ArticlePDF Available

Value-chain analysis of Egyptian aquaculture

Authors:
  • Poseidon Aquatic Resource Management Limited
  • Central Lab for Aquacultre Research (CLAR) - ARC Egypt

Abstract and Figures

Value-Chain Analysis of Egyptian Aquaculture Graeme Macfadyen , Ahmed Mohamed Nasr Allah , Diaa Abdel Reheem Kenawy , Mohamed Fathi Mohamed Ahmed , Hussien Hebicha , Ahmed Diab , Samy Mohmed Hussein , Ramadan Mohamed Abouzied , and Gamal el Naggar . Executive Summary Egypt’s aquaculture production (705,490 tonnes in 2009) is by far the largest of any African country and places it 11th in terms of global production. The aquaculture sector makes a significant contribution to income, employment creation and food security in the country, all of which are national priority areas given low per capita income levels, rising population, worsening food security indicators, and official unemployment levels which have remained at around 10% for the last ten years. Despite the fact that the aquaculture sector in Egypt is now a mature one, having developed over a period of more than 30 years, the economic performance of the sector is not well understood or documented. To help improve this understanding this report presents the outputs of a value-chain study for the sector. The study focused on four of the most important governorates in terms of aquaculture production: Kafr el Sheikh, Behera, Sharkia, and Fayoum. Individual interviews and focus group discussions with fish farmers, traders/wholesalers, and retailers, were used to collect quantitative and qualitative information about financial performance, employment creation, and the critical factors impacting on the performance of each sub-sector of the value-chain. The farmed fish value-chain in Egypt is strongly based on the production of tilapia, with mullet a key second species, and with small quantities of carp and catfish also contributing to farm production. Some key features of the value-chain are that: • There are virtually no exports of farmed fish, and so the value-chain is a short and simple one compared to aquaculture value-chains in some other countries; • There is no processing at all of farmed fish i.e. all fish is sold in whole form, with no value-addition either through primary processing into fillets or into other secondary processed products (e.g. ready meals, etc); • Most fish are sold either fresh on ice (in summer months or if sales are made far from farms) or fresh with no ice (in winter months and/or if sales are made close to farms). There is a growing trend however for the sale of live tilapia, motivated by the fact that fish prices have fallen in real terms over the last ten years and higher prices can be achieved for live product; • There is a very short time-period from harvest to final consumption by the consumer (due to the live/fresh nature of all sales), and very low rates (<1%) of post-harvest losses (which is in contrast to many wild fisheries value-chains in developing countries); and • Direct employment creation throughout the value-chain is significant, at around 14 full-time equivalents for every 100 tonnes of fish produced and sold. This employment is fairly evenly divided between those over and under 30 years of age, and is mostly accounted for by men, although some female employment is created in the retail sub-sector. Considerable additional indirect employment creation results from sector activity through jobs created through the production of inputs used by the value-chain i.e. jobs in feed mills, hatcheries, ice plants, suppliers of vehicles, water pumps and generators, building contractors, and manufacturers of boxes used during transport. Constructing costs and earnings models for each link in the value chain, allows for a comparison across the various sub-sectors, and for performance to be assessed both individually in each governorate and across all governorates. Some key findings from the data analysis made possible by the fieldwork completed during the study are: • Fish farmers obtain a high percentage (72%) of the final consumer price, due to the lack of any exports, the short-supply chain, and the lack of value-addition in the value-chain; • The average total production cost across all fish-farms is LE 7,769/tonne. This represents the break-even weighted sales price i.e. the average price of all fish sold by a farm must be more than LE 7,769/tonne if the farm is to make a profit; • Feed costs represent a very high percentage in all governorates of operational costs for the farming sub-sector (67% of operational costs); • Operational costs represent a very high percentage of total costs for all sub-sectors in the value-chain i.e. fixed are relatively small; • In the farming sub-sector operational profits are 29% of sales and net profits 22% of sales. Corresponding figures for the trader/wholesaler sub-sector are 4.1% and 3.9%, and for the retail sub-sector are 7.1% and 6.8%; and • Operational profits generated throughout the value-chain are LE 4,460/tonne of fish produced/sold, net profits are LE 3,736/tonne, and value-added (net profits plus wage earnings) is LE 4,619/tonne, with the farming sub-sector contributing more than 60% of total profits/value-added for all of these indicators. While the above figures confirm that the industry is sustainable and generates considerable profits and employment, this study suggests that the sector as a whole is under increasing financial pressure. Critical factors facing the sector and impacting on profitability, can be grouped into those related to inputs, those related to production, and those related to the marketing, transportation and sale of product. With regards to inputs the price and quality of fish feed have had a critical impact on costs and profits. Prices have risen by 200-250% over the last 7 years. The poor quality of fish fry, lack of available land for expansion in many governorates and short lease periods, poor quality of water, lack of access to capital, and the lack of electricity and high fuel costs for generators and vehicles, are all additional problems of considerable importance. At the production level, critical factors affecting value-chain performance are: poor practices with regards to feed management, farm design and construction, fish health management, and stocking densities; a growing season which is restricted to about 8 months due to the colder weather in the winter months; absence of improved strains of fish that been shown to have major impacts on production in other countries; and a widespread lack of effective representative organisations for any of the sub-sectors. With regards to the marketing and distribution of fish, the study showed that critical factors are: declining fish prices in real terms; consumer preference for wild fish and a distrust of filleted/processed products; strongly fluctuating seasonal prices (with declines in prices towards the end of the year coinciding with the major harvesting period); poor fish hygiene and handling practices throughout the value-chain; the lack of any value-addition through processing; the lack of any exports; and in some cases poor road networks impacting on the ability to get fish to markets. This report provides a large number of recommendations for support to the aquaculture sector in Egypt, which flow directly from these challenges and critical factors. Some of the necessary actions should be the responsibility of the sector itself, some the responsibility of government, and some the responsibility of donors and NGOs. What is clear is that for meaningful improvements in value-chain performance, substantial action and investments will be needed by many stakeholders. Citation of this report is : Macfadyen, G et al. 2011. Value Chain Analysis of Egyptian Aquaculture. Project Report 2011- 54. The WorldFish Center. Penang, Malaysia. 84 pp.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Value-chain analysis An assessment methodology to estimate Egyptian
aquaculture sector performance
Graeme Macfadyen , Ahmed Mohamed Nasr-Alla
1
, Diaa AlKenawy
1
, Mohamed Fathi
1
, Hussien Hebicha
1
,
Ahmed Mohammed Diab
1
, Samy Mohmed Hussein
1
, Ramadan Mohamed Abou-Zeid
1
, Gamal El-Naggar
1
The WorldFish Center, Abbassa, Abou Hammad, Sharkia 44662, Egypt
abstractarticle info
Article history:
Received 15 December 2011
Received in revised form 11 April 2012
Accepted 21 May 2012
Available online 20 July 2012
Keywords:
Value-chain analysis
Egypt
Aquaculture
Tilapia
Egypt's aquaculture production (705,490 tonnes in 2009) is by far the largest of any African country and
places it 11th in terms of global aquaculture production. The aquaculture sector in Egypt is now a mature
one having developed over a period of more than 30 years, but the nancial performance of the sector is
not well understood or documented, even though value-chain analysis provides a methodological tool to
do so. To provide a better understanding of the sector, a WorldFish Center study completed in September
2011 and funded by the Swiss Agency for Development and Cooperation, conducted a value-chain analysis
of the pond sh farming sector. The sector concentrates on the production of tilapia with additional produc-
tion of mullet, catsh and carp from earthen ponds. The study mapped the value-chain and showed that there
is no processing and virtually no export of farmed sh, a short time-period from harvest to nal consumption
by the consumer (typically around one day) due to the live/fresh nature of all sales, and very low rates (b1%)
of post-harvest losses. Quantitative data were collected for each link in the value-chain on operational and
nancial performance (e.g. gross output values, variable and xed costs, operational and net prot margins,
value-added generation), and on employment creation (by gender, age and full-time/part-time). The results
showed that theindustry generates a combined LE 4619 ($775) of value-added (i.e. prots plus wages/earnings)
for farmers,traders and retailers for each tonne of sh produced. Employment generation is also signicant with
around 14 full-time equivalent jobs generated for every 100 tonnes of sh produced. However, the sector as a
whole is under increasing nancial pressure. Critical factors impacting on the performance of the
value-chain relate to inputs (most importantly to rising feed costs and the poor quality of fry), to production
(most importantly to poor practices with regard to feed management, farm design and construction, sh
health management, and stocking densities), and to the marketing, transportation and sale of product
(most importantly to declining sh prices in real terms, consumer preference for wild sh and a distrust
of lleted/processed products, uctuating seasonal prices, poor hygiene and handling practices, the lack
of value-addition through processing, and the lack of exports). This paper highlights the benets of
value-chain analysis as a useful tool to understand sector performance and argues for its wider use in iden-
tifying critical factors and actions to support aquaculture sector improvements.
© 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
The main sources of sh production in Egypt include marine sh-
eries, inland capture sheries and aquaculture. Total production in-
creased from 724,300 tonnes in 2000 to 1.1 million tonnes in 2009.
These increases were primarily obtained from signicant increases
in aquaculture production, and the share of total production provid-
ed by aquaculture had risen to 65%, up from 47% in 2000 (GAFRD,
2011).
Egypt's aquaculture production was 705,490 tonnes in 2009
(GAFRD, 2011), which is the largest of any African country. According
to FAO statistics (FAO FISHSTAT) Egypt ranks 11th in terms of global
aquaculture production. Eighty-four percent of aquaculture production
comes from earthen ponds, with the rest produced in sh/rice elds,
Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
Abbreviations: LE, Egyptian pounds (LE1 = $5.96); FTE, full time equivalents; Av.,
average; g, grammes; FCR, Feed Conversion Ratio; BMPs, Best Management Practices;
Fed, Feddan (1 ha =2.381 feddan).
All authors listed above were part of the study team which planned and executed
the eldwork which generated the data and information used and presented in this
paper.
Corresponding author at: 308 Rue d'Arbere, Divonne les Bains, 01220, France. Tel.:
+33 450 20 68 05.
E-mail addresses: Graeme@consult-poseidon.com (G. Macfadyen),
a.allah@cgiar.org (A.M. Nasr-Alla), d.kenawy@cgiar.org (D. AlKenawy),
m.fathi@cgiar.org (M. Fathi), hhebisha@yahoo.com (H. Hebicha),
ahmeddiab_clar@yahoo.com (A.M. Diab), samyhussien1@yahoo.com (S.M. Hussein),
abouzied2004@yahoo.com (R.M. Abou-Zeid), g.naggar@cgiar.org (G. El-Naggar).
1
Tel.: +20 553404227; fax: +20 553405578.
0044-8486/$ see front matter © 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.aquaculture.2012.05.042
Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect
Aquaculture
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/aqua-online
and intensive cage farms (GAFRD 2011). Aquaculture production is
strongly concentrated in the delta region to the north of Cairo. Tilapia
(Oreochromis niloticus) accounts for 55.5% of national aquaculture
production by volume, grey mullet (Mugil cephalus) and thinlip mullet
(Liza ramada) for 29.9%, common carp (Cyprinus carpio), grass carp
(Ctenopharyngodon idella), and silver carp (Hypophthalmichthys molitrix)
for 10.5%, North African catsh (Clarias gariepinus) for 2.5%, and Europe-
an seabass (Dicentrarchus labrax) and gilthead seabream (Sparus aurata)
for 1.5% (GAFRD 2011).
With a production of over 700,000 tonnes in 2011 and more
than 120,000 people estimated to be employed in the sector
2
Egyptian aquaculture makes an important contribution to income,
employment creation and food security, all of which are national
policy priority areas given low per capita income levels (LE1 2556
or $2107 in 2010),
3
a population that has been growing in recent
years at a constant rate of about 1.48 million per year, worsening
food security indicators, and ofcial unemployment levels which
have remained at around 10% for the last ten years (CAPMAS,
2011).
However, despite the fact that the aquaculture sector in Egypt
is now mature, having developed over a period of more than
30 years, the nancial and social performance of the sector are
not well understood or documented. This is a little surprising
given the existence of value-chain analysis as a useful tool to as-
sess performance, and its increasing prominence as a form of anal-
ysis in the sheries and aquaculture sectors (Veliu et al., 2009;
Christensen et al., 2011). The increasing interest in value-chain
analysis is due to the fact that it provides an excellent means of
assessment to:
Focus on distributional issues and pro-poor and gender equitable
growth (Mayoux and Mackie 2008;Rubin et al., 2009;USAID
2011), and on global linkages in the context of globalisation;
Benchmark changes over time;
Assess the relative importance of factors affecting competitive-
ness, and the costs and earnings of those involved in the value
chain;
Identify gaps/weaknesses in value chain performance; and to
Identify leversand targeted action programmes to upgradeand
improve value chain performance.
This paper presents the outputs of a value-chain study completed
during September 2011. The study was funded by the Swiss Agency
for Development and Cooperation and completed by a team from
the WorldFish Center and CARE Egypt, supported by an international
expert in value-chain analysis.
The objectives of the study were to better understand, and report
on, the pond sh farming value-chain in Egypt. In particular the study
aimed to:
Map the value-chain for pond farmed sh to describe the main
stakeholders and the ow of product through the value-chain;
Consider the employment generated by the sector;
Understand the costs and earnings proles and nancial perfor-
mance of the different sub-sectors/links of the value-chain; and
Identify the key constrains and problems impacting on different ac-
tors in the value-chain.
This paper focusses on presenting the results of the rst three of
these bullets, and only presents in summary form some of the key
constraints and problems identied during the study as impacting
on the value-chain.
2. Material and methods
2.1. Study scope
The scope of the study presented in this paper was limited to
earthen pond farming (which accounts for 85% of the total Egyptian
aquaculture production) in four governorates, which together ac-
count for almost 74% of the total national production from ponds,
namely: Kafr el Sheikh, Behera, Fayoum and Sharkia (see Fig. 1).
Pond farms in Egypt are generally considered as semi-intensive, al-
though there are a range of different strategies used by sh farmers
in terms of stocking densities and the use of feed.
The mapping and nancial analyses of the pond farming value-
chain start at the sh farm and nish with retail sales to the consumer,
with sh fry/ngerlings viewed as a farm input along with other key
inputs such as sh feed, labour, capital etc. Hatchery operations and
the quality and quantity of fry being produced were considered by
the study in terms of the critical challenges and problems facing the
sector, but costs and earnings data for hatcheries were not collected
as part of the study. The study was also limited to the retail sector,
and did not cover the food service sector (e.g. restaurants).
All data on the nancial performance of the value chain collected
and presented in this paper pertain to the full calendar year 2010,
and are yearly averages. The data for each link in the value-chain
presented for the four governorates covered by the study are aver-
ages, and hide nuances in performance between individual operators.
2.2. Study phases
The study was completed in three main phases.
During the rst phase, two study questionnaires covering both qual-
itative and quantitative issues were drafted, one for sh farmers, and
one to cover the post-harvest sub-sector i.e. traders/wholesalers and re-
tailers. The two questionnaires were then piloted at the WorldFish Cen-
ter ofce in Abbassa with one sh farmer and one sh trader/
wholesaler. This piloting resulted in some small changes to the ques-
tionnaires, which were then nalised and printed for the eld work.
In Phase 2, individual interviews and focus group discussions were
held with sh farmers, traders/wholesalers, and retailers. In order to
maximise the number of interviews possible during the time
available for the eld work, the study team (the authors of this
paper) arranged to meet small groups of stakeholders at a central lo-
cation in each governorate. This provided an opportunity to introduce
the study and to hold a focus group discussion in plenary before
individual interviews with those participating in the focus groups
were then conducted with the participants (each member of the
study team sat with a different participant and went through the
questionnaire). The introductory comments and focus group discus-
sions, which concentrated mainly on key stakeholder problems and
potential solutions, generally lasted around 60 to 90 min, as did the
individual interviews.
Table 1 provides information on the number of individual ques-
tionnaires completed in each of the four governorates and the num-
ber of participants that were involved in the focus group discussions.
During Phase 3, data from the questionnaires were entered into a
Microsoft Excel spreadsheet and then analysed to generate the re-
sults. The quantitative results were considered in light of, and in-
formed by, the qualitative focus group discussions which had also
taken place during Phase 2.
3. Theory/calculation
3.1. Value-chain analysis
A value chain is a sequence of related enterprises conducting ac-
tivities so as to add value to a product from its primary production,
2
Figures estimated by the General Authority for Fisheries Resource Development.
3
Most nancial/economic gures in this paper are provided in Egyptian pounds
(LE). LE 1= US$ 5.96.
19G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
through its processing and marketing to the nal sale of the product
to consumers. The functions of each link in the chain involve sourcing
inputs, making/producing, and then delivering/selling product to the
next link in the chain.
Value chain analysis seeks to understand and describe the enter-
prises involved in the value-chain and their nancial performance.
Value chain analysis was rst popularised by Michael Porter in the
mid-1980s (Porter, 1985), and forms of analysis with many
similarities have been undertaken since then by others (Womack
and Jones, 1996 on value-streams, and Gerefet al., 2005 on power
relations in value-chains). However, it is only more recently that
value chain analysis has become increasingly mainstream in develop-
ment circles.
An important component of value-chain analysis is recognition
that support and action for improving performance throughout the
value chain can be achieved both by those within the value chain it-
self i.e. the private sector operators, and by those outside of it i.e. typ-
ically governments. For businesses in the chain, they can improve
performance by reducing costs, increasing output, and/or increasing
the prices of their products (see Riisgard et al., 2010 for more infor-
mation on ways to upgrade the value-chain). Typically mechanisms
to do so involve being more efcient at what they do, and improving
the quality or form of product being sold to the next link in the value
chain. Improvements in value chain performance can also be
supported by governments and other parties external to the value
chain. For example, policy, institutions and infrastructure all impact
on the ability of businesses in the value chain to source the inputs
that they need, to make or engage in their primary activity, and
then to sell and deliver their product to their customers. Govern-
ments may therefore have an impact on value-chain performance
through their inuence on policy, subsidies, licensing, standards,
transport infrastructure and related costs, property rights, enforce-
ment of regulations, government charges/rent collection, and other
impacts on factor costs (e.g. labour, capital, land, utilities).
3.2. Calculations
The data collected during the study have allowed us to estimate a
number of key indicators for each link in the value chain. For each link
in the value chain the indicators were calculated both separately for
each of the four governorates by taking averages of the data provided
by the respondents in each governorate, and for the sample frame as a
whole.
Fig. 1. Map of the study area.
Table 1
Sample frame used during the study.
Governorate Fish farmers Fish traders and/or wholesalers Fish retailers Total
Kafr el Sheikh 22 questionnaires
1 focus group with 9
1 focus group with 7
1 focus group with 8
6 questionnaires
1 focus group with 8
5 questionnaires 33 questionnaires
Focus group discussions with 32
Behera 14 questionnaires
1 focus group with 15
5 questionnaires
1 focus group with 9
19 questionnaires
Focus group discussions with 24
Fayoum 16 questionnaires
1 focus group with 29
4 questionnaires 7 questionnaires 27 questionnaires
Focus group discussions with 29
Sharkia 9 questionnaires
1 focus group with 12
6 questionnaires 1 questionnaire 16 questionnaires
Focus group discussions with 12
Totals 61 questionnaires
6 focus groups with total of 80
21 questionnaires
2 focus groups with a total of 17
13 questionnaires 95 questionnaires
8 focus group discussions with a total of 97
20 G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
The nancial indicators calculated include: gross output values per
kg (i.e. prices); operational prots
4
in LE per tonne of sh produced
or sold and as a percentage of sales; net prots
5
in LE per tonne of
sh produced or sold and as a percentage of sales; total net
value-added
6
per tonne of sh sold; and the percentage of the total
operational prots, net prots, and value-added made throughout
the chain derived from the different links in the value-chain. Calculat-
ing these indicators was possible because of the detailed questions in
the questionnaires which asked for data on sales volumes and values/
prices, operational costs, and xed costs, and which allowed for the
construction of costs and earnings models for each respondent.
Operational costs are those costs which vary depending on the
amount of sh being produced. For sh farmers these typically in-
clude costs for feed, fertiliser, fry, power, transport, ice, sales commis-
sion paid to traders/wholesalers, and labour. For traders/wholesalers
and retailers operational costs typically relate to transport of sh
from markets, boxes, labour and ice.
Fixed costs are those costs which do not vary depending on pro-
duction volumes i.e. they need to be paid each year irrespective of
production/sales. For the sh farming value-chain, they typically in-
clude government licences, repair and maintenance costs, rents paid
for land and buildings, and the depreciation costs of assets. Depreciation
costs have beenestimated by obtaining information onthe replacement
costs of xed assets, and depreciating these costs over standardised
lifespans for different items e.g. buildings over 25 years, nets over
3 years, water pumps over 5 years, generators over 10 years, vehicles
over 10 years.
The study outputs were not just limited to nancial indicators
however. Individuals were asked to provide information on the num-
ber of people employed and on: whether employment is full-time,
part-time or seasonal; the number or working days per year for
part-time and seasonal workers; whether employees are men or
women; whether employees are over or under the age of 30; and
where labour comes from. The data collected were analysed and
converted into full-time equivalent (FTE) jobs based on the number
of days usually worked in the different sub-sectors as reported in
our interviews. This allowed for the calculation, for each link in the
value-chain (and per governorate), of: the FTE jobs per 100 tonnes
of sh sold; the percentage of FTE jobs that are men and women;
the percentage of FTE jobs that are full-time as opposed to
part-time or seasonal; and the percentage of FTE jobs that are created
for those over- and under-thirty years of age.
In addition to these quantitative calculations, the focus groups and
some sections of the questionnaires allowed for the collection of more
qualitative information, particularly on the key factors impacting on
value-chain performance and on some potential solutions to these
problems.
4. Results and discussion
4.1. The value-chain for farmed sh from earthen ponds
There are virtually no exports of farmed sh, and so the value-chain
is a short and simple one compared to aquaculture value-chainsin some
other countries. This is especially true given that there is no processing
at all of farmed sh i.e. all sh is sold in whole form (either live, fresh on
ice, or fresh without ice),
7
and there is no value-addition either through
primary processing into llets or into other secondary processed prod-
ucts (e.g. ready meals, etc.).
Fish is harvested by sh farms (typically but not exclusively be-
tween September and December, with stocking having taken place
in March/April), bought by traders/wholesalers who either collect
sh from the farms or have sh delivered to them by the sh farms,
and then sold on to retailers and restaurants (sometimes, but not
often, through a second trader/wholesaler). Some product, especially
in Kafr el Sheikh, Behera and Sharkia governorates, may pass through
wholesale markets, while other product is transported directly by
traders/wholesalers to retailers. It appears that much of the largest
size-grade of tilapia (>350 g, known locally as super) is sold
through the wholesale markets in Kafr el Sheikh, Behera and at
Al-Obour close to Cairo, while smaller sh may by-pass these market
establishments and be sold closer to the farms, where purchasing
power of the local population is weaker, and where there is thus a
greater demand for smaller and cheaper sh.
Once sh has been harvested, there are no distinct value-chains
for different species i.e. individual traders/wholesalers and retailers
deal in all sh species, rather than in particular ones. All sh farms
reported that they produce and sell a mix of sh species, dominated
by sales of tilapia, but also including sales of mullet, catsh, and
carp. The average size of sh being harvested is 265 g for tilapia,
409 g for grey mullet, 216 g for thinlip mullet, and 1481 g for catsh.
Eighty-nine percent of the volume and 81% of the value of farm pro-
duction in 2010 covered by our survey were accounted for by tilapia.
Mullet represented 9% of farm volumes and 18% of farm values, carp
0.2% of volumes and 0.1% of values, and catsh 1.7% of volumes and
1.3% of values.
All catsh is sold live, while other species (tilapia, mullet, carp) are
generally sold either fresh on ice (in summer months or if sales are
made relatively far from farms) or fresh with no ice (in winter
months and/or if sales are made relatively close to farms). There is a
growing trend in the country for the sale of live tilapia. This is partic-
ularly the case for tilapia being produced in Fayoum governorate,
which is almost all sold live, and transported in drums/tanks with ox-
ygen by traders to wholesaler and retailers. This live sh is typically
held in pens/cages in the Nile in Giza and Beni Suef and sold as
wildsh from the Nile. In other governorates in the delta, live sh
may also be held in irrigation channels, and sold as wild sh, indicat-
ing a consumer preference for wild sh over farmed sh.
Interesting features of the value-chain and the ow of product
through it include: the very short time-period from harvest to nal
consumption by the consumer due to the live/fresh nature of all
sales, with sh generally sold to consumers the same day as the har-
vest or the day after; and almost zero post-harvest losses (which is in
contrast to many wild sheries value-chains, where signicant post
harvest losses often occur in developing countries). These features
are reective of an efcient distribution system and production locat-
ed close to major areas of population.
4.2. Employment creation through the value-chain
Table 2 demonstrates that in the sh farming sub-sector, employ-
ment is entirely male, is fairly evenly divided between those over and
under 30 years of age, is more strongly made up of full-time work,
and generates 8.3 jobs for each 100 tonnes of sh produced.
Non-full time employment is associated with the seasonal nature of
some sh farming activities e.g. stocking and harvesting, weed clear-
ance, etc. Seasonal activities on farms e.g. harvesting, are an unskilled
activity which can be completed by younger people with fewer skills
(at a low cost to the farmers), hence the relatively high rate of em-
ployment for the under 30s. Employment creation in Fayoum gover-
norate is probably higher than in other governorates due the small
average farm size in this governorate (12 fed), and the resulting in-
ability to generate economies of scale.
4
Sales revenues less operational costs.
5
Sales revenues less operational costs and xed costs.
6
In national accounts, net value-added is the sum of remuneration of labour plus
capital i.e. pre-tax prots to owners net of depreciation, plus wages.
7
Some tiny quantities of farmed sh may be sold frozen by retailers if they are un-
able to sell product on a particular day, and deteriorating quality requires them to
place sh in home/shop freezers and then to sell it frozen. There is however no mass
freezing of product at the wholesale/trading stage of the value-chain.
21G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
For the trader/wholesaler sub-sector, employment is also almost
exclusively male, even more full-time in nature than in the farming
sub-sector, and generates a lower percentage of jobs for the under
30s. Employment is generally associated with loading and unloading
of sh. The lower percentage of employment for those under 30s
compared to the farm sub-sector is probably explained by the fact
that traders/wholesalers represent key players in the value-chain, re-
quiring considerable amounts of capital (generally from their own
sources) which the young are likely to nd less able to provide. The
trading/wholesaling sub-sector generates just under 1 FTE job for
each 100 tonnes of sh being sold much lower than for the farming
sub-sector due to the short-time traders have the product in their
possession and the fact that they are in the business of distribution,
rather than processing.
It is only at the retail sub-sector that there are any meaningful quan-
tities of female employment being created, sometimes as managers/
owners of small businesses but more commonly as employees. This em-
ployment tends to be full-time in nature, and with a low proportion of
total employment being for the under 30s, again probably because of
the need to have capital and/or facilities to commence such an activity.
The retail sector creates 4.6 jobs per 100 tonnes of sh sold.
Data on FTE creation per tonne of sh passing through the
value-chain, allow us to estimate that for every 100 tonnes of sh
produced by pond sh farms, once the product has travelled through
the value-chain, it has resulted in almost 14 FTE jobs being created.
For the total production from ponds in Egypt (591,296 tonnes in
2009), a total of around 82,000 FTE jobs can thus be estimated in
the sector as a whole at the national level.
8
For the sector as a whole, and for all sub-sectors within it, almost
all labour is sourced from within the governorate in which the busi-
ness is based. However, our interviews did identify some limited num-
bers of people, especially from Kafr el Sheikh, who work in other
governorates. Wages paid to those working in the sector are typically
around LE 800900/month ($134151/month) for full-time labour,
and LE 3050/day ($58.4/day) for part-time and seasonal labour.
4.3. Fish farming sub-sector operational and nancial performance
Table 3 provides the average operational data for sh farms in
each of the four governorates, and average operational data for the
sample frame as a whole.
Some interesting points to highlight from these results are:
The relatively low average farm size in Fayoum, explained by the
fact that Fayoum is an oasis to the south-west of Cairo, and there-
fore suitable land for farming and sh farming is less available
than in the other governorates;
The fact that most interviewees have been involved in the sh farm-
ing business for many years;
The relatively uniform stocking size for tilapia (around 10 g), ex-
cept in Behera where stocking size is lower;
Feed Conversion Ratios (FCRs) that are similar in Kafr el Sheikh and
Fayoum, but not as good as in Behera and Sharkia (which also have
similar FCRs to each other). Differences in the FCR rates are likely to
be the result of a number of different factors such as: the size of sh
at stocking; the extent to which fertiliser is also used; feed manage-
ment techniques and relative efciencies; the quality of the feed
being used, which varies considerably between farms and gover-
norates; and the extent of water exchange;
Production per fed that is comparable in Kafr el Sheikh, Fayoum and
Sharkia, but highest in Behera. This is perhaps due to fact that many
of the sh farms included in the sample frame in Behera are located
close to lake Idku, and so water availability and exchange is partic-
ularly good in this area;
Relatively low sh prices in Behera due mainly to a smaller percent-
age of total production consisting of super(largest) grade tilapia in
that governorate, and the relatively high prices in Fayoum due to
the dominance of the live sh trade in that governorate;
Tilapia superprices in Fayoum which are higher than the average
price for total production in Fayoum, due to the low percentage of
total production consisting of mullet compared to other governor-
ates because mullet prices are higher than prices for tilapia, in
other governorates mullet production means that the average
price for all production is higher than the price for supertilapia;
Stocking densities that are quite uniform across governorates, but
which can vary hugely between farms, depending on farming strat-
egies. Stocking rates reported during interviews range between
6000 and 30,000 per fed for tilapia. However most farms stock be-
tween 10,000 and 15,000 tilapia per fed; and
Fairly consistent average size of sh at harvest in the four
governorates.
Table 4 provides information on the nancial performance, and
the costs and earnings, of the sh farms.
Key points of interest from the results are:
The positive nancial performance in all governorates in terms of
average net prots (LE 247,172), net prots per tonne of sh (LE
2329), and net prots as a percentage of sales (22%). Fayoum is
the best performing governorate even though it has the highest
production cost per tonne, due largely to the high prices of sh
paid for their live product. Other reasons may be the level of skills
and good management practices in the governorate due to the
fact that farmers in Fayoum in particular have been the beneciaries
of considerable amounts of training in the past, and more so than
farmers in other governorates. In general farms in Kafr el Sheikh
have the worst performance of the four governorates;
An average total production cost across all farms of LE 7769/tonne,
which represents the break-even weighted sales price i.e. the aver-
age price of all sh sold by a farm must be more than LE 7769/tonne
if the farm is to make a prot;
The consistently high percentage in all governorates of operational
costs which consist of feed costs (67% across all farms). Fish fry con-
stitute the next most important input (13% of operational costs),
followed by labour (8%), sales commission (5%), and fuel/electricity/
power (3%);
The high percentage (91.5%) of total costs which consist of operation-
al costs, as opposed to xed costs. Fixed costs are low due to the
8
This study did not attempt to estimate multiplier employment impacts from pond
farming, or employment from other production methods e.g. cage farming.
Table 2
Employment creation in the value chain.
Employment Kafr el Sheikh Behera Fayoum Sharkia Overall average
Full time equivalent jobs per 100 tonnes sold
Farmers 6.99 5.31 12.59 7.98 8.31
Traders/wholesalers 0.40 0.62 0.92 1.56 0.87
Retailers 1.34 n/a 7.79 2.02 4.62
Total 8.73 5.93 21.29 11.57 13.80
% of FTE days contributed by men
Farmers 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%
Traders/wholesalers 100% 100% 100% 94% 98%
Retailers 60% n/a 80% 50% 69%
% of FTE days for full-time employment as opposed to part-time or seasonal work
Farmers 70% 86% 63% 73% 72%
Traders/wholesalers 83% 91% 97% 92% 91%
Retailers 100% n/a 100% 100% 100%
% of FTE days contributed by those under 30 years of age
Farmers 71% 41% 52% 56% 57%
Traders/wholesalers 35% 52% 36% 28% 37%
Retailers 50% n/a 16% 100% 37%
22 G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
nature of the sh farming business, and also because many farms are
on rented land with short lease periods, which decreases the incen-
tive for farmers to invest in xed assets;
Land rents are the highest single xed cost, representing 62% of
xed costs for our sample as a whole, with depreciation, and
repair/maintenance costs both contributing 17% of total xed
costs. Very few farms have any formal xed nance costs in the
form of interest payments on loans, as there is virtually no formal
bank lending to the sector;
Total value-added by the sub-sector i.e. net prots plus wages paid
to labour, is LE 2989 per tonne of sh produced. Again, this gure
is the highest for sh farms in Fayoum.
4.4. Trader/wholesaler sub-sector operational and nancial performance
Table 5 provides the outputs of the data collected and analysed for
this sub-sector of the value-chain. Traders/wholesalers are key players
in the value-chain, especially in terms of determining prices. The one
exception to this is in Fayoum, where sh farmers are reported to
have a much stronger inuence on farm gate prices than in other gov-
ernorates (although the inuence of traders/wholesalers is still signif-
icant in Fayoum also). The traders/wholesalers play a key role in
providing nance to many of the sh farms (along with feed mills/
traders in many cases), and most of them nance their operations
out of their own nance (often earned from other economic activi-
ties). This provides an indication of the overall nancial position/
wealth of such individuals, and their inuence in the value-chain.
Even though nal prot margins (3.9% on average) and prots per
tonne of sh sold (LE 422) are both low compared to the farming
sub-sector, given the large average value of sales made by individuals
each year (LE 11.9 million on average), prots inabsolute terms are sig-
nicant, with individuals typically earning around LE 400,000 per year.
The earnings made by traders/wholesalers are generated from a
sales commission, usually of between 3 and 6% on the sales of sh,
which is paid to them by the sh farmers. This margin is typically
lower (e.g. 3%) when farmers deliver product to them, and higher
(56%) if a) they collect sh from the farms and therefore have to
pay for transportation and ice, and/or b) they have provided nance
to sh farmers. Individual questionnaire responses reveal that net
prots and net prot margins are generally higher when traders/
wholesalers collect sh from the farms, because the costs they incur
on ice and transport are less than the difference between the commis-
sion they take for collecting sh at the farms, and the commission
they get if sh is delivered to them.
Other interesting observations which can be drawn from the data
in the table are:
The higher farm gate price for sh in Fayoum continues to be passed
through the value-chain, with higher average prices of sh sold by
traders/wholesalers in Fayoum compared to other governorates;
Average annual sales values for individual traders/wholesalers sold
within Fayoum are lower than in other governorates, due to the
lower level of total farm production in this governorate;
Operational costsconsist almost entirely of the sh traders/
wholesalers buy from farms or sell for them. Other operational
cost items include labour, truck rental/transport, ice, and fuel/
Table 4
Financial performance of sh farms.
Financial performance data Kafr el Sheikh Behera Fayoum Sharkia Overall Average
Average sales revenue (LE) 804,447 1,385,487 427,841 1,267,517 885,964
Average operational costs (LE) 563,226 1,008,630 286,703 720,814 600,242
Average feed costs as % of operational costs 72% 66% 68% 57% 67%
Average labour costs per tonne produced (LE) 516 486 948 768 660
Average op. costs per tonne produced (LE) 7020 6405 8011 6692 7115
Average operational prot (LE) 253,551 410,652 141,138 546,703 301,357
Average operational prot per tonne (LE) 2724 2243 3402 3179 2997
Average operational prot as % of sales revenue 27% 24% 32% 31% 29%
Average xed costs (LE) 68,612 52,593 13,498 87,933 51,343
Average total production cost (LE/tonne) 8051 6688 8392 7442 7769
Average net prot (LE) 182,036 356,410 127,639 458,770 247,172
Average net prot per tonne (LE) 1640 1914 3402 2429 2329
Average net prot as % of sales 16% 20% 29% 24% 22%
Average total value-added per tonne (LE) 2155 2400 4350 3198 2989
Table 3
Operational data for the sh farming sub-sector.
Operational data Kafr el Sheikh Behera Fayoum Sharkia Overall
Total fed of interviewed farms under production 531 448 198 341 1517
Average years involved in the sector 20 18 16 18 18
Average area under production (fed) 25 34 12 38 26
Average size of tilapia when stocking (g) 10 4 11 10 9.05
Average FTE per fed 0.21 0.23 0.38 0.23 0.26
Average FTE per 100 tonnes 6.99 5.31 12.59 7.98 8.31
Average production (tonnes/fed) 3.26 4.81 3.16 3.12 3.55
Average FCR 1.89 1.44 1.71 1.38 1.66
Average sales price (LE/kg (all species)) 9.70 8.26 11.79 9.87 9.98
Average sales price tilapia super(LE/kg) 9.59 8.75 11.88 9.34 10.14
Average % of total production from tilapia 86% 94% 93% 79% 89%
Average stocking density tilapia/fed 12,786 17,500 13,656 11,012 13,790
Average stocking density mullet M. Cep/fed 700 784 858 788 776
Average stocking density mullet M. Cap/fed 1600 1354 1466 2167 1676
Average stocking density catsh/fed 200 317 n/a 844 332
Average growth period (months) 9.6 8.7 8.3 7.7 8.7
Average size tilapia at harvest (g) 276 235 283 252 265
Average size mullet M. Cep at harvest (g) 421 342 453 402 409
Average size mullet M. Cap at harvest (g) 223 206 500 177 216
Average size catsh at harvest (g) 1321 1333 n/a 1340 1481
23G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
power, but none of these items alone comprise more than one per-
cent of the value of sales;
Fixed costs are generally very low, and more evenly distributed
across a range of items such as rents/leases (32% of total xed
costs), depreciation of buildings, sh boxes and vehicles (30% of
xed costs), and repairs and maintenance of buildings and vehi-
cles (15% of xed costs);
The individual average earnings for traders/wholesalers across the
four governorates appear very consistent, with those in Fayoum
similar to those in other governorates even though average total
sales values are lower, due to the higher margins being achieved;
and
The average value-added (net prot plus wages) per tonne of sh
sold is LE 503, with almost double that being generated in Fayoum.
4.5. Retailer sub-sector operational and nancial performance
There are two main types of farmed sh retailers in Egypt. The rst
group engages in informalstreet sales, which take place usually by
individual operators who purchase sh from wholesale markets or
traders, and then set up shop by the roadside to sell their product.
Sales facilities/equipment is minimal, often comprising just a shelter
from the sun. Labour is generally not employed, and these types of re-
tailers aim to make LE 0.51.0 prot on each kg of sh they buy/sell.
The second group is more formalised, with sales taking place from
retail shop facilities, and retailers may also have fridges and or
freezers for storing sh if it cannot be sold the same day it is pur-
chased. These businesses often employ labour to clean/prepare sh.
As a result their operational and xed costs tend to be higher than
the informal street traders. However, this simplistic description and
division is not always entirely accurate or obvious in reality. For ex-
ample some formal retail businesses may employ people to sell sh
(generally of lower quality of or particular species) informally on
the street outside or nearby their shop. Equally, many formal retailers
also engage in some elements of the food service/restaurant business,
and use grills to cook sh for consumers.
The data provided in Table 6 does not distinguish between the two
types of operation, due to the small sample size achieved during the
study. Nevertheless, some condence can be gained from the consis-
tency shown in the data between governorates, and the data are in-
teresting in that they show:
Businesses typically have low xed costs, and a high percentage of
operational costs comprising sh purchases (with other operational
costs being primarily for transport of sh from markets, and ice).
This suggests that as long as retailers can sell their product for a
small standard margin over and above the purchase price, there is
little riskinherent in the business;
Table 6
Operational and nancial performance data for sh retailers.
Kafr el Sheikh Behera Fayoum Sharkia Overall
Operational data
No. of retailers interviewed 5 0 6 1 12
Total annual sales value of interviewees (LE) 5,244,300 n/a 4,998,210 1,056,600 11,299,110
Average FTE per 100 tonnes of sales 1.34 n/a 7.79 2.02 4.62
Average sales price (LE/kg (all species)) 12.51 n/a 15.75 10.67 13.98
Average sales price tilapia super(LE/kg) 10.83 n/a 13.38 11.50 12.19
Financial performance
Average annual sales value (LE) 1,048,860 n/a 833,035 1,056,600 941,593
Average operational costs (LE) 972,648 n/a 786,268 974,880 879,644
Average labour costs per tonne sold (LE) 0 n/a 333 170 181
Average operational prot (LE) 76,212 n/a 46,767 81,720 61,948
Average operation prot per tonne (LE) 916 n/a 1091 825 996
Average operational prot as % of sales 7% n/a 7% 8% 7.1%
Average xed costs (LE) n/a 5557 4700 3170
Average net prot (LE) 76,212 n/a 41,210 77,020 58,778
Average net prot per tonne (LE) 916 n/a 1008 778 951
Average net prot as % of sales 7% n/a 6% 7% 6.8%
Average total value-added per tonne (LE) 916 n/a 1341 948 1131
Table 5
Operational and nancial performance data for sh traders/wholesalers.
Kafr el Sheikh Behera Fayoum Sharkia Overall
Operational data
No. of traders/wholesalers interviewed 6 55622
Total annual sales value of interviewees (LE) 105,948,000 75,463,200 36,026,210 51,739,588 269,176,998
Average FTE per 100 tonnes of sales 0.40 0.62 0.92 1.56 0.87
Average sales price (LE/kg (all species)) 10.83 9.86 12.95 10.23 10.66
Average sales price tilapia super(LE/kg) 10.17 9.67 12.80 10.17 10.5
Financial performance
Average annual sales value (LE) 17,658,000 12,577,200 7,205,242 8,623,265 11,930,954
Average operational costs (LE) 17,158,250 12,172,752 6,800,911 8,226,058 11,510,701
Average operational prot (LE) 499,750 404,448 404,331 397,206 420,254
Average labour costs per tonne sold (LE) 42 96 98 91 80
Average operation prot per tonne (LE) 293 265 822 413 440
Average operational prot as % of sales 2.6% 3.9% 6.5% 4.5% 4.1%
Average xed costs (LE) 34,454 13,517 9532 7918 17,377
Average net prot (LE) 465,296 390,931 394,799 389,288 402,877
Average net prot per tonne (LE) 268 252 804 400 422
Average net prot as % of sales 2.3% 3.7% 6.4% 4.4% 3.9%
Average total value-added per tonne (LE) 310 347 903 491 503
24 G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
Higher prices for sh in Fayoum exhibited in earlier links in the
value-chain are maintained in the retail sub-sector;
Average net prots per individual business owners are LE 58,778,
still considerably above national average earnings; and
The retail sector creates an average of LE 1131 for every one tonne
of sh sold.
4.6. Summary data on nancial performance
Mapping the value chain and constructing costs and earnings
models for each link in the value chain as presented above, allows
for a comparison across the various sub-sectors in the value chain.
Table 7 shows how the average price of product both for all sales
sold by each link the value-chain (i.e. the basket price), and separate-
ly for tilapia supergrade, increases as farmed sh moves through the
supply chain in each governorate. It also shows for the basket price of
sh the percentage of the nal consumer price achieved by each link
in the value-chain. The data in the right-hand column of this table
show that the farmers are obtaining a relatively high percentage of
the nal price. This is due to the lack of any exports, the
short-supply chain, and the lack of value-addition through the chain.
Tables 8 and 9 show the operational and net prot per tonne re-
spectively for each link in the value chain. These two tables also
show the operational and net rates of return on sales values for
each link in the value chain, and the percentage contribution of
each link in the value-chain to total prots created. The tables show
that operational and net prots as a percentage of own sales, and in
absolute terms per tonne of sh sold, are highest in the farm
sub-sector.
Finally, Table 10 provides information on the total value-added
created through the value-chain i.e. the net prot, plus the wages
earned by those working in the sector. The data show that on average
across all governorates, a total of LE 4619 value-added is generated
for each tonne of sh produced by the farming sub-sector. Again,
the levels of value-added created are highest in the sh farming
sub-sector (LE 2985/tonne), and in Fayoum (LE 6594/tonne).
The data presented in Table 7 to Table 10 serve to benchmark perfor-
mance by the sub-sectors of the value-chain in different governorates,
and demonstrate the superior performance in Fayoum governorate.
Table 7
Gross output values i.e. sh prices for the farmed sh value-chain.
Gross output values LE/kg (all species basket price) LE/kg (tilapia superprice) All species basketprice as % ofnal consumer price
K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All
Farmers 9.70 8.26 11.79 9.87 9.98 9.59 8.75 11.88 9.34 10.14 78% n/a 75% 92% 71%
Traders/wholesalers 10.83 9.86 12.95 10.23 10.66 10.17 9.67 12.80 10.17 10.50 87% n/a 82% 96% 76%
Retailers 12.51 n/a 15.75 10.67 13.98 10.83 n/a 13.38 11.50 12.19 100% n/a 100% 100% 100%
Table 8
Operational prots created in the farmed sh value-chain.
Operational prot LE/tonne % of own sales % of value-chain operational prot creation
K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All
Farmers 2724 2243 3402 3179 2997 27.2% 24.5% 32.0% 31.5% 28.8% 69.3% 89.4% 64.0% 72.0% 67.6%
Traders/wholesalers 293 265 822 413 440 2.6% 3.9% 6.5% 4.5% 4.1% 7.4% 10.6% 15.5% 9.4% 9.9%
Retailers 916 n/a 1091 825 996 7.3% n/a 6.8% 7.7% 7.1% 23.3% n/a 20.5% 18.7% 22.5%
Total 3933 2508 5315 4418 4432
Table 9
Net prots created in the farmed sh value-chain.
Net prot LE/tonne % of own sales % of value-chain net prot creation
K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All
Farmers 1640 1914 3402 2429 2329 15.8% 20.4% 28.8% 23.8% 21.8% 58.1% 88.4% 65.2% 67.3% 62.9%
Traders/wholesalers 268 252 804 400 422 2.3% 3.7% 6.4% 4.4% 3.9% 9.5% 11.6% 15.4% 11.1% 11.4%
Retailers 916 n/a 1008 778 951 7.3% n/a 6.3% 7.3% 6.8% 32.4% n/a 19.3% 21.6% 25.7%
Total 2824 2166 5215 3607 3702
Table 10
Total value-added created in the farmed sh value-chain.
Total value-added LE/tonne % of value-chain value-added creation
K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All K el Sh Beh Fay Sha All
Farmers 2155 2400 4350 3198 2989 63.7% 87.4% 66.0% 69.0% 64.7%
Traders/wholesalers 310 347 903 491 503 9.2% 12.6% 13.7% 10.6% 10.9%
Retailers 916 n/a 1341 948 1131 27.1% n/a 20.3% 20.4% 24.5%
Total 3381 2748 6594 4637 4623
25G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
The emphasis on live sh trade, on which Fayoum's superior perfor-
mance appears to be largely based, also seems to be a strategy that isin-
creasingly being pursued in other governorates.
Our eldwork did not collect information to allow for a quantitative
comparison of the changes in performance within the sub-sectors of the
value-chain over time in any one governorate (i.e. benchmarking
sub-sector performance against itself over time). However we did at-
tempt to generate some ndings of a more qualitative nature by asking
interviewees to comment on their perceptions about changes in key
variables over the last three years. A relatively uniform picture was pro-
vided by respondents in terms of the perceived changes in the opera-
tional and xed costs incurred in the sh farming sub-sector, with a
dominant view being that most individual cost items e.g. feed, labour,
rents, power, etc., have increased over recent years. Given that sh
prices have declined in real terms in recent years with only small in-
creases in nominal terms, this would suggest that protability has
been declining in recent years. Sector performance may now be under
threat, especially due to increases in the costs of feed, with feed prices
havingincreasedby200250% over the last 67 years.
To the best of our knowledge, a detailed costs and earnings survey
of the sub-sectors of the farmed sh value-chain similar to the one
presented in this paper has not previously been completed in Egypt.
While our data cannot therefore be used to quantitatively assess
changes in value-chain performance in recent years, the data
obtained during this study may be useful as baseline data to be used
for future benchmarking of changes over time. In particular, the
data may be helpful in the monitoring and evaluation of any subse-
quent interventions in support of the sector.
4.7. Critical factors impacting on value-chain performance
In seeking to explore how value-chain performance could be im-
proved, our study qualitatively explored with questionnaire respon-
dents and focus groups the critical factors impacting on value-chain
performance. We have chosen in this paper to focus primarily on
presenting the nancial performance of the value-chain, rather than
to discuss in detail the myriad of factors determining value-chain per-
formance. However Table 11 provides a brief summary of the key is-
sues impacting on the sector. All of the issues included in the table
represent potential areas of action by the value-chain itself and by
those relevant factors outside of it (e.g. government), to improve
value-chain performance.
5. Conclusions
Egypt is by far the largest aquaculture producer in Africa and the
world's second largest producer of farmed tilapia, and the sector is a
pioneering and vibrant one. When one considers the attempts by
other African countries to develop aquaculture and the small produc-
tion volumes that have resulted, the success achieved in Egypt is all
the more impressive. This paper has demonstrated that the sector
generates very considerable levels of value-added, results in prot-
able businesses at each stage of the value-chain, and provides em-
ployment for many thousands of people (who in turn have many
others in their households dependent on their earnings). Most people
who work in the sector have been doing so for many years, and our
study suggested that this is largely, but not exclusively, due to the
sustainable nature of the value-chain rather than due to a lack of al-
ternative livelihood opportunities.
However, the sector now faces a number of signicant challenges,
and it is noteworthy that the yearly percentage increase in the vol-
ume of aquaculture production in 2009 (1.7% above 2008) was the
lowest yearly percentage increase for the last 10 years. The historical
strength of the sector, coupled with recent challenges, and indeed op-
portunities for further improvements in value-chain performance,
provides a strong argument for action by private sector businesses
within the value-chain, and by government in the form of supportive
policy and legislation (on issues such as land tenure, access and qual-
ity of water, infrastructure, and human capacity development). Such
action would serve both to safeguard the current nancial and
Table 11
Summary of critical issues and factors constraining the sector.
Critical issue or factor
Input factors Access to capital and nance from the banking
sector is virtually non-existent, due to perceptions
of risk held by the banking sector and the collateral
requirements demanded
Feed costs have risen dramatically in the past
67 years, and the quality of feed is very variable
between feed producers
Fry quality for tilapia is often poor with fry sold as
mono-sex reproducing, and in some geographical
areas there are shortages of mullet fry
Water quality can be poor from using agricultural
drainage water, and availability limited at some
times of the year due to agricultural requirements
Expansion of farming into new areas would re
quire considerable human capacity development to
train labour
Access to land for expansion is increasingly prob
lematic, and many farmers operate on land rented
from government without any option to buy and
with short lease periods and low security of tenure
Power/fuel costs have risen in recent years and
many farms do not have access to mains electricity
Production factors While the environmental conditions in Egypt are
generally favourable for sh production, the colder
winter months from January through April place
constraints on the sh farming sub-sector, due to
the lack of cold tolerance of sh and a growth peri
od that is limited to around 8 months
For some farms, pond size, layout and design is not
optimal
There is very variable knowledge about Best
Management Practices (BMPs) for feed use
Many farms are thought to use sub-optimal
stocking strategies
BMPs for sh health management are not always
followed
Sector and sub-sector organisation is very weak.
Only in Fayoum is there any form of representative
organisation that is functioning in a meaningful way
Over-reliance on a small-number of sh species
(i.e. tilapia and mullet)
Post-harvest distribution
and marketing factors
Pressure on sh prices due to increasing
aquaculture production over the last decade,
consumer preference for meat as a source of
protein, the presence of signicant quantities
(although declining) of imports of competitor
products (often of poor quality), and a consumer
preference for wild sh due to health concerns
about sh produced by farms because of water
quality issues
Fish prices can exhibit considerable daily and
seasonal uctuations, primarily due to changes in
the volume of supply on particular days, or between
different months.
Health and hygiene conditions in wholesale and
retail markets, and in the transportation/
distribution network are poor
There are virtually no exports, but not enough
knowledge about Egypt's competitive position vis a
vis other suppliers, about comparative prices in
Egypt and in overseas markets, and about the steps
that would have to be taken to expand exports, in
order to make an informed opinion about the merits
of a push to try to access export markets
There is no processing for value-addition, with all
sh sold in whole form
Poor road networks to farms in some areas impact
on the ability of farmers/traders to get sh to
markets
26 G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
employment benets being generated in the sector, and to increase
such benets in the future.
Value-chain analysis has not been widely adopted in the aquacul-
ture sector, with a continuing focus instead in research and interven-
tions on technical production issues. This paper has showed that
value chain analysis is a useful tool for understanding the nancial
and social benets that are generated by the aquaculture sector, and
for identifying the critical factors that affect the nancial and social
performance of the value chain. Better understanding of these critical
factors can inform the necessary actions and innovations to increase
the nancial and social benets created by the sector.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to acknowledge the important contribu-
tions and suggestions made by Dr. Malcolm Beveridge from the
WorldFish Center to a rst draft of this paper. The authors also grate-
fully acknowledge the support of the Swiss Development Corporation
in funding this work. The paper also represents an output of the
CGIAR Livestock and Fish Research program.
References
Central Agency for Public Mobilization, Statistics (CAPMAS), 2011. Egypt in Figures.
(http/capmas.gov.eg/indicators).
Christensen, V., Steenbeek, J., Failler, P., 2011. A combined ecosystem and value chain
modeling approach for evaluating societal costs and benets of shing. Ecological
Modeling 222, 857864.
FAO FISHSTAT database, accessed at the time of writing.
General Authority For Fisheries Resource Development (GAFRD), 2011. 20012010.
Fish Production Statistics. Miscellaneous Issues.
Geref,G.,Humphrey,J.,Sturgeon,T.,2005.Thegovernanceofglobalvaluechains.
Review of International Political Economy 12 (1), 78104 (February).
Mayoux, L., Mackie, G., 2008. A Practical Guide to Mainstreaming Gender Analysis in
Value Chain Development. International Labour Ofce, Addis Ababa.
Porter, M., 1985. The Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Perfor-
mance. Free Press, N.Y.(Porter, M. E.).
Riisgard, L., Bolwig, S., Ponte, S., Du Toit, A., Halberg, N., Matose, F., 2010. Integrating
poverty and environmental concerns into value-chain analysis: a strategic frame-
work and practical guide. Development Policy Review 28 (2), 195216.
Rubin, D., M anfre, C., Barrett, K .N., 2009. Promotin g gender equitable o pportunities in
agricultural value chains: a handbook. Publication Prepared under the Greater
Access to Trade Expansion (GATE) Project, under the Women in Development
IQC Contract No. GEW-I-00-02-00018-00, Task Order No. 02. United States Agency
for International Development, Washington, DC.
USAID, 2011. Gender and Pro-poor Value Chain Analysis: Insights from the Gate Project
Methodology and Case Studies. (http://www.usaid.gov/our_work/cross-cutting_
programs/wid/pubs/GATE_Gender_Pro-Poor_Value_Chain_Analysis_05-09.pdf).
Veliu, A., Gessese, N., Ragasa, C., Okali, C., 2009. Gender analysis of aquaculture value
chain in northeast Vietnam and Nigeria: World Bank Agriculture and Rural Devel-
opment Discussion Paper, 44.
Womack, J., Jones, D., 1996. Lean Thinking. Simon & Schuster, New York.
27G. Macfadyen et al. / Aquaculture 362363 (2012) 1827
... Tilapia are often co-cultivated with African catfish (Clarias gariepinus), thinlip mullet (Chelon ramada, also known as Mugil capito) and gray mullet (Mugil cephalus). The majority of fish farming operations are small to medium scale private operations, implying aquaculture's important role for income and employment (Macfadyen et al., 2011). Yet sustainable strategies for maintaining high yields are lacking (Soliman and Yacout, 2016). ...
... Egyptian fish farmers depend on the commercial feeds, but pond fertilization is often applied to enhance natural food in ponds and reduce feed costs (Macfadyen et al., 2011;Dickson et al., 2016;El-Sayed, 2020;Rossignoli et al., 2023). Chicken manure (CM) is commonly used as fertilizer, as it is abundant, cheap, and readily available product that is rich in nitrogen. ...
... These results rely an indication of potential eutrophication with only feed and fertilizer inputs correlated with fish yields and nutrient emissions, while any realized local effects will depend on fish pond soil biogeochemistry, effluent nutrient contents, and the recipient's capacity to buffer increased nutrient loads (Boyd and McNevin, 2015). Water from the Nile river is prioritized for agricultural irrigation (Macfadyen et al., 2011;Wally, 2016), while fish farms are limited to downstream agricultural or municipal drainage canals. Farms may even be connected in series to the same channels resulting in re-use of water among aquaculture farms (Macfadyen et al., 2011). ...
Article
Full-text available
Aquaculture is a crucial sector for Egyptian food production, providing a cheap source of animal protein while securing income and employment for a substantial part Egypt's population. Nile tilapia (Oreochromis niloticus) is the most commonly produced fish, usually farmed in earthen ponds around the Northern Delta Lakes. A common practice among farms is to fertilize ponds with chicken manure (CM) in order to increase nutrient levels and promote phytoplankton, consumed by the fish. However, with reports of use of antibiotics in Egypt's poultry sector, and that CM contains residues of antibiotics, antibiotic resistant pathogens and antibiotic resistance genes (ARGs) are production benefits large enough to compensate a potential health hazard? Using production data from 501 aquaculture farms and fish pond sediment from 28 ponds we evaluated potential benefits in yields and profitability for farms using CM for fertilization, and used qPCRs to screen sediments for three antibiotic resistance genes coding for resistance to the most commonly used antibiotics in the poultry sector. The analysis showed no significant benefits to fish yields or profitability in farms where CM was applied, but a risk of significantly increased nutrient loads. Meanwhile, we detected increased abundances of tetA and tetW resistance genes in fish pond sediment where CM was applied. With the risk of disseminating ARGs and causing eutrophication of local waterways, we recommend that Egyptian tilapia pond farmers refrain from using CM and adopt best management practices for increasing farm profitability in order to to reduce environmental and health hazards.
... among different localities and species on feed costs. Macfadyen et al. (2011) who reported that feed cost represented bout (66% , 72%) of operational cost for Behera and Kafr El-Sheikh respectively. ...
... The highest value (7.33 months) recorded in Alexandria governorate and the lowest value (6.55 months) recorded in Behera governorate. Our result agreed with Macfadyen et al. (2011);Eltholth et al. (2015); Cai et al. (2017) as they reported that, production cycle in Egypt (5-9 months) usually stocked in (March/April) and harvested in early winter (November/December) because of the sever drop of temperature in winter cause stress of the fish that can't tolerate with it which lead to tilapia to stop feeding and losing weight. Furthermore, the data illustrated that there were no significant differences among different localities on mortality ratio but there were a significant differences among fish spp. ...
... among different localities and fish species. We concluded from the previous result that feed cost, fry cost and fuel cost respectively are the main costs faced by farmers in different provinces in addition labor cost had remarkable effect on variable cost , the same result was reported by (Macfadyen et al., 2011;Rothuis et al., 2013;Mur, 2014;Soliman and Yacout, 2016;Shaalan et al., 2017) the major constraints affecting aquaculture are feed production and cost , availability of seed , Energy usage and labor. Gamal et al. (2012); Yuan et al. (2017) reported that net profit of tilapia and mugil cephalus are very flexible to the change in selling price which have the greatest effect on profitability another factor as feed, rent and fixed cost also affected furthermore, we concluded that cost per kilogram of mullet species was higher than tilapia this result agreed with Naziri (2011) that cost per kilogram of tilapia was 6 L.E and net profit per kilogram was 2.7 L.E ,Also, Gamal et al. (2012) reported that total cost per kilogram produced of mugil cephalus ranged from 14.9 to 12.8 L.E in small and large cages respectively. ...
... In Egypt, the relatively lower price of African catfish compared to tilapia (Oreochromis niloticus), which precedes it along with carp spp. in the list of cultivated freshwater fish, has driven farmers to use cost-effective alternative feeds such as poultry and discarded chicken waste (Macfadyen et al. 2011;Abou-Zied 2015). Specifically, these practices are followed in the monoculture system of raising catfish. ...
Article
Full-text available
African catfish farmers used animal waste as feed to reduce production costs, a practice that raised concerns among consumers, causing them to avoid it. Consequently, this study aimed to explore factors that influenced the acceptance of farmed African catfish. The data survey involving 2294 participants from Egypt was analyzed using descriptive statistics and the chi-square test. The results indicated that 67% of participants abstained from consuming it, while 2.30% consumed it regularly. The chi-square test revealed significant consumption pattern variations (p < 0.05) based on most demographic factors. Entirely, 43% were uninformed about the nutritional value, market availability, and the potential impact of using aquafeeds on pricing. About 55–57% lacked information on feeding practices, had quality concerns, viewed catfish consumption as a health risk, and were unaware of its prices. Additionally, 68% were worried about pollution, and 76% found the available information insufficient. The main reasons for this challenge lie in consumers’ health, religious, and psychological concerns. To address this, we propose a targeted marketing strategy focusing on improving safety and quality through safe and cost-effective aquafeeds. This involves requiring farmers to obtain quality certifications and adhere to best management practices, adding value to the product, and transparent communication with consumers to provide them with reliable information about cultivation practices and the nutritional value of African catfish. Effective collaboration among key stakeholders in implementation, efficient sector management, establishing an activity licensing system, and prohibiting current feeding practices will enhance sustainable demand and reverse the declining production trend of this promising species.
... Farmers in Africa cultivate a variety of aquatic species; however, the most frequently farmed fish are tilapias, farmed by smallholders and large commercial enterprises alike [3]. The proliferation of smallholder tilapia farming in Africa has had direct and indirect impacts on poverty reduction and improving food and nutrition security [4][5][6]. Pinpointing the exact pathways by which aquaculture leads to improved food security and nutrition outcomes are notably difficult to discern [7]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Background Much has been made of the potential for aquaculture to improve rural livelihoods and food and nutrition security in Africa, though little evidence exists to back such claims. This study, conducted in northern Zambia, assessed the benefits of adopting aquaculture by comparing a sample of households with (n = 177) and without fishponds (n = 174). Results On-farm food production was assessed by summing all crop and livestock activities and calculating a production diversity score (PDS) of key food groups. Aquaculture households had greater crop diversification and were more associated with key nutritious foods grown on the farm, possibly due to additional water irrigation capabilities. A greater diversity of cultivated crops led to better household dietary diversity scores (HDDS). We further assessed the frequency of consumption of 53 food items (including 30 fish species) over a period of 4 weeks via a Food Frequency Questionnaire (FFQ). Using the Simpson’s Index, aquaculture households had greater diversity and evenness in the distribution of foods and fish species consumed, particularly for foods grown on the farm. Using livelihood and dietary factors in a multilevel probit regression on the Household Food Insecurity Access Scale (HFIAS), we found that adopting aquaculture gave households almost two times more likelihood of improving their food security status. Households could further improve their food security outcomes by growing and consuming certain vegetables, especially those that could be integrated along pond dykes. Conclusions The study suggests three clear pathways to food security. (1) Increasing wealth and income from the sale of fish and integrated vegetables and/or crops, which can be used to purchase a diversity of foods. (2) Increasing food and nutrition security via the direct consumption of fish and vegetables grown on the farm. (3) Improving irrigation capabilities in integrated aquaculture–agriculture systems that has direct impact on pathways 1 and 2. Aquaculture should be promoted in the region for its crop diversification and food security benefits, so long as it fits the local farming system and livelihood context. Moving away from productivist approaches to nutrition-sensitive aquaculture widens the scope of uncovering the many benefits of pond farming in smallholder systems.
... While data are scant, some studies specific to aquaculture indicate that people active in the sector are in majority young (<40, and more often <30 years of age), but the positions they occupy within production systems are unclear (Hishamunda et al., 2014). This was found for example in Egypt where 50% of aquaculture workers were men below 30 years of age (Macfadyen et al., 2011), and in Vietnam where "graduates are able to find several job opportunities to work as farm advisors, sales people, quality control personnel, technicians or researchers" (Arulingam et al., 2019, p. 41). In contrast, in Cambodia, young people are finding fewer opportunities for employment and entrepreneurship in a less developed aquaculture sector (Arulingam et al., 2019). ...
Article
Full-text available
Compared with other aquaculture issues, attention to human and social dimensions is lagging behind. Sectoral development, policy, and programmatic factors have created inequities and sub‐optimal social outcomes, which are jeopardizing the broader contribution the sector could make to human well‐being. Human rights in aquaculture are at the core of this article, which argues that aquaculture development, as a major economic and food producing sector, needs to be about human development. The article reviews: the application of human rights in aquaculture, and the related right to decent work; the notions of justice and equity including the idea of Blue Justice and its relevance in aquaculture; and ethics and social license to operate with the challenges that business ethics and public acceptance pose to the sector. It also reviews how these issues affect people: women, along with slow progress in gender equality in the sector; youth and their engagement in aquaculture, while noting that ‘youth’ does not equate to “jobs” and requires the lifting of many more societal hurdles for their full participation in the sector; indigenous people and local ecological knowledge—a precious asset for future aquaculture as well as the survival and enhancement of the cultural value of aquaculture; and people with disabilities and other minorities who have yet to become fully visible and accounted for in aquaculture development. Redressing human and social issues in aquaculture, and placing people at the center of aquaculture development requires a fundamental change from business as usual. To humanize aquaculture development, a renewed human relationship with aquaculture is proposed, which is founded on recognizing substantive equality and agency, embracing intersectionality, that is, the multiple social dimensions of identity and interaction, and valuing cross‐disciplinary knowledge systems. It would be implemented through new, inclusive, business models, social provisioning approaches, and procedural justice and governance mechanisms for overcoming inequalities. Public, private, and non‐state actors will need to be involved, inclusive of small‐scale farmers, women, youth, people with disabilities, and indigenous communities as key groups. Six key messages conclude the article.
... Oedalechilus labeo (Cuvier, 1829) inhabits only marine coastal waters, while the other species [Mugil cephalus Linnaeus, 1758, Liza ramada (Risso, 1827), Liza saliens (Risso, 1810), Liza aurata (Risso, 1810), and Chelon labrosus (Risso, 1827)] usually migrate from the sea into inland transitional waters, such as rivers and coastal lagoons, where they represent a target for aquaculture and fisheries. In many Mediterranean countries, mullets represent the principal yield of lagoons fisheries and extensive aquaculture, e.g. the 'valliculture' of the Northen Italy and the 'howash' in Egypt (Ardizzone, Cataudella & Rossi 1988;Macfadyen, Nasr Allah, Reheem Kenawy, Ahmed, Hebicha, Diab, Hussein, Abouzied & El Naggar 2011). However, between 2006 and 2010, the mullet production in Mediterranean inland aquaculture decreased from 250 000 to 120 000 tons (FAO -General Fisheries Commission for the Mediterranean 2013). ...
Article
Full-text available
Demand for Maize and products with added value has expanded dramatically over the past few years, and there has been a notable growth in the global supply. One of the most important steps in Value Chain Analysis is to understand the connection and interaction between actors and processes along the chain. The research attempts to identify and map the stakeholders involved in value chain of Maize and their functions in Tiruppur district of Tamil Nadu. The results showed that, there were six different marketing channels identified as in existing Maize value chain. The main actors were input suppliers, farmers, local traders, wholesalers, processors, retailers and consumers. The core processes were input provision, production, collection, processing and retailing. Input was provided by input shops and production was taken up by farmers. Collection activity was taken up by the market intermediaries and processors were involved in value addition of Maize which in turn was sold to the consumers through retailers. Geographical mapping indicated physical flow of Maize.
Article
Full-text available
Nile tilapia (Oreochromis niloticus) is one of the most farmed fish globally, with a significant contribution improving local livelihoods, especially in developing countries. Nile tilapia was first cultured in Kenya in 1924 and is the most cultured fish species. Annually, O. niloticus accounts for 62% (∼15,000 tonnes) of total aquaculture production. Although O. niloticus is the most preferred cultured fish, its culture faces challenges, for example, early maturation due to prolific breeding behaviour leading to stunted growth that limits its culture and profitability among smallholder farmers. With the surging demand for locally farmed fish, innovative technologies have emerged to boost aquaculture production. Donor and public research‐funded projects, for instance, the Kenya Climate Smart Agriculture Project, are validating various aquaculture technologies, innovations and management practices (TIMPs) to achieve ‘triple wins’ of increased fish production, improved resilience and reduced greenhouse gas emissions. In addition, the International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD)‐funded Aquaculture Business Development Programme aims at commercialising aquaculture to improve local livelihoods. In this study, we adopt a scoping review methodology to review and synthesise published literature on tilapia culture in Kenya to explore current and emerging tilapia production technologies and document their socio‐economic impacts on farmers’ livelihoods. These emerging innovative technologies range from culture systems, for example, biofloc, periphyton, fingerpond technology, integrated aquaculture, breeding and genetics (selective breeding), fish health and biosecurity measures, to post‐harvest loss reduction, value addition and marketing. The study findings reveal that the technologies have great potential to increase tilapia production and profitability and positively impact the local livelihoods of smallholder fish farmers through employment creation, economic growth and better nutrition.
Article
Full-text available
We describe a combined ecological and economic approach aimed at giving more equal emphasis to both disciplines, while being integrated so that design, analysis, data entry and storage, and result capabilities are developed with emphasis on deriving a user-friendly, easily accessible tool. We have thus developed the approach as an integrated module of the freely available Ecopath with Ecosim scientific software; the world's most widely applied ecological modeling tool. We link the trophic ecosystem model to a value-chain approach where we explicitly and in considerable detail keep track of the flow (amounts, revenue, and costs) of fish products from sea through to the end consumer. We also describe the social aspects of the fish production and trade, by evaluating employment and income diagnostics. This is done with emphasis on distribution income while accounting for social aspects of the fishing sector. From a management perspective, one of the interesting aspects of the approach we introduce here, is that it opens for direct evaluation of what impact management interventions, e.g., quota settings, effort regulation, or area closures, may have on the ecosystem, the economy and the social setting, as well as on food availability for the consumer.
Article
Full-text available
This article builds a theoretical framework to help explain governance patterns in global value chains. It draws on three streams of literature – transaction costs economics, production networks, and technological capability and firm-level learning – to identify three variables that play a large role in determining how global value chains are governed and change. These are: (1) the complexity of transactions, (2) the ability to codify transactions, and (3) the capabilities in the supply-base. The theory generates five types of global value chain governance – hierarchy, captive, relational, modular, and market – which range from high to low levels of explicit coordination and power asymmetry. The article highlights the dynamic and overlapping nature of global value chain governance through four brief industry case studies: bicycles, apparel, horticulture and electronics.
Article
Full-text available
This article aims to guide the design and implementation of action-research projects in value-chain analysis by presenting a strategic framework focused on small producers and trading and processing firms in developing countries. Its stepwise approach - building on the conceptual framework set out in a companion article - covers in detail what to do, questions to be asked and issues to be considered, and integrates poverty, gender, labour and environmental concerns.'Upgrading' strategies potentially available for improving value-chain participation for small producers are identified, with the ultimate purpose of increasing the rewards and&sol;or reducing the risks. Copyright (c) The Authors 2010. Journal compilation (c) 2010 Overseas Development Institute..
FAO FISHSTAT database, accessed at the time of writing. General Authority For Fisheries Resource Development (GAFRD)
FAO FISHSTAT database, accessed at the time of writing. General Authority For Fisheries Resource Development (GAFRD), 2011. 2001-2010. Fish Production Statistics. Miscellaneous Issues.
A Practical Guide to Mainstreaming Gender Analysis in Value Chain Development. International Labour Office
  • L Mayoux
  • G Mackie
Mayoux, L., Mackie, G., 2008. A Practical Guide to Mainstreaming Gender Analysis in Value Chain Development. International Labour Office, Addis Ababa.
Promoting gender equitable opportunities in agricultural value chains: a handbook. Publication Prepared under the Greater Access to Trade Expansion (GATE) Project, under the Women in Development IQC Contract No
  • D Rubin
  • C Manfre
  • K N Barrett
Rubin, D., Manfre, C., Barrett, K.N., 2009. Promoting gender equitable opportunities in agricultural value chains: a handbook. Publication Prepared under the Greater Access to Trade Expansion (GATE) Project, under the Women in Development IQC Contract No. GEW-I-00-02-00018-00, Task Order No. 02. United States Agency for International Development, Washington, DC.
Gender analysis of aquaculture value chain in northeast Vietnam and Nigeria: World Bank Agriculture and Rural Development Discussion Paper
  • A Veliu
  • N Gessese
  • C Ragasa
  • C Okali
Veliu, A., Gessese, N., Ragasa, C., Okali, C., 2009. Gender analysis of aquaculture value chain in northeast Vietnam and Nigeria: World Bank Agriculture and Rural Development Discussion Paper, 44.