Content uploaded by Anneleen Michiels
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Anneleen Michiels on Jan 18, 2018
Content may be subject to copyright.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0894486517736958
Family Business Review
2017, Vol. 30(4) 369 –399
© The Author(s) 2017
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0894486517736958
journals.sagepub.com/home/fbr
Article
Introduction
In their seminal work, Modigliani and Miller (1958)
declared financing decisions to be irrelevant in a perfect
capital market. Discussing and challenging their basic
assumption of a perfect capital market, many researchers
have shown that, in the real world, financing decisions
matter (e.g., Fama, 1978; Myers, 1984; Myers & Majluf,
1984; Stiglitz, 1969, 1974). In family firms, these deci-
sions may be more relevant for both practical and theo-
retical reasons. Practically, the importance given to family
business financing decisions has been demonstrated
through EU policies that consider access to finance as one
of the main challenges of family firms (European
Commission, 2015a). Benavides-Velasco, Quintana-
García, and Guzmán-Parra (2013) along with Voordeckers,
Le Breton-Miller, and Miller (2014) have highlighted the
theoretical importance, showing that finance is not only
one of the top areas in family business research but also a
growing area. This attention, both practically and theo-
retically, is warranted, since the availability of sufficient
financial resources is of critical importance for the family
firm’s survival and growth (Koropp, Kellermanns,
Grichnik, & Stanley, 2014). Financing, for example, has
been linked to strategic decisions such as the timing of
succession (Kimhi, 1997), the sale of the family business
(Bhattacharya & Ravikumar, 2001), and the international-
ization of the family firm (Benito-Hernández, Priede-
Bergamini, and López-Cózar-Navarro, 2014). Overall,
the aforementioned makes clear the significance of this
topic for family firms and that more research is needed in
this direction.
An understanding of financing decisions is clearly of
great importance for family firms and scholars as this is
considered along with the “peculiar financial logic” that
characterizes family firms (Gallo, Tàpies, & Cappuyns,
2004). Specifically, a review of the literature shows that
several inconsistencies can be found and that various
factors complicate a thorough understanding of family
business financing decisions. Therefore, our aim in this
article is to analyze and systematize prior work on
736958FBRXXX10.1177/0894486517736958Family Business ReviewMichiels and Molly
research-article2017
1Universiteit Hasselt, Research Centre for Entrepreneurship and
Family firms, Diepenbeek, Belgium
2KU Leuven, Brussels, Belgium
3Antwerp Management School, Antwerp, Belgium
The authors contributed equally to this article and are listed
alphabetically.
Corresponding Author:
Vincent Molly, Faculty of Economics & Business, KU Leuven,
Warmoesberg 26, 1000 Brussels, Belgium.
Email: vincent.molly@kuleuven.be
Financing Decisions in Family
Businesses: A Review and Suggestions
for Developing the Field
Anneleen Michiels1 and Vincent Molly2,3
Abstract
Motivated by the growing attention to the financing decisions of family firms, this review brings together the two
highly relevant research fields of family business and finance. This study critically reviews 131 articles on financing
decisions in family businesses, published between 1977 and 2016 in 64 finance and management journals. We
develop a state of the art on family business financing literature and present a model to guide extant and future
research by identifying gaps across the theoretical perspectives and across context-specific elements such as family
business heterogeneity and country-specific factors.
Keywords
family business, literature review, financing decisions
370 Family Business Review 30(4)
financing decisions in family firms, which will help
identify (theoretical) shortcomings and present a frame-
work for organizing (future) research in this field. We
focus in this review on articles dealing with “all” types
of family businesses, meaning that they can be charac-
terized by family involvement in various ways, and can
be private or public firms, small or large firms. Given
the dispersed nature of the family business financing lit-
erature and the gap that still exists between the family
business and finance field of research, we believe a thor-
ough review can bring a large contribution to both disci-
plines and will form a good basis to elaborate future
studies on finance in family businesses.
To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study
that gives a state of the art on family business financing
literature. Based on a comprehensive literature review,
we synthesize existing evidence on financing decisions
in family businesses and present a framework for orga-
nizing and better understanding extant and future
research on financing decisions in family firms. It struc-
tures current theoretical thinking and sets a research
agenda for the future, containing several suggestions on
theoretical integration, sampling, and study design. This
way, we articulate and spotlight areas where family
business scholars may most fruitfully direct their atten-
tion, which will in turn advance our knowledge of
financing decisions in family businesses.
Method and Sample
Review Method
In this article, we follow the systematic review method
of David and Han (2004), which is explicit in its selec-
tion of studies and employs quantitative methods of
evaluation. First, we searched for journal articles pub-
lished in peer-reviewed journals until December 31,
2016, written in English language, thereby excluding
book chapters or unpublished work. Second, we ori-
ented our search toward the following two databases,
which cover major journals in the area of finance and
business/management: Business Source Premier and
Academic Search Elite. Third, to find relevant articles,
we looked for the combination of a finance entity and a
family business entity in the title and/or the abstract
(Pukall & Calabrò, 2014; Salvato & Moores, 2010).
With respect to the latter, we focus on articles dealing
with companies that are characterized by family involve-
ment in various ways. This is also visible from the
choice of our search keywords being used in the search
engine: ((financ*) OR (debt) OR (equity) OR (stock) OR
(capital) OR (leverag*) OR (IPO) OR (bank*) OR
(investor*) OR (dividend*) OR (borrow*) OR (lend*)
OR (loan*) OR (credit) OR (collateral)) AND ((“family
firm*”) OR (“family business*”) OR (“family enter-
prise*”) OR (“family influenc*”) OR (“family con-
trol*”) OR (“family owner*”) OR (“family manag*”)
OR (family govern*) OR (“founding family”)).
An article had to provide conceptual advancements
in the understanding of financing decisions in family
firms or empirically test propositions regarding financ-
ing decisions within a family business context.
Therefore, in a fourth step, the relevance was checked
by reading all the abstracts. The remaining articles were
read completely to ensure substantive relevance for this
study. Finally, to ensure that no relevant article was
missed, additionally the major outlets for family busi-
ness research were scanned individually. They were
selected from previous literature reviews in the field
(Kontinen & Ojala, 2010; Pukall & Calabrò, 2014;
Siebels & zu Knyphausen-Aufseß, 2012; Zahra &
Sharma, 2004). We manually checked the indexes of
Family Business Review, Journal of Business Venturing,
Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, and Journal of
Small Business Management. Additionally, we checked
for studies in Journal of Family Business Strategy,
which first appeared in 2010. Using the method and cri-
teria described, a total of 868 articles were identified and
evaluated with 131 articles retained for review.
In a next phase, both authors independently screened
the articles following a predefined coding scheme. In
case of disagreement, a third family business scholar
was asked to code the concerning article, after which a
common understanding was reached. The following
aspects were considered as important in analyzing the
content of the articles: (a) focal topic area, (b) theoreti-
cal approaches (theories used, family business definition
used), (c) methods (country of research, sample size,
data source, period of research, quantitative or qualita-
tive, analytical approach, temporal dimension, public or
private or both, family versus nonfamily or within fam-
ily), (d) main findings, and (e) journal in which the arti-
cle was published.
The review of these 131 articles was supplemented
with data collected from an expert panel, consisting of
prominent scholars in the family business field. The use
of an expert panel can be considered as a qualitative way
to explore and identify key themes in the literature and
Michiels and Molly 371
thus to provide additional insights (Jones & Gatrell,
2014). Additionally, this approach allows us to integrate
the most recent thoughts on family business financing,
and thus reduces the potential limitation of publication
time lag in some scholarly journals. We e-mailed all
associate editors of the two SSCI-ranked family busi-
ness journals (Family Business Review and Journal of
Family Business Strategy), together with some promi-
nent family business and/or finance scholars. In total,
nine scholars cooperated and provided us with valuable
additional insights. We provided them with three ques-
tions on promising research topics, promising theoreti-
cal frameworks, and other suggestions on finance for
family business scholars. We first interpreted the
answers to these questions for each scholar individually,
followed by a comparison of the insights from all the
scholars to find the most relevant suggestions.
General Sample Characteristics
The articles on financing decisions in family firms
accepted for the analysis are published in a wide variety
of management/business, finance, and economics jour-
nals, and they have taken a rapid growth after the year
2000, especially in the management/business and the
finance fields. Appendix A contains a detailed descrip-
tion of the distribution of the sample across journals and
their impact factors.
Our review further indicates that most studies on
financing decisions in family firms are based on
European data, followed by Asia and North America,
while analyses on South American, African, or
Australian samples are rare. Eighty-one percent of the
studies focus on one single country, while in 19% of the
articles, data on multiple countries are included. Table 1
gives an overview of the most important methodological
parameters of the selected articles.
The majority of studies applied regression tech-
niques, followed by categorical dependent variable anal-
yses (logit, probit, tobit). The data mainly come from
(public) databases, and in only 21 out of 131 articles are
analyses based on survey information. Qualitative stud-
ies based on interviews or case studies are quite excep-
tional. Most of the studies are oriented toward public
family firms. The dominance of samples of public fam-
ily firms might be explained by the widespread reliance
on commercial databases and other secondary data
sources. About 70% of the articles includes the criteria
on how to identify family firms, meaning that almost
one out of three studies lacks a clear family business
definition. Finally, two thirds of the studies in our sam-
ple makes the traditional comparison between family
and nonfamily businesses without taking into account
family business heterogeneity. When further examining
this subsample of articles, we find no differences with
regard to type of journal or date of publishing. Yet arti-
cles that ignore family business heterogeneity use public
databases more often as compared with the full sample
of articles and make less use of survey data. Thus,
although numerous scholars have stressed the impor-
tance to acknowledge the heterogeneity of family busi-
nesses, data limitations might be one explanation as to
why the minority of financing studies actually takes this
heterogeneity into account.
More than 40% of the articles in our sample discuss
issues concerning debt decisions (e.g., leverage, debt
maturity, or target debt rate). Decisions regarding equity
(e.g., buyouts, private equity, venture capital, or initial
public offerings [IPOs]) are discussed in 34% of the
articles. Decisions related to retained earnings (e.g.,
dividend payout) are examined in 22% of the articles.
Finally, other alternative financing decisions such as
leasing, factoring, or crowdfunding, are discussed in
about 2% of the articles.
When looking at the applied theoretical framework,
we see a clear dominance of agency theory. In about half
of the articles agency theoretical arguments are used for
developing the hypotheses and explaining the results.
Pecking order theory and the socioemotional wealth
(SEW) perspective close the ranks in the top three of
most frequently used theories. It is also remarkable that
in almost one out of five articles, no theoretical argu-
ments are specified. When further investigating the
characteristics of the articles that are not using a clear
theoretical framework, we find that they are published in
finance journals more often than in our full sample of
articles. Articles without a theoretical framework are
also generally older than studies that have a (partial)
theoretical foundation.
Where Are We Now?
Theoretical Foundations
Our survey of the literature on financing decisions in
family firms shows that several traditional capital struc-
ture theories have been used. As described by Titman and
Wessels (1988), Harris and Raviv (1991), Fama and
372
Table 1. Methodological Parameters.
Data source Sample size Temporal dimension Analytical approach Public versus private FB definition FB/NFB versus within FB
Databases 98 (73%) <100 19 (16%) Cross-sectional 57 (48%) Regression 81 (60%) Public firms 68 (53%) Yes 89 (70%) FB versus NFB 79 (65%)
Mailed/delivered
survey
21 (16%) 100-400 44 (38%) Longitudinal 62 (52%) Logit/probit/tobit 29 (21%) Private firms 36 (28%) No 38 (30%) Within FB 33 (27%)
Interviews 4 (3%) 400-1,000 25 (21%) Theoretical 4 (3%) Both 7 (5%) Both 10 (8%)
Case studies 5 (4%) >1,000 29 (25%) Descriptive
statistics
8 (6%) Not specified 17 (13%)
No data 7 (5%) Qualitative 7 (5%)
SEM 2 (1%)
CFA 1 (1%)
Matched pairs 2 (1%)
Difference-in-
differences
2 (1%)
Note. FB = family business; NFB = nonfamily business; SEM = structural equation modeling; CFA = confirmatory factor analysis. As some articles use multiple data sources or analytical approaches, theories,
the number of articles in this table does not add up to the total sample size of 131.
Michiels and Molly 373
French (2002), and Frank and Goyal (2003), most capital
structure theories start from the trade-off or pecking
order approach, both of which are inspired by agency
theory (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Agency theory points
to the information asymmetries and conflicts of interests
between shareholders and bondholders, between share-
holders and managers (principal–agent), and among
shareholders (principal–principal). Trade-off theory
(Modigliani & Miller, 1958; Myers, 1989) focuses on
costs resulting from information asymmetries between
shareholders and bondholders and on benefits such as a
reduction of the free cash flow agency costs (principal–
agent) resulting from the use of debt. Next to that, poten-
tial bankruptcy costs and deductibility of interest
payments are considered to trade-off the costs and bene-
fits related to debt financing to determine the optimal
capital structure in a company. An alternative capital
structure theory, known as the pecking order model, has
been developed by Myers (1984). This model is based on
information asymmetries between the firm and the capi-
tal supplier. As transaction costs arise for each new issue
of securities or debt, firms will prefer to finance their
investments first with retained earnings, then with debt,
and finally with equity. In this way, the financing choice
is driven by the firm’s desire to minimize information
asymmetry costs in raising external finance.
In addition to these traditional theoretical frame-
works that mainly focus on the optimization of the firm’s
capital structure to maximize firm value, the literature
gives evidence of nontraditional approaches to financ-
ing decisions in family firms. For example, Barton and
Matthews (1989), Hutchinson (1995), and Romano,
Tanewski, and Smyrnios (2001) take into account
owner/manager preferences for understanding the capi-
tal structure of these firms. They point to the importance
of control retention, risk aversion, and nonfinancial val-
ues and goals in the owners’/managers’ financial deci-
sion making. This usually results in a higher preference
for internally generated funds rather than external
sources, or debt financing rather than external equity
funding. Recently, these approaches and arguments have
been linked to theoretical frameworks such as the stew-
ardship theory (Davis, Schoorman, & Donaldson, 1997),
the SEW perspective (Gómez-Mejía, Haynes, Núñez-
Nickel, Jacobson, & Moyano-Fuentes, 2007), and the
theory of planned behavior (Ajzen, 1991). Stewardship
theory starts from the idea that individuals in a company
are not predominantly self-serving but that their motives
support those of the company and go beyond purely
economic goals (Zahra, Hayton, Neubaum, Dibrell, &
Craig, 2008). As opposed to agency theory, which
focuses on extrinsic motivation of individuals serving
themselves, stewardship theory stresses their intrinsic
motivation. The SEW perspective is rooted within the
behavioral agency model (Wiseman & Gomez-Mejia,
1998) and refers to the firm’s nonfinancial aspects that
meet the family’s affective needs, such as identity, exer-
cising family influence, and perpetuating the family
dynasty (Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007). According to this
perspective, family firms are expected to pay significant
attention to maintaining family control and are loss
averse when their SEW is threatened. Finally, the theory
of planned behavior considers the family’s attitudes and
values, preferences and norms, and behavioral control as
determining factors of behavioral intentions, which
eventually influence behavioral decisions and choices
(Koropp et al., 2014).
What Do We Know About Financing
Decisions in Family Firms?
In this section, we discuss family business financing
studies in detail, by categorizing them into three groups,
based on the source of financing they deal with.
Debt. When family businesses consider using external
sources of financing, leverage remains by far the most
preferred funding option for family firms (Burgstaller &
Wagner, 2015; Croci, Doukas, & Gonenc, 2011; Koropp,
Grichnik, & Kellermanns, 2013; Poutziouris, 2001;
Romano et al., 2001). As indicated by Blanco-Mazaga-
tos, Quevedo-Puente, and Castrillo (2007), research
findings give evidence of a pecking order in financing
family firms, where debt instead of new equity is pre-
ferred when additional external financing is sought.
However, other studies find evidence of a negative effect
of family ownership on the use of debt financing in both
private (Gallo & Vilaseca, 1996) and public (Mishra &
McConaughy, 1999) family firms. This negative relation
is explained by the dominance of control risk motiva-
tions, the fear of bankruptcy costs, and the bank’s credit
underwriting policy, which concentrates on owners’
wealth instead of the repayment capability of the family
firm (Gallo & Vilaseca, 1996; Mishra & McConaughy,
1999). An interesting phenomenon that has further been
linked to the lower leverage in many family businesses
concerns the zero-leverage company, which tends to
occur more often in family than in nonfamily firms,
374 Family Business Review 30(4)
explained by a stronger aversion in family firms to the
risks linked to financial distress (Strebulaev & Yang,
2013). Finally, studies of Coleman and Carsky (1999)
and Bjuggren, Duggal, and Giang (2012), both focusing
on privately held firms, contradict the aforementioned
findings, as they were not able to find significant differ-
ences in the level of debt used by family versus nonfam-
ily firms.
This overview shows that the literature still remains
inconclusive on the level of debt used in family firms.
This is no surprise, since, according to González,
Guzmán, Pomp, and Trujillo (2013), Schmid (2013),
and Burgstaller and Wagner (2015), a trade-off needs to
be made in family firms between retention of control,
which favors the use of debt financing over external
equity, and risk aversion, which stimulates the company
to adopt more cautious attitudes toward debt. These non-
traditional, behavioral aspects illustrate the complexity
of the leverage decision in family firms. Another factor
that further complicates the debt choice analysis con-
cerns the wide array of leverage alternatives. Although
most studies focus on the total debt rate, the work of
Chaganti and Damanpour (1991), Al-Ajmi, Abo
Hussain, and Al-Saleh (2009), Mishra and McConaughy
(1999), Shyu and Lee (2009), Croci et al. (2011),
Poutziouris (2011), and Segura and Formigoni (2014)
considers the distinction between short- and long-term
debt financing, where findings are mainly explained
through agency, pecking order, and trade-off theories.
Since information asymmetry and transaction costs dif-
fer according to the debt maturity structure, this compli-
cates the comparison between studies and the search for
consistent results.
Furthermore, most studies in our literature review
focus on the comparison between family and nonfamily
businesses. In almost two out of three studies that were
reviewed, a comparison is explicitly made between
these two types of organization. The heterogeneity
among family businesses is therefore often neglected.
However, the differences within the group of family
firms may potentially be even larger than the differences
between family and nonfamily firms (Chua, Chrisman,
Steier, & Rau, 2012), and researchers have therefore
called to focus on the heterogeneous nature of family
businesses (Chua et al., 2012; Nordqvist, Sharma, &
Chirico, 2014). Some studies on capital structure do take
this into consideration by integrating the family’s role in
management (Schmid, 2013), the difference between
owner-managed and non–owner-managed companies
(Batten & Hettihewa, 1999), or the presence of indepen-
dent outside directors in the governance of the firm
(Napoli, 2012). It is clear that these differences in the
management, ownership, and governance structure can
influence the relationship and information asymmetries
between shareholders and bondholders. Other authors
consider family ownership by focusing on the distinc-
tion between cash-flow and control rights, and the pres-
ence of principal–principal agency problems, and how
this influences the family firm’s leverage (King &
Santor, 2008; Shyu & Lee, 2009). Also, Bjuggren et al.
(2012) focus on ownership and find evidence of a
U-shaped relation between ownership dispersion and
debt in private family businesses, which confirms the
earlier work on private family firms of Schulze,
Lubatkin, and Dino (2003). Schulze et al. (2003) found
evidence that the risk attitude of private family firms
changes due to the ownership dispersion in family busi-
nesses. Especially sibling partnerships were found to
use less debt, and thus willing to bear less risk, com-
pared with controlling owners and cousin consortiums,
since they are characterized by increased levels of loss
aversion and misalignment among family members.
A number of authors further stress the importance of
the generational effect on a family firm’s capital struc-
ture. While most of these studies exclusively focus on
privately held firms (Blanco-Mazagatos et al., 2007;
Burgstaller & Wagner, 2015; Koropp, Grichnik, &
Gygax, 2013; Molly, Laveren, & Deloof, 2010; Molly,
Laveren, & Jorissen, 2012), others include both public
and private firms in their sample (Amore, Minichilli, &
Corbetta, 2011; González et al., 2013). Findings indicate
that family generation negatively affects debt financing
(Molly et al., 2010; Molly et al., 2012), while Blanco-
Mazagatos et al. (2007) and González et al. (2013) come
to the opposite conclusion. Burgstaller and Wagner
(2015) were not able to confirm a generational effect on
the use of debt in the family firm. Finally, Koropp,
Grichnik, and Gygax (2013) and Amore et al. (2011)
investigate the impact of succession on the firm’s financ-
ing policies, where the latter study, for example, finds
that nonfamily CEOs stimulate the use of leverage. It is
also important to stress that inconsistent findings can
partly result from the focus in different studies either on
behavioral aspects (retention of control and risk aver-
sion), or on agency theoretical aspects (free cash flow
problems and shareholder–bondholder agency prob-
lems), or on both. In addition, some studies only indi-
rectly measure a generation effect through the firm’s
Michiels and Molly 375
age, or only make a comparison between founders and
descendants without discerning between first-, second-
or later-generation family firms.
Where most of the studies on debt policy in family
businesses take into account the demand side of financ-
ing, other studies mainly focus on the banks’ point of
view and the applied debt conditions toward family
businesses (supply side). Overall, these studies find that
banks generally have a positive feeling toward family
businesses, reducing potential shareholder–bondholder
agency problems. They are considered to be better bor-
rowers with less moral hazard problems (Bopaiah,
1998). This higher trust of banks in family firms results
in easier access to credit in general (Bopaiah, 1998), and
more long-term debt in particular (Croci et al., 2011). In
addition, the easier access to debt financing enables
family firms to adjust faster toward their target leverage
(Pindado, Requejo, & la Torre, 2015). With respect to
this, Song and Wang (2013) focus on the importance of
the relational strength between the family firm and the
financial institution in order to lower information asym-
metries. Chua, Chrisman, Kellermans, and Wu (2011)
even bring forward the relevance of borrowing social
capital (relying on relationships to get access to
resources) available in the family to improve access to
bank financing in new family ventures. Other findings
indicate that several aspects, such as the presence of
pyramid structures (Masulis, Pham, & Zein, 2011) lower
the financing constraints imposed by banks on family
firms. Finally, Chen, Ding, Wu, and Yang (2016) find
that family firms benefit less from the adoption of
International Accounting Standards than nonfamily
firms in terms of access to foreign banks.
When turning to the cost of debt financing, Anderson,
Mansi, and Reeb (2003) also focus on the owner–debt-
holder agency problem to analyze debt financing in pub-
licly listed U.S. family firms. They find evidence that
the cost of debt is lower in firms with family ownership,
external CEOs, or family CEOs who belong to the
founding generation. Also, Boubakri and Ghouma
(2010) focus on the information asymmetries between
shareholders and bondholders in public firms, but they
come to an opposite conclusion in their European and
Asian samples. Because bondholders fear the expropria-
tion by controlling shareholders, family control is found
to increase the cost of debt funding. Similarly, Tanaka
(2014) finds that bondholders of listed Japanese firms
are concerned about family agency conflicts, with an
increasing effect on the cost of public debt as a result.
The findings of Yen, Lin, Chen, and Huang (2015) can
be linked to these previous studies, as they conclude that
public family firms enjoy more favorable loan contracts
than nonfamily firms, but that this positive effect dimin-
ishes when they are more likely to expropriate external
investors. Finally, Waisman (2013) further examines the
effect of family ownership and the takeover friendliness
of a country, on the pricing of loans in U.S. listed firms.
A limited number of studies deepen the understand-
ing of the shareholder–bondholder agency relationship
by taking collateral or guarantees into consideration.
Bagnoli, Liu, and Watts (2011) find that listed family
firms use financial covenants more intensively than non-
family firms. Steijvers and Voordeckers (2009) and
Steijvers, Voordeckers, and Vanhoof (2010) further
point to the use of personal collateral to reduce agency
problems in private family firms. Similarly, Voordeckers
and Steijvers (2006) present several determinants of col-
lateral protection such as bank competition, the use of
credit, the length of the relationship between the bank
and the borrower, next to various other factors. In line
with these studies, Schmid (2013) finds evidence that
the level of debt used in family firms depends on the
level of credit monitoring and is different whether they
are located in bank-based versus other economies.
Finally, a number of studies focus on alternative
forms of debt financing. Di Giuli, Caselli, and Gatti
(2011), Fitó, Moya, and Orgaz (2013), and Landry,
Fortin, and Callimaci (2013) stress to investigate also
other financial instruments used by small- and medium-
sized enterprises (SMEs) such as leasing or factoring.
Evidence is found that family firms are less eager to use
leasing (Landry et al., 2013) and that the level of finan-
cial sophistication (making use of nonbasic financial
products such as leasing) increases over generations and
when the family firm is characterized by an external
CFO or external shareholder (Di Giuli et al., 2011).
Other studies point to the intertwinement of household
and business financing (Haynes, Walker, Rowe, &
Hong, 1999; Muske et al., 2009; Yilmazer & Schrank,
2006) or investigate the use of informal financing com-
ing from friends and family of the owner-manager
(Coleman & Carsky, 1999). The studies indicate that
family firms do not significantly differ from nonfamily
firms in their use of informal sources of financing (such
as loans from family and friends) or financial intermin-
gling (Coleman & Carsky, 1999; Yilmazer & Schrank,
2006) and that the level of intermingling can be linked to
the fact whether the business is incorporated or a sole
376 Family Business Review 30(4)
proprietorship (Haynes et al., 1999), or whether the fam-
ily business is operated by copreneurs (Muske et al.,
2009). Finally, Lappalainen and Niskanen (2013) and
Psillaki and Eleftheriou (2015) specifically focus on
trade credit, a type of nonfinancial leverage, which is
extensively used in many privately held family firms in
practice as well. Lappalainen and Niskanen (2013) focus
on the use and attitude toward trade credit in family and
nonfamily SMEs, while Psillaki and Eleftheriou (2015)
rather investigate the relation and complementarity
between bank borrowing and trade credit.
External Equity. Another stream of research focuses on
the use of external equity. On the one hand, several stud-
ies indicate that family involvement appears to result in
lower use of external equity (Wu, Chua, & Chrisman,
2007; Poutziouris, 2011), both based on samples consist-
ing of private as well as public firms. Usually, the dis-
tance between family firms and outside investors is quite
large, mainly due to the so-called empathy gap between
owners and investors (Poutziouris, 2011) or because of
the generally preferred retention of control rather than
the firm’s growth and development (Wu et al., 2007). On
the other hand, contrary to the pecking order perspective,
King and Peng (2013) find that in industries character-
ized by cyclicality, capital intensity, and growth, large
listed family firms rely on equity financing before debt
financing to fund their expansion, mainly because of a
strong aversion linked to financial distress.
When further analyzing the literature on external
equity in family firms, a number of studies focus on the
use of private equity and venture capital. These sources
may be more preferred than generally thought because
of the opportunities it offers to fund the family firm tran-
sition (Upton & Petty, 2000), or because of the nonfi-
nancial benefits that such investors can bring to the
family such as managerial support, expertise, and con-
tacts (Martí, Menéndez-Requejo, & Rottke, 2013;
Tappeiner, Howorth, Achleitner, & Schraml, 2012).
Other studies investigate the impact of private equity
investors on the long-term performance (Desbrières &
Schatt, 2002; Viviani, Giorgino, & Steri, 2008), the gov-
ernance structure, its benefits, and costs (Achleitner,
Herman, Lerner, & Lutz, 2010), and the strategy
(Scholes, Wright, Westhead, Bruining, & Kloeckner,
2009) of the family business. Evidence is found that the
participation of private equity reduces performance in
the years after an IPO (Viviani et al., 2008) or after a
leveraged buyout (Desbrières & Schatt, 2002). With
regard to strategy, Scholes et al. (2009) come to the con-
clusion that private equity–backed buyouts strongly
affect the strategy of family firms, but that this impact
varies according to the presence of the founder, the pres-
ence of managers with equity stakes, the involvement of
nonexecutive directors, and the involvement in succes-
sion planning. Finally, while most studies take the per-
spective of the family business (demand side), a number
of recent studies focus on the perceptions of private
equity investors (Dawson, 2011) or institutional inves-
tors (Fernando, Schneible, & Suh, 2014) toward family
businesses (supply-side). Dawson (2011) finds that pri-
vate equity investors take into account human resources,
the level of professionalization, and the opportunity to
reduce agency costs when selecting family firms.
Fernando et al. (2014) bring forward that institutional
investors avoid to invest in family firms because of
increased Type 2 agency problems compared with non-
family firms.
Firms can also acquire equity financing through an
IPO. Our sample contains several articles on this topic,
all published after the year 2000. While this is an impor-
tant event for all kinds of firms, it especially is for family
businesses. After all, a change in ownership structure by
going public implies a significant change in the gover-
nance of family businesses, because it is often the first
time that outside shareholders come into play (Ehrhardt
& Nowak, 2003). The most important financial reason
for family businesses to go public is the need to raise
higher funds to finance growth or to rebalance the debt–
equity level (Mazzola & Marchisio, 2002). Research on
the IPO process can be divided into three categories: the
pre-IPO process, the IPO itself (first trading day), and the
post-IPO process. As the aim of this article is to review
studies on the financing decision in family firms, we only
examine studies on the pre-IPO process and the IPO
itself, and not the performance after an IPO (post-IPO).
The first stream of research indicates that outside
expertise in the pre-IPO process appears to be advanta-
geous for family-controlled firms. Family firms may thus
benefit from associations with venture capitalists
(Astrachan & McConaughy, 2001) and with prestigious
investment banking firms (Walker, 2008) as this lowers
the information asymmetries between the issuer and the
investors. The second stream of research investigates the
IPO itself, and more in particular the relation between the
closing price and the offer price (IPO over- or underpric-
ing). Family firms are found to have 10 percentage points
more IPO underpricing than nonfamily firms (Leitterstorf
Michiels and Molly 377
& Rau, 2014). A number of studies have further investi-
gated this phenomenon of family business IPO underpric-
ing. IPO underpricing is found to be positively related to
family ownership (Lin & Chuang, 2011), generational
stage (Yu & Zheng, 2012), participation of family mem-
bers at the board level (Hearn, 2011), and the willingness
to preserve their SEW (Leitterstorf & Rau, 2014). IPO
underpricing is found to be negatively related to the ratio
of nonfamily directors (Ding & Pukthuanthong-Le,
2009), to wider dispersion of family ownership (Hearn,
2011), and to associations with prestigious investment
banking firms (Walker, 2008). These findings indicate
that family firms tend to use IPO underpricing as a way of
retaining control of the family firm. Alternatively, family
firms’ IPO underpricing might be a sign of risk aversion,
as IPO underpricing reduces the risk of lawsuits (Ibbotson,
1975) and the risk of a failed IPO (Welch, 1992). Recently,
Cirillo, Romano, and Ardovino (2015) find that family
firms positively influence IPO value, although the authors
measure IPO value differently by separately considering
offering and closing price, and by including accounting-
based information.
Other empirical studies investigate differences
between family and nonfamily firms for several stock
exchange–related phenomena, by focusing mainly on
the presence of principal–principal information asym-
metries and the importance of retention of control. For
instance, family controlled firms are found to have
higher voting premiums (Caprio & Croci, 2008), have
increased liquidity when double voting rights are used
(Ginglinger & Hamon, 2012), and have a higher price of
vote in unifications (Hauser & Lauterbach, 2004) than
nonfamily firms. In addition, a number of studies focus
on the cost of equity capital in listed family firms in rela-
tion to various other topics, for example, to the Asian
financial crisis (Boubakri, Guedhami, & Mishra, 2010),
to corporate social responsibility practices in listed
Taiwanese firms (Wu, Lin, & Wu, 2014), or to corporate
governance attributes (D. H. Tran, 2014). Finally, the
recent study by Jain and Shao (2015) investigates the
financial policy choices following an IPO and find that
family firms have a higher leverage, prefer a longer debt
maturity structure, and raise less external capital post-
IPO compared with nonfamily firms.
Retained Earnings Versus Dividends. Pecking order theory
states that firms prefer to finance new investments first
internally, through retained earnings (Myers, 1984). All
earnings that are retained in the firm, however, cannot
be distributed as dividends. This has led researchers to
examine this trade-off (retained earnings vs. dividend
payouts) that family businesses are facing when decid-
ing on how to allocate their earnings. The majority of the
articles study dividend policy in the context of publicly
held firms, and about half of the dividend articles in our
literature review focus on firms in Asia, where many
economies are characterized by considerable family
ownership of listed corporations (Chen, Cheung, Sto-
uraitis, & Wong, 2005). The studies in our sample inves-
tigate one (or more) of the following aspects of dividend
policy: propensity to pay dividends, dividend payout
level, or dividend smoothing.
Regarding the propensity to pay dividends, research-
ers found family firms to be less likely to pay dividends
than nonfamily firms because of their stronger focus on
the firm’s long-term orientation (Lace, Bistrova, &
Kozlovskis, 2013). Within the group of family firms,
SMEs (How, Verhoeven, & Wu, 2008) and private fam-
ily firms with passive family shareholders (Michiels,
Voordeckers, Lybaert, & Steijvers, 2015) are more likely
to pay dividends than other family firms, mainly
explained by information asymmetries between major-
ity and minority shareholders.
A large group of studies on the topic of dividend pol-
icy particularly examines the level of dividend payout.
Most researchers agree that family firms have higher
dividend payout levels than nonfamily firms (Carney &
Gedajlovic, 2002; Chen et al., 2005; Huang, Chen, &
Kao, 2012; Pindado, Requejo, & la Torre, 2012; Setia-
Atmaja, Tanewski, & Skully, 2009; Yoshikawa &
Rasheed, 2010). These studies thus find support for the
expropriation hypothesis, according to which paying
dividends is a mechanism that can be used to align the
interests of controlling family and minority shareholders
(Faccio, Lang, & Young, 2001; Setia-Atmaja et al.,
2009). Thus, the higher dividend payouts of family firms
might be considered as a result of investors demanding
higher dividend payouts from companies with the high-
est risk of expropriation of minority shareholders.
Risk arguments are also often used to explain the
higher dividend payout levels of family firms. Some
authors explain the higher dividends in family firms by
using risk aversion arguments. Family firm owners con-
sider high retained earnings as an undesirable concentra-
tion of firm-specific risk (Carney & Gedajlovic, 2002;
Huang et al., 2012) and a more concrete threat to their
welfare than a decline in the stock price (DeAngelo &
DeAngelo, 2000), and therefore prefer dividends that
378 Family Business Review 30(4)
can be reinvested in other firms or which can be used for
personal consumption. Other authors focus on argu-
ments of control risk (or retention of control) to explain
the higher dividend payouts of family firms. For exam-
ple, to enhance their wealth through capital gains, fam-
ily firm owners will have to sell their shareholdings,
which will dilute their control over the firm (Vandemaele
& Vancauteren, 2015; Yoshikawa & Rasheed, 2010).
Also, when a family has low levels of cash flow rights,
controlling families of public firms are found to pay
higher dividends in order to preserve personal wealth
due to the threat to lose control at any time (Huang et al.,
2012). In addition, several studies confirm the impor-
tance of taking into account the heterogeneity of family
businesses when studying dividend payout. For exam-
ple, family SMEs are found to pay out more dividends
than larger family firms (How et al., 2008). Family
influence on dividend policy was also proven to vary
depending on family involvement in ownership, man-
agement, and control, for a sample of private firms
(Vandemaele & Vancauteren, 2015) and a sample con-
sisting of both private and public firms (González,
Guzmán, Pomp, & Trujillo, 2014). The theoretical argu-
ments used in both articles differ and include factors
such as retention of control or information asymmetries
between shareholders.
Regarding dividend smoothing, family firms are
found to have less stable dividends than state-owned
firms (He, Li, & Tang, 2012) and nonfamily firms
(Gugler, 2003), which suggests that family firms can
adjust their dividend policy as investment opportunities
or financing needs occur and thus have more freedom in
making financing decisions. On the contrary, Pindado
et al. (2012), who use a more extensive database than the
above-mentioned studies (using data from 645 public
firms in 9 different countries, over a period of 10 years)
find that family firms distribute more stable dividends
than nonfamily firms. These authors argue that family
firms smooth their dividends to avoid future financing
constraints such as running out of capital and thereby
compromising profitable future investments. In com-
parison to the work of Gugler (2003), the authors do not
focus on principal–agent but on principal–principal
agency problems.
A Framework to Understand Family Business
Financing Decisions
In Figure 1, we present a framework that structures the
extant literature on financing decisions in family firms.
As has become clear from the aforementioned literature
review, several factors complicate a thorough under-
standing of family business financing decisions and may
lead to inconsistent results: the theoretical arguments
applied, the demand- versus supply-side focus, the com-
parison between family and nonfamily firms or within
the group of family firms, and contextual factors.
Appendix B gives an overview of the extant literature
Figure 1. Framework for organizing research on financing decisions in family businesses.
Michiels and Molly 379
reviewed in this article and how to frame these studies in
the structure of Figure 1. This framework will also be
used in the next section to structure suggestions to fur-
ther develop the field in the future.
Where Should We Go?
Based on the literature review above and on the results
of an enquiry of an expert panel in the area of finance
and/or family businesses, this section discusses opportu-
nities and challenges for future research in the field of
financing decisions in family firms. We discuss opportu-
nities and challenges across theoretical perspectives, as
well as across context-specific elements. Suggestions of
potential research questions are stated throughout the
text and are summarized in Table 2.
Future Research Opportunities and
Challenges Across Theoretical Perspectives
Researchers have been questioning the applicability of
classical agency theory to family firms because of the
absence of a separation between ownership and control,
especially in privately held family businesses (Anderson
& Reeb, 2003; Ang, Cole, & Lin, 2000). Still, agency
theory and other traditional finance theories such as
pecking order theory and trade-off theory are among the
dominant frameworks used by family business research-
ers in studying financing decisions (Fama & French,
2002; Frank & Goyal, 2003; Harris & Raviv, 1991;
Titman & Wessels, 1988). However, a number of limita-
tions to the applicability of these traditional finance
theories to explain family business financing decisions
are worth getting attention.
First, agency theory, pecking order theory, and trade-
off theory are all based on the wealth maximization prin-
ciple of organizations, assuming that mainly financial
motives will influence financing decisions. More specifi-
cally, the trade-off theory assumes that firms are trying to
reach an optimal debt level by balancing the costs of debt
against the benefits of debt (Kraus & Litzenberger,
1973). As such, this theory partly relies on agency theory
to identify costs related to information asymmetries
between shareholders and bondholders, and benefits
related to the potential of debt financing in reducing
information asymmetries between shareholders and
managers. Pecking order theory focuses on the diminish-
ing preference in using retained earnings, then debt and
finally external equity, based on information asymmetry
costs linked to these different forms of financing (Myers,
1984). While these financial arguments can be applied to
family businesses, financing behavior in family firms is
not exclusively driven by financial motives, but also by
noneconomic considerations such as the risk-taking pro-
pensity, emotions, preferred values, and goals of the fam-
ily. Thus, traditional finance theories, in their current
form, are unable to fully explain financing behavior in
family firms. Therefore, it is worth investigating further
how behavioral arguments (such as, e.g., SEW, theory of
planned behavior, stewardship theory) relate to each
other and to the dominant agency perspective for explain-
ing financing behavior. Despite the increasing attention
to the behavioral financing approach, it remains an
underresearched topic that has much potential in analyz-
ing financing decisions in family firms. Future research
that links noneconomic considerations such as family
business goals and risk preferences to capital structure
decisions would fill a gap in the literature on the actual
incentives and motives of family owners to steer capital
structure decisions. A way to open this black box can be
through qualitative research, which is very relevant in
examining and understanding processes (Langley &
Abdallah, 2011; Pratt, 2009), but at the same time, it
allows answering “why” and “how” questions, which are
very difficult to answer through quantitative research
methods (Reay, 2014). Relying on interviews, case stud-
ies, or observations would enable scholars to signifi-
cantly improve our knowledge on why certain sources of
financing are used in family firms and how financing
decisions are taken in reality (Koropp et al., 2014; Shyu
& Lee, 2009). Qualitative case study research is
also ideal to help sharpen existing theory by pointing to
gaps and beginning to fill them (Siggelkow, 2007).
Alternatively, when performing quantitative research, a
multirespondent approach in which all persons poten-
tially involved in the financial decision-making process
are questioned, would on the one hand allow researchers
to gain representativeness by forming a consensus-based
data set in which method biases caused by individual
respondents’ affect or mood are reduced (e.g., Chua,
Chrisman, & Sharma, 1999; Podsakoff, MacKenzie, Lee,
& Podsakoff, 2003). On the other hand, dispersion mod-
els that take into account discord among family members
are interesting to explore as well in the analysis of finan-
cial decision making in family firms (see Holt, Madison,
& Kellermanns, 2017). This way, broader and deeper
theoretical insights on the financial decision-making pro-
cess can be obtained.
380 Family Business Review 30(4)
Table 2. Potential Future Research Questions on Financing Decisions Within Family Firms.
Gaps
Demand/supply
side
Source of
financing Possible research questions
Theoretical Both Various How do behavioral arguments for explaining financing behavior
(such as SEW [socioemotional wealth] or stewardship
theory) relate to each other and to the dominant agency
perspective? How are noneconomic considerations such as
family business goals and risk preferences related to capital
structure decisions? How could the socioemotional wealth
perspective extend our view on the demand side of financing?
How could alternative forms of financing such as leasing,
crowdfunding, mini bonds, state-subsidize or subordinated
loans and intermingling between firm and household finance
be incorporated into the traditional finance theories? How
does the importance of SEW influence financing behavior of
family firms in comparison to nonfamily firms?
Heterogeneity
across family
firms
Demand Various Do variations in the importance attached to SEW lead to
heterogeneous financing decisions among family firms? What
is the impact of potential SEW gains on financing decisions?
Do female and male family business managers tend to differ
with respect to financing decisions? What is the impact of
visible minorities in the board or management team on a
family firm’s financing choices? What is the impact of the
financial knowledge and competencies of family owners and
their reliance on financial advice on the financing decisions
that are being taken? To what extent are financing decisions
in family firms time-varying and depending on the family and
the firm’s life stage?
Demand Debt What is the effect of board characteristics on the amount of
debt financing that is applied for? How does the process
develop through which financing decisions are taken within
the board and/or the management of the company? What is
the impact of family governance on the willingness to take on
extra bank financing?
Demand External equity What is the impact of family governance on the willingness to
take on external equity?
Demand Retained
earnings
What is the impact of family governance on the willingness to
adapt dividend payouts?
Supply Debt, external
equity
Does the degree to which a family business is professionalized
influence the access to external financing? How does the
presence of venture capital influence access to bank debt?
Are SEW aspects in family firms considered either as a risk-
enhancing or a risk-reducing motive by capital suppliers?
Supply Debt What is the impact of relationship lending on getting bank
financing for family businesses? How is relationship lending
influenced by generation?
Heterogeneity
across countries
Demand Various What are the consequences for family business financing
behavior that result from certain policy shifts due to taxation?
Both Various How can country-level factors be differentiated from firm-level
effects on family firm financing behavior? How has the global
financial crisis that began in 2007 affected the demand and
supply of finance to family firms?
Michiels and Molly 381
A second main limitation of the traditional finance
theories is that they do not clearly distinguish between
the demand and supply sides of financing. If family busi-
nesses, for example, make less use of certain sources of
financing, the main question is whether this is because of
a restricted access to external financing (supply) or
because of a lower willingness to attract financing
(demand). In the traditional finance theories both per-
spectives can be detected. For the trade-off and agency
theories, the agency costs of debt between shareholders
and debtholders refer to the supply side of financing as it
forms one of the main arguments why some family busi-
nesses are constrained in attracting financing. With
respect to the demand side, we can refer to the costs of
financial distress, which increases the reluctance to use
debt financing, or to the debt control mechanism, which
can stimulate family business owners to use debt financ-
ing to reduce information asymmetries between manag-
ers and themselves. When turning to pecking order
theory, both perspectives can be detected as well. The
information asymmetry costs linked to certain forms of
financing put constraints on the provisions of external
financing to family firms (supply), leading to a sequen-
tial order in the preference of using various sources of
financing (demand). Thus, in developing and testing
hypotheses, and in selecting and constructing samples,
future research should make a clear distinction between
supply-side and demand-side perspectives. Otherwise,
findings will be biased as they will not be able to separate
demand-side from supply-side arguments in explaining
the relation(s) found.
Furthermore, following a behavioral approach
extends our knowledge on the demand side of financing,
which is only partially captured by the traditional
finance theories, and to gain more knowledge on how it
relates to the supply-side factors of financing. Especially
the SEW perspective (Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007), which
is based on behavioral agency theory in management lit-
erature, appears to be a promising framework to study
demand aspects of financing decisions in family busi-
nesses. Preservation of SEW is usually an important
objective for many family-owned businesses, which
translates itself among others in keeping independence
and control in ownership, exerting control over the com-
pany’s strategic direction, limiting the role of outside
directors in the board, building strong and long-term
relations based on trust, decision making affected by
emotions and sentiments, and long-term evaluation of
investments (Berrone, Cruz, & Gomez-Mejia, 2012).
Each of these factors is likely to affect the willingness of
family businesses to use various sources of financing,
extending our view on the demand side of financing. In
addition, SEW arguments can also be linked to the avail-
ability of external financing (supply), since capital sup-
pliers might take these arguments into account as well
when making financing/investment decisions. In this
respect, future research might investigate whether SEW
aspects in family firms are considered either a risk-
enhancing or a risk-reducing motive by capital suppli-
ers? Overall, SEW could provide benefits to the finance
field by integrating the idea that family firms are willing
to sacrifice economic gains in order to preserve noneco-
nomic utility. At the same time family business financ-
ing could also be an interesting context to deepen our
knowledge on the theoretical underpinnings of SEW,
which still need further attention and development
(Chua, Chrisman, & De Massis, 2015). In addition, also
other nontraditional behavioral perspectives such as the
stewardship theory or the theory of planned behavior
form promising theoretical frameworks for future stud-
ies in this field, as they consider noneconomic goals and
pro-organizational behavior in the family firm (steward-
ship theory), and norms, attitudes, perceived behavioral
control, and behavioral intentions of family owners/
managers (theory of planned behavior).
Another important aspect in explaining the demand
side of financing revolves around the interaction
between financing and growth, and the extent to which
capital structure and growth are determined by the will-
ingness to borrow versus the willingness to grow. In the
extant literature, financing and growth behavior have
been studied separately, although several studies sug-
gest that financing and growth are interrelated.
According to pecking order approach, growth is an
important determinant when analyzing the capital struc-
ture of a company (Fama & French, 2002). Other stud-
ies point at the impact of a firm’s capital structure on a
firm’s growth rate, where firm growth is constrained by
the availability of financial resources (Carpenter &
Petersen, 2002; Oliveira & Fortunato, 2006). It is there-
fore important for future research to further explore the
simultaneous interaction between a firm’s debt level
and growth rate and potential endogeneity by using the
appropriate estimation techniques such as simultaneous
equations analysis, as demonstrated for example in the
work of Molly et al. (2012).
382 Family Business Review 30(4)
Next, traditional frameworks such as pecking order
theory also need a more extended and detailed view
beyond the use of classic financing forms such as
retained earnings, debt, and external equity. For exam-
ple, alternative forms of financing such as leasing,
crowdfunding, mini bonds, state-subsidized loans, sub-
ordinated loans, and intermingling between firm and
household finances should be incorporated in these tra-
ditional theories. This way, scholars can make an inter-
esting and incremental contribution to family business
literature by modifying existing theories to improve
their explanatory power (Reay & Whetten, 2011).
Future Research Opportunities and
Challenges Across Context-Specific Elements
Heterogeneity Among Family Firms. In analyzing the arti-
cles on financing decisions in family firms, a significant
number of studies do not integrate the criteria to identify
family firms. Our review shows that about 25% of the
articles published after 2010 still lacks a clear family
business definition. The remaining studies define family
firms in very diverging ways. This is especially trouble-
some because it hampers the accumulation of knowl-
edge (Schulze & Gedajlovic, 2010). In light of this
discussion in family business literature on what exactly
characterizes a family business, we urge researchers to
take fully into account the family firm definition used in
their sample, in order to enhance cross-study compari-
son of research results. Moreover, we also recommend
scholars to focus more strongly on the heterogeneity of
family businesses and how this influences their financ-
ing decisions, since the majority of articles exclusively
takes into account the oversimplified comparison
between family and nonfamily firms. Family firms
could indeed have a peculiar financial logic, but this is
likely to be influenced by a variety of factors that can be
traced back to the internal characteristics of the family
and the business, and of the external environment as
well. As such, we are echoing recent calls for research
that have been made by Chua et al. (2012) and Nordqvist
et al. (2014) to go beyond comparisons between family
and nonfamily firms and to focus on the heterogeneous
nature of this type of organization. Most studies in our
review rely on secondary data, which often do not
account for this family business heterogeneity in a
refined way. Analysis based on detailed survey data or
qualitative research could deepen our knowledge in this
direction. In addition, meta-analyses could bring more
clarity as well in the various dichotomies that can be
found in the literature (e.g., Do family firms pay out
more or less dividends?).
This heterogeneous nature could be captured by tak-
ing into account the different goals, governance struc-
tures, and resources they have (Chrisman & Patel, 2012;
Chrisman, Sharma, Steier, & Chua, 2013; Chua et al.,
2012). As these three drivers are considered to be the
sources of differences in behavior among family firms as
well as between family and nonfamily firms (Chrisman
& Holt, 2016; De Massis, Kotlar, Chua, & Chrisman,
2014), they provide an excellent basis to distinguish
between different types of family firms to investigate
financing decisions in the remainder of this article.
Goal-related sources of heterogeneity that might
broaden our insight into the financing decisions of fam-
ily firms are, for example, the importance family owners
place on SEW goals. As indicated above, researchers
have started to rely on the SEW premise in order to
explain financing behavior of family firms. Yet none of
these studies have directly measured SEW, which essen-
tially makes it hard to indicate what exactly drives fam-
ily firm financing behavior. In this sense, the
Socioemotional Wealth Importance Scale, recently
developed by Debicki, Kellermanns, Chrisman, Pearson,
and Spencer (2016) could be an interesting measure.
Future research might use this scale to test how the
importance of SEW influences financing behavior of
family firms in comparison with nonfamily firms and
how variations in the importance attached to SEW leads
to heterogeneous financing decisions among family
firms. As an example, it would be interesting to investi-
gate whether the use of collateral is influenced by the
family owners’ risk tolerance and willingness to give up
control. Additionally, although researchers generally
only focus on SEW loss aversion in financial decision
making (risk of losing control, financial risk aversion),
we encourage future research that investigates the
impact of potential SEW gains on financing decisions as
well. After all, family firms may prioritize financial
goals when the socioemotional gains of these goals are
perceived as outweighing socioemotional costs. Thus,
family firms may sometimes choose not to pursue SEW
goals when the second order, negative socioemotional
effects (i.e., the socioemotional costs) are expected to be
too large (Martin & Gomez-Mejia, 2016).
Governance-related sources of heterogeneity arise
from the family’s involvement in ownership and man-
agement and can also lead to a wide variety of outcomes
Michiels and Molly 383
(Chua et al., 2012). Next to investigating the difference
in importance placed on socioemotional concerns, the
discretion that family members have in pursuing those
concerns are important to take into account (Chrisman
& Holt, 2016). Since capital structure decisions are nor-
mally influenced or taken by the board of directors, the
role and quality of this board are likely to affect financ-
ing decisions in family firms. Future research could
therefore study the effect of board characteristics on the
amount of debt financing that is applied for and the pro-
cess through which financing decisions are taken within
the board and/or the management of the company. In
contrast to nonfamily firms, the sustainability of family
firms depends not only on the success of the firm but
also on the functionality of the family (Stafford, Duncan,
Dane, & Winter, 1999). Thus, as the business family
also needs to be governed, specific family governance
mechanisms might be installed in the firm. Through
these family governance mechanisms, family members
can, for example, be informed about interesting invest-
ment opportunities, thereby raising the families’ aware-
ness of the negative second-order effects that are
associated with SEW goals (Martin & Gomez-Mejia,
2016). An interesting avenue for future research might
therefore be to investigate whether family governance
influences the willingness to, for example, take on exter-
nal equity or extra bank financing (demand-side) or to
adapt dividend payouts. In addition, both corporate and
family governance mechanisms implemented within the
family business might be taken into account by external
investors or loan officers. More specifically, having a
formalized board of directors, and/or well-functioning
family governance practices might be a sign of profes-
sionalization to capital suppliers. Future research could
investigate whether this higher professionalization
degree indeed influences the ability to obtain external
financing (supply-side).
Family firm goals are also likely to change when
the firm moves from one generation to another, and
the financing challenge is likely to become even big-
ger over generations (Coleman & Carsky, 1999).
Future research is needed to provide us with further
insight into the extent to which financing decisions in
family firms are time-varying and depending on the
family and firm’s life stage. For example, factors worth
investigating concern the changing goal orientation
and risk behavior of founders versus successors, the
relationship and conflicts between different genera-
tions of family members, the changing ownership and
management structure pre- versus post-succession, the
type of succession, the source of transition funding,
and so on. The role of family offices in intergenera-
tional wealth creation and preservation also forms an
interesting avenue for future research (see Zellweger
& Kammerlander, 2015, for a profound theoretical
overview on this topic).
Apart from investigating the importance family
members place on SEW and other concerns, and their
ability to pursue those concerns, also the family firm’s
capabilities to achieve these goals are important aspects
to consider (Chrisman & Holt, 2016). Examples of
resource-related sources of heterogeneity that could be
taken into account when examining financing decisions
in family firms are, for example, the availability of fam-
ily-based human assets (Verbeke & Kano, 2012), the
ability to professionalize the firm (Chua, Chrisman, &
Sharma, 2003), or the presence of venture capital, which
can influence the resources available to the firm both in
quantity and quality. Therefore, future research could
investigate how these resource-related aspects influence
the availability of external financing (supply) as well as
the willingness (demand) to attract debt or equity financ-
ing. Another interesting research direction related to the
human resources available to the family firm concerns
the impact of gender on financing decisions in family
firms. Although women’s access to, and use of, debt
(e.g., Coleman, 2004; Constantinidis, Cornet, &
Asandei, 2006; Francis, Hasan, & Wu, 2013), angel cap-
ital (Becker-Blease & Sohl, 2007), and bootstrap financ-
ing (Neeley & Van Auken, 2010) has been explored in
finance and entrepreneurship journals, none of these
studies has considered the family firm or family CEO
contingency. Yet the impact of having a female CEO on
a firm’s financing choices might be different for family
firms than for nonfamily firms and might also differ
within the group of family firms. Additionally, woman
entrepreneurship studies have emphasized that female
business owners tend to balance economic goals with
noneconomic goals more often than their male counter-
parts (Hechavarria, Ingram, Justo, & Terjesen, 2012;
Jennings & Brush, 2013; Sullivan & Meek, 2012). Thus,
future research could investigate whether female and
male family business managers tend to differ with
respect to financing decisions by using the SEW per-
spective. A similar ongoing debate worth investigating
concerns the impact of visible minorities in the board or
management team on a family firms’ financing choices
(e.g., Cavalluzzo & Cavalluzzo, 1998; Coleman, 2004).
384 Family Business Review 30(4)
Firm size can also lead to heterogeneity among fam-
ily firms, as it might explain the goals, governance, and
resources of family firms (Chua et al., 2012). As indi-
cated by the literature review, most of the studies are
oriented toward large public firms even though, in real-
ity, small private firms are the norm. The findings result-
ing from samples of large listed family businesses
cannot automatically be transferred to privately owned
companies that usually are of a much smaller size, and
thus more explicit evidence is required on this size
effect. For example, many small family firms will be
confronted with financial illiteracy (Koropp, Grichnik,
& Kellermanns, 2013), which could be addressed par-
tially through the financial advice provided by bankers
or accountants. However, the literature is quite silent on
the financial knowledge and competencies of family
owners and their reliance on financial advice. Also, firm
age could be an important factor in explaining financing
decisions, as relationship lending could play a signifi-
cant role in getting bank financing for companies with a
longer history. However, little knowledge exists on this
topic, thus warranting further research on, for example,
how the family’s history, generation, and legacy influ-
ences this relationship. We recognize, however, that this
presents “both an opportunity and a challenge to future
research, as access to data from a large sample of these
[privately held] firms is severely limited” (Gómez-
Mejía, Larraza-Kintana, & Makri, 2003, p. 236).
Heterogeneity Across Countries. The majority of empirical
articles in our review are single-country studies. This is
somewhat surprising, given that several researchers
have pointed to the large differences that occur between
countries regarding their level of investor and creditor
protection, their level of development of financial mar-
kets, the degree to which the capital markets are bank-
centered, their culture, and their legal framework (civil
vs. common law; Driffield, Mahambare, & Pal, 2007;
King & Santor, 2008; Lappalainen & Niskanen, 2013;
Santos, Moreira, & Vieira, 2014). For example, several
countries have introduced rules to correcting the incen-
tive to take on excessive debt, such as limiting the
deductibility of interest costs (France, Germany, Hun-
gary, Spain, Italy) or extending the deductibility to
include the cost of equity financing (Belgium, Italy, Por-
tugal; European Commission, 2015b). These incentives
might significantly influence decisions on capital struc-
ture and dividend payout. More investigation into these
country-level factors, and how they can be differentiated
from firm-level effects, on family firm financing behav-
ior, are thus warranted. Performing these multicountry
studies might also clarify some of the inconsistent
results on family business financing found in extant
studies (see, e.g., the multicountry study of Pindado
et al., 2012, on dividend smoothing).
In addition, longitudinal approaches could allow for
capturing the consequences for family business financ-
ing behavior that result from certain policy shifts due to
taxation (e.g., the changes in deductibility of interest
costs, as discussed above), banking regulation (e.g., the
implementation of Basel III), or financial–economic
shocks. More specifically, taxation rules might discour-
age family firms to take on debt or pay out dividends in
some countries, whereas they will not in other countries.
So as to be able to compare studies, and to find explana-
tions for contrasting results, we urge researchers to dis-
cuss the taxation rules applicable in their sample country,
and, in case of a multicountry study, to thoroughly
review the differences in taxation rules.
Finally, future research could examine how a major
crisis such as the global financial crisis that began in
2007 has affected financing decisions in family firms.
After all, periods of economic downturn could strongly
influence financing decisions in family businesses
given the reduced availability of capital and other
sources of financing. Apart from a number of articles
in this direction, more efforts are needed to signifi-
cantly broaden our knowledge on how financial crises
affect family firm financing decisions (Amann &
Jaussaud, 2012; Boubakri et al., 2010; Pindado et al.,
2012). Possible research questions are abundant. For
example, the effect of a financial crisis on voluntary
delistings, the use of private equity, the commitment to
pay dividends, and so on. Again, we especially encour-
age researchers to take into account the heterogeneity
of family firms when examining the impact of eco-
nomic shocks or crises.
Conclusion
Motivated by the growing attention to family firms in
general, and their financing decisions in particular,
this review brings together the two highly relevant
research fields of family business and finance. As the
knowledge and contributions on financing decisions in
family firms are quite dispersed, we develop a state of
the art on family business financing literature and
present a model to guide future research by identifying
Michiels and Molly 385
gaps across the theoretical perspectives, the demand
versus supply side of financing, and across contexts.
More specifically, we discuss the arguments underly-
ing traditional theories and elaborate on their applica-
bility to study financing decisions in family businesses.
We also present future research opportunities and
challenges across the context-specific elements such
as family business heterogeneity and country-specific
factors. We hope that our review provides finance
scholars with fruitful research ideas which eventually
will contribute to advance our understanding of family
firm financing behavior in theory and practice.
Appendix A
Distribution of Articles by Journal.
Journal 2016 Impact factor N%
Family Business Review 4.229 17 12.98%
Small Business Economics 2.421 8 6.11%
Journal of Banking & Finance 1.776 8 6.11%
Journal of Family Business Strategy 2.375 6 4.58%
Journal of Small Business Management 2.876 6 4.58%
Journal of Business Venturing 5.774 5 3.82%
Corporate Governance: An International Review 3.571 5 3.82%
Journal of Financial Economics 4.505 4 3.05%
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 1.276 4 3.05%
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 4.916 3 2.29%
Asia Pacific Journal of Management 2.024 2 1.53%
Business History 0.83 2 1.53%
Journal of Management & Governance N/A 2 1.53%
Journal of Private Equity N/A 2 1.53%
Journal of Small Business & Entrepreneurship N/A 2 1.53%
Journal of Management Studies 3.962 2 1.53%
Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 1.754 2 1.53%
Review of Financial Studies 3.689 2 1.53%
Strategic Management Journal 4.461 2 1.53%
The Journal of Risk Finance N/A 2 1.53%
Journal of Corporate Finance 1.579 2 1.53%
Academy of Management Journal 7.417 1 0.76%
American Journal of Small Business N/A 1 0.76%
Annals of Finance N/A 1 0.76%
Annals of Financial Economics N/A 1 0.76%
Asia Pacific Business Review 1 1 0.76%
Asian Academy of Management Journal of Accounting & Finance N/A 1 0.76%
Brazilian Business Review N/A 1 0.76%
British Accounting Review 2.135 1 0.76%
Business Ethics Quarterly 1.703 1 0.76%
Business: Theory & Practice N/A 1 0.76%
Economics & Rural Development N/A 1 0.76%
Economics Letters 0.558 1 0.76%
Economics of Transition 0.479 1 0.76%
Emerging Markets Finance & Trade 0.826 1 0.76%
European Financial Management 1.236 1 0.76%
Finance N/A 1 0.76%
(continued)
386 Family Business Review 30(4)
Appendix B
Journal 2016 Impact factor N%
Industrial & Corporate Change 1.777 1 0.76%
International Review of Financial Analysis 1.457 1 0.76%
International Review of Law & Economics 0.57 1 0.76%
Japan & the World Economy 0.489 1 0.76%
Journal of Business 1.133 1 0.76%
Journal of Business & Retail Management Research N/A 1 0.76%
Journal of Business Ethics 2.354 1 0.76%
Journal of Business Research 3.354 1 0.76%
Journal of Enterprising Culture N/A 1 0.76%
Journal of Financial & Quantitative Analysis 1.673 1 0.76%
Journal of Financial Services Research 1.13 1 0.76%
Journal of Financial Counseling & Planning N/A 1 0.76%
Journal of General Management N/A 1 0.76%
Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money 1.379 1 0.76%
Journal of International Business Studies 5.869 1 0.76%
Journal of Law & Economics 0.932 1 0.76%
Journal of Multinational Financial Management N/A 1 0.76%
Journal of the Japanese & International Economies 0.542 1 0.76%
Journal of World Business 3.758 1 0.76%
Management Decision 1.396 1 0.76%
Multinational Business Review N/A 1 0.76%
South African Journal of Business Management 0.246 1 0.76%
Strategic Change N/A 1 0.76%
The International Journal of Business in Society N/A 1 0.76%
The Journal of Private Equity N/A 1 0.76%
Universia Business Review 0.138 1 0.76%
Venture Capital N/A 1 0.76%
Total 131 100%
Appendix A (continued)
Overview of Extant Literature on Financing Decisions in Family Firms.
Author(s)
Source of
financing Theoretical arguments
Demand
or supply
FB/NFB or
within FB
Country of
research
Achleitner etal. (2010) Equity Retention of control NA Within FB Germany
Adams, Manners, Astrachan,
and Mazzola (2004)
Multiple Aversion to risk Demand NA NA
Ahlers, Hack, and
Kellermanns (2014)
Equity NA Supply Within NA
Al-Ajmi etal. (2009) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, and between
shareholders and managers
NA FB/NFB Saudi Arabia
Alekneviciene (2012) Alternative
sources
NA NA FB/NFB Lithuania
Amann and Jaussaud (2012) Debt Aversion to risk Demand FB/NFB Japan
(continued)
Michiels and Molly 387
Author(s)
Source of
financing Theoretical arguments
Demand
or supply
FB/NFB or
within FB
Country of
research
Amore etal. (2011) Debt Free cash flow hypothesis,
retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand Within FB Italy
Anderson etal. (2003) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB USA
Anderson and Reeb (2003) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB USA
Astrachan and McConaughy
(2001)
Equity Signaling hypothesis NA FB/NFB USA
Attig, El Ghoul, Guedhami,
and Rizeanu (2013)
Alternative
sources
Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply Both EU, Asia
Bagnoli etal. (2011) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB USA
Batten and Hettihewa
(1999)
Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB Sri Lanka
Benito-Hernández etal.
(2014)
Debt Retention of control Demand FB/NFB Spain
Berghoff (2013) Multiple Transaction costs NA NA Germany
Bhattacharya and Ravikumar
(2001)
Multiple NA Supply Within FB NA
Bjuggren etal. (2012) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, free cash flow
hypothesis, aversion to risk
Demand FB/NFB Sweden
Blanco-Mazagatos etal.
(2007)
Multiple Free cash flow hypothesis,
retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand FB/NFB Spain
Bopaiah (1998) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB USA
Boubakri and Ghouma
(2010)
Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB EU, Asia
Boubakri etal. (2010) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply FB/NFB Asia
Burgstaller and Wagner
(2015)
Debt Retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand FB/NFB Austria
Caprio and Croci (2008) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
retention of control
Supply FB/NFB Italy
Carney and Gedajlovic
(2002)
Retained
earnings
Aversion to risk Demand FB/NFB Hong Kong
Chaganti and Damanpour
(1991)
Multiple NA Demand FB/NFB USA
Chan, Dang, and Yan (2012) Multiple NA Supply FB/NFB China
Appendix B (continued)
(continued)
388 Family Business Review 30(4)
Author(s)
Source of
financing Theoretical arguments
Demand
or supply
FB/NFB or
within FB
Country of
research
Chen etal. (2005) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
retention of control
Demand FB/NFB Hong Kong
Chen etal. (2016) Debt Asymmetric information
between lenders and
borrowers
Supply FB/NFB Multiple
Chua etal. (2011) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, social capital
Supply Both USA
Cirillo etal. (2015) Equity Stewardship Supply Within FB Italy
Coleman and Carsky (1999) Debt NA Demand FB/NFB USA
Croci etal. (2011) Multiple Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, retention of
control
Both FB/NFB EU
Dailey, Reuschling, and De
Mong (1977)
Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
NA Within FB USA
Dawson (2011) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply NA Italy
DeAngelo and DeAngelo
(2000)
Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Demand Within FB USA
Dejung (2013) Debt NA Demand NA Switzerland
Desbrières and Schatt
(2002)
Equity NA NA FB/NFB France
Di Giuli etal. (2011) Alternative
sources
NA Demand Within FB Italy
Ding and Pukthuanthong-Le
(2009)
Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply FB/NFB Taiwan
Dreux (1990) Multiple NA Both NA NA
Driffield etal. (2007) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders, and
between shareholders and
managers, aversion to risk
Demand Both Asia
Ebihara, Kubota, Takehara,
and Yokota (2014)
Multiple Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
retention of control
Demand FB/NFB Japan
Ehrhardt and Nowak (2003) Equity NA NA Within FB Germany
El-Chaarani (2013) Debt Retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand Within FB France,
Lebanon
Faccio and Parsley (2009) Debt NA Demand FB/NFB Multiple
Fernando etal. (2014) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply FB/NFB USA
Fitó etal. (2013) Debt Aversion to risk Demand FB/NFB Spain
Gallo and Vilaseca (1996) Multiple Aversion to risk, financial
distress costs
Both Within FB Spain
Ginglinger and Hamon
(2012)
Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
aversion to risk
NA Both France
Appendix B (continued)
(continued)
Michiels and Molly 389
Author(s)
Source of
financing Theoretical arguments
Demand
or supply
FB/NFB or
within FB
Country of
research
González etal. (2013) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, free cash flow
hypothesis, retention of
control, aversion to risk
Both FB/NFB Colombia
González etal. (2014) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Demand FB/NFB Colombia
Gugler (2003) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
managers
Demand FB/NFB Austria
Hakim, Lypny, and Bhabra
(2012)
Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply FB/NFB Multiple
Hauser and Lauterbach
(2004)
Equity Retention of control NA FB/NFB Israel
Haynes etal. (1999) Debt NA Demand FB/NFB USA
He etal. (2012) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
retention of control
Demand FB/NFB Hong Kong
He, Li, and Tang (2013) Retained
earnings
NA Demand FB/NFB Hong Kong
Hearn (2011) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply Both Africa
Hearn (2014) Equity Transaction costs Supply FB/NFB Africa
How etal. (2008) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Demand FB/NFB Hong Kong
Huang etal. (2012) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
retention of control
Demand Within FB Taiwan
Jain and Shao (2015) Multiple Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
between shareholders and
managers, and between
shareholders and bondholders,
risk aversion, retention
of control, protection of
reputation
Both Both USA
Keasey, Martinez, and
Pindado (2015)
Debt Retention of control,
asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Both Both EU
Kimhi (1997) Debt NA Supply Within FB NA
King and Peng (2013) Multiple Aversion to risk Demand Within FB USA
King and Santor (2008) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, aversion to risk
Demand Both Canada
Koropp, Grichnik, and
Gygax (2013)
Debt Retention of control, aversion
to risk, debt use intention
Demand Within FB Germany
Koropp, Grichnik, and
Kellermanns (2013)
Debt Retention of control Demand Within FB Germany
Appendix B (continued)
(continued)
390 Family Business Review 30(4)
Author(s)
Source of
financing Theoretical arguments
Demand
or supply
FB/NFB or
within FB
Country of
research
Koropp etal. (2014) Multiple Retention of control Demand Within FB Germany
Kusnadi (2011) Alternative
sources
Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
managers
Demand FB/NFB Singapore,
Malaysia
Lace etal. (2013) Retained
earnings
NA Demand FB/NFB EU
Landry etal. (2013) Multiple Retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand Both Canada
Lappalainen and Niskanen
(2013)
Multiple Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, retention of
control
Both FB/NFB Finland
Leitterstorf and Rau (2014) Equity Retention of control, protection
of reputation
Demand FB/NFB Germany
Lin and Chuang (2011) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply FB/NFB Taiwan
López-Gracia and Sánchez-
Andújar (2007)
Debt Financial distress costs Both FB/NFB Spain
Mahérault (2004) Equity Retention of control Supply Within FB France
Martí etal. (2013) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Both FB/NFB Spain
Martinez and Serve (2011) Equity Aversion to risk Demand FB/NFB France
Masulis etal. (2011) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Both FB/NFB Multiple
Matias Gama and Manuel
Mendes Galvão (2012)
Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand FB/NFB Portugal
Maula, Autio, and Arenius
(2005)
Equity NA Supply FB/NFB Finland
Mazzola and Marchisio
(2002)
Equity NA NA FB/NFB Italy
McConaughy (1999) Multiple NA NA Both NA
McConaughy, Matthews,
and Fialko (2001)
Debt Aversion to risk Demand FB/NFB USA
Michiels etal. (2015) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Demand Within FB Belgium
Mishra and McConaughy
(1999)
Debt Aversion to risk Demand FB/NFB USA
Molly etal. (2010) Debt Retention of control, aversion
to risk
Both Within FB Belgium
Molly etal. (2012) Debt Retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand Within FB Belgium
Muske etal. (2009) Debt NA Demand NA USA
Napoli (2012) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, social capital
Supply Within FB Italy
Nielsen (2008) Equity NA Supply FB/NFB NA
Noordin, Ariffin, and Law
(2008)
Equity NA Supply FB/NFB Asia
Appendix B (continued)
(continued)
Michiels and Molly 391
Author(s)
Source of
financing Theoretical arguments
Demand
or supply
FB/NFB or
within FB
Country of
research
O’Regan, Hughes, Collins,
and Tucker (2010)
Multiple Retention of control Demand Within FB UK
Pindado etal. (2012) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Demand FB/NFB EU
Pindado etal. (2015) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply Both EU
Poutziouris (2001) Equity Retention of control Demand FB/NFB UK
Poutziouris (2011) Multiple Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, retention of
control
Both FB/NFB UK
Psillaki and Eleftheriou
(2015)
Debt Asymmetric information
between lenders and
borrowers
Supply FB/NFB France
Romano etal. (2001) Multiple Retention of control, aversion of
risk, protection of reputation
Both Within FB Australia
Santos etal. (2014) Debt Free cash flow hypothesis,
retention of control, aversion
to risk
Both FB/NFB EU
Schmid (2013) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders, and between
shareholders and managers,
free cash flow hypothesis,
retention of control
Both FB/NFB EU, Asia
Scholes, Wright, Westhead,
Burrows, and Bruining
(2007)
Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders, and
between shareholders and
managers, game theory
Both Within FB EU
Scholes etal. (2009) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
managers
Both Within FB EU
Schulze etal. (2003) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
aversion to risk, loss aversion
Demand Within FB USA
Segura and Formigoni
(2014)
Debt Retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand FB/NFB Brazil
Setia-Atmaja etal. (2009) Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders, free
cash flow hypothesis
Demand FB/NFB Australia
Shyu and Lee (2009) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders, free
cash flow hypothesis
Both FB/NFB Taiwan
Song and Wang (2013) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply NA China
Steijvers and Voordeckers
(2009)
Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB USA
Appendix B (continued)
(continued)
392 Family Business Review 30(4)
Author(s)
Source of
financing Theoretical arguments
Demand
or supply
FB/NFB or
within FB
Country of
research
Steijvers etal. (2010) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB USA
Strebualev and Yang (2013) Debt Aversion to risk Demand FB/NFB USA
Tanaka (2014) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB Japan
Tappeiner etal. (2012) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
retention of control
Demand Within FB Germany
H. T. Tran and Santarelli
(2014)
Multiple Asymmetric information
between shareholders, and
between shareholders and
bondholders, social capital
Supply Within FB Vietnam
D. H. Tran (2014) Multiple Asymmetric information
between shareholders, and
between shareholders and
bondholders
Demand FB/NFB Germany
Upton and Petty (2000) Equity NA Supply Within FB USA
Vandemaele and
Vancauteren (2015)
Retained
earnings
Retention of control, aversion
to risk
Demand Within FB Belgium
Viviani etal. (2008) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply FB/NFB Italy
Voordeckers and Steijvers
(2006)
Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB Belgium
Waisman (2013) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB USA
Walker (2008) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply FB/NFB Multiple
Wright, Amess, Weir, and
Girma (2009)
Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
NA NA NA
Wu etal. (2007) Equity Asymmetric information
between shareholders
Supply FB/NFB Canada
Wu etal. (2014) Multiple NA Demand FB/NFB Taiwan
Yilmazer and Schrank
(2006)
Debt Transaction costs Demand FB/NFB USA
Yoshikawa and Rasheed
(2010)
Retained
earnings
Asymmetric information
between shareholders,
retention of control
Demand FB/NFB Japan
Yen etal. (2015) Debt Asymmetric information
between shareholders and
bondholders
Supply FB/NFB Taiwan
Yu and Zheng (2012) Equity Retention of control Demand FB/NFB Hong Kong
Zellweger and
Kammerlander (2016)
Multiple Family blockholder conflicts NA NA NA
Zhang, Venus, and Wang
(2012)
Multiple Retention of control Demand Within FB China
Note. FB = family business; NFB = nonfamily business.
Appendix B (continued)
Michiels and Molly 393
Acknowledgments
The authors would like to thank a panel of experts that pro-
vided valuable insights for this review, based on their expe-
rience as a family business and/or finance scholar and/or
editor of a prominent family business journal: Joseph
Astrachan, Joern Block, Marc Deloof, Luis Gomez-Mejia,
Danny Miller, Pannikos Poutziouris, Alessandro Minichilli,
Wim Voordeckers, and Pramodita Sharma. We are also
grateful for the helpful comments from Daniel Holt and
three anonymous FBR reviewers on earlier versions of this
article.
Declaration of Conflicting Interests
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with
respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this
article.
Funding
The author(s) received no financial support for the research,
authorship, and/or publication of this article.
References
Sample articles of the literature review are marked with
an asterisk.
*Achleitner, A. K., Herman, K., Lerner, J., & Lutz, E. (2010).
Family business and private equity: Conflict or collabora-
tion? The case of Messer Griesheim. Journal of Private
Equity, 13(3), 7-20.
*Adams, A. F., Manners, G. E., Astrachan, J. H., & Mazzola,
P. (2004). The importance of integrated goal setting: The
application of cost-of-capital concepts to private firms.
Family Business Review, 17, 287-302.
*Ahlers, O., Hack, A., & Kellermanns, F. W. (2014). “Stepping
into the buyers’ shoes”: Looking at the value of family
firms through the eyes of private equity investors. Journal
of Family Business Strategy, 5, 384-396.
Ajzen, I. (1991). The theory of planned behavior.
Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,
50, 179-211.
*Al-Ajmi, J., Abo Hussain, H., & Al-Saleh, N. (2009).
Decisions on capital structure in a Zakat environment with
prohibition of riba: The case of Saudi Arabia. Journal of
Risk Finance, 10, 460-476.
*Alekneviciene, V. (2012). Cost of equity capital in agricul-
tural organizations: Theoretical approach and empiri-
cal analysis. Economics and Rural Development, 8(2).
Retrieved from http://erd.asu.lt/erd/article/view/46
*Amann, B., & Jaussaud, J. (2012). Family and non-family
business resilience in an economic downturn. Asia Pacific
Business Review, 18, 203-223.
*Amore, M. D., Minichilli, A., & Corbetta, G. (2011). How
do managerial successions shape corporate financial poli-
cies in family firms? Journal of Corporate Finance, 17,
1016-1027.
*Anderson, R. C., Mansi, S. A., & Reeb, D. M. (2003).
Founding family ownership and the agency cost of debt.
Journal of Financial Economics, 68, 263-285.
*Anderson, R. C., & Reeb, D. M. (2003). Founding-family
ownership, corporate diversification, and firm leverage.
Journal of Law & Economics, 46, 653-684.
Ang, J. S., Cole, R. A., & Lin, J. W. (2000). Agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Finance, 55, 81-106.
*Astrachan, J. H., & McConaughy, D. L. (2001). Venture
capitalists and closely held IPOs: Lessons for family-
controlled firms. Family Business Review, 14, 295-312.
*Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O., & Rizeanu, S. (2013).
The governance role of multiple large shareholders:
Evidence from the valuation of cash holdings. Journal of
Management and Governance, 17, 419-451.
*Bagnoli, M., Liu, H. T., & Watts, S. G. (2011). Family firms,
debtholder–shareholder agency costs and the use of cov-
enants in private debt. Annals of Finance, 7, 477-509.
Barton, S. L., & Matthews, C. H. (1989). Small firm financing:
Implications from a strategic management perspective.
Journal of Small Business Management, 27, 1-7.
*Batten, J., & Hettihewa, S. (1999). Small firm behaviour in
Sri Lanka. Small Business Economics, 13, 201-217.
Becker-Blease, J. R., & Sohl, J. E. (2007). Do women-owned
businesses have equal access to angel capital? Journal of
Business Venturing, 22, 503-521.
Benavides-Velasco, C. A., Quintana-García, C., & Guzmán-
Parra, V. F. (2013). Trends in family business research.
Small Business Economics, 40, 41-57.
*Benito-Hernández, S., Priede-Bergamini, T., & López-Cózar-
Navarro, C. (2014). Factors determining exportation and
internationalization in family businesses: The importance
of debt. South African Journal of Business Management,
45(1), 13-25.
*Berghoff, H. (2013). Blending personal and managerial capi-
talism: Bertelsmann’s rise from medium-sized publisher
to global media corporation and service provider, 1950-
2010. Business History, 55, 855-874.
Berrone, P., Cruz, C., & Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (2012).
Socioemotional wealth in family firms theoretical dimen-
sions, assessment approaches, and agenda for future
research. Family Business Review, 25, 258-279.
*Bhattacharya, U., & Ravikumar, B. (2001). Capital mar-
kets and the evolution of family businesses. Journal of
Business, 74, 187-219.
*Bjuggren, P. O., Duggal, R., & Giang, D. T. (2012). Ownership
dispersion and capital structures in family firms: A study
of closed medium-sized enterprises. Journal of Small
Business & Entrepreneurship, 25, 185-200.
394 Family Business Review 30(4)
*Blanco-Mazagatos, V., Quevedo-Puente, D., & Castrillo, L.
A. (2007). The trade-off between financial resources and
agency costs in the family business: An exploratory study.
Family Business Review, 20, 199-213.
*Bopaiah, C. (1998). Availability of credit to family business.
Small Business Economics, 11, 75-86.
*Boubakri, N., & Ghouma, H. (2010). Control/ownership
structure, creditor rights protection, and the cost of debt
financing: International evidence. Journal of Banking &
Finance, 34, 2481-2499.
*Boubakri, N., Guedhami, O., & Mishra, D. (2010). Family
control and the implied cost of equity: Evidence before and
after the Asian financial crisis. Journal of International
Business Studies, 41, 451-474.
*Burgstaller, J., & Wagner, E. (2015). How do family own-
ership and founder management affect capital structure
decisions and adjustment of SMEs? Evidence from a
bank-based economy. Journal of Risk Finance, 16, 73-
101.
*Caprio, L., & Croci, E. (2008). The determinants of the vot-
ing premium in Italy: The evidence from 1974 to 2003.
Journal of Banking & Finance, 32, 2433-2443.
*Carney, M., & Gedajlovic, E. (2002). The coupling of owner-
ship and control and the allocation of financial resources:
Evidence from Hong Kong. Journal of Management
Studies, 39, 123-146.
Carpenter, R. E., & Petersen, B. C. (2002). Is the growth of
small firms constrained by internal finance? Review of
Economics and Statistics, 84, 298-309.
Cavalluzzo, K. S., & Cavalluzzo, L. C. (1998). Market struc-
ture and discrimination: The case of small businesses.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30, 771-792.
*Chaganti, R., & Damanpour, F. (1991). Institutional owner-
ship, capital structure, and firm performance. Strategic
Management Journal, 12, 479-491.
*Chan, K. S., Dang, V. Q., & Yan, I. K. (2012). Chinese
firms’ political connection, ownership, and financing con-
straints. Economics Letters, 115, 164-167.
*Chen, Q., Ding, S., Wu, Z., & Yang, F. (2016). Family control,
international accounting standards, and access to foreign
banks: Evidence from international entrepreneurial firms.
Journal of Small Business Management, 54, 598-621.
*Chen, Z., Cheung, Y. L., Stouraitis, A., & Wong, A. W.
(2005). Ownership concentration, firm performance, and
dividend policy in Hong Kong. Pacific-Basin Finance
Journal, 13, 431-449.
Chrisman, J. J., & Holt, D. T. (2016). Beyond socioemotional
wealth: Taking another step toward a theory of the family
firm. Management Research, 14, 249-287.
Chrisman, J. J., & Patel, P. C. (2012). Variations in R&D
investments of family and nonfamily firms: Behavioral
agency and myopic loss aversion perspectives. Academy
of Management Journal, 55, 976-997.
Chrisman, J. J., Sharma, P., Steier, L. P., & Chua, J. H. (2013).
The influence of family goals, governance, and resources
on firm outcomes. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,
37, 1249-1261.
Chua, J. H., Chrisman, J. J., & De Massis, A. (2015). A closer
look at socioemotional wealth: Its flows, stocks, and pros-
pects for moving forward. Entrepreneurship Theory and
Practice, 39, 173-182.
Chua, J. H., Chrisman, J. J., & Sharma, P. (1999). Defining the
family business by behavior. Entrepreneurship: theory
and practice, 23(4), 19-19.
*Chua, J. H., Chrisman, J. J., Kellermanns, F., & Wu, Z.
(2011). Family involvement and new venture debt financ-
ing. Journal of Business Venturing, 26, 472-488.
Chua, J. H., Chrisman, J. J., & Sharma, P. (2003). Succession
and nonsuccession concerns of family firms and agency
relationship with nonfamily managers. Family Business
Review, 16, 89-107.
Chua, J. H., Chrisman, J. J., Steier, L. P., & Rau, S. B. (2012).
Sources of heterogeneity in family firms: An introduction.
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 36, 1103-1113.
*Cirillo, A., Romano, M., & Ardovino, O. (2015). Does family
involvement foster IPO value? Empirical analysis on Italian
stock market. Management Decision, 53, 1125-1154.
Coleman, S. (2004). Access to debt capital for women-
and minority-owned small firms: Does educational
attainment have an impact? Journal of Developmental
Entrepreneurship, 9, 127-143.
*Coleman, S., & Carsky, M. (1999). Sources of capital
for small family-owned businesses evidence from the
National Survey of Small Business Finances. Family
Business Review, 12, 73-84.
Constantinidis, C., Cornet, A., & Asandei, S. (2006). Financing
of women-owned ventures: The impact of gender and
other owner- and firm-related variables. Venture Capital,
8, 133-157.
*Croci, E., Doukas, J. A., & Gonenc, H. (2011). Family
control and financing decisions. European Financial
Management, 17, 860-897.
*Dailey, R. C., Reuschling, T. E., & De Mong, R. F. (1977).
The family owned business: Capital funding. American
Journal of Small Business, 2(2), 30-39.
David, R. J., & Han, S. K. (2004). A systematic assessment
of the empirical support for transaction cost economics.
Strategic Management Journal, 25, 39-58.
Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L. (1997).
Toward a stewardship theory of management. Academy of
Management Review, 22, 20-47.
*Dawson, A. (2011). Private equity investment decisions in
family firms: The role of human resources and agency
costs. Journal of Business Venturing, 26, 189-199.
*DeAngelo, H., & DeAngelo, L. (2000). Controlling stock-
holders and the disciplinary role of corporate payout
Michiels and Molly 395
policy: A study of the Times Mirror Company. Journal
of Financial Economics, 56, 153-207.
Debicki, B. J., Kellermanns, F. W., Chrisman, J. J., Pearson,
A. W., & Spencer, B. A. (2016). Development of a socio-
emotional wealth importance (SEWi) scale for family firm
research. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 7, 47-57.
*Dejung, C. (2013). Worldwide ties: The role of family busi-
ness in global trade in the nineteenth and twentieth centu-
ries. Business History, 55, 1001-1018.
De Massis, A., Kotlar, J., Chua, J. H., & Chrisman, J. J. (2014).
Ability and willingness as sufficiency conditions for
family-oriented particularistic behavior: Implications for
theory and empirical studies. Journal of Small Business
Management, 52, 344-364.
*Desbrières, P., & Schatt, A. (2002). The impacts of LBOs
on the performance of acquired firms: The French case.
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 29, 695-729.
*Di Giuli, A., Caselli, S., & Gatti, S. (2011). Are small fam-
ily firms financially sophisticated? Journal of Banking &
Finance, 35, 2931-2944.
*Ding, H. B., & Pukthuanthong-Le, K. (2009). Family
firm IPO performance and market signals. Journal of
Enterprising Culture, 17, 55-77.
*Dreux, D. R. (1990). Financing family business: Alternatives
to selling out or going public. Family Business Review,
3, 225-243.
*Driffield, N., Mahambare, V., & Pal, S. (2007). How does
ownership structure affect capital structure and firm
value? Recent evidence from East Asia. Economics of
Transition, 15, 535-573.
*Ebihara, T., Kubota, K., Takehara, H., & Yokota, E. (2014).
Market liquidity, private information, and the cost of
capital: Market microstructure studies on family firms in
Japan. Japan and the World Economy, 32, 1-13.
*Ehrhardt, O., & Nowak, E. (2003). The effect of IPOs on
German family-owned firms: Governance changes,
ownership structure, and performance. Journal of Small
Business Management, 41, 222-232.
*El-Chaarani, H. (2013, October). The success keys for fam-
ily firms: A comparison between Lebanese and French
systems. Journal of Business and Retail Management
Research, 8(1). Retrieved from http://www.jbrmr.com/
admin/content/pdf/i-17_c-151.pdf
European Commission. (2015a). Promoting entrepreneurship:
Family business—Main challenges faced by family firms.
Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/growth/smes/promoting-
entrepreneurship/we-work-for/family-business/index_en.htm
European Commission. (2015b). Tax reforms in EU member
states 2015 tax policy challenges for economic growth
and fiscal sustainability. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.
eu/economy_finance/publications/eeip/pdf/ip008_en.pdf
Faccio, M., Lang, L. H. P., & Young, L. (2001). Dividends and
expropriation. American Economic Review, 91, 54-78.
*Faccio, M., & Parsley, D. C. (2009). Sudden deaths: Taking
stock of geographic ties. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, 44, 683-718.
Fama, E. F. (1978). The effects of a firm’s investment and
financing decisions on the welfare of its security holders.
American Economic Review, 68, 272-284.
Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2002). Testing trade-off and
pecking order predictions about dividends and debt.
Review of Financial Studies, 15, 1-33.
*Fernando, G. D., Schneible, R. A., & Suh, S. (2014). Family
firms and institutional investors. Family Business Review,
27, 328-345.
*Fitó, M. À., Moya, S., & Orgaz, N. (2013). The debate on
rented assets capitalization: The economic impact on fam-
ily firms. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 4, 260-269.
Francis, B., Hasan, I., & Wu, Q. (2013). The impact of CFO
gender on bank loan contracting. Journal of Accounting,
Auditing & Finance, 28, 53-78.
Frank, M. Z., & Goyal, V. K. (2003). Testing the pecking
order theory of capital structure. Journal of Financial
Economics, 67, 217-248.
Gallo, M. Á., Tàpies, J., & Cappuyns, K. (2004). Comparison
of family and nonfamily business: Financial logic and per-
sonal preferences. Family Business Review, 17, 303-318.
*Gallo, M. A., & Vilaseca, A. (1996). Finance in family busi-
ness. Family Business Review, 9, 387-401.
*Ginglinger, E., & Hamon, J. (2012). Ownership, control and
market liquidity. Finance, 33, 61-99.
Gómez-Mejía, L. R., Haynes, K. T., Núñez-Nickel,
M., Jacobson, K. J., & Moyano-Fuentes, J. (2007).
Socioemotional wealth and business risks in family-
controlled firms: Evidence from Spanish olive oil mills.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 52, 106-137.
Gómez-Mejía, L. R., Larraza-Kintana, M., & Makri, M.
(2003). The determinants of executive compensation
in family-controlled public corporations. Academy of
Management Journal, 46, 226-237.
*González, M., Guzmán, A., Pombo, C., & Trujillo, M. A.
(2013). Family firms and debt: Risk aversion versus risk
of losing control. Journal of Business Research, 66, 2308-
2320.
*González, M., Guzmán, A., Pombo, C., & Trujillo, M. A.
(2014). Family involvement and dividend policy in
closely held firms. Family Business Review, 27, 365-385.
*Gugler, K. (2003). Corporate governance, dividend payout
policy, and the interrelation between dividends, R&D,
and capital investment. Journal of Banking & Finance,
27, 1297-1321.
*Hakim, T., Lypny, G., & Bhabra, H. S. (2012). IPO lockup
expiration in the Middle East and North Africa. Journal of
Multinational Financial Management, 22, 252-262.
Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (1991). The theory of capital structure.
Journal of Finance, 46, 297-355.
396 Family Business Review 30(4)
*Hauser, S., & Lauterbach, B. (2004). The value of voting rights
to majority shareholders: Evidence from dual-class stock
unifications. Review of Financial Studies, 17, 1167-1184.
*Haynes, G. W., Walker, R., Rowe, B. R., & Hong, G. S.
(1999). The intermingling of business and family finances
in family-owned businesses. Family Business Review, 12,
225-239.
*He, T. T., Li, W. X., & Tang, G. Y. (2012). Dividends behav-
ior in state-versus family-controlled firms: Evidence from
Hong Kong. Journal of Business Ethics, 110, 97-112.
*He, T. T., Li, W. X., & Tang, G. Y. (2013). Dividends, con-
trolling shareholders and firm performance: An investi-
gation of large firms on the Hong Kong stock exchange.
Annals of Financial Economics, 8(2), 1350011.
*Hearn, B. (2011). The performance and the effects of fam-
ily control in North African IPOs. International Review of
Financial Analysis, 20, 140-151.
*Hearn, B. (2014). The political institutional and firm gov-
ernance determinants of liquidity: Evidence from North
Africa and the Arab Spring. Journal of International
Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, 31, 127-158.
Hechavarria, D. M., Ingram, A., Justo, R., & Terjesen, S.
(2012). Are women more likely to pursue social and
environmental entrepreneurship. In K. D. Hughes & J.
E. Jennings (Eds.), Global women’s entrepreneurship
research: Diverse settings, questions and approaches (pp.
135-151). Cheltenham, England: Edward Elgar.
Holt, D. T., Madison, K., & Kellermanns, F. W. (2017).
Variance in family members’ assessments: The impor-
tance of dispersion modeling in family firm research.
Family Business Review, 30, 61-83.
*How, J., Verhoeven, P., & Wu, C. (2008). Dividends
and expropriation in Hong Kong. Asian Academy of
Management Journal of Accounting & Finance, 4, 71-85.
*Huang, Y., Chen, A., & Kao, L. (2012). Corporate gover-
nance in Taiwan: The nonmonotonic relationship between
family ownership and dividend policy. Asia Pacific
Journal of Management, 29, 39-58.
Hutchinson, R. W. (1995). The capital structure and investment
decisions of the small owner-managed firm: Some explor-
atory issues. Small Business Economics, 7, 231-239.
Ibbotson, R. G. (1975). Price performance of common stock
new issues. Journal of Financial Economics, 2, 235-272.
*Jain, B. A., & Shao, Y. (2015). Family firm governance and
financial policy choices in newly public firms. Corporate
Governance, 23, 452-468.
Jennings, J. E., & Brush, C. G. (2013). Research on women
entrepreneurs: Challenges to (and from) the broader entre-
preneurship literature? Academy of Management Annals,
7, 663-715.
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm:
Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership struc-
ture. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-360.
Jones, O., & Gatrell, C. (2014). Editorial: The future of writ-
ing and reviewing for IJMR. International Journal of
Management Reviews, 16, 249-264.
*Keasey, K., Martinez, B., & Pindado, J. (2015). Young fam-
ily firms: Financing decisions and the willingness to dilute
control. Journal of Corporate Finance, 34, 47-63.
*Kimhi, A. (1997). Intergenerational succession in small fam-
ily businesses: Borrowing constraints and optimal timing
of succession. Small Business Economics, 9, 309-318.
*King, M. R., & Santor, E. (2008). Family values: Ownership
structure, performance and capital structure of Canadian
firms. Journal of Banking & Finance, 32, 2423-2432.
*King, R., & Peng, W. Q. (2013). The effect of industry char-
acteristics on the control longevity of founding-family
firms. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 4, 281-295.
Kontinen, T., & Ojala, A. (2010). The internationalization of
family businesses: A review of extant research. Journal of
Family Business Strategy, 1, 97-107.
*Koropp, C., Grichnik, D., & Gygax, A. F. (2013b). Succession
financing in family firms. Small Business Economics, 41,
315-334.
*Koropp, C., Grichnik, D., & Kellermanns, F. (2013). Financial
attitudes in family firms: The moderating role of family
commitment. Journal of Small Business Management, 51,
114-137.
*Koropp, C., Kellermanns, F. W., Grichnik, D., & Stanley,
L. (2014). Financial decision making in family firms:
An adaptation of the theory of planned behavior. Family
Business Review, 27, 307-327.
Kraus, A., & Litzenberger, R. H. (1973). A state-preference
model of optimal financial leverage. Journal of Finance,
28, 911-922.
*Kusnadi, Y. (2011). Do corporate governance mechanisms
matter for cash holdings and firm value? Pacific-Basin
Finance Journal, 19, 554-570.
*Lace, N., Bistrova, J., & Kozlovskis, K. (2013). Ownership
type influence on dividend payments in CEE coun-
tries. Business: Theory and Practice/Verslas: Teorija ir
Praktika, 14, 259-266.
*Landry, S., Fortin, A., & Callimaci, A. (2013). Family
firms and the lease decision. Journal of Family Business
Strategy, 4, 176-187.
Langley, A., & Abdallah, C. (2011). Templates and turns in
qualitative studies of strategy and management: Building
methodological bridges. Research Methodology in
Strategy and Management, 6, 201-235.
*Lappalainen, J., & Niskanen, M. (2013). Behavior and atti-
tudes of small family firms towards different funding
sources. Journal of Small Business & Entrepreneurship,
26, 579-599.
*Leitterstorf, M. P., & Rau, S. B. (2014). Socioemotional
wealth and IPO underpricing of family firms. Strategic
Management Journal, 35, 751-760.
Michiels and Molly 397
*Lin, C. P., & Chuang, C. M. (2011). Principal-principal con-
flicts and IPO pricing in an emerging economy. Corporate
Governance, 19, 585-600.
*López-Gracia, J., & Sánchez-Andújar, S. (2007). Financial
structure of the family business: Evidence from a group of
small Spanish firms. Family Business Review, 20, 269-287.
*Mahérault, L. (2004). Is there any specific equity route for
small and medium-sized family businesses? The French
experience. Family Business Review, 17, 221-235.
*Martí, J., Menéndez-Requejo, S., & Rottke, O. M. (2013). The
impact of venture capital on family businesses: Evidence
from Spain. Journal of World Business, 48, 420-430.
Martin, G., & Gomez-Mejia, L. (2016). The relationship between
socioemotional and financial wealth: Re-visiting family
firm decision making. Management Research, 14, 215-233.
*Martinez, I., & Serve, S. (2011). The delisting decision:
The case of buyout offer with squeeze-out (BOSO).
International Review of Law and Economics, 31, 228-239.
*Masulis, R. W., Pham, P. K., & Zein, J. (2011). Family busi-
ness groups around the world: Financing advantages, con-
trol motivations, and organizational choices. Review of
Financial Studies, 24, 556-600.
*Matias Gama, A. P., & Manuel Mendes Galvão, J. (2012).
Performance, valuation and capital structure: Survey of
family firms. Corporate Governance, 12, 199-214.
*Maula, M., Autio, E., & Arenius, P. (2005). What drives
micro-angel investments? Small Business Economics, 25,
459-475.
*Mazzola, P., & Marchisio, G. (2002). The role of going pub-
lic in family businesses’ long-lasting growth: A study of
Italian IPOs. Family Business Review, 15, 133-148.
*McConaughy, D. L. (1999). Is the cost of capital different for
family firms? Family Business Review, 12, 353-360.
*McConaughy, D. L., Matthews, C. H., & Fialko, A. S. (2001).
Founding family controlled firms: Performance, risk, and
value. Journal of Small Business Management, 39, 31-49.
*Michiels, A., Voordeckers, W., Lybaert, N., & Steijvers, T.
(2015). Dividends and family governance practices in pri-
vate family firms. Small Business Economics, 44, 299-314.
*Mishra, C. S., & McConaughy, D. L. (1999). Founding fam-
ily control and capital structure: The risk of loss of control
and the aversion to debt. Entrepreneurship Theory and
Practice, 23, 53-64.
Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capi-
tal, corporation finance and the theory of investment.
American Economic Review, 48, 261-297.
*Molly, V., Laveren, E., & Deloof, M. (2010). Family busi-
ness succession and its impact on financial structure and
performance. Family Business Review, 23, 131-147.
*Molly, V., Laveren, E., & Jorissen, A. (2012).
Intergenerational differences in family firms: Impact on
capital structure and growth behavior. Entrepreneurship
Theory and Practice, 36, 703-725.
*Muske, G., Fitzgerald, M. A., Haynes, G., Black, M., Chin, L.,
MacClure, R., & Mashburn, A. (2009). The intermingling
of family and business financial resources: Understanding
the copreneurial couple. Journal of Financial Counseling
and Planning, 20, 27-47.
Myers, S. C. (1984). The capital structure puzzle. Journal of
Finance, 39, 574-592.
Myers, S. C. (1989). Still searching for optimal capital struc-
ture: Are the distinctions between debt and equity disap-
pearing. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 1989,
80-95.
Myers, S. C., & Majluf, N. S. (1984). Corporate financing and
investment decisions when firms have information that
investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics,
13, 187-221.
*Napoli, F. (2012). The board’s strategic and control tasks;
family firms and their search for outside directors to sup-
port growth. Journal of General Management, 37, 1-27.
Neeley, L., & Van Auken, H. (2010). Differences between
female and male entrepreneurs’ use of bootstrap financing.
Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship, 15, 19-34.
*Nielsen, R. P. (2008). The private equity-leveraged buyout
form of finance capitalism: Ethical and social issues, and
potential reforms. Business Ethics Quarterly, 18, 379-404.
*Noordin, A., Ariffin, B., & Law, S. H. (2008). Family con-
trol business and capital market development in ASEAN.
Journal of Financial Economics, 6, 46-55.
Nordqvist, M., Sharma, P., & Chirico, F. (2014). Family firm
heterogeneity and governance: A configuration approach.
Journal of Small Business Management, 52, 192-209.
Oliveira, B., & Fortunato, A. (2006). Firm growth and liquid-
ity constraints: A dynamic analysis. Small Business
Economics, 27, 139-156.
O’Regan, N., Hughes, T., Collins, L., & Tucker, J. (2010).
Strategic thinking in family businesses. Strategic Change,
19, 57-76.
*Pindado, J., Requejo, I., & la Torre, C. (2015). Does family
control shape corporate capital structure? An empirical
analysis of Eurozone firms. Journal of Business Finance
& Accounting, 42, 965-1006.
*Pindado, J., Requejo, I., & la Torre, C. (2012). Do family
firms use dividend policy as a governance mechanism?
Evidence from the Euro zone. Corporate Governance, 20,
413-431.
Podsakoff, P. M., MacKenzie, S. B., Lee, J. Y., & Podsakoff,
N. P. (2003). Common method biases in behavioral
research: a critical review of the literature and rec-
ommended remedies. Journal of Applied Psychology,
88(5), 879.
*Poutziouris, P. Z. (2001). The views of family companies on
venture capital: Empirical evidence from the UK small
to medium-size enterprising economy. Family Business
Review, 14, 277-291.
398 Family Business Review 30(4)
*Poutziouris, P. Z. (2011). Estructura financiera y rentabili-
dad en empresas familiares gestionadas por la propiedad:
evidencias de la economía inglesa [The financial struc-
ture and performance of owner-managed family firms:
Evidence from the UK economy]. Universia Business
Review, 32, 70.
Pratt, M. (2009). For the lack of a boilerplate: Tips on writ-
ing up (and reviewing) qualitative research. Academy of
Management Journal, 52, 856-862.
*Psillaki, M., & Eleftheriou, K. (2015). Trade credit, bank
credit, and flight to quality: Evidence from French SMEs.
Journal of Small Business Management, 53, 1219-1240.
Pukall, T. J., & Calabrò, A. (2014). The internationalization
of family firms: A critical review and integrative model.
Family Business Review, 27, 103-125.
Reay, T. (2014). Publishing qualitative research. Family
Business Review, 27, 95-102.
Reay, T., & Whetten, D. A. (2011). What constitutes a theo-
retical contribution in family business? Family Business
Review, 24, 105-110.
*Romano, C. A., Tanewski, G. A., & Smyrnios, K. X. (2001).
Capital structure decision making: A model for family
business. Journal of Business Venturing, 16, 285-310.
Salvato, C., & Moores, K. (2010). Research on accounting
in family firms: Past accomplishments and future chal-
lenges. Family Business Review, 23, 193-215.
*Santos, M. S., Moreira, A. C., & Vieira, E. S. (2014).
Ownership concentration, contestability, family firms,
and capital structure. Journal of Management and
Governance, 18, 1063-1107.
*Schmid, T. (2013). Control considerations, creditor monitor-
ing, and the capital structure of family firms. Journal of
Banking & Finance, 37, 257-272.
*Scholes, L., Wright, M., Westhead, P., Bruining, H., &
Kloeckner, O. (2009). Family firm buy-outs, private
equity and strategic change. Journal of Private Equity,
12, 7-18.
*Scholes, M. L., Wright, M., Westhead, P., Burrows, A., &
Bruining, H. (2007). Information sharing, price negotia-
tion and management buy-outs of private family-owned
firms. Small Business Economics, 29, 329-349.
Schulze, W. S., & Gedajlovic, E. R. (2010). Whither family
business? Journal of Management Studies, 47, 191-204.
*Schulze, W. S., Lubatkin, M. H., & Dino, R. N. (2003).
Exploring the agency consequences of ownership disper-
sion among the directors of private family firms. Academy
of Management Journal, 46, 179-194.
*Segura, L. C., & Formigoni, H. (2014). Influence of control
and family management in the indebtedness of Brazilian
open business: A quantitative study. Brazilian Business
Review, 11, 50-74.
*Setia-Atmaja, L., Tanewski, G. A., & Skully, M. (2009).
The role of dividends, debt and board structure in the
governance of family controlled firms. Journal of
Business Finance & Accounting, 36, 863-898.
*Shyu, Y. W., & Lee, C. I. (2009). Excess control rights
and debt maturity structure in family-controlled firms.
Corporate Governance, 17, 611-628.
Siebels, J. F., & zu Knyphausen-Aufseß, D. (2012). A review
of theory in family business research: The implica-
tions for corporate governance. International Journal of
Management Reviews, 14, 280-304.
Siggelkow, N. (2007). Persuasion with case studies. Academy
of Management Journal, 50, 20-24.
*Song, H., & Wang, L. (2013). The impact of private and
family firms’ relational strength on financing perfor-
mance in clusters. Asia Pacific Journal of Management,
30, 735-748.
Stafford, K., Duncan, K. A., Dane, S., & Winter, M. (1999). A
research model of sustainable family businesses. Family
Business Review, 12, 197-208.
*Steijvers, T., & Voordeckers, W. (2009). Private family
ownership and the agency costs of debt. Family Business
Review, 22, 333-346.
*Steijvers, T., Voordeckers, W., & Vanhoof, K. (2010).
Collateral, relationship lending and family firms. Small
Business Economics, 34, 243-259.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1969). A re-examination of the Modigliani-
Miller theorem. American Economic Review, 59, 784-793.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1974). On the irrelevance of corporate financial
policy. American Economic Review, 64, 851-866.
*Strebulaev, I. A., & Yang, B. (2013). The mystery of zero-
leverage firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 109, 1-23.
Sullivan, D. M., & Meek, W. R. (2012). Gender and entre-
preneurship: A review and process model. Journal of
Managerial Psychology, 27, 428-458.
*Tanaka, T. (2014). Corporate governance and the cost of pub-
lic debt financing: Evidence from Japan. Journal of the
Japanese and International Economies, 34, 315-335.
*Tappeiner, F., Howorth, C., Achleitner, A. K., & Schraml, S.
(2012). Demand for private equity minority investments:
A study of large family firms. Journal of Family Business
Strategy, 3, 38-51.
Titman, S., & Wessels, R. (1988). The determinants of capital
structure choice. Journal of Finance, 43, 1-19.
*Tran, H. T., & Santarelli, E. (2014). Capital constraints and
the performance of entrepreneurial firms in Vietnam.
Industrial and Corporate Change, 23, 827-864.
*Tran, D. H. (2014). Multiple corporate governance attributes
and the cost of capital: Evidence from Germany. British
Accounting Review, 46, 179-197.
*Upton, N., & Petty, W. (2000). Venture capital investment
and US family business. Venture Capital, 2, 27-39.
*Vandemaele, S., & Vancauteren, M. (2015). Nonfinancial
goals, governance, and dividend payout in private family
firms. Journal of Small Business Management, 53, 166-182.
Michiels and Molly 399
Verbeke, A., & Kano, L. (2012). The transaction cost econom-
ics theory of the family firm: Family-based human asset
specificity and the bifurcation bias. Entrepreneurship
Theory and Practice, 36, 1183-1205.
*Viviani, D., Giorgino, M., & Steri, R. (2008). Private equity-
backed IPOs and long-run market performance analysis of
Italian firms. Journal of Private Equity, 11, 50-60.
*Voordeckers, W., & Steijvers, T. (2006). Business collateral
and personal commitments in SME lending. Journal of
Banking & Finance, 30, 3067-3086.
Voordeckers, W., Le Breton-Miller, I., & Miller, D. (2014). In
search of the best of both worlds: Crafting a finance paper
for the Family Business Review. Family Business Review,
27, 281-286.
*Waisman, M. (2013). Product market competition and the
cost of bank loans: Evidence from state antitakeover laws.
Journal of Banking & Finance, 37, 4721-4737.
*Walker, T. (2008). Family control, underwriter prestige, and
IPO underpricing: A cross country analysis. Multinational
Business Review, 16, 1-42.
Welch, I. (1992). Sequential sales, learning, and cascades.
Journal of Finance, 47, 695-732.
Wiseman, R. M., & Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (1998). A behav-
ioral agency model of managerial risk taking. Academy of
Management Review, 23, 133-153.
*Wright, M., Amess, K., Weir, C., & Girma, S. (2009). Private
equity and corporate governance: Retrospect and pros-
pect. Corporate Governance, 17, 353-375.
*Wu, S. W., Lin, F., & Wu, C. M. (2014). Corporate social
responsibility and cost of capital: An empirical study of
the Taiwan stock market. Emerging Markets Finance &
Trade, 50(Suppl. 1), 107-120.
*Wu, Z., Chua, J. H., & Chrisman, J. J. (2007). Effects of fam-
ily ownership and management on small business equity
financing. Journal of Business Venturing, 22, 875-895.
*Yen, J. F., Lin, C. Y., Chen, Y. S., & Huang, Y. C. (2015).
Founding family firms and bank loan contracts. Journal of
Financial Services Research, 48, 53-82.
*Yilmazer, T., & Schrank, H. (2006). Financial intermingling
in small family businesses. Journal of Business Venturing,
21, 726-751.
*Yoshikawa, T., & Rasheed, A. A. (2010). Family control and
ownership monitoring in family-controlled firms in Japan.
Journal of Management Studies, 47, 274-295.
*Yu, X., & Zheng, Y. (2012). IPO underpricing to retain fam-
ily control under concentrated ownership: Evidence from
Hong Kong. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting,
39, 700-729.
Zahra, S. A., Hayton, J. C., Neubaum, D. O., Dibrell, C., &
Craig, J. (2008). Culture of family commitment and stra-
tegic flexibility: The moderating effect of stewardship.
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 32, 1035-1054.
Zahra, S. A., & Sharma, P. (2004). Family business research: A
strategic reflection. Family Business Review, 17, 331-346.
*Zellweger, T., & Kammerlander, N. (2015). Family, wealth,
and governance: An agency account. Entrepreneurship
Theory and Practice, 39, 1281-1303.
*Zhang, X., Venus, J., & Wang, Y. (2012). Family owner-
ship and business expansion of small-and medium-sized
Chinese family businesses: The mediating role of financ-
ing preference. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 3,
97-105.
Author Biographies
Anneleen Michiels is an assistant professor of Finance and
Governance at the Research Centre for Entrepreneurship and
Family Firms at Hasselt University. Her current research
focuses on financing decisions, executive compensation, and
professionalization of family firms.
Vincent Molly is an assistant professor of Entrepreneurship and
Family Business at the Strategy, Innovation & Entrepreneurship
Department at KU Leuven. He is also academic director of the
Family Business Community at Antwerp Management School.
His research focuses on financing decisions, governance, per-
formance, and succession of family firms.