enhance their welfare. ...
... In the microfinance domain, neoliberalism's dominant discourse framing development and women's empowerment programs are based on microfinance minimalism, whereas a counterhegemonic discourse critiques this and proposes alternatives (Batliwala, 2007 as cited in Tanima, Brown & Dillard, 2020). Controversies persist between the minimalist and maximalist approaches (Bhatt & Tang, 2001;Morduch 2000 as cited in Lensink et al. 2018). ...
... In fact, the major objective behind integrating NFS for MFIs is to improve the well-being of clients and enhance their financial knowledge to generate bigger profits. (Lensink et al., 2018;RIZK et.al, 2022) In Western Nigeria, Ogunrinola and Alege (2007) examined the impact of NFS such as preloan training, group membership, and cross guarantees, along with microcredit, in microenterprise in rural Lagos State. Their study concluded that NFS really benefitted these businesses when complemented with credit and that the metrics mentioned above had positive impact on microenterprise development in Lagos state. ...
... According to Lensink et al. (2018), the provision of NFS by MFIs increases the operational costs, approximately amplifying 5-10% of the MFIs operational expenses, which leads to higher financial burdens on the MFIs and thus a lower financial performance. Various other studies have argued that MFIs clients considered NFS to be of low quality and irrelevant (Berger, 1989). ...
Thesis
Full-text available
Loan repayment rates are more often than not, the main criterion used to assess the success of microfinance models. While repayment rates are a direct indicator of credit risk and provide valuable insight into the financial capability of the borrower, it does not capture the full range of outcomes and impacts that microfinance interventions can trigger. Through a careful examination of how European microfinance models that supplement financial assistance with Non-Financial Services (NFS) help borrowers go beyond simple loan repayment and achieve sustainable entrepreneurial success, this research aims to challenge the status quo. With the guidance of Amartya Sen’s Capability Approach framework, this study aims to shed light on how NFS can empower microentrepreneurs, not only in terms of loan repayment but also in ensuring their entrepreneurial success and long-term business prosperity. Additionally, the research explores the current landscape of Pakistani Microfinance Institutions (MFIs), where Islamic finance serves as the foundation of the MFI model, characterized by interest-free principles, to understand why NFS is not a key component within such models and if there are possibilities for adaption. Utilizing a mixed-methods approach, incorporating qualitative interviews from 47 borrowers across Karachi, Lahore, and Islamabad along with quantitative analysis, this research seeks to investigate the perspectives of microcredit borrowers in Pakistan. It seeks to ascertain their existing financial and non-financial needs, evaluate the efficacy of current MFI models in empowering microentrepreneurs, and identify gaps that borrowers themselves identity and advocate for a change in. Through understanding borrower needs and deficits, and juxtaposing these insights with successful MFI models that integrate NFS, this research seeks to inform the design and implementation of microfinance programs to go beyond mere financial assistance. These strategies acknowledge that true poverty alleviation achieved through microfinance extends beyond mere loan repayment, emphasising the importance of ensuring that borrowers’ businesses are self-sustaining and growth-capable.
... Bank Size (Vidyarthi, 2020;Lensink et al., 2018) The firm's size plays a role in sustainability and efficiency as larger banks benefit from economies of scope. The natural logarithm of total assets measures a bank's size. ...
Article
Full-text available
In today’s highly competitive and complex banking industry, the long-term viability of banks depends on their ability to operate efficiently. This has become of utmost significance in light of globalisation and liberalisation. The importance of efficiency has become even more evident since India began its financial liberalisation process in 1991, followed by a greater focus on globalisation in the 2000s, the global financial crisis of 2008, and the ongoing effects of the COVID-19 pandemic. These events have highlighted the pressing requirement for efficiency. This article evaluates the effectiveness of public sector banks (PSBs) by utilising scaling techniques and DEA assumptions. The assessment is by designated efficiency indicators and takes into account the banks’ size. The findings suggest that the interest income efficiencies of the majority of banks are typically near optimal levels. Nevertheless, a considerable proportion of banks demonstrate subpar efficiencies in generating non-interest income, failing to meet satisfactory benchmarks. The difference between the efficiencies of interest and non-interest income has a significant impact on the overall efficiency of banks, which brings it closer to acceptable levels. The panel regression analysis reveals that factors such as cost to income, spread, CASA, income per branch, NPAs, and bank size significantly influence the efficiency of banks.
... Hossain and Khan (2016) previously utilized ordinary least squares (OLS) reducedform equations to quantify the association between dependent and explanatory variables to assess the financial sustainability of MFIs. Preceding research employed a combination of the ordinary least squares (OLS) approach with a random effect model to ascertain the financial viability of MFIs (Ahlin et al., 2011;Lensink et al., 2018). Furthermore, the OLS model (Quayes, 2012), Logit model (Quayes, 2012), and Probit model (Bayai and Ikhide, 2018) have been utilized in preceding analyses to examine financial sustainability thus far. ...
Article
Full-text available
Bangladesh can be proudly recognized as the pioneer of the microcredit concept. This paper aims to discover the potential firm-specific factors that influence the economic stability of MFIs (microfinance institutions) in Bangladesh. The study has collected quantitative data on one sustainability variable and six predictor variables through performance analysis of the top 120 MFIs of Bangladesh from 2022 to 2023. MFIs having 110% or more operational sustainability have been regarded as financially sustainable and examined based on managerial inefficiency, MFIs size, leverage, breadth of outreach, loan intensity, and deposit mobilization. The findings revealed that except deposit mobilization, all other stated predictors have imposed statistically significant effects on the financial sustainability of the microfinance institutions of Bangladesh of which size and loan intensity have a positive impact whereas managerial inefficiency, leverage, and breadth of outreach have a negative impact. The results of the research can be utilized to increase knowledge about the factors that can be eliminated or controlled to achieve financial sustainability and eventually, all the MFIs being operated in society, especially those who are facing challenges in accumulating their funds will benefit from this research by getting an idea of which determinants to control.
... Additionally, the firm's size plays a role in sustainability and comparative advantages, as larger banks benefit from economies of scope. The natural logarithm of total assets measures a bank's size (Gupta & Moudud-Ul-Huq, 2020;Lensink et al., 2018;Vidyarthi, 2020). The CASA ratio, which stands for current and savings accounts, reflects the proportion of these accounts to total deposits. ...
Article
This article delves into the intricate relationship between revenue diversification and the financial performance and sustainability of both public and private sector banks in India. Through a comprehensive analysis of nine years’ panel data from 2015 to 2023 and applying descriptive statistics, the Herfindahl–Hirschman index, panel data regression models and generalized method of moments, our findings reveal a concerning trend—Revenue diversification is exerting a negative influence on the financial well-being of the Indian public sector banks (PSBs) and positively impacts the private sector banks. Contrary to conventional wisdom, the pursuit of diversifying revenue streams has not yielded the anticipated benefits for Indian PSBs. Instead, it has emerged as a source of financial instability and vulnerability. Hence, our findings suggest that a focused approach to revenue sources may be more advantageous for the PSBs. This study underscores the importance of strategic revenue planning and resource allocation for Indian PSBs to enhance their financial performance and self-sufficiency. The results have practical implications for policymakers, bank executives and stakeholders in the Indian banking sector, offering guidance on optimizing revenue strategies to ensure the long-term sustainability of PSBs in India.
... Additionally, Shaikh (2020) argues that women entrepreneurs in developing economies, such as Pakistan, face acute shortages of financial resources and limited freedom to operate in a free and fair market. Several studies demonstrate the adverse effects of financial handicaps on women entrepreneurs, which negatively impact society in terms of economic contribution (Khandker, 2005;Mawa, 2008;Lucy et al., 2008;Karlan & Morduch, 2010;Hermes & Lensink,2011;Hermes et al., 2018;Lensink et al., 2018;De Clercq et al., 2021a,b;De Clercq et al., 2022a,b, c;De Clercq et al., 2023). Furthermore, (De Clercq et al., 2022a,b,c, 2023) emphasize the transformative role of microfinance in enhancing the decision-making autonomy of women entrepreneurs, leading to significant societal and economic improvements. ...
Article
Unsustainability and the menace of poverty are the major challenges confronted by developing countries like Pakistan. This study intends to highlight the impact of microfinance interventions on women entrepreneurs in Pakistan and their potential to foster women's entrepreneurial ambition as a means of poverty alleviation. A quantitative research design has been used to collect data through a questionnaire from 400 women entrepreneurs who have benefited from the National Rural Support Program (NRSP)'s, (2019-2021) Microfinance and Enterprise Development Program in Pakistan. The study found that the concept of microfinance resources is gaining significance and its access is significantly impacting the entrepreneurial inclination and success of women entrepreneur's vis a vis reduces poverty levels in low-income communities. The findings have significant implications for policymakers, microfinance institutions and women entrepreneurs in Pakistan, emphasizing the need for programs that target women entrepreneurs and provide them with microfinance resources and training to empower them to take charge of their businesses. Limited generalizability and self-reported data are the limitations to mention. Strategies like offering microfinance were found to be valuable tool in combating poverty and inequality from the women entrepreneurial initiatives perspective.
Article
Full-text available
This paper examines the effect of microfinance products on the performance of rural businesses in developing economies. The study is survey research that uses multiple regression models with a sample of 228 small businesses from rural communities. Two regression models were developed and tested. The two dependent variables are: profits and sales growth. The four independent variables are: loans, savings, insurance, and education, with five control variables: gender, managerial skills, age, industry, and size. Both regression models are significant (0.000) with adjusted R-squared values > 70%. Thus, the two models are valid predictors of financial performance. The optimal strategy is to get micro-loans, education and insurance, and to have micro-savings. The study extends the literature on the microfinance drivers and other characteristics influencing the development of rural businesses in an emerging market context. The study also serves as a benchmark in utilizing scarce resources for the sustainability and performance of rural businesses. Implications for practice and research for rural entrepreneurs, microfinance institutions, and government as well as limitations and further studies, are discussed.
Article
Full-text available
Purpose: The Cameroon Microfinance sector has been facing stiff competition as a result of globalization where other players have joined the sector with differentiated innovative products/services rendering MFIs in quest of new strategies of development. Partnerships are becoming an alternative business strategy and hence the formation of strategic alliances in the microfinance industry. This study sought to determine the influence of complementary alliances on the sustainability of MFIs in Cameroon. The objectives were to examine how complementary alliances in financial institutions and complementary alliances in non-financial institutions affect sustainability of MFIs in Cameroon. Materials and Methods: The study used a survey research design to examine the effects of the independent variables on the dependent variable. Purposive and snowball sampling techniques were used in this study. The target population of the study comprised of the 361 MFIs in the Centre, Littoral, NW, SW and West regions of Cameroon that have carried out strategic alliances which were retained and used to develop the sample size. Data was collected through the use of opened and closed ended questionnaires administered to senior management of the MFIs. Data collected was analysed using the Structural Equation Modelling with Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regression estimation techniques to check the robustness of the data set. Findings: OLS Findings suggest that complementary alliances in financial institutions, more than complementary alliances in non-financial institutions has a positive and significant relationship with sustainability of MFIs in Cameroon given their β coefficients of 0.243** and 0.036 respectively. The regression coefficient for complementary alliances in financial institution is significant at 5%. Implications to Theory, Practice and Policy: It is recommended that MFIs should partner with other financial and non-financial institutions in terms of commercialisation of services. This will strengthen their business relationships, enable them have access to resources and expertise from partner organisations to expand their operations, generate revenue that will keep them going and boost the financial growth of the economy.
Article
Full-text available
This paper investigates the impact of integrating climate change interventions in informal community‐based institutions called savings groups. By integrating climate‐related activities into these groups, the aim is to simultaneously strengthen the group's financial activities as well as improve knowledge and investment capacity in climate adaptation. We find that the introduction of the training increases meeting attendance rate and average loan sizes, suggesting that members can access larger sums for investment to implement the knowledge acquired during the training. We provide evidence that there are opportunities for economies of scope and for a larger positive impact on the livelihoods of the populations at the bottom of the pyramid by combining financial services offered in the savings groups and climate‐related interventions.
Chapter
This paper sheds light on a poorly understood phenomenon in microfinance which is often referred to as “mission drift”: A tendency reviewed by numerous microfinance institutions to extend larger average loan sizes in the process of scaling–up. We argue that this phenomenon is not driven by transaction cost minimization alone. Instead, poverty-oriented microfinance institutions could potentially deviate from their mission by extending larger loan sizes neither because of “progressive lending” nor because of “cross-subsidization” but because of the interplay between their own mission, the cost differentials between poor and unbanked wealthier clients, and region-specific clientele parameters. In a simple one-period framework we pin down the conditions under which mission drift can emerge. Our framework shows that there is a thin line between mission drift and cross subsidization, which in turn makes it difficult for empirical researchers to establish whether a microfinance institution has deviated from its poverty-reduction mission. This paper also suggests that institutions operating in regions which host a relatively small number of very poor individuals might be misleadingly perceived as deviating from their social objectives. Because existing empirical studies cannot differentiate between mission drift and cross-subsidization, these studies can potentially mislead donors and socially responsible investors pertaining to resource allocation across institutions offering financial services to the poor. The difficulty in separating cross-subsidization and mission drift is discussed in light of the contrasting experiences between microfinance institutions operating in Latin America and South Asia. © 2011 by World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd. All rights reserved.
Chapter
’smart subsidy’ might seem like a contradiction in terms to many microfinance experts. Worries about the dangers of excessive subsidization have been central to microfinance conversations since the movement first gained steam in the 1980s. From then on, the goal of serving the poor has been twinned with the goal of long-term financial self-sufficiency on the part of microbanks: aiming for profitability became part of what it means to practise good microfinance. The influential ‘Pink Book’, a newly reformulated set of ‘donor guidelines on good practice in microfinance’, for example, includes the idea that ‘microfinance can pay for itself, and must do so if it is to reach very large numbers of people. Unless microfinance providers charge enough to cover their costs, they will always be limited by the scarce and uncertain supply of subsidies from donors and governments.’1
Book
This handbook, intended as a comprehensive source for donors, policy makers and practitioners, covers the policy, legal and regulatory issues relevant to microfinance development and examines the key elements in the process of building sustainable financial institutions with effective outreach to the poor. The handbook is divided into three parts: (1) issues to consider when providing microfinance - understanding the country context, the target market and impact analysis, products and services, and the institution; (2) designing and monitoring financial products and services - designing lending products, designing savings products and management information systems; and (3) measuring performance and managing viability - adjusting financial statements, performance indicators and performance management.
Article
It has become common to try and increase the effectiveness of microfinance programmes by adding supplementary services to the financial product. However, the added value accruing from this ‘credit-plus’ approach has been little analysed. We hypothesise that the extent of added value from credit-plus depends on the ability of the credit supplier to cultivate trust, or social capital, amongst clients. Applying difference-in-difference estimation, we exploit a natural experiment of two ‘credit-plus’ programmes in Mexico. The findings suggest that credit-plus is not universally effective, but that it is at its most effective, especially with low-income groups, where ‘bonding’ (within-group) social capital exists.