ArticlePDF Available

Testing Bienenfeld's Second-Order Approximation for the Wage-Profit Curve, BULLETIN OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, 9:2 (2015): 161-17

Authors:

Abstract

This paper constructs Bienenfeld's second-order approximation for the wage-profit curve and tests it using data from ten symmetric input-output tables of the Greek economy. The results suggest that there is room for using low-dimensional models as surrogates for actual single-product economies.
* Department of Public Administration, Panteion University, Athens, Greece; E-mail:
mariolis@hotmail.gr
BULLETIN OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
9:2 (2015): 161-170
Testing Bienenfeld’s Second-Order
Approximation for the Wage-Profit Curve
THEODORE MARIOLIS*
This paper constructs Bienenfeld’s second-order approximation for the
wage-profit curve and tests it using data from ten symmetric input-output
tables of the Greek economy. The results suggest that there is room for
using low-dimensional models as surrogates for actual single-product
economies.
INTRODUCTION
Typical findings in many empirical studies of single-product systems
are that, in the economically relevant interval of the profit rate, (i) the
approximation of the production prices through Bienenfeld’s (1988)
linear and, a fortiori, quadratic formulae works pretty well; and (ii) the
wage-profit curves (WPCs) are almost linear, i.e. the correlation
coefficients between the distributive variables tend to be above 99%,
and their second derivatives change sign no more than once or, very
rarely, twice, irrespective of the numeraire chosen. As it has recently
been argued, these findings could be connected to the skew distribution
of the eigenvalues of the matrices of vertically integrated technical
coefficients (Schefold, 2008, 2013; Mariolis and Tsoulfidis, 2009, 2011,
2014, 2015; Iliadi et al., 2014).
The present paper, drawing on Bienefeld’s (1988) polynomial
approximation of prices, constructs a ‘proper rational’ approximation
for the WPC and tests its second-order form using data from the 19 x
19 Symmetric Input-Output Tables (SIOTs) of the Greek economy,
spanning the period 1988-1997.1 The selection of this dataset was based
on its extensive use in a number of closely related studies (see Mariolis
and Tsoulfidis, 2015a, chs 3 to 5, and the references therein).
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2
presen ts the ne cessary pre limin arie s. Se ction 3 de riv es the
approximation for the WPC. Section 4 brings in the empirical evidence.
Finally, Section 5 concludes.
162 / THEODORE MARIOLIS
PRELIMINARIES
Consider a closed, linear and viable system involving only single
products, basic commodities (in the sense of Sraffa, 1960) and
circulating capital. Under the usual assumptions, the wage-price-profit
rate relations for the system may be written as
(1 )
w r
 p l pA
(1)
where p denotes a n vector of production prices, w the money wage
rate, and 1 (>0) the 1×n vector of direct labour coefficients, r the uniform
profit rate, and A the n×n matrix of direct technical coefficients.2 After
rearrangement, equation (1) becomes
w
 p v pJ
(2)
or, if < 1,
1
[ ]
w
 
p v I J
(2a)
where
1
[ ]
 
v l I A
denotes the vector of vertically integrated labour
coefficients or labour values, and
1
[ ]
 
H A I A
(>0) the vertically
integrated technical coefficients matrix. Moreover, rR–1, 0  1,
denotes the ‘relative (or normalized) profit rate’, which equals the share
of profits in the Sraffian Standard system (SSS), and
1 1
1 1
1
A H
R
 
   
the maximum profit rate, i.e. the profit rate corresponding to [w = 0, p
> 0], which equals the ratio of the net product to the means of
production in the SSS. Finally, J RH denotes the normalized vertically
integrated technical coefficients matrix, where 1 1
1.
J H
R
  
If commodity zT, with vzT = 1, is chosen as the numeraire, i.e. pzT =
1, then equation (2a) implies
Z 1 T 1
( [ ] )
w
 
 v I J z (3)
and
   
(4)
Post-multiplying equation (2) by SSC, i.e.
T T
1
[ ]
 
A
s I A x
, with
T
1
1,
A
lx and rearranging terms, gives
Z Z T
(1 )w  
p s
(3a)
TESTING BIENENFELDS SECOND-ORDER APPROXIMATION... / 163
where pzsT represents the price of net output, measured in terms of
commodity zT, of the SSS. Equations (3) and (4) gives the WPC and the
production prices, measured in terms of commodity zT, as functions of
, respectively. It then follows that:
(i) At = 0 we obtain wz(0) = 1 and pz(0) = v, while in the other
extreme case, i.e. at = 1, we obtain wz(1) = 1 and Z T 1
1 1
(1) ( )
J J
p y z y
.
(ii) The WPC is an improper rational function of degree n, and
strictly decreasing in 0 1 (see equations (3) and (3a)):
Z Z Z Z 1 T
/ [ ]w dw d w
   
p J I J z
Z Z T T
(0) (0)w   
p Jz vJz
(3b)
Z Z T T 1 T
1 1
(1) (1) ( )w
    J J
p s y z y s
(3c)
where vJzT equals the ratio of the capital-net output ratio (measured
in terms of labour values) in the vertically integrated industry
producing the numeraire commodity to the capital-net output ratio,
R–1, in the SSS. Finally, the WPC may admit up to 3n 6 inflection
points (though it is not certain that they will all occur in 0 1;
Garegnani, 1970, p. 419).
(iii) If 1 (v) is the P-F eigenvector of A (J) or if SSC is chosen as the
numeraire, then
wS = 1 – (5)
i.e. the WPC is linear, as in a one-commodity world. The former case
corresponds to the Ricardo-Marx-Samuelson ‘equal value compositions
of capital’ case, and implies that p = v, i.e. the ‘pure labour theory of
value’ holds true. In the latter case,
S 1
0
(1 ) [ ] (1 )( )h
h

     
p v I J v J
(6)
which is the reduction of prices to ‘dated quantities of embodied labour’
(Kurz and Salvadori, 1995, p. 175) in terms of SSC. Differentiation of
equation (6) with respect to finally gives
S(0)
  p v vJ
(6a)
APPROXIMATION FOR THE WAGE-PROFIT CURVE
Assume that prices are measured in terms of SSC. As is well known,
for any semi-positive n–vector y, yJh tends to the left P-F eigenvector
of J as h tends to infinity, i.e.
164 / THEODORE MARIOLIS
T T 1
1 1 1 1
lim [( )( ) ]
h
h

J J J J
yJ yx y x y
while an upper bound on the rate of convergence is given by
h
bc
K,
where
T 1 T
1 1 1 1
( )
h
 
J J J J
K J y x x y
the norm
K
denotes the maximum of the absolute values of the
elements of K, and b represents a positive constant, which depends on
J and c, for any c such that 2
1
c
 
J (see, e.g. Horn and Johnson,
1990, p. 501). Therefore, for a sufficiently large value of m such that
1 S
... (1)
m m
 vJ vJ p (7)
it follows from equation (6) that
1
S 2 S
0
(1 )( ) (1 ) (1 ...) (1)
m
h m
h
        
p v J p
or
1
S A 1 S 1
1
( ) ( (1) )
m
h h h m m
h
 
 
p p v vJ vJ p vJ (8)
The vector pA is Bienenfeld’s (1988) polynomial approximation for
the price vector measured in terms of SSC:
(i) It is exact at the extreme, economically significant, values of .
(ii) For m 2, it gives, the correct slope of the actual pj curves at
= 0 (consider equation (6a)).
(iii) Its accuracy is directly related to the rate of convergence in (7),
which in its turn is directly related to the magnitudes of
1
k
J. In the
extreme case where the non-labour conditions of production in all
industries are linearly dependent on each other, it holds that rank[J] =
1, which implies T 1 T
1 1 1 1
( )
J J J J
J y x x y
and 2
0 
J. Thus, vJ = pS(1) and
Bienenfeld’s approximation becomes linear and exact for all , i.e.
S A S
( (1) )   p p v p v
Equations (3) to (6) imply
TESTING BIENENFELDS SECOND-ORDER APPROXIMATION... / 165
Z 1 Z T S 1 S T
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
w w
 
p z p z
or
Z S S T 1
( )
w w
p z
Thus, invoking approximation (8), we obtain
Z S A T 1
( )
w w
p z
or
1
Z A S 1 T S 1 T 1
1
{1 ( ) ( (1) ) }
m
h h h m m
h
w w w
 
  
vJ vJ z p vJ z (9)
The approximate wA curve has the following attributes:
(i) It is a proper rational function of degree m, and exact at the
extreme values of , while its accuracy is directly related to the
magnitudes of
1
k
J.
(ii) It gives the correct slope of the actual WPC at = 1 (consider
equations (9) and (3c)):
A A T 1 S T 1
(1) ( (1) ) ( (1) )
w
 
   p z p z
or
A T 1 T Z
1 1
(1) ( ) (1)
w w
 
J J
y z y s
� �
For m 2, it also gives the correct slope at = 0 (consider equations
(9) and (3b)):
A S T
(0) (1)
w 
p z
, for m = 1
A T Z
(0) (0)
w w  vJz
� �
, for m 2
(iii) For m 2, it may admit up to 2m – 1 inflection points.
Setting m = 1, wA reduces to the homographic function
A S S T 1
[1 ( (1) 1)]
w w
  p z (9a)
which has exactly the same algebraic form as the WPC for the
Samuelson-Hicks-Spaventa or ‘corn-tractor’ model (see Spaventa,
19 70). Moreove r, A
0
w
for
0 1  
if f S T
(1) 1
p z or, since
S S
(1) (1)
p J p ,
S T 1
(1)
R
p Hz , i.e. at  = 1 the vertically integrated
166 / THEODORE MARIOLIS
industry producing zT is labour intensive relative to the SSS. When
rank[J]=1, this approximation becomes exact for all .3
Finally, setting m = 2, wA reduces to
A S T 2 S T T 1
[1 ( 1) ( (1) )]
w w
    vJz p z vJz (9b)
Let
, 1,2, 3
 
be the roots of equation A
0
w
, let be the
discriminant of the numerator of
A
w
, and set
T
 
vJz
and
S T
(1)
 
p z
,
. It is easily checked that
2 2
1 2 3
( )( )
   
1
1 2 1 3 2 3
3 ( )
     
1 2 3
3  
2 2 4
432 [(1 ) 4 ]( )  
It then follows that:
(i) All the roots are real and distinct iff
1 2
4 (1 )
   
, where
2 1 2
4 (1 )
   
for
0 1  
, while
1 2 2
4 (1 )
   
for
1 
.
(ii) The second-order approximate curve (9b) has at most one
inflection point in the interval
0 1  
. More specifically, that inflection
point occurs when < (>) 1 and 1
( ) 2 (1 )
   
or
2
( )  
.
EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
The test of the second-order approximate WPC, measured in terms of
the ‘actual’ real wage rate, with data from the flow SIOTs of the Greek
economy, spanning the period 1988-1997, gave the results summarized
in Table 1. This table reports:
(i) The actual, *, and the estimated, e, values of , 0  1, at
which the inflection points occur.
(ii) The signs of the discriminant, , and of 1 –.
(iii) The mean of the absolute error in this approximation, i.e.
1
Z A
0
MAE w w d  
(iv) The Euclidean angles (measured in degrees) between pS(1) and
vJm, m = 0, 1, 2, which are denoted by m.
TESTING BIENENFELDS SECOND-ORDER APPROXIMATION... / 167
(v) The modulus of the subdominant eigenvalue, |J2|, and the
arithmetic (AM) and geometric (GM) means of the moduli of the non-
dominant eigenvalues.
Table 1
Indicators and determinants of the accuracy of the second-order
approximate wage-profit curve
1988 19 89 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997
* 0.269 0.300 0.360 0.302 0.534 0.385 0.336 0.110 0.200
( 0)
z
w
e0.275 0.298 0.311 0.299 0.410 0.325 0.302 0.216 0.247 0.136
<0 <0 <0 <0 <0 <0 <0 <0 <0 <0
1–>0 >0 >0 >0 >0 >0 >0 >0 >0 >0
MAE 0.007 0.009 0.008 0.007 0.004 0.007 0.008 0.006 0.006 0.005
029.3 o 31.1 o 30.4 o 30.0 o 25.3 o 26.5 o 27.8 o 28.1 o 27.3 o 26.4 o
115.0 o 16.6 o 15.7 o 14.8 o 10.3 o 13.3 o 13.7 o 13.1 o 12.5 o 10.8 o
26.4 o 8.3 o 7.7 o 7.2 o 4.3 o 6.7 o 6.9 o 5.9 o 5.7 o 4.7 o
|J2| 0.643 0.683 0.675 0.657 0.624 0.667 0.678 0.655 0.664 0.641
AM 0.168 0.175 0.176 0.176 0.185 0.174 0.171 0.161 0.167 0.157
GM 0.086 0.086 0.088 0.087 0.089 0.081 0.088 0.074 0.074 0.073
From this table, the associated numerical results and the hitherto
analysis we arrive at the following conclusions:
(i) Although the systems deviate considerably from the equal value
compositions of capital case (see the values of 0), the approximation
works pretty well. With the exception of the year 1997, both curves
switch from convex to concave at ‘adjacent’ values of the relative profit
rate (the error |e*| is in the range of 0.002 to 0.124), and the MAE
is no greater than 0.010. The graphs in Figure 1 are sufficiently
representative and display the actual (depicted by a solid line) and the
approximate (depicted by a dotted line) WPCs for the years 1989 (where
MAE, m and
2
J
exhibit their highest values) and 1997 (where
Z
0
w
).
(ii) In all systems, vJm tend quickly to S
(1)
p, and the moduli of the
first non-dominant eigenvalues fall quite rapidly, whereas the rest
constellate in much lower values forming a ‘long tail’. In fact, as it has
already been pointed out (Mariolis and Tsoulfidis, 2011, pp. 104-105),
the moduli of the eigenvalues of each system matrix follow an
exponential pattern of the form
0.2
0 1
exp( )
y x
 
 
168 / THEODORE MARIOLIS
where 0
1.738 1.827
  ,1
0.986 1.040
  and the R – squared
is in the range of 0.975 to 0.991. These findings, which are in absolute
accordance with those detected in other studies of quite diverse actual
economies (see Mariolis and Tsoulfidis, 2015a, chs 5-6, and the
references therein), indicate that the accuracy of this second-order
approximation would not be so sensitive to the numeraire choice.
1989
0.5
1.0
0.5
0.5
1.0
1997
0.5
1.0
0.5
1.0
Figure 1: Actual and approximate wage-relative profit rate curves; years 1989
and 1997
-
TESTING BIENENFELDS SECOND-ORDER APPROXIMATION... / 169
CONCLUDING REMARKS
Using data from ten symmetric input-output tables of the Greek
econo my, it has been argued that Bienen felds se cond-order
approximate wage-profit curve, which has at most one inflection point
in the economically relevant interval of the profit rate, is accurate
enough. This argument reduces to the skew distribution of the
eigenvalues of the matrices of vertically integrated tech nic al
coefficients, and suggests that low-dimensional models, with no more
than three industries, can be profitably used as surrogates for actual
single-product economies.
Future research efforts should be directed to the ‘inverse problem’,
that is, to (i) determine the conditions that notional production systems
should fulfil in order to generate Bienenfeld’s-like low-order wage-
price-profit rate curves; and (ii) explore the structural interfaces of those
systems with the actual ones.
Acknowledgements
I am indebted to two anonymous referees for comments and hints. A first draft of
this paper was presented at a Work sh op of the ‘Stud y Group on Sraffia n
Economics’ at the Panteion University, in December 2014: I am grateful to Nikolaos
Rodousakis and George Soklis for remarks. Furthermore, I would like to thank
Lefteris Tsoulfidis for suggestions and discussions. The usual disclaimer applies.
Notes
1. For the available data and the construction of the relevant variables, see
Tsoulfidis and Mariolis (2007, pp. 435-437).
2. The transpose of a 1×n vector
[ ]
j
y
y is denoted by yT. Furthermore, A1
denotes the Perron-Frobenius (P-F) eigenvalue of a semi-positive n×n matrix
A, and T
1 1
( , )
A A
x y
denote the corresponding eigenvectors, while Ak, k = 2, ...,
n and 2 3 ...
n
 
 
A A A , denote the non-dominant eigenvalues.
3. For the derivation of an alt er nati ve homographic approximati on, i.e .
S T 1
[1 ( 1)]
w
 vJz , see Mariolis (2015).
References
Bienenfeld, M. (1988), Regularity in price changes as an effect of changes in
distribution, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 12, pp. 247-255.
Garegnani, P. (1970), Heterogeneous capital, the production function and the
theory of distribution, The Review of Economic Studies, 37, pp. 407-436.
Horn, R. A. and Johnson, C. R. (1991), Topics in Matrix Analysis, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Pres s.
170 / THEODORE MARIOLIS
Iliadi , F., Marioli s, T., Sokli s, G., an d Tsoulfi dis, L. (2014), Bienen fe ld’s
approximation of production prices and eigenvalue distribution: further
evidence from five European economies, Contributions to Political Economy,
33, pp. 35-54.
Kurz, H. D. and Salvadori, N. (1995), Theory of Production. A Long-Period Analysis,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mariolis, T. (2015), Norm bounds and a homographic approximation for the wage-
profit curve, Metroeconomica, 66, pp. 263-283.
Mariolis, T. and Tsoulfidis, L. (2009), Decomposing the changes in production
prices into ‘capital-intensity’ and ‘price’ effects: theory and evidence from
the Chinese economy, Contributions to Political Economy, 28, pp. 1-22.
Mariolis, T. and Tsoulfidis, L. (2011), Eigenvalue distribution and the production
price-profit rate relationship: theory and empirical evidence, Evolutionary and
Institutional Economics Review, 8, pp. 87-122.
Mariolis, T. and Tsoulfidis, L. (2014), On Bródy’s conjecture: theory, facts and
figures about instability of the US economy, Economic Systems Research, 26,
pp. 209-223.
Mariolis, T. and Tsoulfidis, L. (2015), Capital theory ‘paradoxes’ and paradoxical
results: resolved or continued?, paper presented at the 19th European Society
for the History of Economic Thought Conference, 14-16 May 2015, Roma Tre
University, Italy.
Mariolis, T. and Tsoulfidis, L. (2015a), Modern Classical Economics and Reality: A
Spectral Analysis of the Theory of Value and Distribution. Tokyo: Springer Verlag
(forthcoming).
Schefold, B. (2008), Families of strongly curved and of nearly linear wage curves:
a contribution to the debate about the surrogate production function, Bulletin
of Political Economy, 2, pp. 1-24.
Schefold, B. (2013), Approximate surrogate production functions, Cambridge Journal
of Economics, 37, pp. 1161-1184.
Spaventa, L. (1970), Rate of profit, rate of growth, and capital intensity in a simple
production model, Oxford Economic Papers, 22, pp. 129-147.
Sraffa, P. (1960), Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. Prelude to a
Critique of Economic Theory, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Tsoulfidis, L. and Mariolis, T. (2007), Labour values, prices of production and the
effects of income distribution: evidence from the Greek economy, Economic
Systems Research, 19, pp. 425-437.
... , it becomes exact for all . 5 For the corresponding treatment of the WRP curves; see Mariolis (2015aMariolis ( , 2015b) and Mariolis and Tsoulfidis (2016a, Chap. 5). ...
Research
Full-text available
Capital theory and the associated with it price effects consequent upon changes in the distributive variables hold centre stage when it comes to the internal consistency of both classical and neoclassical theories of value. This paper briefly reviews the literature and then focuses on the detected skew eigenvalue distribution of the vertically integrated technical coefficients matrices of actual economies. The findings prompt the use of the Schur triangularization theorem for the construction even of a single industry from the input-output structure of the entire economy. Such a hyper-basic industry, in combination with hyper-non-basic industries, embodies properties that may capture the behaviour of the entire economic system. Thus, we can derive some meaningful results consistent with the available empirical evidence, which finally suggest that actual economies tend to respond as 'irregular-uncontrollable' systems.
Article
Capital theory and the price effects consequent upon changes in the distributive variables hold center stage when it comes to the internal consistency of both classical and neoclassical theories of value. This paper briefly reviews the literature and then focuses on the detected skew eigenvalue distribution of the vertically integrated technical coefficients matrices of actual economies. The findings prompt the use of the Schur triangularization theorem for the construction even of a single industry from the input–output structure of the entire economy. Such a hyper-basic industry, in combination with hyper-non-basic industries, embodies properties that may capture the behavior of the entire economic system. Thus, we can derive some meaningful results consistent with the available empirical evidence, which finally suggest that actual economies tend to respond as ‘irregular-uncontrollable’ systems.
Article
Full-text available
This paper tests Bienenfeld's polynomial approximation of production prices using data from ten symmetric input–output tables of five European economies. The empirical results show that the quadratic formula works extremely well and the degree of its accuracy is connected to the actual distribution of the eigenvalues of the matrices of vertically integrated technical coefficients. It then follows that the number of vertically integrated industries that shape the production price–profit rate curves is rather low.
Article
Full-text available
A typical finding in many empirical studies is that the production price-profit rate relationship is, by and large, monotonic. This paper derives, in terms of the usual single-product model, the spectral conditions that make possible the appearance of such monotonicity. Furthermore, using data from input-output tables for a number of countries and years, it examines the extent to which actual economies fulfil those spectral conditions.
Book
This book presents an in-depth, novel, and mathematically rigorous treatment of the modern classical theory of value based on the spectral analysis of the price–profit–wage rate system. The classical theory is also subjected to empirical testing to show its logical consistency and explanatory content with respect to observed phenomena and key economic policy issues related to various multiplier processes. In this context, there is an examination of the trajectories of relative prices when the distributive variables change, both theoretically and empirically, using actual input–output data from a number of quite divers e economies. It is suggested that the actual economies do not behave like the parable of a one-commodity world of the traditional neoclassical theory, which theorizes the relative scarcities of “goods and production factors” as the fundamental determinants of relative prices and their movement. By contrast, the results of the empirical analysis are fully consistent with the modern classical theory, which makes the intersectoral structure of production and the way in which net output is distributed amongst its claimants the fundamental determinants of price magnitudes. At the same time, however, these results indicate that only a few vertically integrated industries (“industry core” or “hyper-basic industries”) are enough to shape the behaviour of the entire economy in the case of a disturbance. This fact is reduced to the skew distribution of the eigenvalues of the matrices of vertically integrated technical coefficients and reveals that, across countries and over time, the effective dimensions of actual economies are surprisingly low.
Article
The Cambridge debate showed that an aggregation of capital is not possible in general. A recent investigation has found one example for reswitching and several for reverse capital deepening, but the paradoxes appear to be infrequent. The paper provides a theoretical justification of this result and shows how wage curves of input–output matrices with small non-dominant eigenvalues become quasi-linear with some numéraires. Large random systems lead to the genesis of such states. Approximate surrogate production functions then seem possible. A family of economic systems with constant capital composition allows construction of a surrogate production function.
Article
This paper provides lower and upper norm bounds for the wage–profit curve in linear single-product systems. Thus, it also constructs an algebraically simple (i.e. homographic) and empirically powerful approximation to that curve. The results finally suggest that actual economies tend to behave as ‘corn-tractor’ systems with respect to the shape of the wage–profit curve and, at the same time, behave as three-industry systems with respect to the shape of the production price–profit rate curves.
Article
Bródy's conjecture regarding the instability of economies is submitted to an empirical test using input–output flow tables of varying size for the US economy, for the benchmark years 1997 and 2002, as well as for the period 1998–2011. The results obtained using input–output tables of various dimensions lend support to the view of increasing instability (in the sense of Bródy) of the US economy over the period considered. Furthermore, our analysis shows that only a few vertically integrated industries are enough to shape the behaviour of the entire economy in the case of a disturbance. These results may usefully be contrasted with those derived in a parallel literature on aggregate fluctuations from microeconomic ‘idiosyncratic’ shocks.
Article
This paper deals with the changes in prices of production induced by variations in income distribution on the basis of a linear model of production with circulating capital and homogeneous labour. It is shown that the total effect of income distribution on prices can be decomposed into a “capital-intensity” and a “price” effect and that, in actual economies, the former is expected to dominate the latter. In order to obtain a concrete idea of the actual trajectories of the price movements and to quantify the relative strength of the two effects, we use input–output data of the Chinese economy.
Article
This paper explores the relationship between labour values, prices of production and changes in income distribution in an actual economy. For this purpose we use a linear model of production with circulating capital and homogeneous labour, assuming that wages are paid ex ante. On the basis of this model and data from input-output tables of the Greek economy for the period 1988-1997 we estimate the labour values and prices of production, which are normalized with the use of the Sraffian standard commodity and the actual output vector. Furthermore, we extend Steedman's polynomial approximation of prices of production to include the case where wages are paid ex ante and the accuracy of this approximation is tested with actual input-output data. Finally, we find that prices of production change as a result of hypothetical changes in income distribution more often than not in a monotonic way and in a few cases display curvatures that reverse the order between prices of production and values.