ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

During the last decades, the UK economy has increasingly relied on foreign markets to fulfil its material needs, becoming a net importer of both emissions and employment. While the emissions footprint reflects the pressure that consumption exerts on the planet's climate, the labour footprint represents the employment that is created across the globe associated with the demand for products and services. This paper has a twofold objective. First, it focuses on analysing the behaviour over time, drivers, and sectoral and regional composition of both UK's footprints. Second, it explores the relationship between both measures by estimating the elasticity between the growth of emissions and employment embodied in imports. The results show that around half of the emissions associated with UK consumption were generated outside its borders, while only 40% of total employment was domestic. This has important policy implications. Reducing UK's imports can contribute to cut both its footprints, generating less emissions abroad and more employment opportunities within. However, cutting imports is challenging, since this would require a lengthy and difficult process of structural transformation. The UK could contribute to curb emissions outside its borders, while safeguarding development overseas, by offering increased support to emission-intensive trade partners in the form of technology transfer and financial aid.
Content may be subject to copyright.
sustainability
Article
The UK’s Emissions and Employment Footprints:
Exploring the Trade-Offs
Marco Sakai * ID , Anne Owen and John Barrett
Sustainability Research Institute, School of Earth and Environment, University of Leeds, Leeds LS2 9JT, UK;
a.owen@leeds.ac.uk (A.O.); j.r.barrett@leeds.ac.uk (J.B.)
*Correspondence: m.a.h.sakai@leeds.ac.uk; Tel.: +44-113-343-5576
Received: 29 April 2017; Accepted: 7 July 2017; Published: 16 July 2017
Abstract:
During the last decades, the UK economy has increasingly relied on foreign markets to fulfil
its material needs, becoming a net importer of both emissions and employment. While the emissions
footprint reflects the pressure that consumption exerts on the planet’s climate, the labour footprint
represents the employment that is created across the globe associated with the demand for products
and services. This paper has a two-fold objective. First, it focuses on analysing the behaviour over
time, drivers, and sectoral and regional composition of both UK’s footprints. Second, it explores the
relationship between both measures by estimating the elasticity between the growth of emissions
and employment embodied in imports. The results show that around half of the emissions associated
with UK consumption were generated outside its borders, while only 40% of total employment
was domestic. This has important policy implications. Reducing UK’s imports can contribute
to cut both its footprints, generating less emissions abroad and more employment opportunities
within. However, cutting imports is challenging, since this would require a lengthy and difficult
process of structural transformation. The UK could contribute to curb emissions outside its borders,
while safeguarding development overseas, by offering increased support to emission-intensive trade
partners in the form of technology transfer and financial aid.
Keywords:
consumption-based emissions; employment; international trade; emissions footprint;
labour footprint
1. Introduction
Over the past decades, the increasing globalisation of markets has been reflected in a rapid and
significant expansion of international trade. According to data by the World Bank [
1
], the total volume
of traded goods and services has grown almost twice as fast as global gross domestic product (GDP)
since 1990. This phenomenon has been particularly evident in developing nations, whose volume of
trade rose by a factor of five during this period, while that of advanced economies grew by a factor
of three. These trends have been accompanied by a reconfiguration of the international division of
labour and an associated geographical fragmentation of production and consumption [
2
,
3
]. Companies
increasingly found that outsourcing portions of the production process offshore was profitable, thus
becoming a standard practice [
4
]. Materials are, in this sense, extracted from diverse regions around
the planet to manufacture and assemble products in different countries, to be distributed to yet other
economies for consumption. This fragmentation is revealed in the growing share of value that is added
outside the country of completion along most product chains [
5
,
6
]. A new trade reality has thus been
forged, where the rise of global value chains has intensified the interdependence of nations.
The UK is a major player in this new trade reality. It represented the world’s 9th largest
economy in purchasing power parity terms in 2015, according to the World Bank [
1
]. As many
other developed nations, the UK has become a service economy, gradually offshoring its industry,
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242; doi:10.3390/su9071242 www.mdpi.com/journal/sustainability
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 2 of 19
mainly as a cost-saving strategy, and increasingly relying on foreign markets to acquire products
and services that are vital to fulfil its material needs [
2
,
7
]. Its volume of trade represents 10.7% of
the total for the European Union, having expanded by 2.8 times from 1990 to 2015 [
1
]. According
to Greenaway et al. [
8
], the deindustrialisation process has led to the displacement of around two
million jobs in UK manufacturing between 1979 and 1991. Figures from the International Labour
Organization [
9
] show that a further 1.9 million jobs were displaced from 1992 to 2015. As the total
amount of jobs in the country continued to grow over the period, this suggests that these jobs were
absorbed into other occupations and activities, mainly in services [
10
]. Industrial value added, in turn,
remained relatively stable in real terms during the period according to figures from the UK Office for
National Statistics (ONS) [
11
], which indicates the presence of productivity gains from a territorial
perspective. In turn, the share of industrial value added, as a percentage of GDP, declined from 31.6%
in 1990 to 20.2% in 2015, close to the average share in high-income economies of 24.7% in 2014 [
1
]. This
reflects a deep restructuring of the UK industrial sector.
As expected, the complex reorganisation of the UK economy has had economic, political, social
and environmental implications. In environmental terms, the offshoring of UK industries has
allowed it to reduce its territorial emissions, which contributes to achieving its emissions reduction
commitments [
12
]. Nonetheless, the country’s reliance on imports has transformed it into a net
importer not only of emissions, but also of employment. While the UK’s emissions footprint represents
the pressure that UK consumption exerts on the planet’s climate, its labour footprint represents the
employment that is created in different regions of the globe due to its demand for imported products
and services.
This paper focuses on the UK case, for which there is sufficient data to conduct a detailed analysis
over time. The UK’s greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and employment footprints are estimated here
for the period 1997 to 2012 with a two-fold objective. First, both footprints are analysed in terms of
their behaviour, drivers and sectoral and regional composition. Second, the relationship between both
measures is explored by estimating the elasticity between the growth of emissions and employment
embodied in imports.
The attempt to address the UK’s rising reliance on imports and implement reindustrialisation
strategies is a topic that has gained more interest with Brexit. Claims to protect manufacturing
jobs from globalisation and reactivate certain industrial activities have become a common political
discourse. Reshoring the UK industry, nonetheless, is not a straightforward task, most certainly
implying limitations and high associated costs [13]. Relying less on foreign markets could contribute
to shrink the country’s emissions footprint and generate more employment domestically. But this
can also imply adverse consequences for its trade partners [
14
]. The results presented in this paper
thus have important policy implications. Reducing UK imports involves clear trade-offs in terms
of emissions and employment. It is not clear if the UK or other advanced economies could adopt
reindustrialisation strategies successfully in the future. It is also difficult to determine at this point
what the Brexit process could bring. What is certain is that the UK, as well as other advanced and
emerging economies, should increase their efforts to avoid dangerous climate change. In this sense,
the UK could contribute to curbing emissions outside its borders by offering increased support to its
emission-intensive trade partners in the form of technology transfer and financial aid to help them
achieve emissions reductions, while safeguarding jobs in the developing world.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. The next section provides some background
on the nexus between trade, emissions and employment. The methodology and data used in the
analysis are explained in the subsequent section. The results are presented and discussed next,
highlighting some policy implications. Conclusions are offered at the end.
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 3 of 19
2. Trade, Emissions and Employment
The consequences of the trade reality that the world currently faces are manifested in various
domains. Of particular interest are the implications for development and the environment, which have
been amply discussed in the literature [1519].
Starting with the relationship between trade and development, the prevailing view is that more
open economies register higher rates of economic growth, based on the claim that trade incentivises
productivity gains and competitiveness in domestic industries [
20
24
]. There are, nonetheless, some
critical views on the matter, mainly rooted in the ideas of Prebisch [
25
] and Singer [
26
], who suggest
that the terms of trade of developing nations tend to deteriorate over time in comparison to those of
their developed counterparts. Others believe that the existent empirical evidence regarding this issue
is inconclusive due either to methodological problems [
27
] or the use of inadequate assumptions [
28
].
Nonetheless, numerous developing countries have opened their economies and adopted export-led
models of growth as a development strategy in an attempt to reap the benefits of international trade,
such as poverty reduction, job creation and foreign direct investment [2931].
The links between trade and the environment also represent a contested matter. Those who
advocate that trade is good for the environment generally base their arguments on a logic related
to the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) hypothesis. In simple terms, this hypothesis states that
environmental conditions tend to improve as countries advance towards higher echelons of economic
development and income per capita [
32
]. Empirical evidence shows that the EKC only holds true for
some types of local and short-lived pollutants, but is not applicable to global and long-term problems,
such as GHG emissions [
33
,
34
]. A more predominant view, however, considers that the production
of traded goods has accelerated environmental pressure and generated serious impacts, both locally
and globally, in the form of pollution, resource depletion, and biodiversity loss, among others [
35
37
].
According to Wiedmann [
38
], at least a fifth and up to 64% of global environmental impacts can be
linked to international trade, being GHG emissions the indicator that has attracted more attention.
The nexus between trade and emissions is intrinsically linked to the ongoing political debate
on the allocation of responsibility among nations for reducing GHG emissions [
39
]. The United
Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) adopts a production-based accounting
framework, whereby countries are responsible for the emissions generated within their territories
to produce goods and services. Emissions, however, can be alternatively accounted for from a
consumption approach, which means that countries are held responsible for the emissions associated
with the goods and services they consume. The basic difference between both approaches is the
treatment of emissions embodied in exports and imports [
40
]. Territorial or production emissions take
into account the domestic and export components, while consumption emissions exclude exports and
include imports.
Previous studies have consistently shown that developed countries have become net importers
of emissions, while the developing world is generally a net exporter [
41
,
42
]. This indicates that there
has been a transfer of emissions from the latter to the former group of countries, which has grown
by a factor of four from 1990 to 2008 [
43
]. Some authors consider this transfer of emissions as a
form of carbon leakage, which has been driven by an increasing demand for imports in advanced
economies [
44
]. These transfers have important climate policy implications, as reductions made so
far by net-importing countries with internationally agreed mitigation commitments tend to be less
significant from a consumption approach [43,45].
An aspect that has been attracting attention is the determination of the value that is added along
global supply chains [
46
]. Daudin et al. [
47
], for instance, estimated that around 32% of the world’s
industrial value added is associated with foreign consumption. An important part of this value added
is comprised by payments to labour, one of the factors of production. Alsamawi et al. [
48
] calculated
wages and labour embodied in international trade, finding that the largest flows of labour tend to be
unidirectional, originating in developing economies like China, India, Russia, Indonesia, and Mexico,
to fulfil the consumption requirements of developed economies. However, many of the major flows of
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 4 of 19
wages occur between developed countries. The authors indicate that the full-time equivalent work of
more than 200 million labourers is embodied in exports from China and India alone.
Most of the existing studies have usually focused on examining embodied emissions and other
‘virtual’ contents on an individual basis, while little attention has been devoted to understand the more
complex relationship between these footprint indicators. A handful of studies have examined the
triangle formed between trade, its economic benefits and its environmental implications.
Arto et al. [49]
conducted a study in this regard, focusing on emissions and employment. The authors found that
24% of global GHGs and 20% of total employment are embodied in international trade flows. Their
results also show that China exported 30% of traded emissions and hosted 37.5% of jobs generated
by trade around the world. Simas et al. [
50
] measured the labour, energy, and emissions footprints
of the European Union, finding that the region has tended to offshore its production to cheaper and
low-skilled, labour-abundant countries, offsetting any energy efficiency gains achieved domestically.
Sakai and Barrett [
51
], in turn, introduced the concept of ‘labour productivity of carbon’, an efficiency
indicator that specifies the amount of labour (i.e., number of jobs, wages paid, etc.) associated with
every kilogram of CO
2
released during the production of export goods. They show that when it
comes to unskilled labour, the most productive activity in high-income economies is services, while
agricultural activities are the most productive in low-income nations.
Understanding the specificities of the trade-emissions-employment triangle is important, in order
to ensure the consistency of trade, development and environmental policies. This paper seeks to
address this gap in the literature and offer useful insights for both climate and development policies
by undertaking a detailed analysis of the UK’s emissions and labour footprints.
3. Materials and Methods
Multi-regional input-output (MRIO) analysis has been broadly used to estimate the embodied or
‘virtual’ content of trade flows (e.g., emissions, water, value added, etc.) [
52
]. In standard input-output
notation, economic output (X) is given by:
X= (IA)1Y(1)
where I represents an identity matrix, A is the technical coefficients matrix and Y is final demand. The
term (I
A)
1
is known as the Leontief inverse (hereafter identified as L), which indicates the extent
to which output rises in each sector derived from a unit increase in final demand.
In an MRIO framework (see: Miller and Blair [
53
]), the technical coefficients matrix (A) accounts
for the proportion of intermediate inputs, both domestic and foreign, that a sector from country n
requires to produce one unit of output. In this sense, the sectoral requirements of region n are
decomposed into a domestic component, which represents inter-industry relationships within the
region, and another one that represents imports, which shows the inter-industry relationships with
other sectors located in the n-th region.
Matrices X and Y include total output and final demand, respectively, of all sectors located in
all regions. Regarding Y, it incorporates the components of final demand (i.e., private and public
consumption, gross capital formation and change in stocks) and direct exports to final demand.
The input-output framework can be extended to incorporate emissions or other variables, as long
as these are a function of total output. In the case of GHGs, a row vector of emissions disaggregated
by sectors and regions is included in the model. The emissions generated by sector i are divided
by the corresponding output (X
i
), resulting in a diagonalised vector of direct intensity multipliers (
ˆ
g
).
Post-multiplying these intensities by the Lmatrix yields total intensity multipliers. The diagonalised
vector
ˆ
g
provides a set of weights to L, so post-multiplying
ˆ
g
L by Y allows determining the direct and
indirect emissions (G) originated from a given level of final demand.
G=ˆgLY (2)
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 5 of 19
Similarly, a diagonalised vector of employment
ˆ
e
can also be included following the same
procedure to calculate direct and indirect employment requirements (E) to fulfil a certain level of
final demand.
E=ˆeLY (3)
The i-th row of the G and E matrices represents production-based measures; that is, the
emissions or employment that are generated in country n in order to satisfy the domestic and
foreign consumption of its goods and services. On the other hand, the j-th column stands for
consumption-based measures, or well the emissions or employment that are created not only in
country n but also in other countries, so as to satisfy country n’s consumption of domestic and
imported goods and services.
3.1. Structural Decomposition Analysis
Structural decomposition analysis (SDA) has been widely used in the context of input-output
analysis to decompose the growth observed in a certain variable into the changes in its
determinants [
54
]. This technique thus allows quantifying the relevant root causes of change in
a wide range of variables, including economic growth, energy use, labour requirements and many
other [55,56].
In this paper, we use an additive decomposition procedure (also called additive identity splitting,
see: Rose and Casler [
55
]) as described in Miller and Blair [
53
]. We decompose the growth in
both the emissions and labour footprints into changes in intensity (emissions or labour per unit
of output), industrial structure (i.e., inter-industry requirements represented by the A matrix) and final
demand. In this sense, the change in a variable, here denoted as Λ(included in the MRIO model as a
vector extension and which can stand for emissions or employment in this analysis), is given by the
following expression:
Λ=1
2ˆ
λL0Y0+L1Y1+1
2hˆ
λ0LY1+ˆ
λ1LY0i +1
2ˆ
λ0L0+ˆ
λ1L1Y(4)
where superscripts 0 and 1 indicate the initial and final years, respectively, and
indicates changes
in a variable between year 0 and 1. L stands for the Leontief inverse, Y represents the final demand
matrix, and
ˆ
λ
is a diagonalised vector of direct intensity multipliers (i.e., units of
Λ
per unit of output).
The first term in the right-hand side stands for the fraction of the change in
Λ
due to improvements
in emissions or labour intensity. The second term represents the portion caused by technological
improvements as reflected in industrial structure, and the third term indicates the proportion of the
change owed to final demand.
It is important to mention that in some cases several determinants might not be independent
from each other. Dietzenbacher and Los [
57
], in this regard, warn that SDA should be treated with
caution, since the technique assumes that the determinants are independent. In this analysis, it cannot
be expected that a change in intensities (i.e.,
ˆ
λ
) can occur independently of the technology matrix
used to calculate L. Dietzenbacher and Los [
57
] propose a solution, but it is seldom applied. In fact,
only few studies highlight this matter [
58
,
59
]. There is not a straightforward solution to rearrange the
terms so as to avoid dependency problems, and we acknowledge that this issue might affect the SDA
results presented in this paper by not completely isolating the effects derived from changes in intensity
and industrial structure.
3.2. Data
An environmentally-extended MRIO model requires a substantial amount of data, and this
represents a greater challenge when constructing time series of input-output tables. Domestic and
import tables are needed for each region, as well as bilateral trade data and environmental impact
variables. The UK MRIO database, described in greater detail in Owen, et al. [
60
], provides these data
requirements and includes input-output time series. This database is used to produce the UK’s official
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 6 of 19
consumption-based indicators (i.e., footprints) for carbon dioxide and six other main GHGs, published
by the UK Department for Environment, Food & Rural Affairs (DEFRA) [
61
]. Given that these are
official statistics, preferably they must be constructed using available data from UK official sources.
The ONS publishes supply and use tables (SUTs) for the UK economy on an annual basis, starting from
1997 [
62
]. The ONS also publishes domestic analytical tables, which are used to construct import tables
(see [
60
] for a more detailed explanation). The UK SUTs are disaggregated at a level of 106 sectors,
following the classification used in the UK’s National Accounts.
UK data is supplemented with the Eora database [
63
] to form the UK MRIO. Eora provides a
time series of high resolution input-output tables for 187 countries, which contains data on bilateral
trade between nations, including the UK. The Eora database is mapped onto the ONS sectoral
classification. Given that Eora possesses a heterogeneous sector disaggregation, we manipulate the
countries’ input-output tables in order to comply with the 106 sector classification using concordance
matrices. Once the ONS and Eora data are combined, the resulting MRIO table is balanced using the
RAS technique [
53
]. After this task has been undertaken, the data is further aggregated into regions to
simplify the analysis. Since Eora comprises an extensive number of countries, we opted for selecting
an appropriate regional grouping that is illustrative for UK trade. We constructed twelve regions: the
UK, China, India, Japan, Russia, Africa, Asia, Europe, the Middle East, North America, Oceania, and
South America.
All the input-output tables were deflated in order to transform them into constant prices [
64
].
Deflator data for the UK were taken from the ONS [
11
], while for the rest of the regions in the dataset,
deflators were taken from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD) [65].
Regarding the MRIO extensions, a vector of emissions and another vector for employment
were constructed. The emissions vector consists of total annual GHG emissions for all the regions
disaggregated into sectors. GHG data for the UK were taken from the annual statistics published
by the ONS environmental accounts and the Department for Business, Energy & Industrial Strategy
(BEIS). GHG data for the rest of the countries in the database were obtained from Eora. In regards to
the employment vector, we constructed it using data from the ONS in the case of the UK and from
Eora for the rest of the world. ONS employment data is expressed in number of employment jobs,
while Eora data is expressed in full-time equivalent employment. The amount of employee jobs is not
equal to the total amount of available jobs in an economy, since one person can hold more than one
job (see: [
66
]). Full-time equivalent employment, according to the OECD, is the number of full-time
equivalent jobs, defined as total hours worked divided by average annual hours worked in full-time jobs [
67
].
After comparing the ONS figures with the UK data provided by Eora, we found that both datasets
were aligned, thus deciding to use ONS information for the UK. For reasons of simplicity, we will
hereafter refer to employment as being expressed in number of jobs.
Further information about the data and sources used in this analysis is offered in Appendix A.
4. Results
The UK is a net importer of embodied emissions, since it imports more emissions than those it
exports. Similarly, the UK is a net importer of employment embodied in traded goods. Hence, the
amount of employment that it creates in foreign countries via international trade is greater than the
amount of employment that is generated by its local export sectors. This can be clearly appreciated
in Figure 1, in which the consumption curves (i.e., GHG and employment footprints) lie above the
territorial ones (herein referred to as production). The space between both types of curves represents
the net transfer of both emissions and labour embodied in trade flows.
Production emissions declined by about 1.1% per year on average during the period 1997–2012.
Consumption emissions (i.e., emissions footprint), in turn, rose by 1.6% every year on average until
2008. From that point on, they showed an important annual drop of about 3.2% on average with
respect to previous levels, due to a significant plunge of 9.2% in imports during the financial crisis.
The trends for both types of emissions can be appreciated in Figure 1.
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 7 of 19
Sustainability 2017, 9, 1242 6 of 18
classification. Given that Eora possesses a heterogeneous sector disaggregation, we manipulate the
countries’ input-output tables in order to comply with the 106 sector classification using concordance
matrices. Once the ONS and Eora data are combined, the resulting MRIO table is balanced using the
RAS technique [53]. After this task has been undertaken, the data is further aggregated into regions
to simplify the analysis. Since Eora comprises an extensive number of countries, we opted for
selecting an appropriate regional grouping that is illustrative for UK trade. We constructed twelve
regions: the UK, China, India, Japan, Russia, Africa, Asia, Europe, the Middle East, North America,
Oceania, and South America.
All the input-output tables were deflated in order to transform them into constant prices [64].
Deflator data for the UK were taken from the ONS [11], while for the rest of the regions in the dataset,
deflators were taken from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD) [65].
Regarding the MRIO extensions, a vector of emissions and another vector for employment were
constructed. The emissions vector consists of total annual GHG emissions for all the regions
disaggregated into sectors. GHG data for the UK were taken from the annual statistics published by
the ONS environmental accounts and the Department for Business, Energy & Industrial Strategy
(BEIS). GHG data for the rest of the countries in the database were obtained from Eora. In regards to
the employment vector, we constructed it using data from the ONS in the case of the UK and from
Eora for the rest of the world. ONS employment data is expressed in number of employment jobs,
while Eora data is expressed in full-time equivalent employment. The amount of employee jobs is
not equal to the total amount of available jobs in an economy, since one person can hold more than
one job (see: [66]). Full-time equivalent employment, according to the OECD, is “the number of full-
time equivalent jobs, defined as total hours worked divided by average annual hours worked in full-time jobs
[67]. After comparing the ONS figures with the UK data provided by Eora, we found that both
datasets were aligned, thus deciding to use ONS information for the UK. For reasons of simplicity,
we will hereafter refer to employment as being expressed in number of jobs.
Further information about the data and sources used in this analysis is offered in Appendix A.
4. Results
The UK is a net importer of embodied emissions, since it imports more emissions than those it
exports. Similarly, the UK is a net importer of employment embodied in traded goods. Hence, the
amount of employment that it creates in foreign countries via international trade is greater than the
amount of employment that is generated by its local export sectors. This can be clearly appreciated
in Figure 1, in which the consumption curves (i.e., GHG and employment footprints) lie above the
territorial ones (herein referred to as production). The space between both types of curves represents
the net transfer of both emissions and labour embodied in trade flows.
Figure 1. UK’s greenhouse gas (GHGs) and employment historical trends (production and
consumption).
Figure 1.
UK’s greenhouse gas (GHGs) and employment historical trends (production and consumption).
Production emissions are composed of domestic and export emissions. The former represents
the emissions that are associated with goods and services consumed domestically, while the latter
component includes the emissions that are created within the UK to produce exports. Domestic
emissions amounted to around 550 MtCO
2
e in 1997 and descended to about 450 MtCO
2
e in 2012.
Emissions linked to exports waned at a similar rate, from slightly more than 200 MtCO
2
e in 1997
to almost 185 MtCO
2
e in 2012, a yearly average drop of nearly 0.9%. Consumption emissions, in
turn, include the domestic component plus emissions embodied in imports. UK’s consumption was
associated with the generation of approximately 525 MtCO
2
e on average per annum around the globe
during the period of study. A more thorough examination of these emissions is presented below.
In relation to employment, the number of jobs in the UK grew constantly by a rate of 1.3% annually
until 2008, when it started to drop by about 0.8% every year. The UK’s employment footprint increased
before the crisis faster than domestic employment at a rate of 2.2%, but fell strongly afterwards by 4.4%
per year.
Employment linked to goods and services destined for domestic consumption amounted to
around 17 million persons employed in 1997, rising to 18 million in 2012. Employment associated with
exports, in turn, expanded slightly faster, from nearly 8.5 million in 1997 to 9.5 million in 2012. On the
other hand, the UK generated an average of 25 million jobs on a yearly basis across the world during
the period. Employment linked to imports rose quickly until 2007 at an average annual pace of 2.8%,
but then descended drastically after the crisis, as will be explained with more detail below.
The financial crisis caused a significant influence on both the emissions and employment footprints.
In both cases, their 2012 levels were lower than at the beginning of the period. However, both footprints
have started to show signs of becoming more stable.
The GHG and employment footprints can be regionally decomposed with the purpose of
determining the geographical areas where emissions and employment are created to satisfy the
UK’s needs. In relation to GHGs, around half of the emissions were generated within the UK during
the period of study, as can be seen in Figure 2. However, domestic emissions showed a gradual decline,
reflecting an increasing dependency on imports. Domestic emissions represented around 55% of the
total footprint in 1997 and went down to 44% in 2007. However, given the decline in imports registered
during the financial crisis, their share increased again to 51% in 2012.
China’s contribution to the emissions footprint was relatively low in 1997, amounting to about 5%,
but it quickly doubled one decade later as it increased its participation in global markets. The effects of
the financial crisis barely affected China’s share, which just observed a small reduction, representing
around 9.5% in 2012. In relation to other regions, approximately 15% of the UK’s GHG footprint
corresponds to the rest of Europe, and this share remained relatively steady, although with some
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 8 of 19
slight reductions since 2009. A similar stable pattern can be appreciated in the case of the rest of Asia,
whose contribution amounted to about 6% on average during the period. North America’s share,
which includes the US, slowly declined from about 6% in 1997 down to 4% in 2012. The rest of the
world (ROW) contributed with an average of 14%, and more specifically Russia and Africa, which are
not shown in the graphs.
Sustainability 2017, 9, 1242 7 of 18
Production emissions declined by about 1.1% per year on average during the period 1997–2012.
Consumption emissions (i.e., emissions footprint), in turn, rose by 1.6% every year on average until
2008. From that point on, they showed an important annual drop of about 3.2% on average with
respect to previous levels, due to a significant plunge of 9.2% in imports during the financial crisis.
The trends for both types of emissions can be appreciated in Figure 1.
Production emissions are composed of domestic and export emissions. The former represents
the emissions that are associated with goods and services consumed domestically, while the latter
component includes the emissions that are created within the UK to produce exports. Domestic
emissions amounted to around 550 MtCO2e in 1997 and descended to about 450 MtCO2e in 2012.
Emissions linked to exports waned at a similar rate, from slightly more than 200 MtCO2e in 1997 to
almost 185 MtCO2e in 2012, a yearly average drop of nearly 0.9%. Consumption emissions, in turn,
include the domestic component plus emissions embodied in imports. UK’s consumption was
associated with the generation of approximately 525 MtCO2e on average per annum around the globe
during the period of study. A more thorough examination of these emissions is presented below.
In relation to employment, the number of jobs in the UK grew constantly by a rate of 1.3%
annually until 2008, when it started to drop by about 0.8% every year. The UK’s employment
footprint increased before the crisis faster than domestic employment at a rate of 2.2%, but fell
strongly afterwards by 4.4% per year.
Employment linked to goods and services destined for domestic consumption amounted to
around 17 million persons employed in 1997, rising to 18 million in 2012. Employment associated
with exports, in turn, expanded slightly faster, from nearly 8.5 million in 1997 to 9.5 million in 2012.
On the other hand, the UK generated an average of 25 million jobs on a yearly basis across the world
during the period. Employment linked to imports rose quickly until 2007 at an average annual pace
of 2.8%, but then descended drastically after the crisis, as will be explained with more detail below.
The financial crisis caused a significant influence on both the emissions and employment
footprints. In both cases, their 2012 levels were lower than at the beginning of the period. However,
both footprints have started to show signs of becoming more stable.
The GHG and employment footprints can be regionally decomposed with the purpose of
determining the geographical areas where emissions and employment are created to satisfy the UK’s
needs. In relation to GHGs, around half of the emissions were generated within the UK during the
period of study, as can be seen in Figure 2. However, domestic emissions showed a gradual decline,
reflecting an increasing dependency on imports. Domestic emissions represented around 55% of the
total footprint in 1997 and went down to 44% in 2007. However, given the decline in imports
registered during the financial crisis, their share increased again to 51% in 2012.
Figure 2. GHG and employment footprints according to region (share of total).
Figure 2. GHG and employment footprints according to region (share of total).
Regarding the employment footprint, around 40% of the jobs required to produce goods and
services consumed in the UK were domestic, as can be seen in Figure 2. Nonetheless, this share
registered an increase since the financial crisis, again due to the fall in trade. The country that benefited
the most by UK’s consumption is China, with an average 7.7 million jobs during the period. China’s
share in the UK’s labour footprint declined slightly after the crisis, ranging from 19% in 2007 and going
down to 14% in 2012. India is the second country that benefited from engaging in trade with the UK
with an average of 3.3 million jobs. Its share of the total footprint remained relatively stable with an
average of 7.5%. The next two most important regions were the rest of Europe and the rest of Asia,
representing on average 13% and 11% of the footprint, respectively. North America held a relatively
steady portion of about 2% throughout the years. The ROW represented around 8% on average.
When it comes to economic sectors, around a fifth of the emissions embodied in UK’s imports
were generated abroad by agricultural and material extraction activities during the period, as can be
observed in Figure 3. Around another third of emissions, in turn, were associated with industrial
products, of which chemicals (e.g., coke, petrochemicals, cement, etc.) held the largest share. Electricity
use by itself was accountable for the largest proportion, which increased from nearly 19% in 1997
to 25% in 2012. Transport activities (i.e., land, water and air) were related to about 18% of the total,
showing a minor decline at the end of the period. Finally, other services contributed with less than 5%.
In terms of employment, approximately a fourth of the jobs that the UK contributed to create
in foreign regions were related to agricultural and extraction activities, as can be seen in Figure 3.
Nevertheless, its share tended to decline, representing about 27% of the total in 1997 and dropping to
19% in 2012. The proportion of jobs in occupations belonging to the manufacturing sector remained
relatively stable during the period, representing around 37% of the total. Of these, jobs related to the
production of machinery and equipment, as well as other types of manufactures, held the biggest
shares (14% and 12%, respectively, on average). Employment in the electricity sector was minimal with
around 2%. Jobs associated with services, on the other hand, held a significant share, which increased
from almost 34% in 1997 to 40% in 2012. This includes services such as transport, leisure activities
and retail.
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 9 of 19
Sustainability 2017, 9, 1242 8 of 18
Chinas contribution to the emissions footprint was relatively low in 1997, amounting to about
5%, but it quickly doubled one decade later as it increased its participation in global markets. The
effects of the financial crisis barely affected China’s share, which just observed a small reduction,
representing around 9.5% in 2012. In relation to other regions, approximately 15% of the UK’s GHG
footprint corresponds to the rest of Europe, and this share remained relatively steady, although with
some slight reductions since 2009. A similar stable pattern can be appreciated in the case of the rest
of Asia, whose contribution amounted to about 6% on average during the period. North America’s
share, which includes the US, slowly declined from about 6% in 1997 down to 4% in 2012. The rest of
the world (ROW) contributed with an average of 14%, and more specifically Russia and Africa, which
are not shown in the graphs.
Regarding the employment footprint, around 40% of the jobs required to produce goods and
services consumed in the UK were domestic, as can be seen in Figure 2. Nonetheless, this share
registered an increase since the financial crisis, again due to the fall in trade. The country that benefited
the most by UK’s consumption is China, with an average 7.7 million jobs during the period. China’s
share in the UK’s labour footprint declined slightly after the crisis, ranging from 19% in 2007 and going
down to 14% in 2012. India is the second country that benefited from engaging in trade with the UK
with an average of 3.3 million jobs. Its share of the total footprint remained relatively stable with an
average of 7.5%. The next two most important regions were the rest of Europe and the rest of Asia,
representing on average 13% and 11% of the footprint, respectively. North America held a relatively
steady portion of about 2% throughout the years. The ROW represented around 8% on average.
When it comes to economic sectors, around a fifth of the emissions embodied in UK’s imports were
generated abroad by agricultural and material extraction activities during the period, as can be
observed in Figure 3. Around another third of emissions, in turn, were associated with industrial
products, of which chemicals (e.g., coke, petrochemicals, cement, etc.) held the largest share. Electricity
use by itself was accountable for the largest proportion, which increased from nearly 19% in 1997 to
25% in 2012. Transport activities (i.e., land, water and air) were related to about 18% of the total,
showing a minor decline at the end of the period. Finally, other services contributed with less than 5%.
Figure 3. GHGs and employment embodied in imports according to economic sector (share of total).
In terms of employment, approximately a fourth of the jobs that the UK contributed to create in
foreign regions were related to agricultural and extraction activities, as can be seen in Figure 3.
Nevertheless, its share tended to decline, representing about 27% of the total in 1997 and dropping
to 19% in 2012. The proportion of jobs in occupations belonging to the manufacturing sector remained
relatively stable during the period, representing around 37% of the total. Of these, jobs related to the
production of machinery and equipment, as well as other types of manufactures, held the biggest
shares (14% and 12%, respectively, on average). Employment in the electricity sector was minimal
with around 2%. Jobs associated with services, on the other hand, held a significant share, which
Figure 3. GHGs and employment embodied in imports according to economic sector (share of total).
4.1. Structural Decomposition
As has been already noted, production emissions registered a constant decline, achieving a
reduction of nearly 17% in 2012 with respect to 1997. This is depicted in Figure 4, which shows the
cumulative change in relation to the beginning of the period. It can be clearly seen that consumption
emissions showed exactly the opposite behaviour until 2009, when they became almost 20% higher
than 1997 levels, but then started dropping significantly. In 2012, consumption emissions were almost
10% lower than at the base year.
The number of jobs in the UK rose constantly during the period, growing by almost 14% in 2008
with respect to 1997, as can be appreciated in Figure 4. The crisis decelerated this trend and the quantity
of new jobs started falling since 2009, stabilising a couple of years later at a level of 10%. The amount
of jobs created outside the UK, however, grew much faster than domestically. In 2007, the foreign
jobs associated with UK consumption were about 25% higher than in 1997. However, as has also been
noted, the fall in imports during the crisis contributed to shrink the UK’s labour footprint significantly.
In 2012, it became almost 8% lower than at the beginning of the period.
Sustainability 2017, 9, 1242 9 of 18
increased from almost 34% in 1997 to 40% in 2012. This includes services such as transport, leisure
activities and retail.
4.1. Structural Decomposition
As has been already noted, production emissions registered a constant decline, achieving a
reduction of nearly 17% in 2012 with respect to 1997. This is depicted in Figure 4, which shows the
cumulative change in relation to the beginning of the period. It can be clearly seen that consumption
emissions showed exactly the opposite behaviour until 2009, when they became almost 20% higher
than 1997 levels, but then started dropping significantly. In 2012, consumption emissions were almost
10% lower than at the base year.
Figure 4. Cumulative change in GHGs and employment (production and consumption).
The number of jobs in the UK rose constantly during the period, growing by almost 14% in 2008
with respect to 1997, as can be appreciated in Figure 4. The crisis decelerated this trend and the
quantity of new jobs started falling since 2009, stabilising a couple of years later at a level of 10%. The
amount of jobs created outside the UK, however, grew much faster than domestically. In 2007, the
foreign jobs associated with UK consumption were about 25% higher than in 1997. However, as has
also been noted, the fall in imports during the crisis contributed to shrink the UK’s labour footprint
significantly. In 2012, it became almost 8% lower than at the beginning of the period.
In order to understand better the forces that lie behind these changes, growth in emissions and
employment was decomposed by means of SDA. Figure 5 shows the structural decomposition of the
changes in both emissions and employment from a production perspective. Regarding GHGs, the
emissions intensity (emissions per unit of output) of products destined to be consumed domestically,
as well as exports, contributed to drive emissions down, registering a decline of 11% and 30%,
respectively. Emissions intensity of export products helped to reduce emissions, particularly during
and after the crisis. Emissions embodied in exports fell 8.2% in 2009 with respect to the previous year,
while output decreased in 4.9%. From 2009 to 2012, emissions embodied in exports remained almost
constant (i.e., 0.3% on average), while output grew by 1.5% per year on average. Technological
improvements, reflected in the industrial structure of the economy (i.e., the inter-industry
requirements represented by the A matrix), also contributed to push emissions down. However, the
effect of final demand offset greater reductions in emissions. The change in emissions, solely due to
final demand effects, grew constantly. It is interesting to point out that foreign demand for UK
exports exerted a larger pressure than domestic demand. The latter, ceteris paribus, caused an
increase of around 25% in emissions, while domestic demand led to an increase of about 14%.
Figure 4. Cumulative change in GHGs and employment (production and consumption).
In order to understand better the forces that lie behind these changes, growth in emissions and
employment was decomposed by means of SDA. Figure 5shows the structural decomposition of
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 10 of 19
the changes in both emissions and employment from a production perspective. Regarding GHGs,
the emissions intensity (emissions per unit of output) of products destined to be consumed domestically,
as well as exports, contributed to drive emissions down, registering a decline of 11% and 30%,
respectively. Emissions intensity of export products helped to reduce emissions, particularly during
and after the crisis. Emissions embodied in exports fell 8.2% in 2009 with respect to the previous
year, while output decreased in 4.9%. From 2009 to 2012, emissions embodied in exports remained
almost constant (i.e., 0.3% on average), while output grew by 1.5% per year on average. Technological
improvements, reflected in the industrial structure of the economy (i.e., the inter-industry requirements
represented by the A matrix), also contributed to push emissions down. However, the effect of final
demand offset greater reductions in emissions. The change in emissions, solely due to final demand
effects, grew constantly. It is interesting to point out that foreign demand for UK exports exerted a
larger pressure than domestic demand. The latter, ceteris paribus, caused an increase of around 25% in
emissions, while domestic demand led to an increase of about 14%.
Sustainability 2017, 9, 1242 10 of 18
Figure 5. Structural decomposition of GHGs and employment (production).
A fairly similar picture can be observed in the case of employment (Figure 5). The labour
intensity of both goods for domestic consumption and exports diminished throughout the period, as
fewer jobs were required to generate the same amount of output. It is worth noticing that the labour
intensity of export sectors did not improve as much as its domestic counterpart. The configuration of
the industrial structure in this case also contributed to drive employment down, although to a much
lesser extent. The force that drove employment up was final demand from domestic and foreign
markets, with the former exerting a stronger influence. The change in employment caused solely by
domestic final demand amounted to nearly 30% in 2012, holding other effects constant, and external
demand to nearly 26%.
The GHG and employment footprints were also decomposed into the same driving forces, as is
shown in Figure 6. The contributions related to the domestic components are similar to those
presented in Figure 5, and any differences are due to the focus on imports rather than exports.
Starting with GHGs, improvements in emissions intensity constituted the most relevant factor that
contributed to reduce the footprint. The effect on emissions caused by reductions in the emissions
intensity of imports, however, was much more significant compared to the domestic component. Part
of this effect can be explained by the increasing use of cleaner technologies in the countries of
production. Nevertheless, the big drop in emissions intensity of imports registered after the crisis
could also reflect the fact that emissions embodied in imports collapsed by 19.4% in 2008 with respect
to the previous year. They dropped again in 2009 by a further 12.1% and kept falling until 2012 by
1.1% per year on average. Output, as has been mentioned, decreased by 4.9% in 2009 and then
gradually recovered its pre-crisis levels. Changes in the configuration of industrial structure also
contributed to push the GHG footprint down, achieving a reduction of about 10% in 2012 with respect
to 1997. The industrial structure factor shows the same behaviour as in the case of production
emissions, since the effect was not split into domestic and import components as was done with the
rest of the factors. We recognise this to be a limitation, since it is assumed that the industrial
configuration of the UK’s trade partner countries has experienced transformations over time.
Regarding final demand, once again, it contributed to counteract the influence of the rest of the
drivers during almost the entire period. The effect on emissions from final demand for imports grew
much faster than for domestic, and the effects of the global financial crisis can be clearly seen. The
cumulative change of final demand for imports registered rates in 2012 of 20%.
Figure 5. Structural decomposition of GHGs and employment (production).
A fairly similar picture can be observed in the case of employment (Figure 5). The labour intensity
of both goods for domestic consumption and exports diminished throughout the period, as fewer jobs
were required to generate the same amount of output. It is worth noticing that the labour intensity of
export sectors did not improve as much as its domestic counterpart. The configuration of the industrial
structure in this case also contributed to drive employment down, although to a much lesser extent.
The force that drove employment up was final demand from domestic and foreign markets, with
the former exerting a stronger influence. The change in employment caused solely by domestic final
demand amounted to nearly 30% in 2012, holding other effects constant, and external demand to
nearly 26%.
The GHG and employment footprints were also decomposed into the same driving forces, as is
shown in Figure 6. The contributions related to the domestic components are similar to those presented
in Figure 5, and any differences are due to the focus on imports rather than exports. Starting with
GHGs, improvements in emissions intensity constituted the most relevant factor that contributed
to reduce the footprint. The effect on emissions caused by reductions in the emissions intensity of
imports, however, was much more significant compared to the domestic component. Part of this
effect can be explained by the increasing use of cleaner technologies in the countries of production.
Nevertheless, the big drop in emissions intensity of imports registered after the crisis could also
reflect the fact that emissions embodied in imports collapsed by 19.4% in 2008 with respect to the
previous year. They dropped again in 2009 by a further 12.1% and kept falling until 2012 by 1.1%
per year on average. Output, as has been mentioned, decreased by 4.9% in 2009 and then gradually
recovered its pre-crisis levels. Changes in the configuration of industrial structure also contributed
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 11 of 19
to push the GHG footprint down, achieving a reduction of about 10% in 2012 with respect to 1997.
The industrial structure factor shows the same behaviour as in the case of production emissions,
since the effect was not split into domestic and import components as was done with the rest of the
factors. We recognise this to be a limitation, since it is assumed that the industrial configuration of
the UK’s trade partner countries has experienced transformations over time. Regarding final demand,
once again, it contributed to counteract the influence of the rest of the drivers during almost the entire
period. The effect on emissions from final demand for imports grew much faster than for domestic,
and the effects of the global financial crisis can be clearly seen. The cumulative change of final demand
for imports registered rates in 2012 of 20%.
Sustainability 2017, 9, 1242 11 of 18
Figure 6. Structural decomposition of GHGs and employment (consumption).
The case of the employment footprint shows a similar pattern. In relation to the industrial
structure, it caused a minor effect on the footprint (and, as in the case of emissions, this effect was not
split into domestic and import components). Final demand effects, in turn, dominated over almost
the entire period, with demand for imports being higher than domestic demand, representing an
increase, keeping other things constant, of 26%. Once again, the consequences of the crisis on the
demand for imports are evident. Reductions in labour intensity contributed to drive the footprint
down and, once more, the effects derived from the import component are quite significant. As was
explained, this reflects productivity gains (i.e., fewer jobs to produce the same level of goods and
services), and also the fact that export sectors of economies that produce goods consumed in the UK
have gradually become more capital intensive. However, the deep plunge in foreign labour intensity
could also reflect the significant annual reductions in employment embodied in imports during and
after the crisis. Employment associated with UK imports fell by 17.4% and 19.0% in 2008 and 2009,
respectively, continuing to fall until 2012 by 2.8% per year on average. Meanwhile, output only fell
in 2009, as has been noted. The sharp declines during and after the crisis in the contribution of the
intensity factors to the overall changes of the employment footprint, as well as in the case of the
emissions footprint, represents an issue that deserves further research in order to be verified.
4.2. The Relationship between the Emissions and Employment Footprints
After estimating the emissions and employment footprints, it is straightforward to calculate the
am ount of impo rted e missi ons as sociated with e very j ob tha t is cr eated by UK f inal d emand in for eign
regions. This is specifically done by dividing the emissions footprint by the labour footprint according
to country and sector. Table 1 presents these ratios as averages for the whole period (1997–2012). In
relation to regions, it is the Middle East, Africa, Oceania and North America, in this order, where
more emissions were emitted per job created. This is due to their high carbon intensity and the low
number of jobs that are generated there. The value of 10.9 associated with China, viewed on its own,
might be deceiving. The ratio is low given the large denominator or, in other words, the large amount
of jobs that are created in that country in relation to the emissions associated with UK consumption.
Regarding sectors across all regions, it can be observed that electricity produces the largest
ratios, with an average of more than 300 tonnes of emissions per job. This is expected, given the high
carbon-intensity and low labour-intensity of the sector. Electricity is then followed by transport,
chemical products and agriculture. Services (excluding transport) displays the smallest value, with
around 2.5 tonnes per job.
Figure 6. Structural decomposition of GHGs and employment (consumption).
The case of the employment footprint shows a similar pattern. In relation to the industrial
structure, it caused a minor effect on the footprint (and, as in the case of emissions, this effect was not
split into domestic and import components). Final demand effects, in turn, dominated over almost the
entire period, with demand for imports being higher than domestic demand, representing an increase,
keeping other things constant, of 26%. Once again, the consequences of the crisis on the demand for
imports are evident. Reductions in labour intensity contributed to drive the footprint down and, once
more, the effects derived from the import component are quite significant. As was explained, this
reflects productivity gains (i.e., fewer jobs to produce the same level of goods and services), and also
the fact that export sectors of economies that produce goods consumed in the UK have gradually
become more capital intensive. However, the deep plunge in foreign labour intensity could also
reflect the significant annual reductions in employment embodied in imports during and after the
crisis. Employment associated with UK imports fell by 17.4% and 19.0% in 2008 and 2009, respectively,
continuing to fall until 2012 by 2.8% per year on average. Meanwhile, output only fell in 2009, as has
been noted. The sharp declines during and after the crisis in the contribution of the intensity factors
to the overall changes of the employment footprint, as well as in the case of the emissions footprint,
represents an issue that deserves further research in order to be verified.
4.2. The Relationship between the Emissions and Employment Footprints
After estimating the emissions and employment footprints, it is straightforward to calculate the
amount of imported emissions associated with every job that is created by UK final demand in foreign
regions. This is specifically done by dividing the emissions footprint by the labour footprint according
to country and sector. Table 1presents these ratios as averages for the whole period (1997–2012).
In relation to regions, it is the Middle East, Africa, Oceania and North America, in this order, where
more emissions were emitted per job created. This is due to their high carbon intensity and the low
number of jobs that are generated there. The value of 10.9 associated with China, viewed on its own,
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 12 of 19
might be deceiving. The ratio is low given the large denominator or, in other words, the large amount
of jobs that are created in that country in relation to the emissions associated with UK consumption.
Table 1.
UK imported emissions (tonnes) per job created overseas by country and sector (averages for
the period 1997–2012).
By Country/Region Emissions (Tonnes) per Job By Sector (across Regions) Emissions (Tonnes) per Job
China 10.9 Agriculture and extraction 19.3
India 6.8 Chemicals (including
cement) 39.6
Japan 26.5 Metal products 14.3
Russia 34.9 Machinery and equipment 10.3
Africa 90.7 Other manufactures
(including construction) 9.5
Asia 11.4 Electricity, gas and water 313.6
Europe 26.9 Transport 58.6
Middle East 91.7 Other services 2.6
North America 52.8
Oceania 63.3
South America 25.8
Regarding sectors across all regions, it can be observed that electricity produces the largest
ratios, with an average of more than 300 tonnes of emissions per job. This is expected, given
the high carbon-intensity and low labour-intensity of the sector. Electricity is then followed by
transport, chemical products and agriculture. Services (excluding transport) displays the smallest
value, with around 2.5 tonnes per job.
4.3. The Emissions Elasticity of Labour
The ratios presented in Table 1might be deceiving if viewed without additional information.
A more useful approach to analyse the relationship between the emissions and the labour footprints
is the emissions elasticity of labour. This indicator can provide us with an initial understanding of
the trade-offs between reducing imported emissions by modifying consumption and its effect on
employment in foreign regions. Figure 7shows the relationship between the number of jobs and
the volume of emissions, both embodied in imports. The variables are expressed in log differences,
thus representing annual growth rates. In this manner, the estimated slope parameter of the regression
line shown in Figure 7constitutes the emissions elasticity of labour, which is almost unitary. This
basically means that every time emissions embodied in UK imports grew by 1%, the number of jobs
created in foreign regions increased by an equal proportion. This finding is not surprising, given that
both variables are driven by the same final demand. Nevertheless, it is worth mentioning that before
the crisis (i.e., 1997–2007 in the period of study) the value of the coefficient was somewhat smaller
(0.92, R
2
= 0.62), but the relationship became more elastic in the period that followed (1.37,
R2= 0.93
).
Changes in employment became proportionally larger per unit change in emissions embodied in
imports. This last result, however, has to be considered with caution as it involves a very limited
number of data points (2009–2012).
The emissions elasticity of labour, however, varies depending on the country that produces the
imports and on the sector. The largest elasticities according to country of production correspond to
India and Russia, with a value of 1.3 each, as can be seen in Table 2. However, the R
2
for Russia
indicates a weak correlation. The lowest elasticities by region belong to North America and Africa,
with values of 0.6 and 0.3, respectively, although the R2s also show weak correlations in these cases.
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 13 of 19
Sustainability 2017, 9, 1242 12 of 18
Table 1. UK imported emissions (tonnes) per job created overseas by country and sector (averages for
the period 1997–2012).
By Country
Region Emissions (Tonnes) per
J
ob By Sector (across Regions) Emissions(Tonnes) per
J
ob
China 10.9 Agriculture and extraction 19.3
India 6.8 Chemicals (including cement) 39.6
Japan 26.5 Metal products 14.3
Russia 34.9 Machinery and equipment 10.3
Africa 90.7
Other manufactures (including
construction) 9.5
Asia 11.4 Electricity, gas and water 313.6
Europe 26.9 Transport 58.6
Middle East 91.7 Other services 2.6
North America 52.8
Oceania 63.3
South America 25.8
4.3. The Emissions Elasticity of Labour
The ratios presented in Table 1 might be deceiving if viewed without additional information. A
more useful approach to analyse the relationship between the emissions and the labour footprints is
the emissions elasticity of labour. This indicator can provide us with an initial understanding of the
trade-offs between reducing imported emissions by modifying consumption and its effect on
employment in foreign regions. Figure 7 shows the relationship between the number of jobs and the
volume of emissions, both embodied in imports. The variables are expressed in log differences, thus
representing annual growth rates. In this manner, the estimated slope parameter of the regression
line shown in Figure 7 constitutes the emissions elasticity of labour, which is almost unitary. This
basically means that every time emissions embodied in UK imports grew by 1%, the number of jobs
created in foreign regions increased by an equal proportion. This finding is not surprising, given that
both variables are driven by the same final demand. Nevertheless, it is worth mentioning that before
the crisis (i.e., 1997–2007 in the period of study) the value of the coefficient was somewhat smaller
(0.92, R2 = 0.62), but the relationship became more elastic in the period that followed (1.37, R2 = 0.93).
Changes in employment became proportionally larger per unit change in emissions embodied in
imports. This last result, however, has to be considered with caution as it involves a very limited
number of data points (2009–2012).
Figure 7. Correlation between employment and GHGs (both embodied in imports, log differences).
The emissions elasticity of labour, however, varies depending on the country that produces the
imports and on the sector. The largest elasticities according to country of production correspond to
India and Russia, with a value of 1.3 each, as can be seen in Table 2. However, the R2 for Russia indicates
Figure 7. Correlation between employment and GHGs (both embodied in imports, log differences).
Table 2. Values for UK emissions elasticity of labour by country and by sector.
By Country/Region Elasticity R2By Sector (across Regions) Elasticity R2
China 0.90 0.67 Agriculture and extraction 0.52 0.30
India 1.29 0.81 Chemicals (including cement) 1.32 0.73
Japan 0.81 0.81 Metal products 1.09 0.69
Russia 1.29 0.27 Machinery and equipment 1.21 0.64
Africa 0.35 0.11
Other manufactures (including construction)
1.38 0.70
Asia 1.17 0.79 Electricity, gas and water 0.57 0.10
Europe 0.88 0.87 Transport 0.97 0.41
Middle East 0.94 0.20 Other services 1.02 0.58
North America 0.60 0.35
Oceania 1.03 0.65
South America 1.13 0.67
Regarding sectors, the largest elasticities correspond to ‘other manufactures’ and ‘chemicals’,
that produce values of the magnitude of 1.4 and 1.3, respectively. The lowest values correspond to
agriculture and utilities (0.5 and 0.6, respectively), but the correlations in these cases are also low.
5. Discussion
The UK economy has shown a strong dependency on imports during the last two decades in
order to obtain the products and services that it requires to fulfil its consumption needs. By consuming
imported goods and services, it contributes to create employment as well as emissions in other regions
of the planet. The UK helped to generate an annual average of 25 million jobs worldwide during
the period 1997 to 2012, the majority of them in the rest of Europe, China, India and the rest of
Asia. Meanwhile, over half of the emissions associated with UK consumption were generated abroad,
and half of these occurred mainly in the rest of Europe and China.
The rise of China as one of the UK’s most important trade partners is clearly reflected in both
footprints. China’s share of total UK imports amounted to around 1.5% in 1999, expanding quickly to
account for nearly 8.0% in 2012, becoming the UK’s second largest import partner behind Germany [
11
].
The implications for embodied emissions is substantial. While China’s contribution to total UK import
emissions was about 10.5% in 1997, it almost doubled in 2012, reaching 19.1%. In terms of employment,
China has been the country that has benefited the most by UK consumption, helping to generate
an average of 7.7 million jobs during the period under study. China is expected to remain a strong
UK trade partner in the future, continuing to provide goods and services that are essential to the
UK’s consumption requirements. It is thus expected that the UK will continue to fuel job creation in
that country. However, China’s intentions to decarbonise its economy and pursue efforts to peak its
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 14 of 19
emissions by 2030, as expressed in its Nationally Determined Contribution (NDC) submitted to the
UNFCCC ahead of the Paris Agreement, could mean that its share of the UK’s emissions footprint,
as well as those of other nations, would decline over time. The same logic applies to other emerging
economies that trade with the UK, such as India, South Africa, Indonesia, and so on. Given that the
Paris Agreement has broaden the mitigation scope to include the developing world, this could mean a
gradual decrease of the emissions intensity of UK’s imports. Accordingly, as the SDA results suggest,
this would contribute to reduce the country’s emissions footprint.
The level of both footprints was lower in 2012 compared to the level they presented in the
beginning of the period. However, until 2009 both footprints increased significantly faster than their
territorial counterparts before registering an important fall. The impact of the global financial crisis
on both indicators was profound. This clearly illustrates a vital point. As was shown by the results
derived from the SDA, final demand is the most influential factor driving both footprints, offsetting
most of the time the gains achieved by technological improvements. Therefore, the most effective
way to attain rapid and drastic reductions in emissions, both from a production and a consumption
perspective, is to decrease the levels of consumption. Nevertheless, the economic implications can
be serious and job creation can be especially jeopardised. According to this paper’s results, around
580 thousand jobs were lost from 2008 to 2009 domestically, as well as almost 5 million jobs associated
with UK consumption during the same years in other regions of the globe. There is, in this sense, a clear
trade-off between reducing the emissions footprint via a decline of consumption and the creation of
economic and development opportunities not only within the UK, but also in the rest of the world.
The emissions elasticity of labour presented in this paper is thus useful to obtain an initial
understanding of the trade-offs between reducing imported emissions by changing consumption and
the corresponding employment effects in foreign regions. Clearly, China, India, Russia, as well as
advanced economies in the rest of Europe and the US, benefit from UK consumption. Consequently,
they would resent a fall of UK imports in relation to, among other things, job creation. According to
this paper’s analysis, it is the big emerging economies, which function as ‘factories of the world’, that
are more exposed and are vulnerable to changes in UK consumption. When it comes to economic
sectors, it is manufacturing and heavy industry which would feel the largest impacts. A deeper
analysis, however, would be helpful, exploring with greater detail at the country and sectoral levels
any opportunities that might arise to reduce UK imports while minimising impacts on employment in
the economies that trade with the UK.
In recent years, and more specifically in the aftermath of the global financial crisis, the argument
of reindustrialising the UK economy has received a renewed impetus [68]. Reshoring manufacturing
would contribute to diminish the UK’s increasing reliance on imports, while helping to create more
employment domestically and reduce its emissions footprint. Arguably, such a move could equally
drive a rise in production emissions, although this might not necessarily be the case if low-carbon
or renewable-energy technologies are in place. Nonetheless, the actual possibilities of achieving this
reshoring are uncertain and some studies have suggested that there are limits as to how far it can occur,
at least in some sectors, mainly due to the availability of required skills and finance along the supply
chain [
13
]. A more realistic view, at least in the near-to-medium term, is that the UK will continue to
depend heavily on imports, while focusing more on high-value activities and services.
Given the inherent difficulties of reducing the consumption of imported goods and services,
the UK should look for other alternatives to diminish its emissions footprint, while contributing to
enhance global development. This could be done by offering increased support to emission-intensive
trade partners in the form of technology transfer and financial aid to help them achieve emissions
reductions and safeguard jobs in export sectors. For instance, the Clean Development Mechanism
(CDM), despite its limitations [
69
], could be an appropriate vehicle to target carbon-intensive sectors
in producing countries and reduce the UK footprint [70].
Finally, the issue of Brexit has raised paramount concerns regarding its implications on trade.
These are still uncertain and will ultimately depend on the type of agreement that is achieved at the end
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 15 of 19
of the negotiating process between the UK government and the EU. A ‘hard’ Brexit, that is, a complete
exclusion of the UK from the European single market, could signify the adoption of a trade regime
under the rules of the World Trade Organisation (WTO) and the potential implementation of tariffs
by both parties. In this scenario, it is expected that trade with the EU could diminish, although it is
unclear to what degree. If this was the case, then it is expected that jobs in the UK to produce exports to
the EU would be lost, with a corresponding effect in the opposite direction (i.e., removal of European
jobs due to lower UK imports and an associated reduction of the UK’s labour footprint). However,
the final consequences for the UK’s emissions and labour footprints would depend on a number
of factors (e.g., exchange rate movements, trade balance, etc.), and among others, the possibility of
materialising free-trade agreements with alternative partners. Expanding trade flows with China and
India, for example, could lead to an increase of the UK’s emissions footprint. However, it is difficult at
this stage to move beyond these assumptions. More research is clearly required in this area to provide
more robust answers.
6. Conclusions
The UK is a major player in an ever more globalised world. Similarly to many other industrialised
nations, the UK has become a high-value service-oriented economy, experiencing complex structural
changes featuring an offshoring process of domestic industries to other regions of the planet. In this
sense, the UK has increasingly relied on foreign markets to acquire products and services that are vital
to fulfil its material needs. This has had both economic and environmental implications, as the country
has become a net importer of emissions and employment.
In this paper, the UK’s GHG emissions and labour footprints were estimated to analyse their
behaviour, drivers and sectoral and regional composition, as well as to understand the relationship
between both measures. The results showed that both footprints have tended to grow substantially
faster than their production counterparts, except during the aftermath of the global financial crisis.
Given the significant influence of final demand as a prevailing driver of both footprints, it can be
expected that UK consumption will continue to fuel the growth of both indicators in the upcoming
years. Consequently, addressing the UK’s reliance on imports and, more importantly, its elevated
levels of consumption, should be a priority to reduce its adverse effects on the global environment.
However, it can be concluded that unilateral actions to modify the country’s consumption patterns can
have unintended consequences in other regions of the world in terms of job creation and development
opportunities. More efforts should thus be focused on supporting the UK’s trade partners to lower
their emissions intensity and helping them to attain their intended emissions reductions as expressed
by their NDCs.
In this sense, this paper offers useful insights into the complex relationship between the emissions
and employment footprints. It also opens new research pathways that are vital to understand the
intricate links between trade, development and the environment.
Acknowledgments:
Our thanks to two anonymous reviewers who helped to identify errors and inaccuracies,
and contributed to improve the quality of the paper. This work was supported by the Research Councils UK
(RCUK) Energy Programme’s funding for the Centre for Industrial Energy, Materials and Products (CIE-MAP),
grant reference EP/N022645/1, and the UK Energy Research Centre (UKERC), under award EP/L024756/1.
Author Contributions:
All authors conceived and designed the article. A.O. assembled the database. M.S. and
A.O. conducted the analysis. M.S. wrote the article. M.S. and A.O. revised the various drafts. J.B. supervised
the research.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 16 of 19
Appendix A
Table A1. Description of data and sources.
Data Repository/Statistical
Agency Description Period URL
UK Supply and
Use tables
Office for National
Statistics
Estimates of industry inputs and outputs,
product supply and demand and Gross
Value Added (GVA) for the United
Kingdom. Supply and use tables for 1997
to 2014 that are consistent with UK
National Accounts in Blue Book 2016.
1997–2014
https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/
nationalaccounts/
supplyandusetables/datasets/
inputoutputsupplyandusetables
Input-Output
tables (domestic
and import) and
bilateral trade data
Eora MRIO
Database
Time series of high resolution IO tables
with matching environmental and social
satellite accounts for 187 countries
1990–2012 http://www.worldmrio.com
UK GDP deflator Office for National
Statistics Implied GDP deflator at market prices 1997–2012
https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/
grossdomesticproductgdp/
timeseries/l8gg/qna
GDP deflators
(various regions)
World
Input-Output
Database
Price levels of gross output, intermediate
inputs and value added, 1995 = 100 1995–2011 http://www.wiod.org
UK GHG emissions
Office for National
Statistics and BEIS
CO2, CH4, N2O, hydrofluorocarbons,
perfluorocarbons and sulphur
hexafluoride
1990–2013
https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/
environmentalaccounts/articles/
greenhousegasemissions/2015-06-02
https://www.gov.uk/government/
collections/uk-greenhouse-gas-
emissions-statistics
GHG emissions
various regions
Eora MRIO
Database
CO
2
, CH
4
, N
2
O and fluorinated gases (by
region and sector) 1990–2012 http://www.worldmrio.com
Number of jobs
(UK)
Office for National
Statistics
Thousands of employee jobs by economic
sector 1996–2014
https://www.ons.gov.uk/
employmentandlabourmarket/
peopleinwork/
employmentandemployeetypes/
datasets/
employeejobsbyindustryjobs03
Number of jobs
(various regions)
Eora MRIO
Database
Thousands of full-time equivalent (FTE)
by region and economic sector 1990–2012 http://www.worldmrio.com
References
1. World Bank. Open data. 2016. Available online: http://data.worldbank.org (accessed on 13 July 2017).
2.
Helg, R.; Tajoli, L. Patterns of international fragmentation of production and the relative demand for labor.
North Am. J. Econ. Financ. 2005,16, 233–254. [CrossRef]
3.
Coe, N.M.; Hess, M. Global production networks, labour and development. Geoforum
2013
,44, 4–9.
[CrossRef]
4.
Feenstra, R.C. Integration of trade and disintegration of production in the global economy. J. Econ. Perspect.
1998,12, 31–50. [CrossRef]
5.
Timmer, M.P.; Erumban, A.A.; Los, B.; Stehrer, R.; de Vries, G.J. Slicing up global value chains. J. Econ.
Perspect. 2014,28, 99–118. [CrossRef]
6.
Los, B.; Timmer, M.P.; de Vries, G.J. How global are global value chains? A new approach to measure
international fragmentation. J. Reg. Sci. 2015,55, 66–92. [CrossRef]
7.
Kollmeyer, C. Explaining deindustrialization: How affluence, productivity growth, and globalization
diminish manufacturing employment. Am. J. Sociol. 2009,114, 1644–1674. [CrossRef]
8.
Greenaway, D.; Hine, R.C.; Wright, P. An empirical assessment of the impact of trade on employment in the
united kingdom. Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 1999,15, 485–500. [CrossRef]
9.
International labour organization (ILO). International Labour Organizations’s Central Statistics Database Ilostat;
ILO: Geneva, Switzerland, 2016; Available online: http://www.ilo.org/ilostat/ (accessed on 13 July 2017).
10.
Hine, R.; Wright, P. Trade with low wage economies, employment and productivity in uk manufacturing.
Econ. J. 1998,108, 1500–1510. [CrossRef]
11.
Office for National Statistics (ONS). UK Office for National Statistics. 2016. Available online:
https://www.ons.gov.uk (accessed on 13 July 2017).
12.
Barrett, J.; Peters, G.; Wiedmann, T.; Scott, K.; Lenzen, M.; Roelich, K.; Le Quéré, C. Consumption-based ghg
emission accounting: A UK case study. Clim. Policy 2013,13, 451–470. [CrossRef]
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 17 of 19
13.
Bailey, D.; De Propris, L. Manufacturing reshoring and its limits: The UK automotive case. Camb. J. Reg.
Econ. Soc. 2014,7, 379–395. [CrossRef]
14.
Sakai, M. Sustainability: Limit consumption to preserve habitats. Nature
2012
,486, 473. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
15.
Røpke, I. Trade, development and sustainability—A critical assessment of the “free trade dogma”. Ecol. Econ.
1994,9, 13–22. [CrossRef]
16.
Antweiler, W.; Copeland, B.R.; Taylor, M.S. Is free trade good for the environment? Am. Econ. Rev.
2001
,91,
877–908. [CrossRef]
17. Copeland, B.R.; Taylor, M.S. Trade, growth, and the environment. J. Econ. Lit. 2004,42, 7–71. [CrossRef]
18.
Frankel, J.A.; Rose, A.K. Is trade good or bad for the environment? Sorting out the causality. Rev. Econ. Stat.
2005,87, 85–91. [CrossRef]
19.
Aller, C.; Ductor, L.; Herrerias, M.J. The world trade network and the environment. Energy Econ.
2015
,52,
55–68. [CrossRef]
20.
Harrison, A. Openness and growth: A time-series, cross-country analysis for developing countries. J. Dev.
Econ. 1996,48, 419–447. [CrossRef]
21.
Edwards, S. Openness, productivity and growth: What do we really know? Econ. J.
1998
,108, 383–398.
[CrossRef]
22.
Chang, R.; Kaltani, L.; Loayza, N.V. Openness can be good for growth: The role of policy complementarities.
J. Dev. Econ. 2009,90, 33–49. [CrossRef]
23.
Estevadeordal, A.; Taylor, A.M. Is the washington consensus dead? Growth, openness, and the great
liberalization, 1970s–2000s. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2013,95, 1669–1690. [CrossRef]
24.
Sakyi, D.; Villaverde, J.; Maza, A. Trade openness, income levels, and economic growth: The case of
developing countries, 1970–2009. J. Int. Trade Econ. Dev. 2015,24, 860–882. [CrossRef]
25.
Prebisch, R. The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems; UN Economic Commission
for Latin America, United Nations Publications: New York, NY, USA, 1950.
26.
Singer, H.W. The distribution of gains between investing and borrowing countries. Am. Econ. Rev.
1950
,40,
473–485.
27.
Rodríguez, F.; Rodrik, D. Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to Cross-National Evidence;
National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1999; p. 82.
28. Feenstra, R.C. Trade and uneven growth. J. Dev. Econ. 1996,49, 229–256. [CrossRef]
29. Krueger, A.O. Trade policy and economic development: How we learn. Am. Econ. Rev. 1997,87, 1–22.
30. Dollar, D.; Kraay, A. Trade, growth, and poverty. Econ. J. 2004,114, F22–F49. [CrossRef]
31.
Rueda-Cantuche, J.M.; Sousa, N.; Andreoni, V.; Arto, I. The single market as an engine for employment
through external trade. J. Common Market Stud. 2013,51, 931–947. [CrossRef]
32.
Grossman, G.M.; Krueger, A.B. Environmental Impacts of a North American Free Trade Agreement; National
Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1991; p. 57. Available online: http://www.nber.org/
papers/w3914/ (accessed on 13 July 2017).
33. Dinda, S. Environmental kuznets curve hypothesis: A survey. Ecol. Econ. 2004,49, 431–455. [CrossRef]
34.
Galeotti, M.; Lanza, A.; Pauli, F. Reassessing the environmental kuznets curve for CO
2
emissions: A
robustness exercise. Ecol. Econ. 2006,57, 152–163. [CrossRef]
35.
Weber, C.L.; Peters, G.P.; Guan, D.; Hubacek, K. The contribution of chinese exports to climate change. Energy
Policy 2008,36, 3572–3577. [CrossRef]
36.
Lenzen, M.; Moran, D.; Kanemoto, K.; Foran, B.; Lobefaro, L.; Geschke, A. International trade drives
biodiversity threats in developing nations. Nature 2012,486, 109–112. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
37.
Bruckner, M.; Giljum, S.; Lutz, C.; Wiebe, K.S. Materials embodied in international trade—Global material
extraction and consumption between 1995 and 2005. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2012,22, 568–576. [CrossRef]
38.
Wiedmann, T. Impacts embodied in global trade flows. In Taking Stock of Industrial Ecology; Clift, R.,
Druckman, A., Eds.; Springer International Publishing: New York, NY, USA; London, UK, 2016; pp. 159–180.
39.
Munksgaard, J.; Pedersen, K.A. CO
2
accounts for open economies: Producer or consumer responsibility?
Energy Policy 2001,29, 327–334. [CrossRef]
40.
Peters, G.P. From production-based to consumption-based national emission inventories. Ecol. Econ.
2008
,
65, 13–23. [CrossRef]
41.
Peters, G.P.; Hertwich, E.G. CO
2
embodied in international trade with implications for global climate policy.
Environ. Sci. Technol. 2008,42, 1401–1407. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Sustainability 2017,9, 1242 18 of 19
42.
Davis, S.J.; Caldeira, K. Consumption-based accounting of co
2
emissions. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA
2010
,
107, 5687–5692. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
43.
Peters, G.P.; Minx, J.C.; Weber, C.L.; Edenhofer, O. Growth in emission transfers via international trade from
1990 to 2008. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2011,108, 8903–8908. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
44. Peters, G.P. Policy update: Managing carbon leakage. Carbon Manag. 2010,1, 35–37. [CrossRef]
45.
Kanemoto, K.; Moran, D.; Lenzen, M.; Geschke, A. International trade undermines national emission
reduction targets: New evidence from air pollution. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2014,24, 52–59. [CrossRef]
46.
IDE-JETRO; World Trade Organisation (WTO). Trade Patterns and Global Value Chains in East Asia: From Trade
in Goods to Trade in Tasks; WTO: Geneva, Switzerland, 2011; p. 132.
47.
Daudin, G.; Rifflart, C.; Schweisguth, D. Who produces for whom in the world economy? Qui produit pour
qui dans l’économie mondiale? Can. J. Econ./Revue Canadienne D
'
économique
2011
,44, 1403–1437. [CrossRef]
48.
Alsamawi, A.; Murray, J.; Lenzen, M. The employment footprints of nations. J. Ind. Ecol.
2014
,18, 59–70.
[CrossRef]
49.
Arto, I.; Rueda-Cantuche, J.M.; Andreoni, V.; Mongelli, I.; Genty, A. The game of trading jobs for emissions.
Energy Policy 2014,66, 517–525. [CrossRef]
50. Simas, M.; Wood, R.; Hertwich, E. Labor embodied in trade. J. Ind. Ecol. 2015,19, 343–356. [CrossRef]
51.
Sakai, M.; Barrett, J. Reducing the carbon footprint and its implications for global employment: The labour
productivity of carbon. In The Sustainability Practitioner’s Guide to Social Analysis and Assessment; Murray, J.,
McBain, D., Wiedmann, T., Eds.; Common Ground Publishing LLC: Champaign, IL, USA, 2015; pp. 130–140.
52.
Wiedmann, T. A review of recent multi-region input-output models used for consumption-based emission
and resource accounting. Ecol. Econ. 2009,69, 211–222. [CrossRef]
53.
Miller, R.E.; Blair, P.D. Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions; Cambridge University Press:
New York, NY, USA; Cambridge, UK, 2009; p. 750.
54.
Dietzenbacher, E.; Los, B. Structural decomposition techniques: Sense and sensitivity. Econ. Syst. Res.
1998
,
10, 307–324. [CrossRef]
55.
Rose, A.; Casler, S. Input-output structural decomposition analysis: A critical appraisal. Econ. Syst. Res.
1996
,
8, 33–62. [CrossRef]
56.
Hoekstra, R.; van den Bergh, J.C.J.M. Comparing structural decomposition analysis and index. Energy Econ.
2003,25, 39–64. [CrossRef]
57.
Dietzenbacher, E.; Los, B. Structural decomposition analyses with dependent determinants. Econ. Syst. Res.
2000,12, 497–514. [CrossRef]
58.
Hoekstra, R.; van den Bergh, J.C.J.M. Structural decomposition analysis of physical flows in the economy.
Environ. Resour. Econ. 2002,23, 357–378. [CrossRef]
59.
Minx, J.C.; Baiocchi, G.; Peters, G.P.; Weber, C.L.; Guan, D.; Hubacek, K. A “carbonizing dragon”: China’s
fast growing CO2emissions revisited. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2011,45, 9144–9153. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
60.
Owen, A.; Brockway, P.; Brand-Correa, L.; Bunse, L.; Sakai, M.; Barrett, J. Energy consumption-based
accounts: A comparison of results using different energy extension vectors. Appl. Energy
2017
,190, 464–473.
[CrossRef]
61.
Department for Environment, Food & Rural Affairs (DEFRA). Official Statistics: UK’s Carbon
Footprint. Available online: https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/uks-carbon-footprint (accessed
on 29 June 2017).
62.
Office for National Statistics (ONS). Supply and Use Tables. Available online: https://www.ons.gov.uk/
economy/nationalaccounts/supplyandusetables (accessed on 29 June 2017).
63.
Lenzen, M.; Moran, D.; Kanemoto, K.; Geschke, A. Building eora: A global multi-region input-output
database at high country and sector resolution. Econ. Syst. Res. 2013,25, 20–49. [CrossRef]
64.
Dietzenbacher, E.; Temurshoev, U. Input-output impact analysis in current or constant prices: Does it matter?
J. Econ. Struct. 2012,1, 1–18. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
65.
Dietzenbacher, E.; Los, B.; Stehrer, R.; Timmer, M.; de Vries, G. The construction of world input-output tables
in the wiod project. Econ. Syst. Res. 2013,25, 71–98. [CrossRef]
66.
Office for National Statistics (ONS). Glossary of Labour Market Terms. Available online:
http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20160106000937/http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/guide-
method/method-quality/specific/labour-market/glossary-of-labour-market-terms/index.html (accessed
on 29 June 2017).