ArticlePDF Available

Mutual Fund Arbitrage and Transaction Costs

Authors:
  • University of Maryland, College Park Robert H.Smith School of Business

Abstract

The 2003 mutual funds scandal that exploded upon the public revealed something that had long been known to insiders: Mutual fund advisers often approve and allow frequent trading, frequent trading arbitrage, and late trading arbitrage to selected traders. To increase adviser profits, fund advisers often require approved arbitrage traders to make “sticky asset” purchases of fund shares to “grow” fund assets. These costly mutual fund adviser practices increase transaction costs along several dimensions and lower current fund and shareholder assets, along with opportunity costs of dilution in fund share values and returns to long-term shareholders. Independent directors have either not been informed or have acquiesced in the decisions. In any case, independent directors have not performed their primary fiduciary duty as “shareholder watchdogs.”
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1419739
SUMMER 2009 THE JOURNAL OF INVESTING 57
“There is no hard line between arbitrage
and speculation: it is a continuum.
—Stephen A. Ross,
Franco Modigliani Professor
of Finance and Economics,
Sloan School of Management, MIT.
T
he Investment Company Act of
1940 (40Act) has not provided
essential protections for mutual fund
shareholders. Palmiter [2006] finds
that the 40Act’s “outsourcing” of key regulatory
functions to independent directors of funds has
also not lived up to the act’s expectations. These
independent directors have been weak and even
feckless protectors of fund shareholders and are
therefore not sufficiently aligned with share-
holder interests. The one thing dedicated inde-
pendent directors can do is perform as
effectively as possible given the act’s limitations.
The 40Act’s reliance on what has proven
to be insufficiently empowered mutual fund
independent directors is the most serious imped-
iment to effective oversight of fund advisers.
The 40Act does not give the SEC the task of
reviewing approvals by mutual fund indepen-
dent directors of management contracts and
marketing arrangements, but rather relies on
independent directors to oversee fees of fund
advisors and those of other service providers,
such as transfer agents. The SEC has also not
provided essential tools and disclosures that inde-
pendent directors need to be more effective.
By all logic, the 2003 mutual fund scan-
dals were not “out of the blue, but rather just
one, though a major, event in the pattern of
industry malfeasance toward shareholders that
has been seen in recent decades. Such behavior
was not anticipated under the 40Act, which
the fund industry has long “advertised” as
effectively protecting shareholder interests. The
claim was that under the act and SEC regula-
tion, there have been only a limited number
of individual fund scandals.
Then, in 2003, the fund industry’s
ongoing “rosy scenario” came to an abrupt
end, thanks to one brave mutual fund adviser
employee and an aggressive New York attorney
general. The scandal that exploded upon the
investing public revealed improper actions that
have long been well known to insiders. One
such behavior is advisers allowing market
timing in fund shares, which includes frequent
trading, frequent trading arbitrage, and late-
trading arbitrage. “Market timing” is rapid
roundtrip trading in fund shares made to
exploit pricing inefficiencies (mispriced shares).
Advisers with stated limits on frequent trading
in their prospectus also engage in this behavior.
Those mutual fund advisers who stated
limits on share redemptions would logically
not have done so if they knew frequent trading
was harmless to long-term shareholders. Why
place limits on redemptions? And, those
advisers who permitted frequent trading arbi-
trage (with or without stated limits) certainly
Mutual Fund Arbitrage
and Transaction Costs
JOHN A. HASLEM
JOHN A. HASLEM
is professor emeritus of
finance in the Robert H.
Smith School of Business at
the University of Maryland
in College Park.
jhaslem@rhsmith.umd.edu
IIJ-JOI-HASLEM:Layout 1 18-05-2009 15:31 Page 57
The Journal of Investing 2009.18.2:57-61. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by JOHN A HASLEM on 07/15/10.
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1419739
knew the practice profited them and harmed long-term
shareholders.
FREQUENT TRADING
Frequent trading is roundtrip “rapid trading” with
short holding periods by new and current mutual fund
shareholders. Investors often buy and sell based on short-
term forecasts of market or company developments. Rapid
trading is often limited in the prospectus to a set number
of roundtrip trades a year. Other funds work to limit fre-
quent trading by policy, monitoring, and redemption fees
for short-term trades.
Frequent trading presents a regulatory challenge
because it imposes higher transaction costs than do the
infrequent trades of long-term mutual fund shareholders,
but this higher cost is a matter of degree, not kind. The
issue is not just whether some fund investors trade more
frequently than others (and impose higher costs), but
whether there is a point at which subsidization of frequent
traders by long-term shareholders becomes egregious and
calls for regulatory reform. That point has been reached.
Mutual fund advisers are not required to limit fre-
quent trading, but if they do the limits must be stated in
the prospectus. For example, one fund’s prospectus states:
“You may not exchange your investment more than four
times in any 12-month period .” While many advisers
state limits, frequent trading has been approved and allowed
for select frequent traders.
In some cases, mutual fund advisers attempted to hedge
their stated limits on frequent trading by making them appear
as discretionary or only implied. For example, it might be
stated that frequent trading is “generally” limited, or that
“short-term” or “excessive” trading is not allowed. The
“catch” is in how advisers then interpreted these limits when
approving and allowing frequent trading to select traders.
In such cases, reference to internal documents may be needed
to determine the adviser’s real intent, but lack of shareholder
access is the problem. Another approach to determining the
adviser’s real intent is to assess how reasonable shareholders
would interpret their hedged statements.
It is useful to think of frequent trading and frequent
trading arbitrage (discussed below) as differing only in
that the latter generates larger mutual fund transaction
costs and lower current fund and shareholder assets, along
with opportunity costs of dilution in fund share values
and returns for long-term shareholders. The practice of
frequent trading (and frequent trading arbitrage) in funds
was widely known in the industry and to the SEC well
before the fund scandals were revealed.
FREQUENT TRADING ARBITRAGE
Approval and allowance of frequent trading arbi-
trage represents a major conflict of interest between mutual
fund advisers and shareholders. While fund advisers are
directly responsible for this practice, independent direc-
tors have failed to protect shareholder interests. But if
advisers do not inform independent directors of their
intentions, the burden rests with them.
In some cases, independent directors apparently
acquiesced when informed of the adviser’s decision to
allow frequent trading arbitrage. These directors were
often long-time friends and “golfing buddies” of the
adviser CEO, who often lack sufficient commitment,
expertise, and qualifications to protect the primary inter-
ests of shareholders. In addition, any independent director
tendencies to “go with the flow” might well be con-
sciously or subconsciously encouraged by their generous
pay and benefits. The lack of independence of “inde-
pendent” directors is an open secret in the funds industry.
But independent directors owe shareholders legal pro-
tections and comprehensive disclosure.
Despite the mutual fund scandal and SEC pressure,
fund advisers generally have not taken action to ensure that
fund closing prices reflect current market prices. Such
action would prevent profitable frequent trading arbitrage,
with larger transaction costs, lower current fund and share-
holder assets, and opportunity costs of dilution in fund
share values and returns for long-term shareholders.
This action requires that mutual fund holdings of for-
eign securities that close trading overseas before the domestic
4:00 p.m. market close be priced at the 4:00 p.m. close. To
do this, a valid and uniform “fair value” pricing system must
be applied to estimate the 4:00 p.m. closing values of for-
eign securities and securities without current market prices.
This inaction by many mutual fund advisers provides
a major conflict with shareholder interests. Frequent trading
arbitrage with larger transaction costs has lower current
fund and shareholder assets, along with opportunity costs
of dilution in fund share values and long-term shareholders.
These are not appropriate costs to long-term shareholders,
especially because they are not normally aware of them or
of their surprising costs. Further evidence of agency con-
flict is seen in the negative relation between dilution and
both expense ratios and number of insider board members.
58 MUTUAL FUND ARBITRAGE AND TRANSACTION COSTS SUMMER 2009
IIJ-JOI-HASLEM:Layout 1 18-05-2009 15:31 Page 58
The Journal of Investing 2009.18.2:57-61. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by JOHN A HASLEM on 07/15/10.
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
Mutual fund shareholders still await effective pro-
tection from frequent trading and late trading arbitrage.
However, it does not appear that arbitrage is high on the
SEC’s list of needed regulatory reforms. For example,
then-New York Attorney General Spitzer was first and
much more aggressive than the SEC in prosecuting
wrong-doers, as witnessed by the much larger amounts
won in direct and indirect damages.
TIME ZONE FREQUENT TRADING
ARBITRAGE
Time zone arbitrage is made possible by several
mutual fund, adviser, and market characteristics and actions.
First, fund shares traded during the day are priced at the
4:00 p.m. close of trading, which is called “forward pricing.
Second, the fund’s holdings of securities trading on Asian
exchanges, for example, are priced at their 3:00 a.m. Eastern
closing price when fund securities are priced at the
4:00 p.m. close. Third, prices of the foreign securities must
increase after their 3:00 a.m. Eastern close, but before the
fund’s 4:00 p.m. close. This price increase is caused by an
arbitrage event, such as announcements of expectedly high
earnings for the foreign securities. Fourth, the fund does
not use these increased prices to price the foreign shares
at the 4:00 p.m. close, but rather uses their 3:00 a.m. Eastern
closing prices at the close. The result is that fund shares are
not priced at their current market values at the 4:00 p.m.
close. Arbitrager share purchases during the trading day
are therefore priced at “discount prices” at the close. Fifth,
fund advisers allow arbitragers to “rapid trade” by per-
mitting them flexibility in holding periods (usually short
ones, such as one trading day) and frequency of roundtrip
trades (usually ongoing). Rapid trading allows arbitragers
to generate abnormal assets over very short periods of
time. Frequent trading also reduces arbitrager risk by aver-
aging the outcomes of individual roundtrip trades.
Frequent trading arbitrage thus involves the purchase
of mutual fund shares at “stale” closing prices below their
current market values. Arbitragers do not create the oppor-
tunity to buy fund shares at bargain prices, but by their
actions they attempt to take advantage of share mispricing.
MECHANICS OF TIME ZONE FREQUENT
TRADING ARBITRAGE
An example by Bullard [2006] of the mechanics of
frequent trading arbitrage indicates how dilution occurs
and dollar amounts. As discussed, arbitrage trading involves
buying fund shares priced below their current market
value at the close of trading. Arbitrage trades are often
made in funds holding securities trading on Asian
exchanges, which close at 3:00 a.m. Eastern. The fund
uses the 3:00 a.m. Eastern closing prices of the Asian secu-
rities when it prices all securities at the 4:00 p.m. close.
Arbitragers can then sell the fund shares at a profit the
next trading day, when the current market prices of all
fund securities will be incorporated into the 4:00 p.m.
closing prices, all else remaining the same.
An example of the mechanics of time zone arbi-
trage provides insight on the amount of dilution created
by one such arbitrage roundtrip trade. To illustrate this
process, assume there are nine mutual fund shareholders
holding one share each. These nine shares are each priced
at $10.00 at the 4:00 p.m. closing and provide a fund total
value of $90.00. At the 4:00 p.m. close, the fund’s share
price reflects the 3:00 a.m. Eastern closing prices of its
foreign securities holdings, but not the arbitrage event’s
subsequent increase in prices of these securities following
their 3:00 a.m. Eastern close. That same day, arbitragers
note the price increase in the fund’s holdings of Asian
securities and purchase one fund share priced at $10.00
at the close. The fund’s total value is now $100.00 with
10 shares. However, the fund’s total market value based
on the arbitrage event is actually $110.00, or $11.00 per
share, at the 4:00 p.m. close.
The next day, the current market prices of the fund’s
foreign securities are included in its 4:00 p.m. closing price
of $11.00, all else having remained the same. That same
day, the arbitrager redeems his fund share at the closing
price of $11.00. This redemption reduces the fund’s arbi-
trage-event total market value of $110.00 to $99.00. The
arbitrager’s share with a cost basis of $10.00 sold for $11.00
and generated an arbitrage profit of $1.00.
The fund’s stale total closing price of $100.00 on
day one has gone to a current total closing price of $99.00
on day two. The current loss of $1.00 in fund and share-
holder assets approximates $0.11 per share, along with
opportunity costs of dilution in fund share values and
returns for long-term shareholders.
LATE TRADING ARBITRAGE
Late trading arbitrage can occur when mutual fund
advisers illegally approve and allow selected traders to pur-
chase fund shares after the market close, but priced at
SUMMER 2009 THE JOURNAL OF INVESTING 59
IIJ-JOI-HASLEM:Layout 1 18-05-2009 15:31 Page 59
The Journal of Investing 2009.18.2:57-61. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by JOHN A HASLEM on 07/15/10.
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
4:00 p.m. closing prices. This opportunity allows traders
to take advantage of “arbitrage events” in fund portfolio
prices that occur after the 4:00 p.m. close. Traders then
buy shares at what are after the 4:00 p.m. close effectively
discounted closing prices, and then sell the shares soon
thereafter for abnormal profits. Arbitrager profits are earned
at the expense of current fund and shareholder assets,
along with opportunity costs of dilution in fund share
values and returns for long-term shareholders.
Mutual fund adviser allowance of late trading arbi-
trage represents a serious unethical and illegal conflict of
interest with fund shareholders. Fund advisers are directly
responsible for approving and allowing this egregious prac-
tice, and independent fund directors have failed to halt it.
But, if independent directors are uninformed, due to no fault
of their own, then the burden rests fully with fund advisers.
However, there are cases where mutual fund advisers
may not be aware of late trading of their fund shares. Tra-
ditionally, advisers have attempted to limit late trading
only through fees and monitoring, but late trading is often
“hidden” in the total of fund trades executed by financial
intermediaries, such as brokerage firms. Financial inter-
mediaries have traditionally “packaged” late trades and
reported them to funds after the 4:00 p.m. close. Efforts
to require all such trades to be reported by a “hard”
4:00 p.m. close should keep advisers informed of fund
late trading allowed by financial intermediaries.
The costs of late trading arbitrage are not inconse-
quential. Following the 2003 mutual funds scandal, Zitze-
witz [2006] found late trading was three times greater in
fund families charged for late trading, and greater in funds
and asset classes that also received heavy “stale price” fre-
quent trading arbitrage inflows. Further, evidence of late
trading arbitrage was statistically significant in 39 out of
66 fund families, and this trend has been corroborated
subsequently by regulators. Late trading arbitrage was
found to be a “stand-alone” strategy, but always paired
with frequent trading arbitrage.
Late trading diluted average annual assets of long-
term shareholders in international and domestic equity
funds by 3.8 and 0.9 basis points, respectively. If similar
dilution rates prevailed in the funds industry, shareholder
losses would be $400 million per year. Initially, this finding
shocked fund observers, but it is a small figure compared
to losses from frequent trading arbitrage.
However, mutual fund shareholder losses from late
trading arbitrage are smaller than those in “soft dollar”
trades. These trades have very high brokerage commissions
and likely higher trading costs, and are often excessively
transacted to benefit brokers and advisers. Brokers partially
rebate their soft-dollar trade commissions to advisers in the
form of in-kind payments of investment products and ser-
vices. Soft-dollar trades reflect important adviser agency
conflicts with shareholders and deserve regulatory reform.
FREQUENT TRADING AND LATE TRADING
ARBITRAGE: SHAREHOLDER IMPLICATIONS
Mutual fund independent directors have the pri-
mary legal responsibility of representing shareholder inter-
ests as primary. However, when advisers fail to inform or
to seek approval of independent directors for approval of
frequent trading arbitrage (the discussion in this section
applies also to late trading arbitrage), directors are not able
to perform their mandate as “shareholder watchdogs.
The mutual fund adviser may provide selected large-
size frequent trading arbitragers with more frequent port-
folio information than is provided to long-term shareholders.
The improper sharing of this information distorts normal
fund management and strategies. The practice may lower
current fund and shareholder assets, along with opportunity
costs of dilution in fund share values and returns for long-
term shareholders.
Mutual fund advisers, by not informing indepen-
dent directors of the approval and allowance of large-size
frequent trading arbitrage, also fail to report frequent
trading to the SEC. And, neither do advisers disclose these
transactions to long-term shareholders, which defers them
from possibly selling their shares. Frequent trading arbi-
trage with larger transaction costs requires larger cash
holdings with lower current fund and shareholder assets,
along with opportunity costs of dilution in fund share
values and returns for long-term shareholders.
Mutual fund advisers’ allowance of especially large-
size frequent trading arbitrage requires larger and more fre-
quent purchases and sales (turnover) of portfolio securities
to meet trader transactions. These larger trades distort
normal fund management and strategies, and possibly
create additional fund trading errors. The resulting higher
costs lower current fund and shareholder assets, along with
opportunity costs of dilution in fund share values and
returns for long-term shareholders.
Mutual fund advisers’ allowance of especially large-
size frequent trading arbitrage also requires additional
administrative mechanisms (by all parties to arbitrage
capacities) that include processing, capacity negotiations,
60 MUTUAL FUND ARBITRAGE AND TRANSACTION COSTS SUMMER 2009
IIJ-JOI-HASLEM:Layout 1 18-05-2009 15:31 Page 60
The Journal of Investing 2009.18.2:57-61. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by JOHN A HASLEM on 07/15/10.
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
communications, record-keeping, and account monitoring.
These higher costs also lower current fund and shareholder
assets, along with opportunity costs of dilution in fund
share values and returns for long-term shareholders.
Mutual fund adviser fee payments to “facilitator bro-
kers” who negotiate and arrange frequent trading arbitrage
“capacities” with large traders increase fund costs. These
higher broker costs lower current fund and shareholder
assets, along with opportunity costs of dilution in fund
share values and returns for long-term shareholders.
The mutual fund adviser normally requires frequent
trading arbitragers to provide “sticky assets with their
timing capacities. These requirements increase fund assets
(often in funds with high expense ratios) and increase cur-
rent fund and shareholder assets, along with larger fund
share values and returns for long-term shareholders.
However, larger mutual fund transactions from fre-
quent trading arbitrage increase trade size and increasingly
subsume fund economies of scale from increasing asset size.
This occurs when the size of trades goes beyond recouping
trading costs. Edelen, Davis, and Kadlec [2007] find that
the scale effects of increased trade size are the primary cause
of subsuming mutual fund economies of scale. This nega-
tive impact on fund assets is not hard to understand, with
transaction costs frequently exceeding expense ratios.
Mutual fund advisers’ allowance of especially large-
size frequent trading arbitrage generates larger and more
frequent fund purchases and sales of portfolio securities
(higher turnover) to meet trader transactions. The larger
and more frequent trades have a negative impact on share-
holder taxes, with larger taxable capital gains distributions
to long-term shareholders and lower after-tax assets.
For additional insights into the issues discussed, see
Birdthistle [2006], Bullard [2006], Edelen, Davis, and
Kadlec [2007], Gil-Bazo and Ruiz-Verda [2008], Greene
and Ciccotello [2006], Haslem [2008], Palmiter [2006], and
Zitzewitz [2003 and 2006].
CONCLUSION
The 2003 mutual funds scandal that exploded upon
the public revealed something that had long been known
to insiders: Mutual fund advisers often approve and allow
frequent trading, frequent trading arbitrage, and late trading
arbitrage to selected traders. To increase adviser profits, fund
advisers often require approved arbitrage traders to make
“sticky asset” purchases of fund shares to “grow” fund assets.
These costly mutual fund adviser practices increase
transaction costs along several dimensions and lower cur-
rent fund and shareholder assets, along with opportunity
costs of dilution in fund share values and returns to long-
term shareholders. Independent directors have either not
been informed or have acquiesced in the decisions. In any
case, independent directors have not performed their pri-
mary fiduciary duty as “shareholder watchdogs.
REFERENCES
Birdthistle, William A. “Compensating Power: An Analysis of
Rents and Rewards in the Mutual Fund Industry.Tulane Law
Review, 80 (2006), pp. 1401–1465.
Bullard, Mercer E. “The Mutual Fund as a Firm: Frequent
Trading, Fund Arbitrage and the SEC’s Response to the Mutual
Fund Scandal.Houston Law Review, Vol. 42, No. 5 (Spring
2006), pp. 1271–1332.
Edelen, Roger M., Richard B. Davis, and Gregory B. Kadlec.
“Scale Effects in Mutual Fund Performance: The Role of
Trading Costs.” Working Paper, SSRN, March 17, 2007.
Gil-Bazo, Javier and Pablo Ruiz-Verda. “The Relation Between
Price and Performance in the Mutual Fund Industry. Working
Paper, SSRN, March 3, 2008.
Greene, Jason T., and Conrad S. Ciccotello. “Mutual Fund Dilu-
tion from Market Trading Trades.” Journal of Investment Man-
agement, Vol. 4, No. 2 (First Quarter 2006), pp. 36–54.
Haslem, John A. “Mutual Funds: Why Have Independent Direc-
tors Failed as Shareholder Watchdogs?” Working Paper, SSRN,
July 30, 2008.
Palmiter, Alan R. “Mutual Fund Boards: A Failed Experiment
in Regulatory Outsourcing.Brooklyn Journal of Corporate, Finan-
cial and Commercial Law, 1 (2006), pp. 161–205.
Zitzewitz, Eric. “Who Cares About Shareholders? Arbitrage
Proofing Funds. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization,
Vol. 19, No. 2 (October 2003), pp. 245–280.
——. “How Widespread Was Late Trading in Mutual Funds?”
American Economic Review, Vol. 96, No. 2 (May 2006), pp. 284–289.
To order reprints of this article, please contact Dewey Palmieri at
dpalmieri@iijournals.com or 212-224-3675.
SUMMER 2009 THE JOURNAL OF INVESTING 61
IIJ-JOI-HASLEM:Layout 1 18-05-2009 15:31 Page 61
The Journal of Investing 2009.18.2:57-61. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by JOHN A HASLEM on 07/15/10.
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
... fund economies of scale. The vast majority of the above issues are detailed in Haslem (2009a, 2009b ...
Article
Full-text available
There are four basic reasons why mutual fund independent directors have failed in their roles as shareholder watchdogs under the Investment Company Act of 1940. The first reason is the 40Act’s flawed regulatory structure that insufficiently empowers independent directors to meet their fiduciary responsibilities under the Act. The Act in fact outsources oversight of fund advisers to independent directors, but fails to empower them adequately through direct adviser oversight by the SEC. The SEC thus relies on independent directors to oversee fund advisers and protect shareholder interests. But the lack of effective adviser oversight (including director acquiescence and ignorance) has led to numerous improper practices that conflict with fund shareholder interests. The second reason mutual fund independent directors have failed to be effective shareholder watchdogs reflects the often flawed structure of fund boards. The 40Act gives independent directors a specified set of responsibilities, the primary ones being approval of fund advisory fee contracts and contracts with other service providers. Research has shown significant relationships between size of fund advisory fees and number of independent directors, the number of independent directors relative to the total number of fund directors, and percentage of adviser’s fund and other fund assets subject to director oversight. The third reason for failure of mutual fund independent directors to act as shareholder watchdogs is the failure of the 40Act and the SEC to provide for normative transparency of disclosure of adviser practices. Normative disclosure is essential for directors and certainly shareholders to be able to monitor adviser practices. This is a very important issue, as there are numerous generally hidden adviser conflicts of interest that reduce shareholder assets and returns. If Congress and the SEC were to require wide-ranging and detailed normative transparency of disclosure, much of what is needed in improved regulation, including the ability of independent directors to perform as effective shareholder watchdogs, would be provided. The fourth reason why mutual fund independent directors are not effective shareholder watchdogs is that until 2009 no Circuit Court of Appeals has ruled for fund shareholder plaintiffs in cases of excessive advisory fees. In 1982, the Second Circuit Court in Gartenberg left effective oversight of excess advisory fees to assumed (incorrectly so) arms-length negotiations between advisers and independent directors, based on the (incorrect) assumption that fund markets are price-competitive with rational investors. The 2008 Seventh Circuit’s decision in Jones et al. v. Harrris Associates rejected the legal foundation in the Gartenberg decision, but it also made it more difficult for mutual fund shareholders to petition courts successfully in cases of excessive advisory fees. However, the differing circuit court decisions plus a vociferous dissent by a leading judge in Jones apparently led the Supreme Court to accept this case in its Fall 2009 term. Mutual fund investors will be greatly and properly served if the Supreme Court finds that adviser Harris Associates charged its Oakmark mutual fund shareholders excessive advisory fees. The court will also have a 2009 Eighth Circuit decision to consider—the first to find for fund shareholders in a petition of excessive advisory fees. Without relief from the Supreme Court, mutual fund shareholders must continue to depend on inadequately empowered, motivated, and informed independent directors to do what they can as shareholder watchdogs. This would be a sad commentary given the laundry list of self-serving adviser practices, such as excessive advisory fees, that reduce shareholder assets and returns.
Chapter
This chapter looks at the economic, technical, and regulatory issues of asset management products, with particular attention paid to collective investment vehicles. Investment fund classification and the alternative legal structures (common funds, open-end investment companies, unit trusts) for conducting collective portfolio management are examined. Management strategies and the choice between active management and indexed management are also investigated. Restrictions to investment policies, public documentation, and charges of investment funds are explored, assuming the perspective of European Union investors. The final part of the chapter examines other types of asset management products, like individual portfolio management, investment-oriented insurance policies, and structured products, which have a high rate of substitutability with investment funds and represent their natural competitors.
Chapter
This chapter looks at the economic, technical and regulatory issues of asset management products, with particular attention paid to collective investment vehicles. Investment fund classification and the alternative legal structures (common funds, open-end investment companies, unit trusts) for conducting collective portfolio management are examined. Management strategies and the choice between active management and indexed management are also investigated. Restrictions to investment policies, public documentation and charges of investment funds are explored, assuming the perspective of a European Union investor. The final part of the chapter examines other types of asset management products, like individual portfolio management, investment-oriented insurance policies and structured products, which have a high rate of substitutability with investment funds and represent their natural competitors.
Chapter
Full-text available
The Investment Company Act of 1940 states that the interests of shareholders are compromised when mutual funds are operated in the interest of fund managers. In this regard, one of the Act's major objectives is to ensure investors receive adequate and accurate information. For this reason, Congress, the SEC. individual funds, and the fund industry must focus on the goal of requiring and attaining normative transparency of disclosure. Normative transparency of disclosure is defined as the degree of mutual fund voluntary and proactive disclosure and also new and revised legal and regulatory disclosure required for shareholders to be able to make information efficient fund investment decisions. The attainment of normative transparency of disclosure requires major changes and prohibitions in current fund practices, laws, and regulation that are inconsistent with or contrary to this goal. If Congress and the SEC were to enact and require, respectively, laws and regulations requiring normative transparency of disclosure, these mandates would be all that should be required. While additional laws and regulatory disclosure are likely to be forthcoming, it is most unlikely that the political process will achieve normative transparency. However, the political obstacles are much more likely to be overcome if individual mutual funds and funds collectively work vigorously and proactively in cooperation with Congress and the SEC. Thus, the achievement of normative transparency of disclosure requires mutual fund managers and independent directors to work vigorously, proactively, and collectively to achieve this goal. However, it is also highly unlikely that these efforts will be collectively optimized as normatively transparent. Further, what is normative transparency of disclosure today will evolve over time as individual fund, fund industry, shareholder, and legal and regulatory conditions change. Thus, there is need to continually benchmark normative transparency in order to maintain normative and improve fund disclosure. The goal of normative transparency disclosure at the fund level requires stated prohibition of inappropriate fund and fund industry practices and actions, including those permitted by regulations, such as 12b-1 fees, soft dollars, and revenue sharing. Further, it requires supplementary disclosure of those regulations that currently provide incorrect accounting, incomplete, missing, misleading and perfunctory disclosure. To attain normative transparency of disclosure, mutual fund managers and independent directors must begin by voluntarily and collectively becoming vigorously proactive in serving and protecting shareholders. But, the initial move towards this goal, pending action by Congress, the SEC, fund managers and the fund industry, rests with proactively motivated independent directors empowered to pursue vigorously their fiduciary mandate of shareholder "watchdogs."
Article
Full-text available
There are four basic reasons why mutual fund independent directors have failed in their roles as shareholder watchdogs under the Investment Company Act of 1940. The first reason is the 40Act’s flawed regulatory structure that insufficiently empowers independent directors to meet their fiduciary responsibilities under the Act. The Act in fact outsources oversight of fund advisers to independent directors, but fails to empower them adequately through direct adviser oversight by the SEC. The SEC thus relies on independent directors to oversee fund advisers and protect shareholder interests. But the lack of effective adviser oversight (including director acquiescence and ignorance) has led to numerous improper practices that conflict with fund shareholder interests. The second reason mutual fund independent directors have failed to be effective shareholder watchdogs reflects the often flawed structure of fund boards. The 40Act gives independent directors a specified set of responsibilities, the primary ones being approval of fund advisory fee contracts and contracts with other service providers. Research has shown significant relationships between size of fund advisory fees and number of independent directors, the number of independent directors relative to the total number of fund directors, and percentage of adviser’s fund and other fund assets subject to director oversight. The third reason for failure of mutual fund independent directors to act as shareholder watchdogs is the failure of the 40Act and the SEC to provide for normative transparency of disclosure of adviser practices. Normative disclosure is essential for directors and certainly shareholders to be able to monitor adviser practices. This is a very important issue, as there are numerous generally hidden adviser conflicts of interest that reduce shareholder assets and returns. If Congress and the SEC were to require wide-ranging and detailed normative transparency of disclosure, much of what is needed in improved regulation, including the ability of independent directors to perform as effective shareholder watchdogs, would be provided. The fourth reason why mutual fund independent directors are not effective shareholder watchdogs is that until 2009 no Circuit Court of Appeals has ruled for fund shareholder plaintiffs in cases of excessive advisory fees. In 1982, the Second Circuit Court in Gartenberg left effective oversight of excess advisory fees to assumed (incorrectly so) arms-length negotiations between advisers and independent directors, based on the (incorrect) assumption that fund markets are price-competitive with rational investors. The 2008 Seventh Circuit’s decision in Jones et al. v. Harrris Associates rejected the legal foundation in the Gartenberg decision, but it also made it more difficult for mutual fund shareholders to petition courts successfully in cases of excessive advisory fees. However, the differing circuit court decisions plus a vociferous dissent by a leading judge in Jones apparently led the Supreme Court to accept this case in its Fall 2009 term. Mutual fund investors will be greatly and properly served if the Supreme Court finds that adviser Harris Associates charged its Oakmark mutual fund shareholders excessive advisory fees. The court will also have a 2009 Eighth Circuit decision to consider—the first to find for fund shareholders in a petition of excessive advisory fees. Without relief from the Supreme Court, mutual fund shareholders must continue to depend on inadequately empowered, motivated, and informed independent directors to do what they can as shareholder watchdogs. This would be a sad commentary given the laundry list of self-serving adviser practices, such as excessive advisory fees, that reduce shareholder assets and returns.
Article
Full-text available
Since September 2003, the U.S. mutual fund industry has been mired in the worst scandal in its 65-year history. The scandal has produced in excess of 40 civil and criminal prosecutions, more than 2billioninmonetarysanctions,numerousCongressionalhearingsandbills,andabevyofnewregulations.Fundmanagersroutinelypermittedinstitutionaltraderstoengageinfundarbitragebyallowingthearbitrageurstobuyfundsharesatadiscountandredeemthemoncethepricehadbeencorrected,withthetradersprofitscomingdirectlyoutofthepocketsofotherfundshareholders.TheSecuritiesandCommissionhasfundamentallymisperceivedthenatureofthescandal,however,infocusing(1)itsenforcementeffortsonthefrequenttradingoffundshares,ratherthanonfundarbitrage,and(2)itsrulemakingonhowfundsharesarepurchased,ratherthanonhowtheyarepriced.TheSECsfocusoncrosssubsidizationcausedbyfrequenttradingmayunderminetheviabilityofthemutualfundasacooperativeenterprise,orfirm,whileshareholderscontinuetobevulnerabletodilutionoftheirinvestmentsbyarbitrageurs.With2 billion in monetary sanctions, numerous Congressional hearings and bills, and a bevy of new regulations. Fund managers routinely permitted institutional traders to engage in fund arbitrage by allowing the arbitrageurs to buy fund shares at a discount and redeem them once the price had been corrected, with the traders' profits coming directly out of the pockets of other fund shareholders. The Securities and Commission has fundamentally misperceived the nature of the scandal, however, in focusing (1) its enforcement efforts on the frequent trading of fund shares, rather than on fund arbitrage, and (2) its rulemaking on how fund shares are purchased, rather than on how they are priced. The SEC's focus on cross-subsidization caused by frequent trading may undermine the viability of the mutual fund as a cooperative enterprise, or firm, while shareholders continue to be vulnerable to dilution of their investments by arbitrageurs. With 8.1 trillion in assets, mutual funds are Americans' investment vehicle of choice, and the creation of private Social Security accounts may further cement their dominant position in the financial services industry. The Commission should reverse course by strengthening pricing rules and withdrawing rules that interfere with the market's efficient regulation of cross-subsidization among mutual fund shareholders.
Article
This paper introduces a model to measure the dilution impact on an open-end fund due to market timing trades. When a timer buys shares of a fund just prior to positive returns, the extra cash in the fund dilutes the fund's return. While this impact can be directly measured on the day after a timer's purchase, the impact on subsequent days depends on whether the fund's cash balance remains distorted. Our model offers a framework that allows the timer's holding period and the portfolio manager's treatment of cash flows to inform an accurate calculation of the dilution impact.
Article
The allegations of malfeasance in the investment management industry - market timing, late trading, revenue sharing, and several others - involve a broad range of mutual fund operations. This Article seeks to explain the common source of these irregularities by focusing upon a trait they share: the practice of investment advisers' capitalizing upon their managerial influence to increase assets under management in order to generate greater fees from those assets. This Article extends theories of executive compensation into the context of investment management to understand the extraction of rents by mutual fund advisers. Investment advisers, as collective groups of portfolio managers, interact with the boards of trustees of mutual funds in ways analogous to the dealings of business executives with corporate boards of directors. In this setting, the managerial power hypothesis of executive compensation provides a useful paradigm for understanding distortions in arm's-length bargaining between investment advisers and fund boards, as well as limitations of the market's ability to ensure optimal contracting between those parties.
Article
Berk and Green (2004) argue that investment inflow at high-performing mutual funds eliminates return persistence because fund managers face diminishing returns to scale. Our study examines the role of trading costs as a source of diseconomies of scale for mutual funds. We estimate annual trading costs for a large sample of equity funds and find that they are comparable in magnitude to the expense ratio; that they have higher cross-sectional variation that is related to fund trade size; and that they have an increasingly detrimental impact on performance as the fund's relative trade size increases. Moreover, relative trade size subsumes fund size in regressions of fund returns, which suggests that trading costs are the primary source of diseconomies of scale for funds.
Article
The Investment Company Act of 1940 anticipated mutual fund boards would remedy a dysfunctional market of fund investors. Rather than the SEC, the fund board (and its independent members) would regulate the conflicts between fund investors and management firms by negotiating the management contract, approving advisory fees and other expenses, and generally serving as a regulatory compliance office.The fund board has not fulfilled its promise. A large and uniform body of empirical studies in the finance literature finds the fund board has failed as outsourced regulator. As fund families have grown, economies of scale have redounded mostly to management firms, not investors. Negotiation of most management contracts has been perfunctory, with boards passively accepting management-proposed fee levels, sales expenses, and marketing programs. Investors find little protection from other quarters. The SEC has generally assumed that fund boards, with periodic infusions of more outside members, are working. The courts have viewed management services and fees as beyond their purview. The current investor market has responded only marginally to high fund fees, return-sapping portfolio turnover, and the misleading marketing of past fund performance.Other investment intermediaries, such as hedge funds and mutual funds outside the United States, do not use boards. Alternatives to board oversight through invigorated SEC and judicial standards, along with more investor education and investor-appropriate disclosure, merit consideration. The illusion of investor protection by a docile watchdog may be worse than no protection at all.
Article
Gruber (1996) drew attention to the puzzle that investors buy actively managed equity mutual funds, even though on average such funds underperform index funds. We uncover another puzzling fact about the market for equity mutual funds: Funds with worse before-fee performance charge higher fees. This negative relation between fees and performance is robust and can be explained as the outcome of strategic fee-setting by mutual funds in the presence of investors with different degrees of sensitivity to performance. We also find some evidence that better fund governance may bring fees more in line with performance. Copyright (c) 2009 the American Finance Association.
Article
Business connections can mitigate agency conflicts by facilitating efficient information transfers, but can also be channels for inefficient favoritism. I analyze these two effects in the mutual fund industry and find that fund directors and advisory firms that manage the funds hire each other preferentially based on the intensity of their past interactions. I do not find evidence that stronger board-advisor ties correspond to better or worse outcomes for fund shareholders. These results suggest that the two effects of board-management connections on investor welfare—improved monitoring and increased potential for collusion—balance out in this setting. Publicado
Article
As is becoming increasingly widely known, mutual funds often calculate their net asset values (NAVs) using stale prices, which causes their daily returns to be predictable. By trading on this predictability, investors can earn 35--70% per year in international funds and 10--25% in asset classes such as small-cap equity and high-yield and convertible bonds. These abnormal returns come at the expense of long-term shareholders, dilution of whom has grown in international funds from 56 basis points in 1998--99 to 114 basis points in 2001. Despite these losses and pressure from the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), the vast majority of funds are not market-updating their prices to eliminate NAV predictability and dilution, but are instead pursuing solutions that are only partly effective. The speed and efficacy of a fund's actions to protect shareholders from dilution is negatively correlated with its expense ratios and the share of insiders on its board, suggesting that agency problems may be the root cause of the arbitrage problem. Copyright 2003, Oxford University Press.