MethodPDF Available

Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices

Authors:
  • InfoBridge Foundation (IBF)

Abstract

A practical example is given how to calculate Fair Prices for agricultural products originating from small-holders. It starts with the calculation of a Living Wage as it is known in industry (esp. textile), based on the needs of a worker to maintain his/her family. This Living Wage is the basis for the calculation of a Living Income for the farmer. The Living Income per household combined with production costs, determines the amount the farmer has to receive for his products. Based on this income needed and the actual production costs, a Fair Price can be calculated for each different crop.
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Ruud Bronkhorst
Rural Development Economist
InfoBridge Foundation
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
September 2016
Ruud Bronkhorst (1948) is a development economist who worked as staff member and as a
consultant with several national and international organizations, such as FAO, WFP, Ministry
of Foreign Affairs of the Netherlands and several NGO’s.
In 2008 he joined InfoBridge Foundation and works on food security, rural development,
living income and fair prices.
rbronkh@infobridge.org / rbronkh@planet.nl
www.infobridge.org
Cover photo: Goats as a source of additional income, Burkina Faso (Photo by author)
@2016 by Ruud Bronkhorst rbronkh@infobridge.org
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Table of contents
SUMMARY ...................................................................... 1
INTRODUCTION .............................................................. 2
CALCULATION OF A LIVING WAGE .............................. ….5
CALCULATION OF LIVING INCOME………………………….......9
CALCULATION OF A 'FAIR' PRICE'………………………..……….10
CONCLUSIONS………………………………………….………………….19
REFERENCES……………………………………..……………..………….20
ANNEX…...………………………………………………………….………..22
Graphs
Graph I Relation family size and wage-earners………………………………………..8
Graph II: Living Wage and Living Income in FCFA………………………………..…..9
Graph III: Fair Prices maize under different production methods…………...13
Graph IV: Producer prices and calculated fair prices for maize
in Burkina Faso during 1985 2005……………………………..……….……14
Tables
Table I: Working days and other costs for 1 ha. maize working with
a plough on soil enriched with fertilizer…………….…….……………………………10
Table II: Maize production in kg/ha……………………………………………………….11
Table III: Maize production costs and production in kg for 4.4 ha………….12
Table IV: ‘Fair’ price in case of 4.4 ha maize only…………………………...……..12
1
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
SUMMARY
A practical example is given how to calculate Fair Prices for agricultural products originating
from small-holders. It starts with the calculation of a Living Wage as it is known in industry
(esp. textile), based on the needs of a worker to maintain his/her family. This Living Wage is
the basis for the calculation of a Living Income for the farmer. The Living Income per
household combined with production costs, determines the amount the farmer has to
receive for his products. Based on this income needed and the actual production costs, a Fair
Price can be calculated for each different crop.
An Excel-sheet is attached showing the different steps to be taken to calculate a Fair Price.
2
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
INTRODUCTION
1
Common opinion is that a market price is the right price, because it is the result of supply
and demand. It is a pity that this belief is so widespread, because the market price is only an
equilibrium price, when and if, all conditions are fulfilled. That means perfect competition
without any distortions like monopolies, oligopolies etc. When we look at markets like those
for cocoa, coffee and tea, it appears that a small number of large companies dominate the
market. Since they all have to compete, none of them is inclined to pay more than the
others. As for the small farmer, he does not have a choice; he has to accept the price offered
to him.
There are numerous reports that small farmers have a larger output/ha than large farms, see
among others Hazell et al (IFPRI), Reardon et al, van der Ploeg. For the small farmer who
wants to market his products, not only the price he is paid is important. Other important
factors are the availability of markets, roads and other infrastructure, availability and price
of inputs, subsidies and taxes, etc.
In practice however, emphasis is laid on these other aspects, while leaving out the price
received by the producer for his products. Prices are taken as an objective factor that cannot
be changed unless the whole system is changed to a situation wherein it is not the market
anymore that leads to equilibrium prices.
Therefore we have to make a brain shift to a situation where not the theory of supply and
demand with all its theoretical assumptions and problems, is in the centre, but the question
how to use the pricing mechanism to ensure not only a decent price to the consumers, but
to the producers as well.
It is in this context that the Living Income / Fair Price approach may be useful.
Before we can discuss the question why thinking about fair prices might be important, first
we should define what we mean by a fair price.
We can define a Fair Price to the producer as the price that enables the producer to earn a
Living Income, which means the net income a household would need to earn to enable all
members of the household to afford a decent standard of living.
1
I would like to thank Marc Bleijenbergh for his critical support and advices, as well as
Eberhard Krain and Friederike Martin, both of GIZ, for sharing ideas on their and my work on
Living Income. Karel Dekker has kindly provided the excel sheet in the Annex.
Of course I remain solely responsible for any faults and mistakes in both approach and
calculations.
3
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
One of the means necessary for agricultural growth is financial means. Farmers can only
invest when their basic needs are satisfied. This means that they must receive a price for
their products that enables them to fulfil their basic needs as well as a small surplus to
invest.
There is a habit to subsidize inputs (seeds, fertilizer) because small farmers cannot afford
them otherwise. This system is vulnerable for fraud and corruption. Should the farmer have
enough income from the sale of his products, however, he can afford to purchase these
essential items himself, without being dependant on governments, financial institutions,
NGO’s etc.
In that case financial institutions do not have to give loans to farmers but can assist them to
save, in line with recent developments where many institutions already have shifted their
attention from giving loans to assisting the customer to save.
Calculation of FP's may be especially useful for policy makers, be it in government, donors,
cooperatives or NGO's. It can help them to formulate clear policies, geared towards the
needs of the target group.
Examples how calculated FP's can support policy decisions:
- Differences between market prices and the prices farmers should receive in order to be
able to continue farming can immediately be seen
- These differences highlight the question of the long term consequences should these
differences continue (e.g. accelerated growth of the cities with poor citizens)
- By changing data in the model, several alternatives can be examined, for example: when
conditions of delivery of inputs change (think of price, availability, training, infrastructure),
different plot-sizes, ways of production, mechanization, imports and labour needs, changes
in family size
- When it is not expected that the calculated fair price can ever be achieved (think of dry
and infertile soils where production is very low like semi-desert areas where pastoralism
may be more rewarding than agriculture), it shows that other alternatives than agriculture
should be explored.
What follows is a practical example how to calculate fair prices for agricultural products
originating from small-holders. It is not meant as an elaborate calculation of a fair price, but
is rather a basis to proceed from when the need for calculating a fair price arises. Each
situation is different, so in each situation the parameters to be used will be different as well,
but this example provides a basic structure to start from.
It consists of three basic elements, first the calculation of a Living Wage and following that,
of a Living Income and then the calculation of the fair price.
Since this is not an all-inclusive, detailed study with a lot of field-work, use has been made as
much as possible of existing data. This to show that indications of what a fair price should be
can be made without costly research as well. For a method for calculating Living Income in a
more sophisticated way, see Anker 2014.
4
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Smallholder rice field in India (Kerala)
Photo by author
Schematically the calculation of a Fair Price (FP) is made in the following way:
Steps
1. Calculation of Living Income (LI) required
2. a. Calculation of production, marketing, storage and other costs
b. Production in kg of target crop
3. Calculation of price/kg that will lead to a Living Income.
This price is the so-called ‘Fair Price’.
The main steps of this approach are worked out in the next example.
For an integrated approach of the LI/FP method in project analysis see Bronkhorst 2014.
In The Annex an Excel model is given that can be used to calculate a Fair Price.
5
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
CALCULATION OF A LIVING WAGE
In the region Boucle du Mouhoun in Burkina Faso, farmers grow maize, millet and sorghum
as food products and cotton for cash income. This example will show that even in a situation
where many relevant data are lacking, it is possible to arrive at satisfactory outcomes and
that way gain important insight.
Definitions :
For Living Wage the following formula is used:
)
savings (set at 10% of income)
+
Whereby:
- The local average household size (which can be different from a standard family) and
the average number of adult earners per household are used
- The sum of the weights of its members is calculated by valuing adults as 1, and
persons aged under 18 as 0.5
- For the adult earners both men and women are calculated as 1
2
. Children between
14 - 18 years may be calculated as 0.5
3
.
- Where the non-food component cannot easily be determined, the extrapolated
approach with percentages adapted to local circumstances can be used
- For the food component a norm of 2400 kcal/day could be used
- Deduct all provisions provided
Living income is the net income a household would need to earn to enable all
members of the household to afford a decent standard of living. Elements of a
decent standard of living thereby include: food, water, housing, education, health
care, transport, clothing, and other essential needs including provision for
2
Productivity of men and women in agriculture can be different, as is the case between two people of the same sex. In this
approach the Living Wage that people should earn is independent of their productivity. What counts here is that everyone who
works full time should earn a Living Wage at least
3
It is everywhere usual that children during peak periods work with their parents on the farm, during their school holidays,
after school hours etc. Therefore they cannot be left out, but also cannot be valued as adult full-time workers.
6
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
unexpected events (Living Income Practitioners’ Workshop hosted by ISEAL & GIZ,
Eschborn, February 2015).
‘Fair’ prices are the prices that result when Total Revenue equals production costs
plus Living Income (Living Income equals the total of Living Wages at the farm plus
10% investment costs).
For our Burkina Faso case, we will start by taking the poverty line as basis for our
calculations, since for this country no Living Wages have been calculated so far (for other
countries Living Wages can be found at WageIndicator.org (www.wageindicator.org).
By taking the poverty line as basis we are faced with the problem that, although the
methodology for how the poverty line has been established, namely on basis of known costs
of food and non-food
4
, different poverty lines exist, namely a national poverty line of CFAF
5
72,110, a rural poverty line of CFAF 71,737 and an urban poverty line of CFAF 73,557 (data
INSD in World Bank 2005).
For our calculations it seems appropriate to take the rural poverty line
6
as our point of
departure because our case is about the rural areas of Burkina Faso, Boucle du Mouhoun.
This rural poverty line has been calculated at CFAF 71,737.
The next step is to look at the average size of the family to calculate the Living Wage.
4
From World Bank Report No. 29743-BUR: Box 4: How is the Official Poverty Line Computed?
INSD constructs a poverty line using the "cost of basic needs" approach, in three steps:
First, the food component of the poverty line is estimated by valuing a set of food items providing the
recommended intake of 2283 calories per capita per day at the prices prevailing during the survey. The food
items used by INSD consist of four staples most consumed by the households in Burkina Faso, namely
sorghum, millet, com and rice. A standard conversion table is used to determine the caloric content of each Kg of product. The
composition of this food basket reflects the share of these four staples in the consumption of the households for each survey,
and thus changes from survey to survey. The basket is evaluated at the prices of the four staples prevailing in Ouagadougou
markets at the time of the survey.
Second, the non-food component is equal to the non-food expenditures observed for the households whose food consumption
is close to the food poverty line estimated above. The ratio of non-food to food consumption is estimated for each household.
Then, the share of non-food consumption in the total poverty line is chosen to be the share reported by those households
whose food consumption is close to the value of the food poverty line (for instance, ±1 percent). The ratio obtained thus far is
multiplied by the food poverty line to get the non-food component of the poverty line. In other words, if the typical household
near the food poverty line consumes food and non-food items of about equal value, the non-food component would be set
equivalent to the food poverty line.
The official poverty line then is determined as the sum of the food and non-food components.
5
FCFA stands for Franc CFA, the currency used in West-Africa. It has affixed exchange rate to the Euro: 100 FCFA = 0.152449
EUR.
6
The high seasonality of prices of the main staples, especially during the lean period, contributes to the fluctuation of the
nominal poverty line, and generates dramatic swings in the share of food in total household consumption from one survey to
the other.
7
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
According to the Burkina Faso household survey, 2003 SARPN the average household size
in 2003 was 6,4 (SARPN).
ONAPAD estimates average household size in Boucle du Mouhoun at 7,8
7
(ONAPAD).
Since ONAPAD figures relate to Boucle du Mouhoun only, while the SARPN data are the
average for the whole of Burkina Faso, it seems preferable to use for our calculations the
data provided by ONAPAD, so an average household size in Boucle du Mouhoun of 7,8.
In the case of African households the wife works as much on the land as the husband. Also
children are involved in agricultural activities in their spare time. Therefore both men and
women between the age of 18 and 60 are valued as 1, and persons from 14 to 18 years as
0.5. both children < 14 yrs and elderly (>60 yrs of age) are valued as 0.
Akresh counts a number of 10.6 per household (Number of Members per Household 10.6,
Number of Wives per Household 1.5, Children Under Age 18 per Household 3.6, Children
Above Age 18 per Household 3.2 and Number of Additional Other Members per Household
1.3) (Akresh 2005), whereas ONAPAD counts 7,8 household members (ONAPAD 2004).
Unfortunately, ONAPAD provides no details about the composition of the households.
If the percentages would be equal in both cases, we can use the data to calculate the
following composition of households in Boucle du Mouhoun:
Number of Members per Household 7.8
Head of the household 1
Number of Wives per Household 1.1
Number of Children Under Age 18 per Household 2.6
Number of Children Above Age 18 per Household 2.3
Number of Additional Other Members per Household 0.9
Total comes at 7,9 because of round-offs.
Since we do not know the number of children between 15 and 18 years of age, we will not
include a figure for them in the calculations.
So we may estimate the number of adult family wage earners (>18<60 yrs) at 1 + 1.1 + 2.3 =
4,4
8
, and the size of the household at 1+1.1+2.6/2+2.3+0.9 = 6,6.
7
A possible explanation for these large families given by ONAPAD is that an important part of the heads of the households is
polygamy (33,6%).
8
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Graph I shows the relationship between the number of family members, the weighed family
size and the number of wage-earners.
Graph I Relation family size and wage-earners
When applied to the formula of the Living Wage, that is
Average household size x (cost of food + cost of non-food per person
)
savings (set at 10% of income)
+
Average number of adult earners per household
This results in: (6,6 * 71.737) / 4,4 + (10% * 107606) = 118.366 FCFA as amount for the
Living Wage per adult worker in Boucle du Mouhoun in Burkina Faso.
It should be noted that the calculation of a Living Wage is based on averages, so a Living
Wage will not be sufficient for everyone. Both for family size and expenses averages are
used so it seldom fits a real situation. Yet, working with averages is the best we can do to
approach reality.
8
Reality is often more complicated than this. Besides that, African men may have more than one spouse, there often is a close
cooperation between several households (brothers, sisters, parents) so that it is preferable to look at the Unit of Production
and the Unit of Consumption to make a better calculation. For this example, this would lead too far however.
9
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
CALCULATION OF LIVING INCOME
The Living Wage per adult worker for an average family of 7,8 persons with 4,4 wage-earners
has been calculated above and amounts to 118.366 FCFA. This means that a family with 4,4
adult wage earners should receive 4,4 * 118.366 = 520.811 FCFA as income for the produce.
At the level of the firm (household) this amount should be raised by another 10% to have
some additional income for small investments (hoe, shovel etc.) as well, so total income of
the household should amount to 520.811 + 10% * 520.811 = 572.892 FCFA in order to
achieve a Living Income.
Graph II shows the difference between the calculated Living Wage and Living Income.
Graph II: Living Wage and Living Income in FCFA
10
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
CALCULATION OF A 'FAIR' PRICE
Our case is an area that can be exploited of 4.4 ha in Boucle du Mouhoun, Burkina Faso,
where sorghum, millet and maize are grown. As additional cash income cotton is produced.
We will take the example of one crop, maize. This will give the equilibrium price should the
peasant produce one crop only and be dependent on that crop only to achieve a Living
Wage. We assume that all adult family workers work all year full-time at the farm.
a. Calculation of production, marketing, storage and other costs
Maize
Maize is cultivated either on a terrain that requires fertilisation or on the same plot where
previously cotton was grown. As the cotton was fertilised the maize doesn’t require further
fertilisation.
There are four cases to be distinguished with regard to the way the work is done:
1. With Plough, no fertilizer
2. With Plough, fertilizer used
3. With Tractor, no fertilizer
4. With Tractor, fertilizer used
The next table indicates the number of working days required per ha for maize when
working with a plough, and fertilizer is applied.
Table I: Working days and other costs for 1 ha. maize working with a plough on soil enriched
with fertilizer
Maize days Costs in FCFA
costs with plough and
fertilizer
Working days
labour
costs
other
costs
Clearing
10 working days at 750 FCFA a day (500 F salary + 250
F food)
7500
Stump removal
10 days
7500
Ploughing
16 days
12000
Seeding and shelving
5 days
3750
Hoeing and weeding
16 days
12000
Earthing up
16 days
12000
Harvesting
10 days
7.500
Packaging, handling,
transport
7 days
5250
19750
11
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Fertilizing
150 kg NPK (150*225) and 100 kg urea (100*215)
55250
Total
90 days
67500
75000
(Source: calculated from data provided by MARH)
Total cost of production is 67.500 + 75.000 = 142.500 FCFA. It is important to realize that
labour costs consist of hired workers only; the cost of family labour is included in the Living
Income.
b. Production in kg of target crop
Table II: Maize production in kg/ha
Production per ha
Fertilizer applied 4500kg/ha
No fertilizer applied 3000 kg/ha
(Source: MARH)
c. Calculation of price/kg (Fair Price) that will lead to a Living Income
What can be calculated now is the price the producer should receive for his produce in order
to obtain a Living Income when producing maize only.
For sake of analysis we distinguish three cases of peasants. One group does not
commercialise food, a second group that does commercialize part of its produce and a third
group that has a larger surface to work and commercializes part of its produce as well. All
groups, however, may produce and sell cotton. The groups are defined according to the
findings of the research done by TASIM/AO
9
1. A group that does not commercialise food and has an average of 2,8 ha. at its
disposal, and
2. A group that commercializes part of its produce has an average of 4,4 ha. at its
disposal, and
3. A group that commercializes part of its produce and has an average of 6,8 ha. at its
disposal.
9
Unfortunately TASIM/AO provides data at U.P. (production unit) only. UP’s do not
necessarily coincide with families. By lack of data at family level the data for UP’s are used in
the calculations.
12
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
The first group with an average of 2,8 ha does produce food but that is mainly for auto-
consumption and barter. They are outside the marketing system for food products (not for
cotton) and therefore market prices of cereals don’t affect them much. For our analysis of
cereal market prices, we leave them therefore out and concentrate on those peasants that
commercialise (part of) their produce. Here we will discuss peasants with an average of 4,4
ha at their disposal.
The case of 4,4 ha
Table III : Maize production costs and production in kg for 4.4 ha
Maize
Cost/ha
(FCFA)
Cost 4.4 ha
(FCFA)
Production/ha
(kg)
Production 4.4 ha
(kg)
tractor and fertilizer
181500
798600
4500
19800
tractor, no fertilizer
118750
522500
3000
13200
plough and fertilizer
142500
627000
4500
19800
plough, no fertilizer
79750
350900
3000
13200
In the case of production of maize on 4,4 ha with plough and fertilizer 19.800 kg must be
equal to 627000 (costs for 4,4 ha) + 572.892 (household income needed) in order to achieve
a fair price (Living Wage for each worker plus production costs plus 10% investments) for the
producer. This means a price to the producer of (627000 + 572.892) / 19.800 = 60,60
FCFA/kg. This is the FP for a producer when producing maize only on 4.4 ha.
This way we get the following ‘fair’ prices for different cases:
Table IV : ‘Fair’ price in case of 4.4 ha maize only
‘Fair’ price (FCFA)
a. tractor and fertilizer
69,27
FCFA/kg
b. tractor, no fertilizer
82,98
FCFA/kg
c. plough and fertilizer
60,60
FCFA/kg
d. plough, no fertilizer
69,98
FCFA/kg
13
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Graph III: Fair Prices maize under different production methods
It is interesting that this table appears to show that in this case the combination plough and
fertilizer is most profitable for the farmer. This shows the necessity of a good availability of
fertilizer at a low price. It also raises the question in what circumstances the use of a tractor
becomes more profitable than use of the plough. This may have to do with investment costs,
size of the farm and the availability of labour.
We can now compare the calculated Fair Prices with the paid producer prices during 1985
2005. This is shown in the next graph.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
tractor and
fertilizer
tractor, no
fertilizer
plough and
fertilizer
plough, no
fertilizer
Fair Price maize 4,4 ha in FCFA
Fair Price maize 4,4 ha in
FCFA
14
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Graph IV: Producer prices and calculated fair prices for maize in Burkina Faso during 1985
2005
Source: Production prices DPSAA/DGPER, Fair prices calculated
It can be very clearly seen that producer prices vary enormously from year to year. This is
due to the erratic rainfall in the country. So the difference between producer price and fair
price is also each year different again.
When calculating ‘fair’ prices for three products instead of for maize only, we may examine
the case where the peasant grows all three crops during the year, on let’s assume 1, 2 ha
millet, 1,1 ha sorghum and 2,1 ha maize. Total 4,4 ha. The total income the peasant derives
from it with ‘fair’ prices equals the amount of Living Income he has to earn.
Production costs are different though for the three crops. So the calculation for maize will
be:
(Production cost maize + 2,1/4,4 * LI) / Quantity produced = Fair Price maize.
So the FP for maize in the case of 2,1 ha maize with production cost of 142500/ha *2,1 =
299250 FCFA and 9450 kg production (4500 kg production/ha) will be:
(299250 + 2,1/4,4* 572.892) / 9450 = 60,60 FCFA / kg.
As could be expected, this amount is the same as when calculated for production of maize
only on all surface.
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
Price in FCFA
Year
Producer prices and Fair prices maize
1985 - 2005
Producer price
Fair Price a
Fair Price b
Fair Price c
Fair Price d
15
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
To summarise
Maize: plough and fertilizer
Costs/ha
Fertilizer, transport etc. 87000
Labour (74 days at 750 F/day)) 55500
--------
Total costs 142500
To be earned (LI/ha) 130203
----------
Total 272703
Production in kg. 4500 kg/ha
Minimal to be earned (FP) per kg 272703 / 4500 = 60,60 F/kg
About labour: labour costs are calculated at actual costs which is higher here than LW. In LI
labour costs are calculated at LW though. This way labour costs are not calculated double.
Labour consists of external labourers, which is a costs factor. Labour by the farmer and his
family costs are implied in the costs of LI. It may follow from this that working for another is
financially more rewarding than working on the peasant’s own farm. But if one chooses the
option of working for another farmer for higher wages, this will provide income for a short
period only.
Should the market price for labour be equal to LW though, we get the following picture:
Costs /ha
Fertilizer, transport etc.
87000
Labour
(74 days at 428,86F/day)
31736
-----------
Total costs
118736
To be earned (LI/ha)
130203
-----------
Total
248939
Production in kg. 4500 kg/ha
Minimal to be earned (FP) per kg 248939 / 4500 = 55,32 F/kg.
16
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Should the market price of labour be below the Living Wage for our calculations we still have
to take the LW into account and not the lower market price, because the FP is based upon
the payment of LW and not on actual prices. So the FP cannot be below 55,32 F, unless
production costs or production/ha change.
All this only applies when the farmer spends a certain amount of his time on this crop, in this
case with 74 days/ha as well. When he spends less time on this crop, production will go
down as well. So for the calculations it is necessary to put a norm to calculate the FP. When
he spends less time on this crop, the FP will not change, but he will not be able to achieve a
LI with this crop (this may be compensated by spending more time on other crops so that in
total he may end with a higher LI).
17
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Additional income
Cattle as a source of additional income, Kerala, India
Photo by author
Additional small income (chickens, eggs, milk etc.) can be included at market prices. So when
they sell and eat for let’s say 1.000 FCFA chicken and 500 FCFA eggs at market prices, the
amount of 1.500 FCFA is deducted from the LI amount. This LI becomes 572.892 1.500 =
571.392 FCFA, or 571392/4.4 = 129862 F/ ha.
So taking into account this additional income, the FP calculation for maize becomes:
Maize: plough and fertilizer
Costs/ha
Fertilizer, transport etc. 87000
Labour (74 days at 750 F/day)) 55500
--------
Total costs 142500
To be earned (LI/ha) 129862
---------
Total 272362
Production in kg. 4500 kg/ha
FP per kg 272362/ 4500 = 60,52 F/kg
18
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
So the extra activities of the household do influence the FP for maize, but to a minor degree.
Suppose net household income of the cultivation of cotton, home grown food and labour for
others amounts to 200.000 FCFA. Maize and cotton are cultivated on the same plot. Then
again the equilibrium prices will change, because net income to be derived from these food
crops may be less. In the formula for calculating the equilibrium price an amount of 572.892
FCFA has been used (Living Wage for each worker plus investment costs) in order to achieve
a fair price.
Now we can diminish the 572.892 FCFA with the 200.000 received from other sources, the
amount then to be used in the formula becomes 372.892. The amount of 200.000 FCFA is
deducted from the LI amount. This LI becomes 572.892 200.000 = 372.892 FCFA, or
372.892/4.4 = 84.748 F/ha.
This has the following effects on the equilibrium prices:
Maize: plough and fertilizer
Costs/ha
Fertilizer, transport etc. 87000
Labour (74 days at 750 F/day)) 55500
--------
Total costs 142500
To be earned (LI/ha) 84748
----------
Total 272703
Production in kg. 4500 kg/ha
FP per kg 272703/ 4500 = 50,50 F/kg
So where small extra activities of the household do influence the FP for maize to a minor
degree, the situation is only different when those activities comprise a larger part of income.
19
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
CONCLUSIONS
With the amount required for a Living Income and production costs known, ´fair´ prices that
the peasant needs to receive for his crops can be calculated.
It appears that the Fair Price calculated does not determine Living Wage and Living Income.
On the other hand, both Living Wage and Living Income, as well as the market price for
labour when this price is above the Living Wage, influence the amount of the Fair Price.
Differences in number of working hours/days do not influence the Fair Price because we are
working with average working hours/days/ha. This way mismanagement of time is not
reflected in the Fair Price.
Minor extra activities of the household do influence the Fair Price, but to a minor degree.
Whereas small extra activities of the household do influence the Fair Price to a minor degree
only, the situation is different when those activities comprise a larger part of income. This
requires a new calculation of the Fair Price.
When market prices are lower than ´fair´ prices, the reasons for this should be analysed. On
the basis of those results policies can be formulated. Possibilities include among others
removal of market distortions (such as subsidized food imports, food aid that is sold on the
market, power positions in the marketing chain) that have a negative effect on market prices
of agricultural products, as well as by providing infrastructure and inputs together with
technical advice, giving income- or production- subsidies or by creating more remunerative
employment in the rural areas.
Use of the Living Income and Fair Price concept in the agricultural context is not easy and
requires a lot of work, but it can be done even when little information is available, as shown
in this Burkina Faso case.
20
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
REFERENCES
Akresh, Richard: Risk, Network Quality, and Family Structure: Child Fostering Decisions in
Burkina Faso, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign; Institute for the Study of Labor
(IZA) January 2005, IZA Discussion Paper No. 1471; Yale University Economic Growth Center
Discussion Paper No. 902 http://ssrn.com/abstract=643163
Anker, Richard and Martha, Living Wage for rural Malawi with Focus on Tea Growing area of
Southern Malawi, January 2014
http://www.fairtrade.net/fileadmin/user_upload/content/2009/resources/LivingWageRepo
rt_Malawi.pdf
Bronkhorst, Ruud (2004): ‘Fair’ Prices and Wages, Economic and Political Weekly, August 21,
2004
Bronkhorst, Ruud (2011): How to strengthen the development effectiveness of local
purchase for food aid, Development in Practice, 21:7, 2011, 913-929
Bronkhorst, Ruud (2013): ‘Fair’ Prices: Peasants and the possibilities of a Living Income
(including a case study of Burkina Faso), InfoBridge, December 2013,
http://www.share4dev.info/fairprice/documents/5194.pdf
Bronkhorst, Ruud (2014): Towards an integrated approach for project analysis for small
farmers: the Living Income / Fair Price method, InfoBridge, November 2014,
http://www.share4dev.info/kb/documents/5218.pdf
Discussion group Fair Price / Fair Wages: http://www.linkedin.com/groups/Fair-Price-Fair-
Wages-3927599
Ducommun, Gil avec Ouedraogo Sylvestre, Cecchini Hugo et Bengaly Abdoulaye: La
commercialisation paysanne de produits vivriers, région de Dédougou, Projet de recherche
TASIM-AO Burkina Faso, Série Documents de travail N° 1, Mars 2003
Hazell, Peter & Poulton, Colin & Wiggins, Steve and Dorward, Andrew: The Future of
Small Farms for Poverty Reduction and Growth IFPRI 2020 Discussion Paper 42, May
2007
ONAPAD: Analyse des déterminants de la pauvreté dans la Boucle du Mouhoun Décembre
2004, ONAPAD série études 8
Ploeg, J.D. van der: Peasant-driven agricultural growth and food sovereignty, The Journal of
Peasant Studies 41 (6), 2014. - p. 999 - 1030
21
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Reardon, Thomas n Kelly Valerie n Crawford, Eric n Jayne, Thomas n Savadogo,
Kimseyinmga n Clay, Daniel: Determinants of farm productivity in Africa: a synthesis of
four case studies, USAID Technical Paper No. 75, December 1997 SARPN: Burkina Faso
household survey, 2003 http://www.sarpn.org/documents/d0002933/16-
Africa_dev_indicators_2007.pdf
WageIndicator www.wageindicator.org
World Bank: Reducing Poverty Through Sustained Equitable Growth Poverty Assessment,
Report No. 29743-BUR Burkina Faso, 2005
http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTPOVERTY/EXTPA/0,,contentMDK:
20571227~menuPK:435735~pagePK:148956~piPK:216618~theSitePK:430367~isCURL:Y~isCU
RL:Y,00.html
22
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
ANNEX
This Annex contains an Excel sheet with the necessary steps to be taken to calculate a Fair
Price. The amounts and quantities respond to the amounts and quantities in the example,
but it can be used as a framework to work with for any crop.
Annex 1 is the calculation in the local currency, while annex 2 contains the same calculations
now expressed in US $.
23
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Table 1
Calculation model for Fair price input
XOF is currency code for FCFA
Family size Head of HH Wives per HH Child < 18yrs Child > 18yrs ≥ 60 yrs Total
Family members 1,0 1,1 2,6 2,3 0,9 7,90
Weigh factor 1,0 1,0 0,5 1,0 1,0
Weighed family members 1,0 1,1 1,3 2,3 0,9 6,6
Cost of food pp /year XOF 35.000 XOF 35 .000 XOF 17.500 XOF 35.00 0 XOF 35.000 XOF 231 .000
Cost of non -food pp/ per year XOF 36.737 XOF 36 .737 XOF 18.369 XOF 36.73 7 XOF 36.737 XOF 242 .464
Total XOF 473.46 4
Needed savings 10% XOF 47.346
Needed hh income/yr XOF 520.811
Head of HH Wives per HH Child < 18yrs Child > 18yrs
≥ 60 yrs /Additional
Average number of adult earners per household 1,0 1,1 0,0 2,3 0,0 4,4
LW pp/yr (per earning adult) XOF 118.366
Working days/ yr = calendar days – Sundays – festivals –
social obligations - calamities – sick days
Total days/yr Sun days free days sickness Total working days / yr
Working days/ yr 365 52 20 18,25 275
LW per adult earning family member per working day XOF 431
On basis of this Living Income (LI) can be calculated factor> 1,1 XOF 572.892
LI/yr= (Number of Adult earners * LW)x 1,1
Size of the farm in ha 4,40 ha
LI/ha = LI / size of the farm XOF 130.203
Needed to calculate costs per crop / ha (these costs may differ, depending on way of cultivation, e.g. with/without fertilizer and/or improved seeds)
a b c d a. maize: plough no fertilizer
Investments / repayments (interest and depreciation) b. maize: plough and fertilizer
Inputs c. rice
Hired labour XOF 67.500 XOF 67.500 d. wheat
Field operation costs
Harvest and post harvest costs
Transformation costs
Storage, Handling and Transport XOF 12.250 XOF 19.750
Fertilizing XOF 55.250
Costs of the umbrellla organization
Taxes
Other
Total production costs / ha XOF 79.750 XOF 142.500
+
Production in kg per ha. per crop for different ways of cultivation
a b c d
3000 4500 3000 4500
FP per ha = (costs/ha + LI/ha) /production/ha XOF 69,98 XOF 60,60
In case of Additional income a b c d
Home grown food XOF 7.000 XOF 7.000
Labour (working for third parties) XOF 6.462 XOF 6.462 15 days
Remittances
Subsidies
Other XOF 186.53 8 XOF 186. 538
Total additional XOF 200.00 0 XOF 200. 000
Additional income is deducted from LI, so the LI becomes
XOF 84.748 XOF 84.748
LI / ha
a b c d
FP per ha = (costs/ha + LI/ha) /production/ha XOF 54,83 XOF 50,50
24
September 2016
Guide How To Calculate Fair Prices
Table 2
Calculation model for Fair price in US $ input calculated
XOF is currency code for FCFA Currency XOF related to $$ XOF 1 $0,001 7
Family size Head of HH Wives per HH Child < 18yrs Child > 18yrs ≥ 60 yrs Total
Family members 1,0 1,1 2,6 2,3 0,9 7,90
Weigh factor 1,0 1,0 0,5 1,0 1,0
Weighed family members 1,0 1,1 1,3 2,3 0,9 6,6
Cost of food pp /year
Cost of non -food pp/ per year
Total pp/yr $122
Needed savings 10% $12
Needed income pp/yr $134
Needed hh income/yr $885
Head of HH Wives per HH Child < 18yrs Child > 18yrs
≥ 60 yrs (Additional)
Average number of adult earners per household 1,0 1,1 0,0 2,3 0,0 4,4
LW pp/yr (per earning adult) $201
Working days/ yr = calendar days – Sundays –
festivals – social obligations - calamities – sick days
Total days/yr Sundays free days sickness Total working days / yr
365 52 20 18 275
LW per adult earning family member per working day $0,73
On basis of this Living Income (LI) can be calculated factor> 1,1 $974
LI/yr= (Number of Adult earners * LW)x 1,1
Size of the farm in ha 4,4
LI/ha = LI / size of the farm $221
Needed to calculate costs per crop / ha (these costs may differ, depending on way of cultivation, e.g. with/without fertilizer and/or improved seeds)
a b c d a. maize: plough no fertilizer
Investments / repayments (interest and depreciation) b. maize: plough and fertilizer
Inputs c. rice
Hired labour $115 $115 d. wheat
Field operation costs
Harvest and post harvest costs
Transformation costs
Storage, Handling and Transport $21 $34
Fertilizing $94
Costs of the umbrellla organization
Taxes
Other
Total production costs / ha $135,58 $242,25
+
Production in kg per ha. per crop for different ways of cultivation
a b c d
3000 4500 3000 4500
FP per kg = (costs/ha + LI/ha) /production/ha $0,119 $0,103
... It will be necessary to replace the payment of a 'premium' which still takes place, by a fair price which implies payment of an amount the producer is entitled to, instead of a gift by a benevolent donor. For a detailed description how to calculate fair prices according to the Living Income/ Fair Price methodology, see 'Guide How to Calculate Fair Prices' [27]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Based on the Living Income concept, a methodology has been developed to calculate ‘fair’ prices for peasants for different crops. Application of this method can guide both policy makers and companies in their development of ‘ethical’ policies, based on the Universal Declaration of Human Rights. “Everyone who works has the right to just and favorable remuneration ensuring for himself and his family an existence worthy of human dignity...” An explanation of the living income / fair price methodology and a practical example of its application, is followed by arguments why market prices are not sufficient to combat poverty among peasants and why a paradigm shift from the use of prices decided by the market with all its imperfections, to an approach founded on ethics is needed. Particular attention is given to local food purchase programs.
Working Paper
Full-text available
The paper provides a basis for an integrated approach of agricultural project analysis with special attention to small farmers by expanding FAO’s Commodity Chain Analysis to an approach that includes power relations, both national and international, and income distribution. In order to be able to invest in production increasing techniques, the farmer must get enough revenue for his/her products to maintain his/her family in an appropriate way, as well as to be able to invest in tools and equipment. The economic, financial and social consequences of the prevailing system of market prices on small farmers are analysed and ‘fair’ prices for the products are calculated. These fair prices are based on a Living Income concept that allows farmers a decent standard of living and some funds to invest.
Article
Full-text available
Lately it has become fashionable, especially in the fair trade movement but not only there, to advertise products with the slogan that 'the producer receives a fair price' for his products. There appears not to be a uniform economic definition of the word 'fair', however, with as a consequence that the word has become meaningless. Here are some approaches on how to define 'fair price' in the Indian context, starting with the calculation of 'fair wages'.
Article
Full-text available
Taking the case of Burkina Faso, the paper analyses effects of local purchase on marginal producers. It argues that because of imports of food together with 'distress sales' on the part of the producers, perfect market conditions do not exist. Therefore market price does not equal the optimal price. In the absence of an optimal price, price interventions are justifiable and this makes payment to local farmers of a 'fairer' price both possible and desirable. The additional income thus generated will not only give the producers greater access to food, but also the ability to invest in order to increase production.
Article
Full-text available
"The people operating small farms in developing countries have to cope with the risks of these small businesses and have long faced heavy challenges. Today, these challenges are particularly severe, and the aspirations of young people on small farms have changed. Globalization and the integration of international markets are stimulating intense competition, offering some opportunities but also new risks. In light of these pressures and others, many of the world's millions of small farmers are simply not making it. Indeed, half of the world's undernourished people, three-quarters of Africa's malnourished children, and the majority of people living in absolute poverty live on small farms. The transformation of the small-farm economy is one of the biggest economic challenges of our time. For some, it entails growth into specialized, market-oriented farms; for others, part-time farming combined with off-farm rural jobs; and for others, a move out of agriculture. The pathways of transformation differ by region and location and will take decades. Policy must take a long-run view to support and guide this process efficiently, effectively, and in social fairness. The role of women farmers and their livelihoods requires particular attention. In this paper, Peter Hazell, Colin Poulton, Steve Wiggins, and Andrew Dorward address several crucial questions. Do small farms in fact have a future? In what situations can small farms succeed? What strategies are most appropriate for helping to raise small-farm productivity? The authors review both sides of the debate over the future of small farms before coming to their conclusions. Coming down firmly on the side of policy support for small farms, they point to small farms' significant potential for reducing poverty and inequity. They also clarify the differing roles of and needs for small farms in different country contexts and spell out a policy agenda for promoting small-farm development. This discussion paper is based on a literature review and the deliberations of an international workshop, “The Future of Small Farms,” organized by the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) 2020 Vision Initiative, the Overseas Development Institute (ODI), and Imperial College London in Wye, England, from June 26 to 29, 2005. (A proceedings volume for this workshop is available from IFPRI, www.ifpri.org/events/seminars/2005/smallfarms/sfproc.asp.) We hope that this discussion paper will help stimulate renewed attention among many stakeholders— including policymakers, researchers, the private sector, and nongovernmental organizations—to small-scale agricultural development. Healthy and productive small farms could serve as a crucial mechanism for achieving the poverty and hunger Millennium Development Goals. " From Foreword by Joachim von Braun
Article
Full-text available
This paper is published by the Department of Agricultural Economics and the Department of Economics, Michigan State University (MSU). Funding for this research was provided by the Food Security II Cooperative Agreement (AEP-5459-A-00-2041-00) between Michigan State University and the United States Agency for International Development, through the Office of Agriculture and Food Security in the Economic Growth Center of the Global Bureau (G/EG/AFS). Supplemental funding for this research was also provided to the FS II Cooperative Agreement by the Africa Bureau, through the Food Security and Productivity Unit of the Sustainable Development Division, Productive Sector, Growth and Environment (AFR/SD/PSGE/FSP). Thomas Reardon is Associate Professor, Valerie Kelly is Visiting Assistant Professor, Eric Crawford is Professor, and Thomas Jayne is Visiting Associate Professor in the Department of Agricultural Economics, MSU. Daniel Clay is Professor in the Institute for International Agriculture, MSU. Kimseyinga Savadogo is Professor, FASEG, Universit de Ouagadougou, Burkina Faso. ii
Article
The concept of food sovereignty presents us with an important theoretical and practical challenge. The political economy of agriculture can only take up this gauntlet through improving its understanding of the processes of agricultural growth. It is very difficult to address the issue of food sovereignty without such an understanding. Developing such an understanding involves (re)combining the political economy of agriculture with the Chayanovian approach. This paper gives several explanations (all individually valid but stronger in combination) as to why peasant agriculture results in sturdy and sustainable growth and also identifies the factors that undermine this capacity. The paper also argues that peasant agriculture is far from being a remnant of the past. While different peasantries around the world are shaped and reproduced by today's capital (and more specifically by current food empires), they equally help to shape and contribute to the further unfolding of the forms of capital related to food and agriculture. It is important to understand this two-way interaction between capital and peasant agriculture as this helps to ground the concept of food sovereignty. The article argues that the capacity to produce enough food (at different levels, distinguishing different needs, and so on) needs to be an integral part of the food sovereignty discourse. It concludes by suggesting that peasant agriculture has the best potential for meeting food sovereignty largely because it has the capacity to produce (more than) sufficient good food for the growing world population and that it can do so in a way that is sustainable.
La commercialisation paysanne de produits vivriers
  • Gil Ducommun
  • Avec Ouedraogo
  • Cecchini Sylvestre
  • Hugo
  • Bengaly Abdoulaye
Ducommun, Gil avec Ouedraogo Sylvestre, Cecchini Hugo et Bengaly Abdoulaye: La commercialisation paysanne de produits vivriers, région de Dédougou, Projet de recherche TASIM-AO Burkina Faso, Série Documents de travail N° 1, Mars 2003
Daniel: Determinants of farm productivity in Africa: a synthesis of four case studies, USAID Technical Paper No. 75 SARPN: Burkina Faso household survey Reducing Poverty Through Sustained Equitable Growth Poverty Assessment
  • Thomas Reardon
  • Kelly Valerie N Crawford
  • Eric N Jayne
  • Thomas N Savadogo
  • Clay Kimseyinmga N
Reardon, Thomas n Kelly Valerie n Crawford, Eric n Jayne, Thomas n Savadogo, Kimseyinmga n Clay, Daniel: Determinants of farm productivity in Africa: a synthesis of four case studies, USAID Technical Paper No. 75, December 1997 SARPN: Burkina Faso household survey, 2003 http://www.sarpn.org/documents/d0002933/16- Africa_dev_indicators_2007.pdf WageIndicator www.wageindicator.org World Bank: Reducing Poverty Through Sustained Equitable Growth Poverty Assessment, Report No. 29743-BUR Burkina Faso, 2005 http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTPOVERTY/EXTPA/0,,contentMDK: 20571227~menuPK:435735~pagePK:148956~piPK:216618~theSitePK:430367~isCURL:Y~isCU RL:Y,00.html
Living Wage for rural Malawi with Focus on Tea Growing area of Southern Malawi
  • Richard Anker
Anker, Richard and Martha, Living Wage for rural Malawi with Focus on Tea Growing area of Southern Malawi, January 2014