ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

Which European Union actors are most powerful in the governance of the euro crisis? The euro crisis has reignited the classic debate between intergovernmentalists, who tend to stress the coercive power of dominant member states in the European Council, and supranationalists, who maintain that through the use of institutional power, the Commission and the European Central Bank turned out the 'winners' of the crisis. This paper argues that euro crisis governance is best understood not just in terms of one form of power but instead as evolving through different constellations of coercive, institutional and ideational power that favored different EU actors over the course of the crisis, from the initial fast-burning phase (2010-2012), where the coercive and ideational power of Northern European member states in the European Council was strongest, to the slow-burning phase (2012-2016), when greater influence was afforded supranational actors through the use of ideational and institutional power.
Power and changing modes of governance in the euro crisis*
By Martin B. Carstensen and Vivien A. Schmidt
Abstract: Which European Union actors are most powerful in the governance of the euro crisis? The euro
crisis has reignited the classic debate between intergovernmentalists, who tend to stress the coercive
power of dominant member states in the European Council, and supranationalists, who maintain that
through the use of institutional power, the Commission and the European Central Bank turned out the
‘winners’ of the crisis. This paper argues that euro crisis governance is best understood not just in terms
of one form of power but instead as evolving through different constellations of coercive, institutional
and ideational power that favored different EU actors over the course of the crisis, from the initial fast-
burning phase (2010-2012), where the coercive and ideational power of Northern European member
states in the European Council was strongest, to the slow-burning phase (2012-2016), when greater
influence was afforded supranational actors through the use of ideational and institutional power.
Key words: power – euro crisis - governance
Forthcoming in Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and
Institutions.
Introduction
Power has always been a key concept for students of the European Union (EU).
Throughout the history of the EU, arguments about which forces drive the EU’s
integration and policy making processes have most often been couched in terms of who
gets, what, when and how, with disagreement revolving around the question of which
institutional actors are in the driver’s seat (Thomson 2015). This debate has been recast
in the context of the euro crisis. On one side are the intergovernmentalists, who insist
that member-state leaders in the European Council have been in charge of crisis
management, effectively superseding the agenda setting role of the Commission. These
include ‘traditional’ intergovernmentalists who emphasize member-states’ pursuit of
national and domestic interests through rationalist calculation (Hoffmann 1966;
* This research was funded by the European Commission Horizon 2020 project “European
Legitimacy in Governing through Hard Times” (#649456-ENLIGHTEN).
1
Moravcsik 1993; Schimmelfennig 2015) and the ‘new’ intergovernmentalists who
instead highlight member-states’ search for consensus through discursive deliberation
(Puetter 2012; Bickerton et al. 2015). On the other side are the supranationalists, who
argue that bureaucratic or regulatory actors like the Commission and the European
Central Bank (ECB) have been able to increase their control over economic governance
despite the European Council’s efforts to dominate the crisis management process.
These encompass the ‘traditional’ supranationalists who emphasize technical actors’
use of institutional rules and dynamics (Sandholtz and Zysman 1989; Niemann and
Ioannou 2015) and the ‘new’ supranationalists who focus on such agents’ ideas and
institutional entrepreneurship (Bauer and Becker 2014; Dehousse 2015; Epstein and
Rhodes 2016).
In disagreeing over who has power and how they have gained or lost it, EU
scholars generally leave undefined what they mean by power. Taking a conceptual
vantage point, the paper suggests that the key to assessing the different claims of
scholars can be found in their implicit understandings of power. Moreover, the paper
advances the argument that to account for the changing modes of governance in the
euro crisis we need to employ a multidimensional conception of power—as coercive,
institutional, and ideational. Although these three dimensions of power are generally
relevant for analyzing any political system (Barnett and Duval 2005, Lukes 1974), we
would argue that the highly compound governance structure of the European Union
(Schmidt 2006) renders a multidimensional understanding of power that retains an
analytical openness and does not a priori privilege certain actors or institutions
particularly important.
Drawing on approaches to power from the general political science literature as
well as from EU studies, section two of this paper identifies the three forms of power
2
relevant for analyzing the euro crisis. Building on existing research on the management
of the euro crisis, section three demonstrates the usefulness of combining these
approaches to power in the analysis of the changing modes of governance in the crisis.
The analysis shows, first, that more than one form of power is relevant for
understanding how crisis management developed during the crisis, and, second, that
relations of power changed through the crisis. Succinctly put, in the fast-burning phase
(2010-2012) of the crisis, intergovernmental actors, notably Germany, took center stage
in the European Council and during EU summits, employing coercive and ideational
power to frame the crisis as a problem of fiscal profligacy with austerity and structural
reform as the only solution. But as the crisis moved to a more slow-burning period
(2012-2015), supranational actors (notably the Commission and the ECB) exercised
greater control and discretion. Increasing economic pressures to save the euro that
followed from the adverse consequences of crisis management in the first part of the
crisis opened up space for supranational actors to employ ideational and institutional
power to leverage their expertise and implementation capacity in ways that challenged
the coalition of Northern European member states, which themselves were no longer
able to dominate the European Council.
This does not mean that coercive power was no longer important in accounting
for the dynamics of the crisis but rather that the relative importance of the three forms
of power became more balanced through the crisis, in particular as institutional power
and ideational power came to the fore. In other words, although coercive power came to
share the stage with institutional and ideational power, it clearly never left the stage.
Indeed, as evidenced by recent rounds of brinkmanship and tough bargaining between
creditors, the Troika and the Greek government (see Tsebelis 2015), coercive power
3
remains as central for understanding the changing modes of governance in the euro
crisis as do institutional and ideational power.
Three dimensions of power
In the euro crisis, a series of questions arise when assessing power and changing modes
of governance. Who has had the power to decide what to do in the euro crisis? Which
modes of governance have been predominant? What kind of power was exercised—
coercive, institutional, or ideational? To answer these questions, we consider the
different EU actors and the varying modes of governance in two different periods of the
euro crisis. We thus differentiate between fast and slow burning phases of the crisis (see
Seabrooke and Tsingou 2016), that is, during 2010 to 2012, when the crisis was ‘hot’
and required quick responses from actors in a position to decide, and from 2012 on,
when the crisis continued to burn, but was ‘colder’, allowing more time for reflection
on optimal solutions.
However, to differentiate between different dimensions of power, and how they
mattered for governance during the euro crisis, we require as a starting point a general
notion of power. Here we draw on the later Lukes’ (2005) insightful combination of
theoretical perspectives that focus on direct decision-making power (Dahl 1957),
indirect agenda-setting power (Bachrach and Baratz 1970) and preference shaping
(Lukes 1974). Lukes (2005: 65) defines power as “agents’ abilities to bring about
significant effects, specifically by furthering their own interests and/or affecting the
interest of others, whether positively or negatively”.
Taking this definition of power as our starting point has a number of important
implications. First, we focus on the capacity to promote or inhibit the interests of
4
actors. In this perspective, power is not equal simply to causality, where power means
having some kind of effect on the behaviour (broadly conceived) of others. Our
definition of power instead focuses on those instances where the actions of A impact on
the ability of B to get what he, she or it wants, whether positively or negatively.
Second, power is conceived in agency terms. This means that when speaking of power
we are referring to the capacities of (individual or collective) agents to affect the
interests of other actors and not to the ways in which economic, political or ideational
structures per se may affect the interests of actors. While such structures may serve as
resources in or objects of agents’ power relations, they are not at the centre of our
definition of power, which involves agents with relative autonomy who could have
acted differently had power not been exercised. In short, power implies that choices
were made that impacted on the interests of agents.
Coercive power
One very common understanding of political power concerns relations of interaction of
direct control by one actor over another where these relations allow one actor to shape
directly the circumstances or action of another (Barnett and Duvall 2005: 43, 49) – this
is what we here term coercive power. This understanding of power is found for
example in the work of the pluralist Dahl (1957), who defined power as instances
where “A has power over B to the extent that he (sic) can get B to do something that B
would not otherwise do” (p. 202-203). The approaches to power analysis within the
rubric of coercive power generally share certain characteristics, notably to consider
power in zero-sum terms, i.e. that A’s wielding of power entails an equivalent loss of
power for B, because the interest of A runs counter to the interest of B; to consider
power as a direct causal relation between intentional actors, which in turn excludes
5
power as ‘action at a distance’, i.e. without some ‘connection’ between A and B (Dahl
1957); and to think of the use of power as an action that includes – or threatens to
include if orders are not followed – negative sanctions.
In the context of EU scholarship, coercive power is most often related to
arguments about who controls the integration process. Thus, the traditional
intergovernmentalistswhether realists who assume that member states’ positions
derive from national interests (Hoffmann 1966) or liberals who insist that they instead
originate in domestic socio-economic interestargue that member states delegate
power to supranational institutions only to the extent that national governments
converge on such an outcome (Moravcsik 1993), or it helps them to credibly commit to
new institutions (Pollack 2003). In other words, the institutional setup is largely a
reflection of the power resources of the member states. Accounts tend to be mainly
rationalist, focused on the interest-based hard bargaining taking place between member
states (Milward 1992), with bargaining success dependent on the material resources
that actors are willing and able to bring to the table (Keohane and Nye 1989) and the
relative voting weights of member states under various qualified majority voting
formulas (Thomson et al. 2006). Such arguments place member states as the locus of
power in the EU and bargaining among political elites in the European Council as the
primary process through which power is practiced. In this view, factors exogenous to
the bargaining situation – notably the resources of relevant actors interact with
endogenous factors such as the potential coalitions available, with bargaining between
actors being shaped by each player’s expectation of what their opponent will accept
(Costello and Thomson 2013).
The exercise of coercive power is not necessarily limited to EU institutional
actors. Although EU scholars tend to underemphasize the role of market actors for EU
6
crisis responses treating them largely as an exogenous factor – they are among the
potentially most powerful actors outside national and supranational political systems.
To be sure, and as argued below, the actions of bond investors were particularly
important in the euro crisis (see also Brunnermeier et al. 2016). However, conceiving of
the actions of market actors in terms of coercive power is not without its conceptual
problems. As laid out above, we think of power in agency terms, as the furthering of
actors’ interests at the expense of the interests of other actors. It is obvious that markets
often significantly impact on actors’ interests, but it is not always clear that such effects
may be traced back to particular actors. In some cases, investors carry so much clout in
the market that they are able to exercise direct power over governments and
organizations, while in other cases effects occur as a result of more general market
developments that may not be connected to specific market actors. Thus, whether we
may speak of coercive power with regards to the effects market actors have had in the
euro crisis turns crucially on whether such effects have been directly sought by actors
or rather are the unforeseen consequences of general market trends.
Institutional power
A conception of power as coercive is not the only way to consider power. As noted by
Costello and Thomson (2013), conceiving of power in terms of decision-making
through direct interaction between actors within an institutional setting is not useful in
all situations relating to the power of EU institutional actors, since power also matters
in the agenda-setting and implementation stages of EU policy-making. We therefore
suggest institutional power as another conception of power that plays a central role in
studies of the EU. Institutional power may be defined as actors’ control of others
through the formal and informal institutions that mediate between A and B (Barnett and
7
Duvall 2005: 51). In this view, institutions are neither neutral coordinating mechanisms
nor simply derivatives of coercive power, but in fact reflect, and also reproduce and
magnify, particular patterns of power distribution (Thelen 1999: 394).
In this institutional perspective, the scope of the parts of the policy-making
process taken into consideration is significantly widened to also include the agenda-
setting and implementation stages (Bachrach and Baratz 1970). Including these stages
of the policy making process opens the way for an appreciation of the potential impact
of gaps between the control that member states are able to exercise over institutions and
the discretion of institutional actors (Pierson 1996). Such institutional considerations
generally serve to pinpoint the sources of power in supranationalism, whether the
traditionalsupranationalism, where supranational technical actors’ institutional
position is at the basis of their agenda-setting empowerment (e.g., Sandholtz and
Zysman 1989), or the ‘new’ constructivist supranationalism, where technical actors set
the agenda for intergovernmental political elites through their ideas for policy initiation
or about subsequent enforcement (Dehousse 2015). Alternatively, however, arguments
about institutional power could equally be seen to reinforce the position of the ‘new’
intergovernmentalists who contend that the political elites in the European Council
have since the Maastricht Treaty recovered their power from supranational institutions
by regaining control of the agenda and by creating de novo regulatory bodies rather
than adding to the duties of the traditional supranational actors (the Commission in
particular) (Bickerton et al. 2015).
One drawback to the institutional analysis of power in EU studies is that it is
often concerned mainly with the formal institutional attributes of power, such as
established position, rules formalized by treaties, or informal rules that become
institutionalized regularities, for example, who gets to table a proposal. In this view,
8
institutional power depends on how formal and informal institutional constraints affect
political actors’ ability to set the agenda and realize their own policy preferences in the
face of competing preferences (Thomson 2015). As already indicated, we suggest a
more expansive understanding of institutional power to also include the more concrete
interpretation and implementation of rules. Here we follow the insights of Streeck and
Thelen (2005) that one central driver of gradual institutional change is the continual re-
interpretation of what an institution can mean, as new rules may be layered on the old
while old rules may be reinterpreted or converted, or allowed to drift. Thus, for
example, traditional supranationalists sometimes point to the increasing institutional
power of supranational actors through the ‘redirection’ of existing instruments, as in the
case of the ECB’s new supervisory responsibilities for banking union, the invention of
new rules ‘copied’ from older institutions, as in the case of the European Financial
Stability Facility (EFSF), and the ‘replacement’ of institutions, as with the substitution
of the EFSF by the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) (Verdun 2015, pp. 226-228)
Ideational power
We define ideational power as the capacity of actors to influence other actors'
normative and cognitive beliefs through the use of ideational elements (Carstensen and
Schmidt 2016). This may occur directly through persuasion or imposition or indirectly
by influencing the ideational context that defines the range of possibilities of others.
This perspective highlights the importance of dominant ideas, in particular with regard
to framing the crisis response of both member states and supranational actors, as well as
of discourse, especially through the continual need to legitimize policy, which might be
problematic institutionally as well as politically if the need for legitimacy is not heeded
(Blyth 2013; Schmidt 2015). Moreover, this approach is equally open to the possibility
9
that other EU actors, long considered powerless, whether in material or institutional
terms, can by dint of their ideas and discourse gain greater power.
Following Carstensen and Schmidt (2016), we differentiate between three forms
that ideational power may take—power through ideas, power over ideas, and power in
ideas. First, ideational power occurs when actors have the capacity to persuade other
actors of the cognitive validity and/or normative value of their worldview through the
use of ideational elements (power through ideas). They tend to do this via discourses
intended to explain and/or legitimate their proposals and actions, whether in
coordination with other policy actors (coordinative discourse), communication with the
public (communicative discourse) (Schmidt 2008), or speaking to the markets to
convince market actors of the efficiency of proposed solutions (Schmidt 2014).
Examples include the ECB acting as a policy entrepreneur when persuading the
Council, and in particular Chancellor Merkel, to agree to Banking Union (De Rynck
2016; Dehousse 2015) and the Commission in convincing the Council first to legislate
legally constraining norms for the European Semester from 2009 to 2013 and thereafter
to accept increasingly flexible interpretation of the rules in the European Semester
(Dehousse 2015; Bauer and Becker 2014; Schmidt 2016).
Second, ideational power is manifested as a capacity of actors to control and
dominate the meaning of ideas, either directly by imposing their ideas or indirectly
through shaming opponents into conformity or resisting alternative interpretations
(power over ideas). This version of ideational power connects with more coercive
forms of power, since here the beliefs of others are directly disregarded. The most
obvious example of ideational domination has been from the ‘Brussels-Frankfurt
consensus’ (the ECB, the Commission, and Germany, including the Bundesbank)
(Howarth and Rommerschild 2013). This was most notable in these actorscapacity to
10
frame the crisis for all other EU actors and citizens, like it or not, as one of public debt
rather than private, diagnose the crisis as behavioural, as resulting from the failure to
follow the rules rather than from the structure of the euro, and therefore to prescribe
remedies of austerity and structural reform that failed to resolve the crisis (Blyth 2013,
Matthijs and McNamara 2015). Alternatively, power over ideas can also come from
less powerful actors, by shaming their more powerful opponents into agreement. One
example of this comes from the ‘new’ parliamentarists’ account of how the main parties
in the EP successfully pushed the idea of the Spitzenkandidat, in which the leader of the
winning majority in the elections would have to be named president of the
Commission, despite major resistance from powerful European Council members
(notably Germany and the UK).
Third, and finally, ideational power shows itself when certain ideas enjoy
authority in structuring thought or institutionalizing certain ideas at the expense of other
ideas (power in ideas). Here ideational power is most closely related to institutional
forms of power, since it concerns the ways that historically specific structures of
meaning or the institutional setup of a polity or a policy area enhances or diminishes the
ability of actors to promote their ideas. This certainly speaks to the ways in which
German ordoliberal ideas of the ‘stability culture’ were institutionally embedded in the
ECB’s Charter, in the Maastricht criteria, and in the Stability and Growth Pact, as well
as how EU intergovernmental and supranational actors all found it easiest to agree to
reinforce the rules and numbers in the eurozone in the heat of the crisis.
11
Table 1: Three dimensions of power in European Union modes of governance
Definition
Relevant resources
Coercive
power
Relations of interaction of direct
control by one actor over
another where these relations
allow one actor to shape directly
the circumstances or action of
another
- Exogenous factors: Material
resources (notably economic
strength), voting rights
- Endogenous factors:
asymmetrical interdependence,
credible threats to veto or
credible exit, side-payments
and issue-linkage, alternative
coalitions
Institutional
power
Actors’ control of others through
the formal and informal
institutions that mediate between
A and B
Formal and informal agenda setting
power
Discretion in interpretation,
implementation, oversight and
enforcement of policy.
Technical capacity and expertise
Ideational
power
The capacity of actors to
influence other actors' normative
and cognitive beliefs through the
use of ideational elements
- Through ideas via
persuasion
- Over ideas via
domination
- In ideas via structuring
thought or
institutionalization
Leadership capacity, rhetorical skill
Professional authority, expertise
Democratic legitimacy
Ability to convince through
cognitive/normative argument
Ability to compel or disregard
Ability to embed ideas in rules and
institutions
Power in the fast burning euro crisis
Since most narratives of the crisis start with member state action in the European
Council in the fast burning phase of the crisis, we too begin here. Such narratives tend
to support intergovernmentalist arguments as they depict the member state leaders as
12
the most powerful players in the crisis, meeting ever more frequently in the European
Council and in Summits to fight the increasingly hot market winds fanning the flames
of the euro crisis, to disagree, delay, bargain, and ultimately act at the last minute, time
and again (e.g., Bastasin 2015). In all of this, the Commission appears relegated to
acting as a secretariat. The member states in the European Council saw themselves as
the only democratically legitimate actors in the crisis, and the ones called upon to act
together as they represented their citizens and pledged their nation’s financial support
to shore up member-states in trouble (Schmidt 2015).
Arguments supporting the traditional rationalist intergovernmentalist
interpretation of coercive power generally present euro crisis decisions as ones in which
government preferences are shaped by national structural financial and economic
positions—not party politics (e.g., Schimmelfennig 2014: 327-328). It is striking how
much of the focus has been on how the economic strength of certain member states has
given them the coercive power to impose the costs of adjustment on the economically
weaker member states suffering the most from the crisis, to the great detriment of the
latter. Most commentators see a divide between a coalition of highly solvent ‘creditor’
countries, led by Germany (and including Finland, Austria, and the Netherlands) which
benefit from moderate sovereign debt, market confidence, and low interest rates on
sovereign debt, versus a coalition of highly indebted or deficit-ridden countries, led by
France (and including Southern European countries) suffering from high interest rates
on sovereign debt and low market confidence (Schimmelfennig 2015). In these power
relations, the Northern Europeans had the upper hand over the Southern Europeans, and
Germany in particular over France. As the traditional Franco-German ‘couple’ that
used to serve as leader of the EU reduced itself to German leadership because of
13
France’s loss of economic credibility, France took a progressively more active role in
leading the coalition of Southern European countries (Vail 2015).
Central to these arguments stands the coercive power of Germany, based in
large part on the economic strength of the German economy and its status as primary
creditor in the setting up of loan programs and crisis management mechanisms, making
it the sine qua non of decision-making in the European Council (Matthijs 2016b,
Thompson 2013). Such coercive power of Germany in the fast-burning phase of the
euro crisis was further bolstered by the ideational power of the Northern European
coalition to impose their own ideas over all others about what to do – i.e., through the
reinforcement of the ‘stabilityrules of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) as well
as to resist ideas proposing institutional innovation in the European Monetary Union
(EMU), such as Eurobonds or a European Monetary Fund. More specifically, German
leadership has consistently been described as able to impose its own ideas about the
crisis and what to do while resisting any alternative ideas. France, in contrast, has
increasingly lost its power to impose its own ideas (Vail 2015). Consider the difference
between Sarkozy from 2008 to 2010, when he appeared to be the leader of the neo-
Keynesian crisis response, and from 2010 to 2012, when he became the junior partner
in the bilateral directoire of ‘Merkozy’, and slowly but surely gave up his discourse of
solidarity for one focused on stability (Crespy and Schmidt 2014).
Here coercive and ideational power combined enabled the Northern European
member state coalition to effectively keep out alternative policy ideas. Notably, it was
primarily Germany, supported by its coalitional allies, together with the ECB and the
Commission, that framed the crisis as one of public debt rather than the socializing of
private debt resulting from the over-indebtedness of the banks and households (Blyth
2013). It was also Germany that defined the problems as behavioral, from member-
14
states not following the rules, rather than resulting from the structure of the euro, as
most economists argue (De Grauwe 2013). Likewise, it was Germany that rejected in
no uncertain terms any deep solutions, such as Eurobonds, and resisted even banking
union for a very long time. Thus, Merkel made good on her pledge to the German
public that: “I will take care that we make sure together with our partners that the whole
of Europe commits herself to ‘a new Stability Culture’” (cited in Howarth and
Rommerskirchen 2013: 762).
At the same time that this was about Germany’s power over ideas, however, we
could also make the case that this was about power in ideas. After all, it was
Germany’s long-standing ordoliberal philosophy about how to run an economy that
infused the ECB’s view of its mandate (imported from the Bundesbank) (Blyth 2013).
Moreover, these are the ideas that informed the ‘Brussels-Frankfurt consensus’ on
austerity and structural reform (Jones 2015). And they were also the ideas that infused
the European Parliament, and guided its actions in the exercise of what little
institutional power it had at the onset of the eurozone crisis. The heightened sense of
crisis combined with the conviction that there was no alternative to ordo-liberal
austerity was such that most MEPs voted for reinforcing the rules in the Six-Pack and
the Two-Pack—indeed, pushed for more stringent measures than were on the table (i.e.,
by adding reverse qualified majority voting which effectively limited the European
Council’s institutional power to block Commission sanctions).
One may object that the ideational power of Northern European ‘creditor
countries’ to impose their ideas about crisis management and structural reform was of
limited importance, since their discourses did little in way of winning the hearts and
minds of elites, let alone publics, in ‘debtor countries’. In this view, coercive power
was the real driver of bargaining and reform processes. To be sure, the exercise of
15
coercive power was essential for the efforts of German leaders and other Northern
European members of the euro to push through their policies and reform demands, but
one should not discount the importance that the power over elite and public debates had
for the effectiveness with which coercive power was exercised. Thus, power is most
effectively exercised when it is accepted following its justifiability in terms of the
beliefs and norms held by subordinates (Beetham 1991), which makes ideational power
a key part of the effective exercise of coercive power. The capacity of policy actors to
dominate debates about the diagnosis of what the crisis was about and what treatment
would be most effective was crucial not only for persuading the elites and the electorate
in ‘creditor countries’ about the right way forward (and, crucially, who should lead the
way forward), but also for setting the tone of debate in the countries most hurt by the
crisis. Clearly it would be a step too far to claim that elites and publics in ‘debtor
countries’ simply accepted the exercise of coercive power on the part of Northern
European ‘creditor countries’. However, as shown by Kriesi and Grande’s (2014)
analysis of public debates about euro crisis management, German leadership and
supranational actors, along with their economic rather than cultural frames on the crisis,
were very well represented across the EU member states. The majority of elites and the
electorate in Southern European member states might not have agreed with the German
approach, but the efforts of actors in ‘creditor countries’ to exercise ideational power
was effective to the extent that their frames came to dominate public debate about the
euro zone crisis, in turn buttressing the preferred crisis management approach of
Northern European euro zone member states.
It is also worth noting that despite the leadership role of Germany in the
management of the euro crisis, German power was, as granted by even staunch
supporters of intergovernmental scholarship, never absolute. If Germany is the
16
‘hegemon’ rationally calculating its interests and imposing its ideas in the eurozone
crisis, it has been a highly unsuccessful one at that. Germany has been, rather, a
‘reluctant’ hegemon (Bulmer and Paterson 2014) that has not wanted to lead and
suffered the consequences. Numbers of analysts point to the miscalculations of German
leaders, whose reluctance to bail out Greece early in the crisis meant that the crisis
spiraled rapidly almost out of control – making any bailout much more costly – before
Chancellor Merkel finally agreed very reluctantly to the May 2010 actions. These
included the loan bailout for Greece and the EFSF as a bailout funding mechanism for
other countries under threat of attack from the markets as a result of contagion from the
Greek crisis (Bastasin 2015). And all of this went against Germany’s initial calculation
of its interests or ideas about what should be done (Matthijs 2016a).
The ECB clearly also played a central role in the fast-burning phase of the euro
crisis. Central banks in advanced industrialized countries have over the years become
increasingly insulated from politics, and the ECB is the example of this par excellence.
It has autonomy with little democratic control from the classic ‘democratic circuit’ of
parliamentary oversight (Héritier and Lehmkuhl 2011: 138-9), leading to a high degree
of institutional power in implementing its policies. The ECB thus has the autonomy to
reinterpret the rules set out in its Charter so long as it can gain agreement internally
from the member-states sitting on its governing board. Initially, the ECB sought to
manage perceptions with a communicative discourse emphasizing the importance of
maintaining its ‘credibility’ through strict adherence to its rules of inflation-fighting
while resisting any political pressure from member-state leaders. Under the helm of
governor Jean-Claude Trichet, this insistence on sticking to the standard interpretation
of its mandate translated into a modest non-standard bond-buying program, in
particular compared to the FED or the Bank of England. Despite the modesty of these
17
programs, the ECB still leveraged the coercive power that followed from its monetary
resources and strong independence to press member states to engage in austerity and
structural reform in a quid pro quo for its own more vigorous monetary interventions
(Schmidt 2015).
Most initial narratives of the crisis took at face value the intergovernmental
story of political leaders’ agenda-setting role throughout the crisis, mainly because they
paid attention to the players at the front of the stage. The new intergovernmentalists in
particular noted that the Commission was ‘not very visible in early crisis management’
(Puetter 2012: 172) and appeared ‘indecisive and uninspiring’ thereafter (Menz and
Smith 2013: 202). But over time, new narratives have added supranational stories,
focused in particular on EU technical actors not only in the ECB but also in the
Commission as occupying a greater place in formulating, implementing, and evaluating
policy (Bauer and Becker 2014: 214-215). Compared to the ECB, the Commission has
less margin for maneuver, since the rules it devises and administers have been decided
by the European Council (with the EP in certain instances) and pushed by the ECB.
That said, within the context of the rules agreed by the European Council, the
Commission does have room for manoeuver with regard to its (re)interpretation of the
rules (Schmidt 2016).
Despite not being privileged with as great institutional power as the ECB, it is
worth noting that even in the fast-burning part of the crisis, and despite having lost its
agenda-setting powers of the Community Method, the Commission has exerted
ideational power in the earlier parts of the crisis. As new supranationalists have argued
(e.g. Bauer and Becker 2014, Dehousse 2015, Epstein and Rhodes 2016), EU technical
actors had been playing major roles throughout by providing the intergovernmental
political actors with new ideas for the policy initiatives, some of which had been
18
worked out long before. So the supranational story is not only about the exercise of
institutional power (see below) but also about the ideational power through ideas that
supranational actors have exercised as they developed and proposed to the
intergovernmental political leaders the policy initiatives they then later came to enforce.
The European Semester, for example, which has given the Commission
unprecedented oversight authority and enforcement powers with regard to member-
state governments’ budgets, was long in coming. The Commission, acting like a
stubborn ideational policy entrepreneur over a long period of time, developed the idea
in deliberation with think-tanks and expert consultants, commissioned reports on it,
inserted it as blue prints in the European Council’s political debates and in legislative
proposals, and saw it finally come to fruition when the crisis served as the propitious
‘window of opportunity’ (Dehousse 2015). Similarly, Banking Union, prepared by the
ECB in consultation with experts and discussed with political leaders—in particular
Chancellor Merkel in a ‘charm offensive by ECB President Draghi over a period of a
year (Spiegel 2014) – has given the ECB unprecedented supervisory authority and
resolution powers over member-state banks (Dehousse 2015; Schmidt 2016). In other
words, despite the dominance of member states in the initial fast-burning phase of the
crisis, EU supranational actors have been active policy entrepreneurs, generating the
ideas for the policies that subsequently empower them to more proactively shape the
reform agenda of the euro crisis.
Power in the slow-burning euro crisis
As the crisis moved from fast burning to slow burning, the ECB and the Commission,
which had remained at the back of the stage, moved forward, to be seen also as key
actors in the pageant. This was due in part to the new institutional powers of oversight
19
and enforcement gained as a result of intergovernmental action. Thus, the traditional
supranationalism of leadership by the technical actors in the Commission may have
indeed diminished, much as the new intergovernmentalists argue, but in its place,
supranational actors—whether in the Commission, the ECB, or de novo bodies—have
gained even greater institutional powers of enforcement than in the past, and this
through the very rules passed by the more active (new) intergovernmental political
leaders.
To see how the shift toward increased power for supranational actors occurred,
it is helpful to once again start with the intergovernmental level and Germany’s
coercive power in the European Council. The switch from the fast-burning to the slow-
burning phase of the crisis signaled not only an increased role for supranational actors,
but also an increasing recognition – more often borne out in actions than in discourse –
that the ordoliberal ideas that had framed policy-making in the initial phase of the
crisis, along with German foot-dragging that time and again frightened bond markets,
was causing more damage than providing viable solutions to bring the EMU on a firmer
footing. Until the summer of 2012, Germany stuck to a narrow version of its ordoliberal
ideas, despite evidence that the resulting policies were systematically doing damage in
material terms (Matthijs 2016a). However, by 2012 it was clear from the slowing of the
European economy as a whole that the rules were not working as anticipated, and the
consensus-seeking deliberation in the European Council turned to greater contestation,
as Italian and French leaders in particular sought to exert power through ideas to
persuade other member-state leaders, and in particular German leaders, to change
course. Growth entered the European Council’s discourse already in late 2011, pushed
by the Italian Prime Minister Monti and then Hollande, first as presidential candidate
and then French president, to be taken up by Merkel, who agreed to stability and
20
growth by mid 2012. These shifts in discourse came to have significant influence on
the management of the subsequent slow-burning crisis. Similarly, flexibility entered the
European Council’s discourse in 2014, brought by the new Italian Prime Minister
Renzi, and supported by Hollande, and after some contestation pushing Merkel to agree
to flexibility ‘within the stability rules.’ Although this did not necessarily alter the
European Council’s actions, it did make a difference for the Commission in the
European Semester beginning in 2012, which adopted a new focus on growth, and
beginning in 2014 and even more in 2015, with an emphasis on flexible reinterpretation
of the rules (Schmidt 2015).
Another prominent example of reinterpreting the rules – which involved a mix
of institutional power through incremental rules-change and ideational power through
ideasis the shift in the ECB’s approach from the earlier fast-burning phase to the
slow-burning phase. When first appointed head of the ECB in late 2011, Trichet’s
successor Mario Draghi initially continued with the discourse of ‘credibility’ while
denying that the ECB could be a LOLR. But by Spring 2012, as the ECB engaged in
more robust bond-buying programs, he switched his legitimizing discourse to a focus
on ‘stability’. The switch from the credibility discourse also opened space for the ECB
to engage in informal interactions with EU leaders in the European Council. Unlike
Trichet, Draghi sought to coordinate with European Council leaders, including his year
long ‘charm offensive’ (mentioned above) to persuade Chancellor Merkel in particular
that ‘unorthodox’ bond-buying programs and banking union were essential. All the
while, the ECB was working to fashion policy packages acceptable (to Germany) and
workable (for EMU) in the face of Bundesbank scepticism. Draghi succeeded in getting
around Bundesbank opposition largely via Merkel and after bypassing the objections of
the German representatives on the ECB board (Schmidt 2016). But while the ECB
21
switched its discourse from credibility to stability beginning in 2011, it continued to
deny publicly that it would or could act as a lender of last resort for member states
despite slowly and incrementally layering on increasingly ‘unorthodox’ bond-buying
policy that brought it close to one (Buiter and Rahbari 2012). The discourse of denial
kept the markets worried and primed for panic and attack (Blyth 2013). Only in July
2012, when Draghi pledged to do ‘whatever it takes to preserve the euro’, did the
markets stop their massive attacks against Spanish and Italian sovereign debt.
So how do we explain the ECB’s remarkable reversals, in particular given the
continual denials in the discourse? In terms of ideas, we could explain the ECB’s slow,
incremental shifts as a search for solutions in which its pre-crisis ‘paradigm’ did not
cover all contingencies. As a result, the ECB had to engage in a continual process of
‘bricolage’ (Carstensen 2011) through which it introduced increasingly ‘unorthodox’
policies that were unimagined prior to the crisis. These were the ad hoc responses of the
ECB agents using their ideational power to puzzle their way through a crisis rather than
the result of ‘willful actors’ using their coercive power to seize the moment (Braun
2013). To explain this in terms of the ECB’s ideational power through ideas, we would
need to look into the coordinative discourse inside the ECB, as member state
representatives of the ECB governing board were engaged behind closed doors in
processes of persuasion and contestation. We could even argue that initially the more
orthodox central bankers mainly from Northern Europe used their coercive power to
form a blocking coalition around Germany, but this changed as more and more
Northern European countries rallied around the ECB president, whose power through
ideas persuaded them to leave the Bundesbank increasingly on its own to espouse the
most orthodox positions (Schmidt 2016). Ideational entrepreneurship through ideas was
22
thus an added factor in the explanation of the ECB’s changing ideas and discourse over
time.
The switch in presidents of the ECB was of equally great significance. Trichet
was the French state-trained civil servant whose career was focused on institution
building in financial and monetary affairs, and whose economic ideas about what to do
remained ‘orthodox’. Draghi was much more innovative, having had a more diverse
background, and he was a bridge-builder (Basham and Roland 2014). In the progressive
reinterpretation of the rules to ‘save the euro’, not only did Draghi manage to bring
fellow central bankers on board, he was also able to exercise his persuasive ideational
power with European Council leaders, developing sufficient rapport with European
Council leaders and in particular Chancellor Markel – so as to gain their trust and
support as well (Bastasin 2015). However, even as Draghi managed to implement more
comprehensive monetary programs, strong conditionality still played an important role
in the setup of the Outright Monetary Transaction program (OMT), probably to satisfy
opposing political forces within the Governing Council (Lombardi and Moschella
2016). This serves as a reminder that the particular institutional setup of the ECB with
power placed in the Governing Board made up of 19 central bank governors of the euro
area countries, and 6 members appointed by the EU – limits the power of the Governor
and makes the capacity to establish coalitions paramount.
More generally, the ECB itself has been very successful as an ideational policy
entrepreneur overall. In banking union, for example, a dominant group in the ECB in
2012 took advantage of European Council decision-makers’ high uncertainty, teamed
up with the Commission (Epstein and Rhodes 2016), and employed power through
ideas – specifically by combining the notion of a ‘vicious circle’ between banks and the
sovereigns and the long-standing idea of centralizing banking supervision in the ECB
23
to help preferences converge around the idea of giving up national supervisory powers
(De Rynck 2016). Notably, the outcome went against German interests, suggesting that
by reframing the problem, policy entrepreneurs were able to effectively employ
ideational power, in turn trumping the coercive power of the Northern European
coalition (see Schäfer 2016)
Other supranational actors were equally able to use both institutional and
ideational power in influencing the reform process in the slow-burning phase of the
crisis. Notably, the Commission also had significant institutional powers, both to
propose rules and, once passed, to bend them to its purposes. In rationalist terms, we
could explain the Commission’s powers by the fact that with so many principals
holding different views in the intergovernmental Council, the Commission as its
delegated agent could enjoy a high degree of discretion (Dehousse 2015: 11). In
institutional terms, the Commission’s powers of discretion are most apparent in the
increasing flexibility it has exercised in its interpretation of the rules over time, as it
layered new elements onto the old, reinterpreted the rules, or even converted them. But
unlike the ECB, which has the autonomy to reinterpret its own rules, and therefore
communicated that its reinterpretations remain true to its cardinal rules, the
Commission largely sought to hide its increasing flexibility with a continued harsh
discourse focused on pushing austerity and structural reforms (Schmidt 2016). But this
suggests that another explanation of its institutional powers of discretion lie in its
ideational powers through ideas, and a discourse that sought to persuade that it actually
was not exercising that discretion.
In the absence of real remedies to the crisis, such as a fiscal union or eurobonds,
the Commission was stuck with searching for solutions ‘like the drunk who looks for
his lost keys under the lamp post’ because ‘that’s where the light is’ (Mabbett and
24
Schelkle 2014). Recognizing this reality, in particular as performance deteriorated, the
Commission began altering the procedures, by making exceptions and flexible
adjustments for non-program countries, such as derogations of the rules for individual
member-states (e.g., extending the time for France and Italy to bring their deficits under
the target numbers) or recalibrating the calculations (e.g., for Spain on the structural
deficit), even as it denied publicly any leniency so as to circumvent objections from
pro-austerity European Council members (Bauer and Becker 2014; Schmidt 2016). In
so doing, the Commission sought to forestall problems with the markets, which it
assumed wanted such policies; to avoid conflict with the European Council, given the
internal political divisions; and to ensure against any possible legal action.
Only with the inception of a new Commission in November 2014 have the
practices and the discourse seemed to be coming into greater alignment. The Juncker
Commission began exercising more autonomous institutional power along with greater
ideational power through persuasion, as it presented structural reform as a quid quo pro
for greater flexibility through slower deficit reduction (with France and Italy given yet
another two-year extension on deficit reduction on these grounds). It also pledged to do
more to alleviate the social costs of the crisis, as well as to promote growth through an
investment fund. Moreover, the Commission’s new double accountability—not just
with the European Council but as of 2015 also with the EP as a result of the
appointment of the leader of the winning majority in EP elections (the Spitzenkandidat)
as Commission President—may give it the needed independence from the European
Council to be more truly innovative – and powerful both ideationally and
institutionally– during the continuing slow-burning crisis phase.
25
Conclusion
To conclude, we may once again ask which institutional actor has been in the driver’s
seat during the euro crisis. As shown above, it is not possible to point to one
institutional actor that has won more power during the euro crisis. That should not be
taken as a sign that power is somehow not important in the crisis. Different institutional
actors did indeed exercise power – whether in the form of coercive, institutional or
ideational power – or, as often was the case, a combination of all three forms of power.
The analysis thus demonstrates the two basic claims of the article, namely that it is not
possible to point to either one institutional actor or one form of power in accounting for
the crisis, and that the relative power of different institutional actors changed
throughout the fast- or slow-burning phase of the euro crisis. The analysis shows that
during the fast-burning phase of the Eurozone crisis, intergovernmental actors
dominated by Germany exercised greater power, both in terms of rationalist power of
coercion and ideational power over ideas, than supranational actors, who nonetheless
exercised important institutional and ideational powers through ideas. In contrast, the
analysis demonstrates that during the slow-burning phase of the crisis, supranational
actors such as the ECB and the Commission exercised equally important if not greater
power, mainly in terms of their institutional and ideational powers through ideas, than
intergovernmental actors, who at the same time shifted toward more ideational power
through ideas while exercising less coercive power. As for parliamentary actors, their
power was negligible throughout the fast-burning phase of the crisis but became
increasingly important in terms of institutional and ideational power through ideas
during the slow-burning phase, although still weak compared to other institutional
actors.
26
Analyzing the euro crisis in terms of different and at times competing
dimensions of power may push the current debates on who are the main drivers of
integration in the EU towards greater appreciation of how the roles of institutional
actors have shifted and not necessarily either diminished or won out – over the course
of the crisis. We would thus tend to agree with ‘new’ intergovernmentalists that
member states remain very much at the helm of short-term crisis management and long-
term reform. However, instead of therefore focusing solely on the power relations
between member states, and rather than seeing supranational actors as playing only the
role of credible commitment, as second fiddle to powerful member states in the
European Council, a multidimensional power approach favors a broader perspective.
For supranational actors, it shows that they have not only reinterpreted their role and
interest in the integration process, they have also found new avenues for doing so. As a
result, supranationalists are right to point to an important entrepreneurial role for the
Commission that shifts its major point of influence from the agenda-setting role in the
Community Method towards a role of expert implementer of economic governance
reforms and provider of new ideas and interpretations, as policies move from the
grander perspective of the European Council to the concrete implementation on the
ground. In sum, the shifting of EU modes of governance in the eurozone crisis does not
represent the pinnacle of member state power at the expense of supranational or
parliamentary actors but, rather, as the Eurozone moves towards greater integration, an
increasing mutual dependence between EU institutional actors with different resources
that each may bring to the table.
Analyzing the management of the euro crisis from the vantage point of a
multidimensional conceptualization of power follows an additive approach to theory
building (Jupille et al. 2003), in the sense that it builds on and combines theories that
27
vary in terms of explanatory factors but share an overall explanatory focus (in this case,
the euro crisis) (Ioannou et al. 2015). However, rather than identifying the respective
‘home domains’ of the central integration theories in EU studies with the ambition to
bring them together in some larger picture, or incorporating them in the ‘mosaic of
integration theory’ (Wiener and Diez 2009), we instead more specifically focus on how
different approaches to power may help us understand the management of the euro
crisis and the creation of new modes of governance in the EU. That is, to analyze the
complexities of the euro crisis, we dispense with ambitions about building grand theory
or maximizing parsimony characteristic of decades of unending battles in EU studies.
Likewise, we deny integration theories a private kingdom in the form of designated
explanatory ‘home turfs’. Instead we suggest that political science analyses of crisis
management in the euro zone may benefit from a multidimensional power perspective
that does not a priori privilege certain sets of actors or certain relations of power, but
instead entertains an analytical openness towards which forms of power mattered, and
how these forms of power interacted under the relevant temporal and institutional
circumstances.
References
Bachrach and Baratz (1970) Power and Poverty: Theory and Practice, Oxford
University Press.
Barnett, Michael and Raymond Duvall (2005) “Power in International Politics”,
International Organization 59 (4): 39-75.
28
Basham, James and Roland, Aanor (2014). Policy-making of the European Central
Bank during the Crisis: Do Personalities Matter?”, Institute for International Political
Economy Berlin. Working paper no. 38/2014.
Bastasin, Carlo (2015) Saving Europe: Anatomy of a Dream Washington, 2nd edition,
D. C.: Brookings.
Bauer, Michael W. and Stefan Becker (2014) “The unexpected winner of the crisis: The
European Commission’s strengthened role in economic governance”, Journal of
European Integration 36 (3): 213-229.
Beetham, David (1991) The Legitimation of Power, MacMillan.
Bickerton, Christopher J., Dermot Hodson and Uwe Puetter (2015) “The New
Intergovernmentalism: European Integration in the Post-Maastricht Era”, Journal of
Common Market Studies 53 (4): 703-722.
Blyth, Mark (2013) Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea, New York: Oxford
University Press.
Braun, Benjamin (2013) “Preparedness, Crisis Management and Policy Change: The
Euro Area at the Critical Juncture of 2008-2013”, British Journal of Politics and
International Relations 17 (3): 419-441.
29
Brunnermeier, Markus K., Harold James and Jean-Pierre Landau (2016) The Euro and
the Battle of Ideas, Princeton University Press.
Buiter, Willem and Ebrahim Rahbari (2012) “The European Central Bank as Lender of
Last Resort for Sovereigns in the Eurozone”, JCMS: Journal of Common Market
Studies 50 (2): 6-35.
Bulmer, Simon and William E. Patterson (2014) “Germany as the EU’s reluctant
hegemon? Of economic strength and political constraints”, Journal of European Public
Policy 20 (10): 1387-1405.
Carstensen, Martin B. (2011) “Paradigm man vs. the bricoleur: An alternative vision of
agency in ideational change”, European Political Science Review 3 (1):147-167.
Carstensen, Martin B. and Vivien A. Schmidt (2016) “Power through, over and in
ideas: Conceptualizing ideational power in discursive institutionalism”, Journal of
European Public Policy, forthcoming.
Costello, Rory and Robert Thomson (2013) “The distribution of power among EU
institutions: who wins under codecision and why?”, Journal of European Public Policy
20 (7): 1025-1039.
Crespy, Amandine and Vivien A. Schmidt (2014) “The clash of Titans: France,
Germany and the discursive double game of EMU reform”, Journal of European Public
Policy 21 (8): 1085-1101.
30
Dahl, Robert A. (1957) “The Concept of Power”, Behavioral Science 2 (3): 201-215.
De Rynck, Stefaan (2016) “Banking on a union: the politics of changing Eurozone
banking supervision”, Journal of European Public Policy 23 (1): 119-135.
De Grauwe, Paul De (2013) “Design Failures in the Eurozone: Can they be fixed?”,
LSE ‘Europe in Question’ Discussion Paper Series no 57, London: London School of
Economics.
Dehousse, Renaud (2015) “The New Supranationalism”. Paper prepared for
presentation at the Council for European Studies Annual Meetings (Paris, July 8-10).
Epstein, Rachel A. and Martin Rhodes (2016) “The political dynamics behind
Europe’s new banking union”, West European Politics 39 (3): 415-437.
Héritier, Adrienne and Dirk Lehmkuhl (2011) “New Modes of Governance and
Democratic Accountability”, Government and Opposition 46 (1): 126-144.
Hoffmann, Stanley (1966) ‘Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation State and the
Case of Western Europe’, Daedalus, 95, 892-90
Howarth, David and Charlotte Rommerskirchen (2013) “A Panacea for all Times? The
German Stability Culture as Strategic Political Resource”, West European Politics 36
(4): 750-770.
31
Ioannou, Demosthenes, Patrick Leblond and Arne Niemann (2015) “European
integration and the crisis: Practice and theory”, Journal of European Public Policy 22
(2): 155-176.
Jupille, Joseph, James A. Caporaso, Jeffrey T. Checkel (2003) “Integrating Institutions:
Rationalism, Constructivism, and the Study of the European Union”, Comparative
Political Studies 36 (1/2): 7-40.
Keohane , R.O. and J. Nye (1989). Power and Interdependence, 2, Boston, MA: Little,
Brown.
Kriesi, Hanspeter and Edgar Grande (2014) “The Europeanization of the National
Political Debate”, in Olaf Cramme and Sara H. Hobolt (eds.) Democratic Politics in a
European Union under Stress, Oxford University Press.
Lombardi, Domenico and Manuela Moschella (2016) “The government bond buying
programmes of the European Central Bank: an analysis of their policy settings”,
Journal of European Public Policy 23 (6): 851-870.
Lukes, Steven (1974) Power: A Radical View, London: MacMillan
Lukes, Steven (2005) “Power, Freedom and Reason”, pp. 60-107 in Steven Lukes
Power: A Radical View, 2nd ed., London: Macmillan
32
Mabbett, Deborah and Waltraud Schelkle (2014) “Searching under the lamp-post: the
evolution of fiscal surveillance”, LSE ‘Europe in Question’ Discussion Paper Series no.
75, London: London School of Economics.
Matthijs, Matthias (2016a) “The Three Faces of German Leadership”, Survival: Global
Politics and Strategy 58 (2): 135-154.
Matthijs, Matthias (2016b) “Powerful Rules Governing the Euro: The Perverse Logic
of German Ideas”, Journal of European Public Policy, forthcoming.
Matthijs, Matthias and Kathleen R. McNamara (2015) “The Euro Crisis’ Theory Effect:
Northern Saints, Southern Sinners, and the Demise of the Eurobond”, Journal of
European Integration 37 (2): 229-245.
Menz, Georg and Mitchell P. Smith (2013) “Kicking the Can Down the Road to More
Europe? Salvaging the Euro and the Future of European Economic Governance”,
Journal of European Integration 35 (3): 195-206.
Milward, Alan (1992) The European Rescue of the Nation-State, London: Routledge.
Moravcsik, A. (1993) ‘Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal
Intergovernmentalist Approach’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 31 (4), 611-28
33
Niemann, Arne and Demosthenes Ioannou (2015) “European economic integration in
times of crisis: a case of neofunctionalism?”, Journal of European Public Policy 22 (2):
196-218.
Pierson, Paul (1996) “The path to European integration: a Historical institutionalist
analysis”, Comparative Political Studies 29 (2): 123-63.
Pollack, Mark (2003) The Engines of European Integration: Delegation, Agency and
Agenda-Setting in the EU, New York: Oxford University Press.
Puetter, Uwe (2012) “Europe’s deliberative intergovernmentalism: The role of the
Council and European Council in economic governance”, Journal of European Public
Policy 19 (2): 161-178.
Sandholtz, Wayne and John Zysman (1989) “1992: Recasting the European Bargain”,
World Politics 42 (1): 95-128.
Schäfer, David (2016) “A Banking Union of Ideas? The Impact of Ordoliberalism and
the Vicious Circle on the Banking Union”, Journal of Common Market Studies, early
view.
Schimmelfennig, Frank (2014) “European integration in the euro crisis: The limits of
postfunctionalism”, Journal of European Integration 36 (3): 321-337.
34
Schimmelfennig, Frank (2015) “Liberal intergovernmentalism and the euro area crisis”,
Journal of European Public Policy 22 (2): 177-195.
Schmidt, Vivien A. (2006) Democracy in Europe: The EU and National Polities,
Oxford: Oxford University Press
Schmidt, Vivien A. (2008) “Discursive Institutionalism: The Explanatory Power of
Ideas and Discourse,Annual Review of Political Science.
Schmidt, Vivien A. (2014) “Speaking to the Markets or to the People? A Discursive
Institutionalist Analysis of the EU’s Sovereign Debt Crisis”, British Journal of Politics
and International Relations 16 (1): 188-209
Schmidt, Vivien A. (2015) “Forgotten Democratic Legitimacy: ‘Governing by the
Rules’ and ‘Ruling by the Numbers’”, in Matthias Matthijs and Mark Blyth (eds.) The
Future of the Euro, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Schmidt, Vivien A. (2016) Reinterpreting the Rules ‘by Stealth’ in Times of Crisis:
The European Central Bank and the European Commission.” West European Politics
39/5: 1032-1052
Seabrooke, Leonard and Eleni Tsingou (2016) “Bodies of Knowledge in Reproduction:
Epistemic Boundaries in the Political Economy of Fertility”, New Political Economy 21
(1): 69-89.
35
Spiegel, Peter (2014) ‘If the Euro Falls, Europe Falls’, Financial Times, (May 14, 15,
17)
Streeck, Wolfgang and Kathleen Thelen (2005) Beyond Continuity: Institutional
Change in Advanced Political Economies, New York: Oxford University Press.
Thelen, Kathleen (1999) “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics, Annual
Review of Political Science 2: 369-404.
Thomson, Robert (2015) “The distribution of power among the institutions”, in
Richardson J. and S. Mazey (eds.) European Union: Power and policy-making, 4th ed.
Routledge.
Thomson, Robert, Frans N. Stokman, Christopher H. Achen and Thomas König (eds.)
(2006) The European Union Decides, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Tsebelis, George (2015) ‘Lessons from the Greek Crisis’, Journal of European Public
Policy 23: 1, 25-41.
Vail, Mark I. (2015) “Europe’s Middle Child: France’s Statist Liberalism and the
Conflicted Politics of the Euro”, in Matthias Matthijs and Mark Blyth (eds). The Future
of the Euro, New York: Oxford University Press.
36
Verdun, Amy (2015) “A historical institutionalist explanation of the EU’s responses to
the euro area financial crisis”, Journal of European Public Policy 22 (2): 219-237.
Wiener, Antje and Thomas Diez (2009) European Integration Theory, 2. edition,
Oxford University Press.
37
... I argue here to not take these as competing explanations but rather useful conceptual lenses to look at different sides of the issue. Following intergovernmentalism, the rules reflect the interest clashes within the euro area and represent much more the preferences of northern European countries for national adjustment mechanism rather than debt mutualization (Carstensen and Schmidt 2018;Schimmelfennig 2015). Consequently, this power imbalance is reflected in the diffusion of a dominant ideological interpretation of the crisis: the widespread cognitive understanding of its origins in the fiscal profligacy of the south made European leaders interpret the events as a failure of the SGP (Matthijs and McNamara 2015;Schmidt 2020). ...
... After the crisis, Italian underperformance generated multiple lines of tension between the Italian government and European institutions, where Italy consistently demanded more flexibility and emphasized the need to restore growth-boosting mechanisms (Carstensen and Schmidt 2018). Those frictions often managed to capture international attention due to the crucial role that Italy plays in the eurozone dynamics. ...
... This unstable ground could be shaken whenever it was useful for political gain. As in 2014, a discourse of flexibility in the rules again came on the agenda of European leaders, thanks to the efforts of the Italian and French government, and an opportunity window to steer the fiscal stance partially away from austerity seemed to open up (Carstensen and Schmidt 2018). ...
Preprint
Full-text available
The sovereign debt crisis triggered a process of reforms in European economic governance that pushed for technocratic handling of budget decisions following standardized procedures, target measures, and indicators for fiscal monitoring. This shift, aimed at producing more stability and less conflict in budget decision-making, transformed fiscal policy, producing a new type of technocratic fiscal politics. These new technocratic instruments impact on national policymaking, yet little is known about the processes and actors behind their constitution. Scholarship on the policy response to the euro area crisis has highlighted the role of national interests but neglected the role of expertise in negotiating highly technical fiscal policies. A key measure in this new technical apparatus, the output gap, has been at the center of a heated contestation between Italian and European institutions over the 2014– 2019 period. Taking the case of the Italian output gap, this paper traces the unfolding of the dispute around the methodology for estimating potential output and clearly reveals the new centrality of expertise. The paper argues that rather than producing a less conflictual policy environment and a depoliticizing of fiscal decisions, technocratic fiscal politics has reshaped discussions around budgetary politics. This reshaping extends and transforms actor constellations and venues of fiscal decisions, giving a larger role to technocratic experts.
... For the new intergovernmentalists, finally, the mistake of traditional intergovernmentalists and supranationalists alike was to assume that the process is all about the pursuit of hard power, whether coercive power through interest-based bargaining in the Council or institutional power through budget maximizing for the bureaucracy. Instead, new intergovernmentalists maintained that the decision-making process in the Council since the Maastricht Treaty of the early 1990s needed also to be understood in terms of the exercise of ideational and discursive power (Carstensen and Schmidt 2018), with member-states seeking to arrive at consensual agreements through deliberation (Bickerton et al. 2015). In the Council in particular, they highlighted the deliberative processes of negotiation that lead to agreements resulting from persuasion rather than power politics (Puetter 2012). ...
... New supranationalists, then, like the new intergovernmentalists and unlike the traditional supranationalists or intergovernmentalists, were also mainly focused on ideational innovation and discursive interactions as the mechanisms through which technical actors were able to prevail even against the wishes of Council political leaders. As for ideational/discursive power, they saw it exercised through actors' innovative ideas and persuasive discourses, whether the ECB radically reinterpreting its mandate to legitimate its increasingly expansive monetary policy or the Commission reinterpreting the rules of the Stability and Growth Pact (Schmidt 2016(Schmidt , 2020aCarstensen and Schmidt 2018). Such supranational ideational/discursive power could also be seen ...
... Missing in this analysis (with the exception of Fabbrini 2016), however, is the recognition that this was not a deliberation among equals, since Germany held outsize power to pursue its own interests. And Germany's power was not only ideational, following from German insistence on the reinforcement of the ordo-liberal rules of the Stability and Growth Pact; it was also institutional, as German opposition to doing anything delayed any decision on Greece until the markets threatened the very existence of the euro; and it was coercive, resulting from Germany's political veto position in any agreement as a result of its economic weight as the strongest economy in Europe(Carstensen and Schmidt 2018;Schmidt 2018). ...
... Crises are not new to the EU, and compromise and change during crises have been thoroughly analysed in the literature (D'Erman and Verdun 2018;Dinan, Nugent, andPaterson 2017, Carstensen andSchmidt 2018). Current literature has tended to shift from the traditional dichotomy between intergovernmentalism and supranationalism, to more nuanced understandings which better grasp the varied and comprehensive range of governance arrangements and policy solutions that different crises have led EU institutions and member states to adopt. ...
Article
Full-text available
Since 2008, the European Union (EU) has been engulfed in several crises. While distinct, these crises are feeding into each other and are testing the capacity and resilience of EU and member states, bringing forward common policy questions and new forms of cooperation. The permanent character of this state of crisis has made analysts talk about our times as the age of permacrisis. As a result, a trend towards a new mode of ‘coordinative Europeanization’ in EU decision-making has been observed since the Covid-19 crisis. In this paper we first define the new mode of coordinative Europeanization and outline its key features. We argue that the recent crises have altered the EU member states’ relationship in pursuit of fast policy responses. We analyse the reasons behind this changing relationship as well as the possible avenues it may take. We then discuss the challenges caused by coordinative Europeanization and how it relates to pre-existing de-Europeanization tendencies. We close the paper with an analysis of the significance of our findings and we propose new avenues for research.
... As is well established, power comes in multiple shapes (Barnett & Duvall, 2005). Similar to the seminal work of Lukes (2005), we thus apply an agency-oriented and multidimensional understanding of power as coercive, institutional, and ideational (Carstensen & Schmidt, 2018a). We understand coercive power as direct control by one actor over another, where these relations allow one actor to shape directly the circumstances or actions of another (Barnett & Duvall, 2005, 43); typically through the threat of negative sanctions by one actor at the expense of another. ...
Article
Full-text available
Is it possible to develop a robust crisis management response in a system where governance is characterized by coercive power and adversarial bargaining rather than the diversity, inclusion, and openness highlighted by extant scholarship as conducive factors for robustness? Using two instances of crisis in the European Union—the Eurozone crisis (2010‒2015) and COVID-19 pandemic (2020‒2022)—the paper argues that how actors reinterpret existing rules and institutions offers an important source of robustness in crisis management. Based on the employment of a disaggregation of robustness into degrees of robustness, as well as the concepts of ideational and institutional power, we show how actors can counter the coercive power of dominant coalitions and open up for rule adaptation through reinterpretations of existing rules that, at least in the short term, can solidify the functioning of existing institutions faced by turbulence. In the context of the Eurozone crisis, ideational and institutional power thus enabled a moderately robust response without treaty reform. In the case of the pandemic, it was possible to convince (particularly German) policymakers of the need to employ new ideas about common debt. This meant less need to employ ideational and institutional power by other actors, leading to significantly more effective crisis management than in the Eurozone crisis, what the paper terms maximal robustness.
... On the evolving meanings of "structural reform" in EU discourse, see Campos, De Grauwe, and Ji (2018) and Crespy and Vanheuverzwijn (2019). 6 For discussions of the ECB's ideational and coercive instruments, see Ban (2016) and Carstensen and Schmidt (2018). 7 The ECB's lack of direct legal authority means that we cannot establish a direct causal link between the central bank's preferences and the implementation of structural reforms at the member-state level. ...
Article
Full-text available
Monetary and financial integration has been shown to increase the pressure on states to liberalize social and labor market policies. If structures do not come with instruction sheets, how do monetary regime pressures translate into policy? Through a case study of the euro area, we show that central banks play an underappreciated role in this process. Using mixed methods to analyze a large amount of data, including the complete corpus of speeches, we trace the evolution of the European Central Bank's advocacy for structural reforms between 1999 and 2019. To explain the ECB's activism in a policy area beyond its mandate, we theorize the ECB as navigating a dilemma between governability and legitimacy. Handed a monetary regime under which flexible labor markets were seen as a condition for governability, the ECB saw no alternative but to push governments toward structural reforms, despite the reputational risks. The ECB ended its advocacy when increasing political backlash coincided with a structural regime shift from an inflationary to a deflationary environment.
Article
Full-text available
In following the interdisciplinary spirit of this symposium, I emphasise the usefulness of the sociological approach of interpretivism, together with qualitative methods, by examining how EU legal actors perceived the Eurozone crisis and how they enabled policy solutions: financial assistance and policy conditionality. This case constitutes a legal conundrum because of how these solutions encompass and connect different forms of law – EU law, international law and private financial law – and how EU lawyers seek to protect the EU legal order from this hybrid arrangement by drawing the arrangement as closely as they can to the EU legal order. This in turn creates issues of accountability as the imposition of policy conditionality engenders litigation by EU citizens who were directly affected therein, raising the question of whether establishing liability for damages is possible in such a hybrid arrangement. Using interviews with legal actors and observations of court proceedings, I foreground the multiple meanings of EU law and explain how such an approach can expand our understanding of not only what EU law means to its practitioners, but also how these meanings give insight into the potential paths of EU law’s development. To interrogate these multiple meanings, I examine the crisis policy solutions as well as a set of court cases – Ledra Advertising, Mallis and Chrysostomides – that sought to hold the EU accountable for losses suffered because of these policies. Using these methods can partially overcome the opaqueness of judicial proceedings at the EU level, as well as give insight into the development of the legal arrangements being contested in court. A novel methodological element is the descriptive analysis of observations of court proceedings in Chrysostomides , where I demonstrate how the interactions between the lawyers and the judges shed light on how legal actors establish legal validity as a collective project.
Article
Full-text available
This article maps and explains the shift in economic thinking at the European Central Bank (ECB), i.e., its “ideational” evolution over the past two decades. When the ECB was set up in 1999 its institutional design and epistemic outlook were very much inspired by the legacy of the German central bank, the Bundesbank. Thus, the ECB embraced a “price stability” paradigm that prioritized inflation control. However, over time, policy learning in response to economic shocks (first and foremost, a series of consecutive financial and economic crises from 2008 onwards) and the internal organic evolution of the ECB have led to a shift of economic thinking at the Bank, which has also been reflected by its policy actions. The new paradigm can be characterized as a “multidimensional stability” paradigm. By relying on inter alia secondary literature, speeches, semi-structured elite interviews, and data we collected concerning the previous experience at national central banks of senior ECB staff, we identify a novel causal mechanism for ideational change at the Bank: the change in the composition of senior managerial staff from 1999 onward.
Technical Report
Full-text available
The European sovereign debt crisis represents an interesting opportunity to investigate the reaction of the European Central Bank as a crisis fighting institution and the importance of central bank personalities in policy execution. Accordingly, this paper aims at investigating to what extent the policy-making of the ECB during the crisis has been influenced by Trichet's and Draghi's different personalities. Based on Friedman's hypothesis that "accidents of personality" have a great impact on the functioning of a rule-based institution, we find that the clear differences in policy-making between Trichet and Draghi can be explained by specific features of their respective personalities. Institutions matter, but so do personalities.
Article
Full-text available
This article examines the ways in which EU actors have engaged in incremental changes to the eurozone rules ‘by stealth’ ‒ that is, by reinterpreting the rules and recalibrating the numbers without admitting it in their public discourse. Using the methodological framework of discursive institutionalism to focus on agents’ ideas and discursive interactions in institutional context, the article links EU actors’ reinterpretation of rules to their efforts to ensure greater legitimacy in terms of policy performance and governance processes as well as citizen politics. Using the normative theoretical framework of EU democratic systems theory, it analyses EU actors’ considerations of legitimacy not only in terms of their policies’ ‘output’ performance and citizens’ political ‘input’ but also the ‘throughput’ quality of their governance processes. The article illustrates this by elaborating on the different pathways to legitimation of the European Central Bank and the European Commission.
Article
David Beetham's book explores the legitimation of power both as an issue in political and social science theory and in relation to the legitimacy of contemporary political systems including its breakdown in revolution. 'An admirable text which is far reaching in its scope and extraordinary in the clarity with which it covers a wide range of material... One can have nothing but the highest regard for this volume.' - David Held, Times Higher Education Supplement ;'Beetham has produced a study bound to revolutionize sociological thinking and teaching... Seminal and profoundly original... Beetham's book should become the obligitory reading for every teacher and practitioner of social science.' - Zygmunt Bauman, Sociology
Article
This article examines the political dynamics behind Europe’s new banking union in two stages. First it examines the accretion of political power to two European institutions – the European Commission and the European Central Bank (ECB) – during the financial crisis, emphasising the ways in which the European Central Bank (especially under Mario Draghi) altered the relationship between principals and agents in the European institutional architecture. Second, it process-traces the policy conflicts and compromises that led to a Europeanisation and centralisation of bank supervision, recapitalisation, recovery and resolution in a remarkably short two years – a transfer in sovereignty to the supranational level equal to that involved in the creation of Economic and Monetary Union. The article argues, contrary to other analyses that stress the intergovernmental nature of the process and the bargains concluded, that the emergence of banking union reflected something of a neo-functionalist logic whereby supranational actors successfully interpreted the crisis as requiring supranational solutions, and shaped the outcomes in the face of sometimes fierce member state opposition.