Content uploaded by Milos Popovic
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Milos Popovic on Sep 28, 2017
Content may be subject to copyright.
Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics
Managing Internationalized Civil Wars
Erin K. Jenne and Milos Popovic
Subject:
Contentious Politics and Political Violence, World Politics
DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190228637.013.573
Summary and Keywords
In their seminal study “Resort to Arms,” Small and Singer (1982) defined a civil war as “any armed
conflict that involves (a) military action internal to the metropole, (b) the active participation of the
national government, and (c) effective resistance by both sides.” Internationalized civil wars constitute a
newer classification, denoting a conflict involving organized violence on two or more sides within a
sovereign state, in which foreign elements play a role in instigating, prolonging, or exacerbating the
struggle. Small and Singer defined civil war as one in which a “system member” intervenes into a substate
conflict involving organized violence. Although Singer and Small conceived “system members” narrowly
as external sovereign states engaged in military intervention into the civil war in question, the definition
has since been expanded by the Peace Research Institute Oslo (PRIO) and Uppsala Conflict Data Program
(UCDP) to include other foreign actors—such as nonstate or private actors, diasporas, IOs, corporations,
or cross-border kin groups—any of which can intervene to intensify a domestic civil conflict. From
superpower interventions during the Cold War to more recent conflicts in Syria and Ukraine,
internationalized civil wars have garnered increasing scholarly attention, primarily because they tend to
be far bloodier and more protracted than noninternationalized civil wars.
How to end such wars is a problem long bedeviling the international community. Civil wars are
already more difficult to end than interstate wars partly because there are more players to satisfy in civil
war settings, with multiple conflict parties coexisting on a single territory, and multiple factions within
each conflict party—each constituting a “veto player” that might plausibly spoil a peace agreement should
the agreement not satisfy their needs. This problem is exacerbated by an order of magnitude when a civil
war becomes internationalized. When outside actors get involved in a civil war, the number of veto players
rises correspondingly to include not only domestic players and internal factions, but also the involved
external players, which may include foreign governments, diaspora groups, foreign fighters, and/or
transnational social networks.
Managing or ending internationalized civil wars is thus a highly complicated balancing act
requiring attention not just to internal, but also to external veto players represented by all involved parties
both inside and outside the conflict state. The traditional methods of conflict management involve
electoral engineering, power-sharing arrangements, or other peace deals that seek to satisfy the
aspirations of involved internal parties, while ensuring that the peace deal is “self-enforcing.” This means
that it will hold up even in the absence of outside pressure. In internationalized civil wars, however,
conflict managers must also satisfy involved outside actors or otherwise neutralize external conflict
processes. There are multiple methods for doing this, ranging from effective border control in cases of
conflict spillover to decomposing internationalized conflicts into civil and international conflicts, which
are solved separately, to outright peace enforcement involving international security guarantees.
Keywords: conflict management, internationalized civil wars, ethnic conflict, security
regimes, mediation, empirical international relations theory
2
Introduction
Internationalized civil wars are violent struggles waged between two or more armed groups,
where foreign elements play a significant role in instigating, prolonging, or exacerbating the
conflict. From superpower interventions during the Cold War to more recent conflicts in Syria
and Ukraine, internationalized civil wars have attracted increasing scholarly attention because
they tend to be bloodier and more protracted than purely domestic struggles.
How to end such wars is a problem that has long bedeviled the international community. Civil
wars are already more difficult to end than interstate wars due to the lack of clear protocols for
ending conflicts in a common state. In civil war settings, the powerful side (usually the
government) cannot easily “credibly commit” to honor an agreement not to retaliate against the
rebels, making them less willing to disarm (Weingast, 1994; Fearon, 1995; Lake &
Rothchild, 1998). To make matters worse, civil wars include many more players who must be
satisfied in order to end the violence—multiple conflict parties and sometimes multiple factions
within each conflict party each serve as a “veto player” that might plausibly spoil a peace
agreement should it fall outside of their respective bargaining ranges. This problem is
exacerbated by an order of magnitude when a civil war becomes internationalized. When outside
actors get involved in a civil war, the number of veto players rises to include not only domestic
players and internal factions, but also external players—which range from foreign governments
to diaspora groups to foreign fighters and/or transnational conflict networks. Before long,
conflict managers find themselves playing something that looks less like two-level games and
more like four-dimensional chess.
Managing internationalized civil wars is thus a highly complicated balancing act requiring
conflict managers to pay attention to veto players both inside and outside the conflict state.
Traditional methods of civil conflict often err by overemphasizing domestic solutions such as
electoral engineering, power-sharing arrangements, or other peace deals aimed to satisfy the
aspirations of involved internal parties. Once the civil war is internationalized, however, conflict
managers must also satisfy outside participants and/or neutralize external conflict processes
(Tsebelis, 2002). There are multiple methods for doing this, ranging from effective border
control in cases of conflict spillover to managing outside interveners by decomposing
internationalized conflicts into civil and international conflicts. The goal is to isolate or
neutralize the external conflict dimension, after which the internal conflict might be more
readily de-escalated or resolved.
Managing Internationalized Civil Wars
Civil wars consist of large-scale violence between one or more armed substate actors1 and the
incumbent state government,2 which controls the state capital and has a claim to a monopoly of
legitimate physical force over the territory of the state. With some exceptions, civil conflicts are
waged over political power or territory. Either way, the hallmark of civil wars is large-scale and
sustained violence. This marks them out from other types of political conflicts such as
assassinations, coups, or organized crime. In the vast quantitative literature on the causes and
effects of civil wars, researchers measure civil wars as political conflicts between two armed
substate actors that have generated a significant number of casualties. The Correlates of War
(COW) defines civil wars as domestic struggles between a government and armed opposition
that have yielded at least 1,000 deaths a year, while the Peace Research Institute Oslo (PRIO)
and Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP) use a much lower casualty threshold of 25 battle-
related deaths per year. The choice of threshold matters because a lower threshold of violence
3
allows for an analysis of a much wider set of conflicts, including low-intensity struggles. By
contrast, the COW data should be used when the researcher is interested in analyzing the causes
and consequences of only the bloodiest substate conflicts (a subset of the former).
What makes a civil conflict “civil” is that military action is internal to the state (Small &
Singer, 1982). However, a great proportion of so-called civil conflicts are actually “international”
in the sense that, while the physical scope and stakes of the conflicts are local, they involve
numerous outside actors and influences—affecting every stage in the life cycle from conflict
initiation to conflict prosecution and, finally, conflict termination. The Syrian civil war is just
one of the most recent examples of internationalized civil wars—internal wars with a significant
international component ranging from military interventions by foreign actors to conflict
spillover from neighboring states to diaspora interventions to cross-border flows of ideas,
fighters, and war materiel.3 Nor are internationalized civil wars particularly rare. In fact, nearly
half of all civil wars since WWII have featured foreign involvement (Cunningham, Gleditsch, &
Salehyan, 2009), complicating the conventional view that civil wars are confined to the borders
of a single state.
These facts are worrisome given that internationalized civil wars are on average longer and
bloodier than noninternationalized civil wars. From superpower interventions during the Cold
War to more recent internationalized civil conflicts in Syria and Ukraine, research has shown
that external intervention tends to prolong civil wars (Balch-Lindsay & Enterline, 2000; Balch-
Lindsay, Enterline, & Joyce, 2008; Gent, 2008). One reason, as noted above, is that external
participants increase the number of “veto players” that can block a peace agreement to end the
civil war if they are dissatisfied with the terms of a given peace agreement (Stedman, 1997;
Cunningham, 2006).4 This has clearly impeded peace-making in Syria, as it has in Afghanistan,
Cambodia, and Congo, where multiple intervenors have brought their own agendas to the
conflict (Cunningham, 2010). With some exceptions, outside participants escalate civil wars by
complicating the stakes of the conflict, making peace harder to broker. They can also prolong
conflict by empowering one or both sides to fight longer and harder. Sudden perceptions of
enhanced leverage can make conflict resolution still more difficult. This illustrates the converse
of Zartman’s dictum that successful resolution of civil war requires a “ripe moment” or “hurting
stalemate” for all sides of the conflict (Zartman, 1995). Military interventions threaten to destroy
such stalemates by empowering the losing side and encouraging it to fight longer.
Interventions on behalf of the opposition have a particularly deleterious impact, as they can
provoke government repression against groups from which the armed rebels draw their recruits
(Weinstein, 2006; Kuperman, 2008). These interventions sometimes encourage predation on
the rebel side as well (Byman & Kreps, 2010; Salehyan, Siroky, & Wood, 2014;
Popovic, 2015a, 2015b). South African support for the Revolutionary United Front in Sierra
Leone is an oft-cited example of how externally backed armed opposition groups can turn into a
perpetrator of mass atrocities. Externally backed governments may also be emboldened to
repress their domestic challengers more brutally as outsiders funnel them money and logistical
support, not to mention regime legitimacy (Peksen, 2012). Conflict in neighboring states might
also foil conflict resolution attempts due to the presence of cross-border sanctuaries that make
rebels less amenable to cutting a deal. For example, the Tamil Tiger rebels used the neighboring
Indian state of Tamil Nadu as a safe haven from which to strike back at the Sri Lankan
government, helping to prolong the war in northeastern Sri Lanka despite efforts by
international negotiators to facilitate a settlement to the conflict (Salehyan, 2009).
4
Some civil wars are internationalized laterally or incidentally, as the outgrowth of regional
conflict processes. Regions plagued by chronic conflict spillover are sometimes described as
“bad neighborhoods” (Weiner, 1996). Here, cross-border flows of refugees, weapons, and
warriors serve to perpetuate civil violence in an endless feedback loop, making the entire
neighborhood more dangerous (Lischer, 2003, 2006; Salehyan & Gleditsch, 2006;
Salehyan, 2007; Lake & Rothchild, 1998). Such neighborhoods can compromise conflict
management efforts. Third-party initiatives to manage a domestic conflict are likely to falter, for
examples, when wars in neighboring countries spread across state borders. For instance, the
1997 civil unrest in Albania produced a flood of weapons that were trafficked over the border for
use in the Kosovo Liberation Army (KLA) insurgency against Belgrade. This directly
undermined attempts by the Organization on Security and Cooperation in Europe (OSCE) to
contain escalating tensions between the Belgrade government and the separatist Kosovar
Albanians. Similarly, U.S. weapons sent to the mujahedeen during the Soviet occupation of
Afghanistan in the 1980s were sold and resold in secondary arms markets in the region—
ultimately winding up in the wars of Bosnia-Herzegovina and Kosovo, where they spoiled long-
term conflict management missions. Internal rebellions also foment insurgencies in neighboring
countries. In 2001, former KLA fighters slipped over the Kosovo border into Macedonia to ignite
a violent conflict between Skopje and the Albanian minority—disrupting a successful ongoing
eight-year mediation by the OSCE High Commissioner on National Minorities, Max van der
Stoel. Finally, cross-border ethnic ties can ruin conflict resolution attempts by supporting a
more radicalized position, as was the case in Macedonia in 2001 when remnants of the former
Kosovo Liberation Army crossed the Macedonian border to mobilize the Albanian minority
there.
Conflict managers very often fail to de-escalate internationalized civil wars because of their
overemphasis on the domestic-level conflict environment. When civil wars have multiple
external players, as in the case of internationalized civil wars, it becomes all the more difficult to
find compromise agreements that can satisfy all players. Internationalized civil wars are also
difficult to end because all sides need to be able to credibly commit to the terms of the peace in
order to secure a lasting peace. What this means is that no matter how technically sophisticated
the domestic postwar institutions, unresolved conflict processes in the wider environment can
spoil domestic level peace initiatives through conflict spillover or diffusion (Salehyan &
Gleditsch, 2006; Buhaug & Gleditsch, 2008; Kathman, 2011; Schutte & Weidmann, 2011).
Methods for Managing Internationalized Civil Wars
What can the international community do in practical terms to manage internationalized civil
conflicts more effectively? If we accept that the solutions for conflicts depend at least in part on
their causes, then it follows that the methods chosen for managing internationalized civil wars
must address the ways in which the conflict in question was internationalized. Conflicts driven
by spillover effects from civil wars in the neighborhood (such as conflicts in the Great Lakes
region in Africa or in Syria and Iraq) require different solutions than civil wars internationalized
due to border wars or other bilateral disputes between neighboring states. We believe that
effective conflict management requires taking a broader perspective on the civil conflict
environment. This calls for focusing on the region as a whole and assuming an “outside-in”
approach to civil conflict management. By stabilizing the regional or wider environment, conflict
managers create a condition of “nested security” within which domestic solutions are more likely
to yield fruit (Jenne, 2015). We explore several different methods below; the choice, once again,
should fit the nature of the internationalized civil war itself.
5
Method I: Managing Outside Interveners
One of the simplest and most efficient means of managing internationalized civil conflict is for
peace managers to use carrots and sticks to induce external participants to withdraw from the
war (Regan & Aydin, 2006). This method is appropriate for de-escalating civil wars that are
driven or exacerbated by the deliberate actions of outside powers, principally foreign
governments. Since most civil conflicts are waged between a rebel group and the state
government, and since the side of the rebels is usually militarily weaker than that of the state,
the easiest way to end the conflict is to get outside players to withdraw military assistance from
the rebels. Indeed, the simple withdrawal of external support from the side of the armed
opposition may be enough to end the conflict.5 Doing so tips the scales decisively on the
battlefield, allowing for state victory and associated conflict termination. The disadvantage of
this approach is that cutting off support to opposition groups often entails tremendous
humanitarian costs due to state-led reprisals—not only against rebel insurgents, but also the
wider group from which the rebels draw their recruits. Terminating support to the rebel group
may therefore lead to a scorched earth campaign by state forces against civilians who are
associated with the rebels.
To consider a few examples, in 1946 two separatist insurgencies emerged in northern Iran by the
Kurds and Azeris who declared independent national states. The northern region had been
occupied by the Soviets during the Second World War, and after the war Moscow helped to set
up separatist states in the region. The separatist groups declared an independent People’s
Republic of Azerbaijan and Republic of Mahabad, both of which were sustained by Soviet
military and economic aid. The United States, however, backed the new Shah of Iran and put
pressure on the Soviets to withdraw their aid to the rebel groups; an implicit promise of oil
concessions helped convince the Soviets to comply with U.S. demands. Once Soviet support was
withdrawn, Iran was able to crush the movements easily. The Azeri republic quickly gave up
autonomy, and its leaders fled into Azerbaijan. At the same time, Iranian forces occupied the
Kurdish republic, and the Kurdish leadership was tried and executed. The conflicts were
effectively terminated due to the withdrawal of support to the rebels, but at tremendous human
cost.
A particularly brutal case of reprisals can be seen in the aftermath of the Vietnam war. After
years of propping up a South Vietnamese government that enjoyed little grassroots support, the
United States abruptly pulled out its troops and other assistance in a 1975 helicopter evacuation
called Operation Frequent Wind. While thousands of South Vietnamese who had collaborated
with the U.S. were evacuated along with American personnel, many tens of thousands were left
behind, and their fate after the North Vietnamese captured Saigon still is not known. According
to the Vietnamese government, 200,000 were sent to “re-education camps,” where torture and
malnutrition were common (Kirkpatrick, 1988, p. 31).
These cases show that simply withdrawing (or inducing outside interveners to withdraw)
support from rebel forces often leads to a brutal rout of the rebels by government forces,
followed by a vicious backlash against civilians residing on the disputed territory. Inducing
outsiders to suddenly cut off support to rebel forces must therefore be viewed as a suboptimal
means of terminating internationalized civil wars.
6
Method II: Managing Borders
Internationalized civil wars might also be de-escalated by managing state borders. This method
is best suited to conflicts that have been and continue to be internationalized laterally—sparked
and/or sustained through conflict spillover, diaspora intervention, or the existence of safe
havens used by rebel groups to equalize their struggle against the government. A salient example
of this is the decades-long separatist war in Sri Lanka. The rebel Tamil Tigers were able to
sustain decades of warfare against government forces due to an active Tamil diaspora that sent
funds to arm the rebel group as well as the availability of safe havens in the neighboring Indian
state of Tamil Nadu. Despite many rounds of negotiations between Tamil leaders and
government representatives, the conflict finally ended with a government victory over the rebels
due to a massive interdiction of ships that smuggled arms and other assistance to the rebels as
well as a global effort to disrupt diaspora funding to the insurgency (Jenne, 2003). Border
management thus facilitated a decisive end to the Sri Lankan conflict. The downside of this
method is similar to that of inducing outside interveners to withdraw. In the case of Sri Lanka,
the costs of the final rout were enormous—the Tamil Tigers used civilians as human shields
while the government closed in on rebel positions. Thousands of civilians were killed or injured
in the final phase of the conflict and hundreds of thousands were displaced. The empirical
record suggests that the first two methods have similar downsides, as they merely change the
calculations on the battlefield, permitting government victory. The predictable consequence is a
massive government-led or -sponsored backlash. To avoid these problems, conflict managers
must not only engineer a resolution to the conflict on the battlefield, but also protect against
government retaliation. Outside kin states might then help keep government retaliation in check
by signaling their intent to retaliate against the government should it engage in predation
against their beleaguered coethnics (Van Houten, 1998; Laitin, 1998). Unfortunately, outside
kin states are notoriously inconsistent in their policies toward kin abroad (Saideman, 2001;
Carment, James, & Taydas, 2006; Carment & Taydas, 2009), and hence are unreliable partners
in the business of conflict management.
A more successful example of border management can be seen in the US/NATO resolution of
the short-lived Macedonian conflict in 2001, in which a small band of Albanian Kosovar rebels
crossed the Kosovo-Macedonian border to spark an insurgency in the northwest Macedonian
territory. As the insurgents moved toward the Macedonian capital of Skopje, the U.S. and NATO
pressured Albanian rebel leaders to agree to disarm and conclude a peace agreement with the
Macedonian leadership, which also agreed to an extensive interethnic power-sharing agreement.
This led to a swift de-escalation of conflict, the disarmament of Albanian rebels and the
consolidation of an (albeit uneasy) peace. Conflict managers were largely able to accomplish this
feat because of the carrot of EU and NATO accession that they were able to offer the
Macedonian leadership in return for concessions (see Vachudova, 2005, and Kelley, 2006, for
more on how NATO and EU conditionality was used to manage ethnic conflict in Central and
Eastern Europe). The government thus constrained, no government reprisals occurred in the
wake of the ceasefire or peace agreement. The success of this case illustrates the importance of
combining border management with institutional constraints on the postwar government.
Method III: Regional Peace Agreements
Regional peace agreements (RPAs) are ideal typical cases of “outside-in” civil conflict
management. This hybrid approach often combines Method I with Method II; the peace
agreement includes border control and postwar political constraints, and the terms of the
7
agreement are guaranteed by one or more regional powers. The use of RPAs is most appropriate
to conflicts featuring both interventions by outside powers and the lateral spread of conflict
processes across state borders. Here, an internationalized civil war is resolved by integrating
external participants into the peace agreement itself, which includes extensive postwar
institutional arrangements.6 These solutions are usually, although not necessarily, guaranteed
by relatively powerful external state(s), alliances, or organizations—actors that wield big carrots
or, more commonly, big sticks. Sometimes, regional peace agreements are imposed on the
warring participants; other times, they are concluded through a series of carefully negotiated
deals including different conflict participants—sometimes these are unilateral commitments;
sometimes they are bilateral or collective agreements. The best of these combine disarmament
of rebel organizations with constraints on the postconflict government. We believe that they are
at once the most humane and effective method of resolving internationalized civil wars; they are
optimal solutions for such conflicts, assuming the guarantors of the agreement are willing and
able to hold it together.
An example is given by the 1995 Dayton Peace Agreement (DPA), which was mediated by the
United States at one of its military bases in Ohio. The DPA required both Serbia and Croatia to
halt their support for Bosnian Serbs and Croats, respectively. The agreement divided Bosnian
territory between Bosnian Serbs, Croats and Muslims and established guarantor roles for the
external parties to the conflict, Serbia and Croatia. At the same time, the DPA included an
extensive power-sharing agreement, written into the Bosnian constitution, that prevented the
Bosniaks from discriminating against the minority Bosnian Serbs and Croats. The entire
agreement was enforced by NATO troops. A similar case can be seen in the 1990s U.S.-mediated
Oslo Peace Process, which aimed to resolve the Palestinian conflict. Oslo was conducted in
parallel to interstate talks between regional players—Israel on one hand, and Jordan, Syria, and
Lebanon, on the other—over the wider Arab-Israeli conflict. Likewise, the conflict between the
Philippine government and the Moros insurgency over the status of the southern region of
Minandao raged for two decades before negotiations between the conflict parties induced a
temporary peace in the early 1990s. Indonesia, Libya, and the Organization of the Islamic
Conference (OIC) mediated a succession of talks beginning in the late 1970s that eventually
terminated the conflict and produced a peace agreement on the status of the region. What made
this a regional peace agreement was that the Muslim states pressured their coethnic Moros
insurgents to ratchet down their demands and simultaneously pressured Manila to engage in
talks with the insurgents using the implicit threat of an oil embargo (Kramer & Aronson, 2009).
The empirical record of regional peace agreements reveals both advantages and disadvantages
of this method as a means of resolving internationalized civil wars. The obvious upside, as
mentioned above, is that such agreements tend to split the difference between the warring
parties rather than institutionalizing a one-sided victory. The balanced approach is likely to
minimize casualties on one or both sides. The downside, however, is also apparent in these
cases: The settlements they produce often do not stick.7 The Oslo Peace Accords meant a
temporary halt to the Palestinian conflict, but violence soon reemerged after the talks broke
down at the end of the 1990s. Similarly, although the Moros insurgency was temporarily halted
through the RPA, it resurged in the late 1990s with Manila’s decision to rout the insurgency
militarily, leading to a resumption of hostilities in the 2000s. In other words, despite their many
advantages, regional peace deals are notoriously fragile, as they are based on international
settlements that can break down at any time. It is telling that of the cases discussed above, the
resolutions that continue to hold up (North Borneo and the Bosnian Dayton Accords) do so
8
because the regional parties keep the peace either through exogenous stabilization (Dayton
Accords) or endogenous stabilization based on mutual interests (the treaty between Indonesia
and Malaysia over the status of North Borneo).
Conclusion
The empirical record to date strongly suggests that domestic techniques of conflict management
efforts by themselves (electoral engineering, minority protections, and the like) are likely to be
insufficient for de-escalating conflict on the ground, as long as the wider neighborhood
continues to fuel the conflict or otherwise disrupt the peace process. The concrete policy
implications of this dynamic cannot be fully worked out here due to space limitations, but there
are a few broad policy guidelines.
First, the mere presence of mediators is not sufficient for reducing violence. Conflicts
undergoing peace negotiations may easily be “undone” when the external environment changes,
despite the best efforts of the negotiators or the existence of well-designed peace arrangements.
Second, if mediators ignore the conflict potential of external intervention and interstate rivalry
(focusing solely on domestic level solutions such as power-sharing or electoral engineering),
then they are unlikely to secure a significant reduction in violence. Third, the most violent civil
wars appear to be waged over control of the government, in poor countries and in unstable
neighborhoods, suggesting that reducing violence on the ground calls for regional solutions that
support and strengthen the host government, while discouraging governments from violently
repressing internal challengers. To achieve this, regional security regimes might be fruitfully
paired with economic development funds aimed at creating incentives for governments of the
region to work together to manage regime threats.
9
References
Adamson, F. (2013). Mechanisms of diaspora mobilization and the transnationalization of civil
war. In J. Checkel (Ed.), Transnational dynamics of civil war. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge
University Press.Find this resource:
Angoustures, A., & Pascal, V. (1996). Diasporas et financement des conflits. Économie des
guerres civiles. Paris: Hachette.Find this resource:
Bakke, K. M. (2013). Copying and learning from outsiders? Assessing diffusion from
transnational insurgents in the Chechen wars. In J. Checkel (Ed.), Transnational dynamics of
civil war. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:
Balch-Lindsay, D., & Enterline, A. J. (2000). Killing time: The world politics of civil war
duration, 1820–1992. International Studies Quarterly, 44(4), 615–642.Find this resource:
Balch-Lindsay, D., Enterline, A. J., & Joyce, K. A. (2008). Third-party intervention and the civil
war process. Journal of Peace Research, 45(3), 345–363.Find this resource:
Beissinger, M. R. (2002). Nationalist mobilization and the collapse of the Soviet State.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:
Bob, C. (2005). The marketing of rebellion: Insurgents, media, and international activism.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:
Brown, M. E. (Ed.). (1993). Ethnic conflict and international security. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.Find this resource:
Buhaug, H., & Gleditsch, K. S. (2008). Contagion or confusion? Why conflicts cluster in
space. International Studies Quarterly, 52(2), 215–233.Find this resource:
Byman, D., & Kreps, S. E. (2010). Agents of destruction? Applying principal‐agent analysis to
state‐sponsored terrorism. International Studies Perspectives, 11(1), 1–18.Find this resource:
Carment, D., James, P., & Taydas, Z. (2006). Who intervenes? Ethnic conflict and interstate
crisis. Columbus: Ohio State University Press.Find this resource:
Carment, D., James, P., & Taydas, Z. (2009). The internationalization of ethnic conflict: State,
society, and synthesis. International Studies Review, 11(1), 63–86.Find this resource:
Carment, D., & Rowlands, D. (1998). Three’s company: Evaluating third-party intervention in
intrastate conflict. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42(5), 572–599.Find this resource:
Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic
Papers, 56(4), 563–595.Find this resource:
Cunningham, D. E. (2006). Veto players and civil war duration. American Journal of Political
Science, 50(4), 875–892.Find this resource:
Cunningham, D. E. (2010). Blocking resolution: How external states can prolong civil
wars. Journal of Peace Research, 47(2), 115–127.Find this resource:
Cunningham, D. E., Gleditsch, K. S., & Salehyan, I. (2009). It takes two: A dyadic analysis of
civil war duration and outcome. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 53(4), 570–597.Find this
resource:
10
Fearon, J. D. (1995). Rationalist explanations for war. International Organization, 49(03),
379–414.Find this resource:
Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political
Science Review, 97(01), 75–90.Find this resource:
Forsberg, E. (2014). Diffusion in the study of civil wars: A cautionary tale. International Studies
Review, 16(2), 188–198.Find this resource:
Gent, S. E. (2008). Going in when it counts: Military intervention and the outcome of civil
conflicts. International Studies Quarterly, 52(4), 713–735.Find this resource:
Gleditsch, K. S. (2007). Transnational dimensions of civil war. Journal of Peace
Research, 44(3), 293–309.Find this resource:
Goertz, G., & Diehl, P. F. (1995). Taking “enduring” out of enduring rivalry: The rivalry approach
to war and peace. International Interactions, 21(3), 291–308.Find this resource:
Hegghammer, T. (2013). Should I stay or should I go? Explaining variation in Western jihadists’
choice between domestic and foreign fighting. American Political Science Review, 107(01), 1–
15.Find this resource:
Howard, L. M. (2008). UN peacekeeping in civil wars. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University
Press.Find this resource:
Jenne, E. K. (2003). Sri Lanka: A fragmented state. In Robert I. Rotberg (Ed.), State Failure
and State Weakness in a Time of Terror (pp. 219–221). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
Press.Find this resource:
Jenne, E. K. (2004). A bargaining theory of minority demands: Explaining the dog that did not
bite in 1990s Yugoslavia. International Studies Quarterly, 48(4), 729–754.Find this resource:
Jenne, E. K. (2007). Ethnic bargaining: The paradox of minority empowerment. Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press.Find this resource:
Jenne, E. K. (2015). Nested security: Lessons in conflict management from the League of
Nations and the European Union. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Find this resource:
Kathman, J. D. (2011). Civil war diffusion and regional motivations for intervention. Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 55(6), 847–876.Find this resource:
Kelley, J. (2006). New wine in old wineskins: Promoting political reforms through the new
European Neighbourhood Policy. Journal of Common Market Studies, 44(1), 29–55.Find this
resource:
Kirkpatrick, J. J. (1988). Legitimacy and force. New Brunswick, U.S.: Transaction
Publishers.Find this resource:
Kramer, T., & Aronson, D. (2009). Neither war nor peace: The future of the cease-fire
agreements in Burma. Amsterdam: Transnational Institute.Find this resource:
Kuperman, A. J. (2008). The moral hazard of humanitarian intervention: Lessons from the
Balkans. International Studies Quarterly, 52(1), 49–80.Find this resource:
11
Laitin, D. D. (1998). Identity in formation: The Russian-speaking populations in the near
abroad (Vol. 22). Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Find this resource:
Lake, D. A., & Rothchild, D. S. (1998). The international spread of ethnic conflict: Fear,
diffusion, and escalation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Find this resource:
Licklider, R. (1995). The consequences of negotiated settlements in civil wars, 1945–
1993. American Political Science Review, 89(03), 681–690.Find this resource:
Lischer, S. K. (2003). Collateral damage: Humanitarian assistance as a cause of
conflict. International Security, 28(1), 79–109.Find this resource:
Lischer, S. K. (2006). Dangerous sanctuaries: Refugee camps, civil war, and the dilemmas of
humanitarian aid. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Find this resource:
Malet, D. (2013). Foreign fighters: Transnational identity in civil conflicts. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.Find this resource:
McNab, R. M., & Mason, E. (2007). Reconstruction, the long tail and decentralisation: An
application to Iraq and Afghanistan. Small Wars & Insurgencies, 18(3), 363–379.Find this
resource:
Orjuela, C. (2008). Distant warriors, distant peace workers? Multiple diaspora roles in Sri
Lanka’s violent conflict. Global Networks, 8(4), 436–452.Find this resource:
Peksen, D. (2012). Does foreign military intervention help human rights? Political Research
Quarterly, 65(3), 558–571.Find this resource:
Popovic, M. (2015a). The perils of weak organization: Explaining loyalty and defection of
militant organizations toward Pakistan. Studies in Conflict & Terrorism, 38(11), 919–937.Find
this resource:
Popovic, M. (2015b). Fragile proxies: Explaining rebel defection against their state
sponsors. Terrorism and Political Violence, 1–21.Find this resource:
Regan, P. M., & Aydin, A. (2006). Diplomacy and other forms of intervention in civil
wars. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(5), 736–756.Find this resource:
Regan, P. M. (2000). Civil wars and foreign powers. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan
Press.Find this resource:
Rosenau, J. N. (1968). The concept of intervention. Journal of International Affairs, 22(2),
165–176.Find this resource:
Ross, M. L. (2004). How do natural resources influence civil war? Evidence from thirteen
cases. International Organization, 58(01), 35–67.Find this resource:
Saideman, S. M. (2001). The ties that divide. New York: Columbia University Press.Find this
resource:
Saideman, S. M., & Jenne, E. K. (2009). The international relations of ethnic conflict. In Manus
I. Midlarsky (Ed.), Handbook of war studies III: The intrastate dimension (pp. 260–279). Ann
Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Find this resource:
12
Salehyan, I. (2007). Transnational rebels: Neighboring states as sanctuary for rebel
groups. World Politics, 59(02), 217–242.Find this resource:
Salehyan, I., Gleditsch, K. S., & Cunningham, D. E. (2011). Explaining external support for
insurgent groups. International Organization, 65(4), 709–744.Find this resource:
Salehyan, I., Siroky, D., & Wood, R. M. (2014). External rebel sponsorship and civilian abuse: A
principal-agent analysis of wartime atrocities. International Organization, 68(03), 633–
661.Find this resource:
Salehyan, I. (2009). Rebels without borders: Transnational insurgencies in world politics.
Cornell University Press.Find this resource:
Salehyan, I. (2010). The delegation of war to rebel organizations. Journal of Conflict
Resolution, 54(3), 493–515.Find this resource:
Salehyan, I., & Gleditsch, K. S. (2006). Refugees and the spread of civil war. International
Organization, 60(2), 335–366.Find this resource:
Schmitz, P. H. (2013). Rebels without a cause? Transnational diffusion and the Lord’s
Resistance Army, 1986–2011. In J. Checkel (Ed.), Transnational dynamics of civil war(pp.
120–149). Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:
Schutte, S., & Weidmann, N. B. (2011). Diffusion patterns of violence in civil wars. Political
Geography, 30(3), 143–152.Find this resource:
Small, M., & Singer, J. D. (1982). Resort to arms: International and civil wars, 1816–1980.
Beverly Hills: SAGE.Find this resource:
Smith, H. A., & Stares, P. (2007). Diasporas in conflict: Peace-makers or peace-
wreckers? Tokyo: United Nations University Press.Find this resource:
Stedman, S. J. (1997). Spoiler problems in peace processes. International Security, 22(2), 5–
53.Find this resource:
Taydas, Z., Enia, J., & James, P. (2011). Why do civil wars occur? Another look at the theoretical
dichotomy of opportunity versus grievance. Review of International Studies, 37(05), 2627–
2650.Find this resource:
Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.Find this resource:
Walter, B. F. (1997). The critical barrier to civil war settlement. International
Organization, 51(03), 335–364.Find this resource:
Wayland, S. (2004). Ethnonationalist networks and transnational opportunities: The Sri Lankan
Tamil diaspora. Review of International Studies, 30(03), 405–426.Find this resource:
Weiner, M. (1996). Bad neighbors, bad neighborhoods: An inquiry into the causes of refugee
flows. International Security, 21(1), 5–42.Find this resource:
Weingast, B. R. (1994). Reflections on distributive politics and universalism. Political Research
Quarterly, 47(2), 319–327.Find this resource:
13
Weinstein, J. M. (2006). Inside rebellion: The politics of insurgent violence. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:
Vachudova, M. A. (2005). Europe undivided: Democracy, leverage, and integration after
communism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:
Van Houten, P. (1998). The role of a minority’s reference state in ethnic relations. European
Journal of Sociology, 39(01), 110–146.Find this resource:
Zartman, I. W. (1995). Elusive peace: Negotiating an end to civil wars. Washington, DC:
Brookings Institution.Find this resource:
Notes:
(1.) One of the earliest definitions of civil war was proposed by Small and Singer (1982) as “any
armed conflict that involves (a) military action internal to the metropole, (b) the active
participation of the national government, and (c) effective resistance by both sides.”
(2.) Civil wars may feature clashes between two or more nonstate actors, and the Syrian conflict
is the most recent example of this dynamic.
(3.) Originally, scholars of internationalized civil wars focused on interventions by foreign
governments (Rosenau, 1968, p. 167; Regan, 2000). Under the original Singer & Small
classification, an internationalized civil war was one in which a “system member” intervenes
into a substate conflict involving organized violence. In more recent decades, researchers have
broadened their scope to other types of interveners and to unintentional and even
epiphenomenal conflict processes, such as diffusion of insurgency strategies (Beissinger, 2002;
Bob, 2005) or direct conflict spillover from wars in neighboring countries (Salehyan &
Gleditsch, 2006; Gleditsch, 2007; Forsberg, 2014). Still other scholars have focused on the
mode of intervention—ranging from diplomatic and economic engagement (Regan &
Aydin, 2006; McNab & Mason, 2007); to lethal support in the form of weapons, funding or
sanctuary (Salehyan, 2009; Salehyan, 2010; Salehyan, Gleditsch, & Cunningham, 2011); to the
outright deployment of troops (Regan, 2000; Balch-Lindsay & Enterline, 2000; Balch-Lindsay,
Enterline, & Joyce, 2008). Meanwhile, civil war databases developed by PRIO and UCDP have
begun to include information on nontraditional participants in civil wars—such as nonstate or
private actors (Cunningham, Gleditsch, & Salehyan, 2009), foreign fighters
(Hegghammer, 2013; Malet, 2013), diasporas (Angoustures & Pascal, 1996; Wayland, 2004;
Smith & Stares, 2007; Orjuela, 2008; Adamson, 2013; Bakke, 2013; Schmitz, 2013), IOs
(Howard, 2008), corporations, or cross-border kin groups (Jenne, 2004; Jenne, 2007;
Saideman & Jenne, 2009)—as well as “systemic” influences, such as the diffusion of ideas,
transnational social networks, diasporas, personnel, or other outside conflict processes
(Salehyan, 2009; Buhaug & Gleditsch, 2008).
(4.) Bilateral rivalry between the embattled government and a neighboring state—what Goertz
and Diehl (1995) have called “enduring rivalries”—can also frustrate mediation attempts, as one
or both sides undermine technical agreements to keep a conflict alive to appeal to their own
constituencies. For example, a rival state on the border of the conflict-ridden state can offer aid
to an ethnic rebellion, undermining efforts by third parties to resolve the conflict in question.
Revisionist states present a significant threat to mediation success in the immediate
neighborhood—particularly so-called kin states with ties to a minority in the target state.
Examples include Russian involvement in the insurgent breakaway regions in eastern Ukraine,
14
which foiled attempts by the OSCE to halt the escalation of hostilities in Ukraine in 2014.
Similar bilateral rivalries keep the conflict in Nagorno-Karabakh alive despite more than twenty
years of peace talks mediated by the OSCE Minsk Group.
(5.) Scholars have found that an ongoing source of finances to the rebels will tend to prolong
conflicts. See Fearon and Laitin (2003), Collier and Hoeffler (2004), and Ross (2004).
(6.) Powerful outside actors can also serve as critical guarantors of negotiated peace settlements,
providing reassurance to the weaker side that the stronger side will not renege on its promises
once the weaker side has disarmed reintegration (Walter, 1997).
(7.) This dilemma is ably outlined by Licklider (1995).
Erin K. Jenne
Department of International Relations, Central European University
Milos Popovic
Minvera Project, Columbia University