ArticlePDF Available

The Global "New Normal" is Not New- But it is still a real concern

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Global growth rates of the last five years are similar to those in the past, but now they are accompanied by unprecedented monetary expansion that seems to have little impact.
No caption available
… 
No caption available
… 
No caption available
… 
Content may be subject to copyright.
1
The Global “New Normal” is Not NewBut it is still a real concern*
C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh
Many different explanations have been proffered for the “new normal” of “secular
stagnation” in the global economy ever since the Great Recession. This is supposed to
be exemplified by low growth, verging on stagnation, in the advanced economies,
now combined with slower growth in the developing world.
Certainly the recovery from the Great Recession of 2008-09 has been anaemic at best,
even as it has failed to generate much employment outside of the US (and even there
it has created mostly casual, part-time and poor quality jobs). Deflation has persisted
in Japan for many years now, and has become evident in the Eurozone and the US as
well. Financial markets are febrile and display nervously erratic behaviour, often
without proximate cause such as in the recent collapse in bond yields across the
advanced economies.
But purely in terms of GDP growth, are the last five years really so very different
from past patterns of global capitalism, even compared to the supposedly more
dynamic period of globalisation? Chart 1 tracks annual GDP growth in developed and
developing/transition economies from 1990. The period from 2002 to 2007 does show
acceleration of growth across economies, but that came to end in the collapse of 2008-
09, and since then GDP growth rates have been similar to those of the 1990s.
Chart 1.
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook April 2016 database.
Indeed, that boom period in the 2000s could even be seen as more of an aberration. It
is well known that the dynamism generated by US expansion which in turn was
driven by a finance-driven bubble centred around the US housing market pulled the
global economy into a brief period of rapid growth. This was associated with faster
2
growth in some developing countries, particularly China, with implications for the
nature and spread of economic activity.
But, precisely because it was based on a bubble, it was by definition short-lived. The
inevitable collapse brought a very sharp downturn with output declining for the
advanced economies taken together, and decelerating sharply for the developing
world. The “recovery” thereafter could simply be seen as a return to the more sedate
growth rates that were evident in the first decade of globalisation.
But that does not mean there are no reasons for concern. First, the boom of the mid-
2000s was an unsustainable bubble generated by finance, which had become the only
means of generating expansion given the wage suppression and rising inequality that
increasingly characterised capitalism. The realisation problem created by wage
suppression the growing difficulty of finding markets for production if mass
incomes are not rising can be answered through credit bubbles only as a very
temporary solution, and one that necessarily gives rise to problems of its own. Once
the bubble bursts, the need for private agents both households and companies to
clean up their balance sheets means that deleveraging adds a further negative impetus
to economic activity. So there are limits to using this as a way out of the stagnationary
tendencies inherent in advanced capitalism.
In addition, there are other ways in which the world economy is different, and why
similar growth rates today cannot be seen as simply a return to status quo ante of the
pre-global crisis years. Consider, for instance, the behaviour of investment rates, as
shown in Chart 2. Investment rates in the advanced economies kept declining
throughout the period of globalisation, even though it was supposed to provide
favourable incentives for investment to private players. Various factors have
contributed to this, including the emphasis since 2010 on fiscal austerity, which has
reduced the positive effects that public investment could have had on private
investment.
Investment rates in the developing world did indeed increase significantly in the
boom years of the 2000s and have since tapered off. But it is noteworthy that they
have remained high even as output has decelerated after 2010. So something is awry
in the accumulation process in developing countries, which may have to do with the
falling effectiveness of investment in generating more output in some larger
economies like as China. So it is not only the stagnation of global demand that is a
problem which indeed it is but the fact that relatively high rates of investment no
longer serve to deliver as much output as earlier.
3
Chart 2.
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook April 2016 database.
The other significant difference is that the global economy is now awash with supply
of liquidity, because of the peculiarly one-sided response to the crisis in the developed
world. Aside from the brief period just after the crisis, in 2009, expansionary fiscal
policy has effectively been discarded as a possible response. Monetary policy has
become not just the preferred instrument, but in most cases the only instrument, to
deal with the threat of economic downturn. And this monetary policy also tends to be
rather limited, focussed on “quantitative easing” and near-zero interest rates that
deliver the potential to provide credit to banks but do not provide purchasing power to
those who would use those resources to spend more and thus raise aggregate demand.
Since January 2008, total assets of the major central banks (which barely increased in
the previous decade, or increased only very sluggishly) went up from around $6.5
trillion to $16.9 trillion. Excluding assets held by the People’s Bank of China (much
of which are the foreign exchange reserves of the country) the assets held by all
central banks went up from just under $4 trillion to nearly $12 trillion (Source:
Central Bank Balance Sheets, www.yardeni.com).
The US Federal Reserve was the leader of that pack, as Chart 3 indicates. Further,
after the initial post-crisis increase, the fastest and largest increase in liquidity creation
by the US Fed took place in the third round of QE, between 2012 and 2014 well
after the so-called recovery was in place. The subsequent “tapering” of QE that
caused so much grief to emerging markets by instigating capital flight back to the US,
still left overall assets of the US Fed at unprecedented high levels.
4
Chart 3.
But this massive injection of liquidity has only just managed to maintain some
semblance of growth in the advanced economies. Meanwhile, many developing
countries and emerging markets are feeling the ill effects of their own credit bubbles
that they created in response to the global crisis, as credit to GDP ratios and non-
performing loans have risen sharply. This adds a further depressing element to the
already listless patterns of investment and consumption. Debt-fuelled expansion
cannot work anymore, yet policymakers everywhere seem to think that the more
sustainable and desirable option of increasing wage incomes is simply unacceptable.
It does indeed appear as if global capitalism is running out of options. This is why
“the new normal” may seem a bit like the old one, but in fact is much more
dangerous.
*This article was originally published in the Business Line on June 20, 2016.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any references for this publication.