ArticlePDF Available

Fiscal Consolidation and Australia's Public Debt

Authors:

Abstract

Australia has experienced one of the fastest growing public debt levels in the world post-Global Financial Crisis due to a series of large federal budget deficits driven by high government spending. In this paper we examine the balance sheet implications of this escalating public debt, before proposing some macro-fiscal objectives for determining its sustainable level. These objectives are to (i) restore the federal government's solvency; (ii) eliminate foreign public debt; and (iii) achieve budgetary balance over the business cycle. Empirically, we first examine how much fiscal consolidation is required for debt stabilisation at current levels, before considering what sized budget balances are needed to achieve the target debt to GDP ratios consistent with the proposed objectives. The results show that no target debt to GDP level consistent with the optimal levels will be met on current fiscal settings in the medium term. This implies significantly greater fiscal consolidation is required to minimise future fiscal risk.
FISCAL CONSOLIDATION AND AUSTRALIA’S OPTIMAL PUBLIC DEBT
Anthony J Makin
Economics, Griffith Business School
Griffith University
Gold Coast Qld 4222
Australia
t.makin@griffith.edu.au
Julian Pearce
julianjp@bigpond.net.au
Abstract
Australia has experienced one of the fastest growing public debt levels in the world post-GFC due to a series
of large federal budget deficits driven by high government spending. In this paper we examine the balance
sheet implications of this escalating public debt, before proposing some macro-fiscal objectives for
determining its optimal level. These objectives are to (i) restore the federal government’s solvency; (ii)
eliminate foreign public debt; and (iii) achieve budgetary balance over the business cycle. Empirically, we
first examine how much fiscal consolidation is required for debt stabilisation at current levels, before
considering what sized budget balances are needed to achieve the target debt to GDP ratios consistent with
the proposed objectives. The results show that no target debt to GDP level consistent with the optimal
levels will be met on current fiscal settings in the medium term. This implies significantly greater fiscal
consolidation is required to minimise future fiscal risk.
JEL: H6 E62
Contents
1. Introduction
2. Trends in Government Borrowing and Net Worth
3. What is the Optimal Level of Australia’s Public Debt?
4. Stabilising Federal Government Debt
5. Fiscal Consolidation Required to Optimise Public Debt
6. Conclusion
2
1. Introduction
Australia is amongst a group of advanced economies (along with Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, Spain,
France, the United Kingdom, the United States and Japan) whose public debt grew markedly following the
2008-10 Global Financial Crisis (IMF 2016). Public debt crises subsequently erupted in a number of these
economies, especially Greece and other Southern European economies. Contrary to this experience, some
advanced economies, for example Norway and Switzerland, managed to reduce public debt, while levels in
Germany and Sweden, have remained much the same as before the crisis (Makin 2015).
Australia’s public debt growth, predominantly driven by federal rather than State and local government
budget deficits, differed from the blowouts in Ireland, the United States and the United Kingdom, where
bank bailouts played a major role in magnifying public debt levels. Despite the strong growth in Australia’s
public debt, the degree of fiscal consolidation since the GFC has been significantly less than for the United
States, the United Kingdom, New Zealand, and the Euro area and, on the basis of forward estimates, is
forecast to remain relatively weak in coming years (Australian Treasury, 2016).
When comparing public debt levels across countries, it is important to bear in mind that it not only matters
how quickly public debt grows, but what programs that public debt has financed, as well as whether the
borrowing is domestically or foreign sourced. Government borrowing to finance budget deficits adds to
existing public debt and worsens the government’s balance sheet, whereas public investment in the form
of productive infrastructure increases government assets and improves the balance sheet.
This suggests the government balance sheet, a much neglected macro-fiscal measure, is an important tool
for analysing an economy’s fiscal performance. Accordingly, the behaviour and implications of Australia’s
deteriorating government net worth, the difference between its public assets and public debt is a major
focus of this paper. On the liabilities side of the balance sheet, given the theoretical and empirical support
for the twin deficits hypothesis (see Born et al (2013), Chinn and Prasad 2003, Ilzetzli et al (2013), and
Makin and Narayan (2014) the distinction between domestically held and foreign held Australian
government bonds issued to fund post GFC federal deficits is also important, as debt servicing on foreign
public debt is a drain on national income.
In what follows, we first show the scale of government borrowing by all levels of government in Australia.
We then consider what Australia’s optimum public debt level should be with reference to three factors
the state of the government balance sheet, Australia’s status as an international borrower country, and
fiscal stabilisation policy more broadly. We then examine recent balance sheet trends and estimate what
3
federal budget balances are needed to stabilise the public debt to GDP ratio and to hit the optimal debt
targets consistent with these factors over the medium term.
2. Trends in Australian Government Borrowing and Net Worth
Australian governments at both national and state level entered the GFC running budget surpluses (see
Chart 1). However, the impact of the GFC on revenue and higher government expenditure post GFC,
especially for the federal government, has resulted in substantial deficits from 2008-9 whereas State
governments have generally been successful in reducing general government deficits from 2012-13. Hence
the Australian federal government has contributed predominantly to the escalation in Australia’s public
debt.
Government Borrowing
The Australian general government deficit as a share of GDP remains relatively high and the degree of
fiscal consolidation since the GFC has been less than in previous economic cycles (as discussed below, in
the previous two cycles deficits returned to surplus from the peak deficit within 4 or 5 years whereas in the
current cycle a surplus is not expected even after 10 years see Chart 4 below).
Sources: ABS (2015b and e); Australian Government (2015b); State and Territory budget and mid-year
review documents cited in references; author calculations
-6.00%
-5.00%
-4.00%
-3.00%
-2.00%
-1.00%
0.00%
1.00%
2.00%
3.00%
2004-05
2005-06
2006-07
2007-08
2008-09
2009-10
2010-11
2011-12
2012-13
2013-14
2014-15
2015-16 (e)
2016-17 (e)
2017-18 (p)
2018-19 (p)
Gen Govt Net Lending (+)/Borrowing (-) - % of GDP
Chart 1: Gen Govt Net Lending (+)/Borrowing (-) - % of
GDP
C'wealth State Local Total
4
As a result of on-going budget deficits, general government borrowings at both national and state level as
a share of GDP have risen sharply from the mid-2000s. As the deficits of State general governments were
wound back from 2012-13, State general government borrowings in aggregate have been approximately
stable as share of GDP from 2013-14
1
. See Makin and Pearce (2014) for further discussion.
Source: As for Chart 1
Consistent with Australia’s status as an international borrower country, non-residents have been
substantial holders of Australian Government securities on issue. As Australian government borrowings
escalated from 2008, non-resident holdings have also risen sharply to over $250bn, representing around
two thirds of the securities on issue. See Chart 3.
1
While this is true in aggregate, borrowings by the West Australian government are expected to more than double over the four
years to June 2019 (Western Australian Government, 2015, p96). In response to the trends in WA’s financial and debt
measures, in February 2016, Moody’s downgraded the long-term and senior unsecured debt issued by the Western Australian
Treasury Corporation backed by the State of WA to Aa2 from Aa1 (Moody’s, 2016).
0.00%
5.00%
10.00%
15.00%
20.00%
25.00%
30.00%
35.00%
40.00%
45.00%
Chart 2: Gen Govt Borrowings - % of GDP
C'wealth State Local Total
5
Source: ABS 2015c; Australian Office of Financial Management, www.aofm.gov.au
Government Net Worth
Government balance sheets measure the public sector’s asset and liability positions. They reflect the
cumulative effects of previous budget imbalances and hence usefully gauge fiscal performance through
time. The key government balance sheet measures are net worth and net financial worth. Net worth, the
most inclusive measure of the government’s financial position, is simply the difference between the value
of all of the federal government assets, and its liabilities.
Government assets include financial assets and real assets, such as public land holdings, infrastructure,
investment properties, plant, equipment, and heritage assets. Public debt dominates the liabilities side of
the government balance sheet, which also includes future liabilities, such as superannuation entitlements
of public sector employees.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
450
500
Chart 3: Non-resident holdings of Aust Government Securities
Non-resident holdings $bn Resident holdings $bn Non-resident proportion %
6
Net worth data relative to GDP reveals quite divergent trends between the fiscal positions of the federal
and State governments. The net worth of the State sector stabilised at just over 40% of GDP from 2011-12.
In contrast, the net worth of the Australian federal government fell considerably more due to larger
budget deficits and has been negative since 2009-10
2
. Both federal net worth and net financial worth have
deteriorated markedly by historical standards since the GFC.
Source: As for Chart 1
In principle, it is possible to run a budget deficit, yet not worsen the government balance sheet, if the
additional government borrowing finances extra capital spending worth at least as much as the debt
liability incurred in the process, and irrespective of whether the borrowed funds are sourced from
domestic or international capital markets. However, Australian general government capital expenditure is
small relative to total expenditure and does not usually yield a financial return enabling the servicing of the
debt. Furthermore, capital expenditure represents less than one quarter of the government deficit (see
Table 1 below).
2
The net worth for the Australian general government sector includes the net assets of the Future Fund, which represented 7%
of GDP in June 2015 (source: Future Fund Annual Report 2014-15 and ABS 2015b). Future Fund assets primarily are intended to
cover Australian Government superannuation liabilities.
-30.0%
-20.0%
-10.0%
0.0%
10.0%
20.0%
30.0%
40.0%
50.0%
60.0%
Chart 4: Net worth - % of GDP
C'wealth State Local
7
Australian Governments deficits have thus been used almost entirely to cover recurrent expenditure
(mainly in social security and health) rather than capital expenditure that is capable of servicing the debt
3
.
With higher debt, even with historically low interest rates, public debt interest has begun to loom large in
expenditure and in 2015-16 will be 4.7 times larger than foreign aid expenditure, 1.7 times expenditure on
higher education and 1.6 times expenditure on the Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme (source: Australian
Government (2015a, pp5-15, 5-21, 5-24 and 5-47; author calculations). Also see Novak (2015).
Table 1: Estimates of total expenses and capital expenditure by function
Total Expenses
Acquisition of non-
financial assets
2015-16
2015-16
$m
$m
Social security and welfare
154,000
386
Other purposes (excl PDI) (a)
70,140
-440
Health
69,381
105
Education
31,854
34
Defence
26,348
8,215
General public services
22,162
1,334
Public debt interest (PDI)
15,561
0
Other economic affairs
9,792
551
Transport and communication
8,575
54
Fuel and energy
6,706
1
Housing and community amenities
5,329
42
Public order and safety
4,885
564
Recreation and culture
3,530
434
Mining, manufacturing and construction
3,142
11
Agriculture, forestry and fishing
3,063
117
Total expenses
434,469
11,408
Memorandum item: Headline cash balance (MYEFO)
-48,171
(a) Negative represents sale of access to radio spectrum
Source: Australian Government (2015a, p 5-52 and 2015b, p52)
Having established that federal government deficits have accounted for most of the rise in public debt, it is
pertinent to examine which side of the federal budget revenue or expenditure - has been mostly
responsible. We show below that the deficit has remained high mainly because expenditure growth has
remained high and is expected to remain high for this stage of the economic cycle, while taxes are
expected to recover broadly in line with their cyclical behaviour.
3
Another way of analyzing the data is to observe that the rise in debt is only matched to a small extent by capital expenditure
over the 10 years to 2015-16 cumulative net capital investment by the Australian Government was $39.5bn relative to an
increase in debt of $524.5bn (or 9%) source Australian Government 2015a, p5-51 and p 9-7, ABS 2015e and author
calculations.
8
In relation to trends in expenditure, Chart 5 below shows that, following the large increase in general
government spending to GDP under the Whitlam government, there were sharp increases in spending to
GDP in the recession in the early 1980s and again in the recession in the early 1990s in both cases,
spending to GDP fell to below 24% of GDP in the subsequent recovery, as it did during the prolonged
period of high growth in the decade up to 2007-8.
There was an increase in spending to GDP during 2008-9 and 2009-10 as a result of the ‘emergency’
spending following the GFC. In contrast to the historical pattern, spending to GDP is expected to remain
high at over 25% as the economy has recovered. This contrasts sharply with spending to GDP falling to
approximately 23% in prior recoveries.
Revenue to GDP has fallen sharply following the GFC to reach a low of 21.4% and is expected to gradually
recover. This collapse in revenue to GDP is a little worse than that following the recession in the early
1990s when revenue to GDP fell to 22.0%. The speed of recovery in revenue to GDP from the trough in
2011-12 is similar to the speed of recovery in revenue to GDP after the early 1990s recession.
The revenue problem facing the government is therefore only a little worse than experienced in the
downturn in the early 1990s. What distinguishes the current cycle is that spending to GDP has remained
stubbornly high relative to the historical experience. The usual swing from budget deficit to surplus over
this cycle has not occurred because spending to GDP has remained high. As a result, the fiscal
consolidation in prospect according to the budget forward estimates is much weaker than over previous
cycles
4
.
Following the downturn in the early 1980s a surplus was reached after 4 years and, after the downturn in
the early 1990s a surplus was reached after 5 years. Based on the forward estimates, a surplus is still not
expected to be achieved 10 years after the peak deficit in 2009-10. Since the federal government budget
has dominated Australia’s overall fiscal position, determining the overall trend in debt and net worth, the
focus in what follows is on fiscal activity at that level.
4
This paper assumes that the Australian Government budget forecasts are met after the most recent reassessment introduced
more conservative economic assumptions (refer Australian Government, 2015b MYEFO 2015-16). It also assumes that
unlegislated budget measures equivalent to a reduction in the cash deficit of 0.2% of GDP are introduced (Parliamentary Budget
Office, 2016b).
9
Sources: ABS (2015b and e); Australian Government (2015a and b); author calculations
A potential weakness in examining spending and revenue to nominal GDP, as done above, is that nominal
GDP is influenced by changes in the terms of trade which have been substantial during the recent
commodity price boom and bust. To ensure that this factor has not led to inaccurate conclusions, the
following analysis examines trends in ‘real’ spending and receipts per capita (using the CPI to adjust for
price changes) which avoids any direct impact on the analysis of movements in the terms of trade.
Chart 6 plots the path for real per capita spending and revenue since the 1970s. The Chart shows that
since 2008-9, real per capita spending has remained above trend, in contrast to earlier cycles when real
spending per capita fell below trend. Real revenue per capita has fallen to be below trend since 2008-9,
though the fall is broadly in the downturn in the early 1990s. Taken together these findings support the
earlier conclusion that the deficit is predominantly the result of expenditure growth remaining high rather
than an unusual weakness in revenue. Data produced by the Parliamentary Budget Office provide support
to this conclusion. Over the 17 years to 2018-19, the estimated cumulative impact on the budget deficit
-10%
-5%
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
Chart 5: Australian General Govt Payments and Receipts
% of GDP
Underlying cash balance/GDP* Receipts/GDP
Payments/GDP Payments/GDP 20 year average(a)
10
from expenditure decisions and expenditure parameter variations is $303bn, which is 2.4 times the
cumulative impact on the deficit from revenue decisions and revenue parameter variations of $127bn
5
Source: Australian Government (2015b); ABS (2015a and d); author calculations
3. What is the Optimal Level of Australia’s Public Debt?
The following considers what level of public debt is optimal in relation to government balance sheet,
Australia’s foreign borrowing, and stabilisation policy.
Restoring Fiscal Solvency
As shown above, there has been a major deterioration in the federal government’s net worth position
since the fiscal stimulus response to the GFC. In short, large budget deficits caused a sharp rise in debt
that was unmatched by a rise in the value of the public capital stock. Accordingly, federal government net
5
Expenditure decisions over this period account for $290bn or 96% of the cumulative impact of expenditure on the deficit,
whereas $70bn of the revenue impact comes from revenue decisions and $57bn from parameter and other variations. Source:
Parliamentary Budget Office (2016a).
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Chart 6: Australian General Government Real Per Capita Payments and
Receipts $'000s in 2011-2 dollars
Real receipts per capita $'000s Real payments per capita $'000s
Linear (Real receipts per capita $'000s) Linear (Real payments per capita $'000s)
11
worth went from near zero to negative of the order of 20 per cent of GDP. This implies that to restore
federal fiscal solvency, sustained fiscal restraint is necessary to pay down public debt.
A commercial entity is technically insolvent if its net worth position is negative. Although this definition of
insolvency suggests the federal government has been technically insolvent since the GFC, the financial
strictures that negative net worth imposes on private firms do not fully translate to governments because
governments uniquely possess the power to tax. However, the fact that a government can wield the
power to tax under these circumstances has adverse implications for the wider economy. Rational forward
thinking households and firms should realise that a government whose net worth has become significantly
negative due to higher public debt may need to impose higher taxes at some stage to repair its balance
sheet. In anticipation, household saving should therefore rise and business confidence and private
investment fall.
Eliminating Foreign Public Debt
Large budget deficits have not only worsened net worth but increased Australia’s foreign borrowing and
foreign public debt. Several theoretical perspectives can be explained why. For instance, from an
international flow of funds viewpoint, budget deficits increase the overall demand for funds in the
economy, other things the same. This increases net foreign borrowing, suggesting that budget and
external deficits are closely related.
Alternatively, post GFC budget deficits worsened Australia’s competitiveness, consistent with the
prediction of the textbook Mundell-Fleming model of how fiscal policy operates in economies with floating
exchange rates and a high degree of international capital mobility. Although many other economies
undertook fiscal expansion simultaneously, Australia’s circumstances were quite different in that its
banking system remained functional, there was no liquidity trap, and the fiscal stimulus was relatively
large.
This meant strong capital inflow to take up newly issued government bonds contributed to exchange rate
appreciation and a subsequent competitiveness loss that hindered the manufacturing sector. Recent
empirical studies have validated the predictions of the Mundell-Fleming, showing that increased budget
deficits under floating exchange rates crowd out net exports, implying higher external deficits (Born et al
(2013), Ilzetzli et al (2013), and Makin and Narayan (2014).
12
Furthermore, competitiveness, defined as the relative price of non-tradables to tradables, further
worsened which, other things equal, crowded out net exports. As most government activity occurs in the
non-tradable sector, increased spending raises non-tradables prices faster than tradables prices.
Australia’s competitiveness measured this way has worsened by over 20% since the crisis (Makin and
Ratnasiri (2015) further discuss this measure).
As noted above, approximately two thirds of Commonwealth securities on issue is held by non-residents.
If these securities had been used to invest in assets that yield an equivalent risk-adjusted return, this would
not be of concern. However, this criterion is not met for the bulk of the debt. In this case, the fact that we
owe the debt to non-residents (as opposed to Australians in effect ‘owing it to ourselves’) is of concern.
This suggests an alternative medium term target of reducing holdings of Commonwealth debt by non-
residents to zero (or equivalently increasing Commonwealth holdings of non-resident financial assets such
that they offset non-resident holdings of debt).
Budgetary Balance Over the Cycle
The Commonwealth Charter of Budget Honesty Act 1998 requires the government to publish its fiscal
strategy. The Government’s medium-term fiscal strategy statement as required by this Charter is: “to
achieve budget surpluses, on average, over the course of the economic cycle” (Australian Government,
2015a, p3-4). The proximate translation of this is in debt/GDP terms is that net debt/GDP is zero at some
point during the cycle (or that gross debt equals financial assets). This is used as one of the targets
analysed below.
The optimal level of debt/GDP also depends on the use to which the debt has been put. If the debt is used
to purchase assets that yield a risk adjusted return on investment that exceeds the cost of debt then a
higher debt/GDP ratio would be appropriate (especially if the investments actually generates cash to
service and repay the debt, though this is rare for the general government sector).
The fact that there has been a move by the Australian Government from a positive net worth to a negative
net worth shows that the debt has not been used to purchase financial or real assets of equal worth but
has instead been used to fund net recurrent expenditure. An alternative target is ensuring that net worth
of the Australian Government sector returns to zero from its current negative positions, which is
equivalent to ensuring that gross debt has been used to finance net assets.
13
If the debt arises because of a fiscal policy being used to effectively stabilise the economy, then one would
be prepared to have higher debt to GDP at least during economic downturns because the “return” from
the debt is the smoother path for households of employment and consumption (and other determinants of
household utility).
Consistent with the Mundell-Fleming model, we contend that for Australia, as a small open economy with
a flexible exchange rate, the effectiveness of such an activist fiscal policy is small at best in the short term
and negative over the medium term (see Guest and Makin 2013 and Uhlig 2010). On these grounds then
the budget should be balance over the cycle and, as above, the target medium net debt/GDP should also
be zero.
In summary, we propose three possible medium term objectives for budgetary policy:
i. net worth equal to zero to restore federal fiscal solvency
ii. zero foreign public debt
iii. zero net federal public debt
Before examining the budgetary response needed to hit these targets, we first consider whether federal
public debt is on a stable trajectory under current fiscal settings.
4. Stabilising Federal Government Debt
The following formula, derived in Appendix 1, shows the necessary condition for stabilising the ratio of
public debt to GDP:
where:
pb is the primary balance to income/GDP ratio;
the primary balance is the actual balance excluding the interest payments;
is the previous period debt to income ratio;
i is the interest rate on government debt; and
g is the growth in nominal income/GDP
Hence the required primary balance to stabilise debt at a given debt/GDP ratio of is:
i. positive, if as is usually the case, the interest rate is higher than the nominal growth rate
(because the real interest rate is usually higher than the real interest rate
6
);
6
For further discussion see Escolano (2010), pp8-9 at www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2010/tnm1002.pdf.
Informally, if the real growth rate exceeds the real interest rate over the long run, then the present value of output and income
would be infinite which violates various boundary conditions for stability. In Australia, over the past 20 years on average, real
growth rates have exceeded real interest rates (or nominal growth exceeded nominal interest rates as shown in Appendix 2).
Presumably this reflects, among other things, Australia’s higher than average growth rates and higher than average population
growth by the standards of other developed economies.
g1 gi
μpb
μ
μ
14
ii. higher, the greater is the interest rate on government debt (for given growth in nominal
interest rate); and
iii. lower, the higher is growth in nominal income/GDP (for given interest rate).
Using the above formula, Table 2 below sets down calculations of the primary budget balance required to
stabilise debt. The analysis shows the primary budget surplus required to stabilise debt in 2015-16 is not
being met in 2015-16 as the government is running a large primary deficit of 1.2 % of GDP (refer Column 1
in Table 2).
By 2018-19, based on the assumptions underpinning the budget forward estimates, the primary budget
deficit projected for 2018-19 is sufficient to stabilise debt to GDP in that year (see Column 2 in Table 2), ten
years after the budget swung into deficit. These projections, however, are based on a relationship
between interest rates and nominal GDP which is quite out of line with historical norms, which raises the
prospect that debt stabilisation might not in the end be realised.
The assumptions underpinning the 2018-19 position are that the government bond rate is expected to
remain at the current low rate of 2.9%, while nominal GDP accelerates to growth of 5.25%. This gap
between interest rates and nominal GDP growth has occurred for only a few quarters in 2008-9 and 2010-
11. See Chart in Appendix 2. If the average gap over the twenty years to 2015-16 between 10 year bond
rates (average of 5.5%) and nominal GDP growth (average of 6.1%) of 0.6% is used instead, the required
primary budget deficit to GDP for 2018-19 is smaller (see Column 3 Table 1), which increases the risk that
debt stabilisation is not achieved.
Furthermore, if interest rates exceed growth in nominal GDP as occurred during much of the decade from
the Banana Republic statement by Treasurer Keating in 1986 to 1997, the degree of fiscal consolidation
required to stabilise debt is much greater, with primary surpluses required.
5. Fiscal Consolidation Required to Optimise Public Debt
We now consider what size budget balances are needed to achieve target levels of debt to GDP, consistent
with restoring federal fiscal solvency, eliminating foreign public debt and achieving budgetary balance over
the cycle.
15
Table 2: Required Primary and Total Balance to Stabilise Debt at Current Level (a)
As at 2015-16 (b)
As at 2018-19
based on forward
estimates (b)
As at 2018-19 with
"normal" conditions
( c)
Column 1
%
Column 2
%
Column 3
%
Interest rate (10 year bond
yield) % - 'i'
2.9
2.9
2.9
Growth in nominal GDP
% - 'g'
2.75
5.25
3.5
Required primary
balance - % of GDP
0.04
-0.7
-0.2
Actual primary balance - % of
GDP (d)
-1.2
0.2
0.2
Denotes debt stability not achieved
Denotes debt stability achieved
(a) Debt to GDP is estimated at 29.7% for 2015-16 and 32.1% at 2018-19 based on Aust Govt 2015b MYEFO 2015-16
(b) Based in 2015-16 MYEFO.
( c) Based on interest rates as in the 2015-16 MYEFO but with the gap between interest rates and nominal GDP
growth equal to the 20 year average to June 2015 of 0.6% ie the difference between an average 10 year bond rate of
5.5% over this period and a (geometric) average of nominal GDP over the same period of 6.1% (source RBA Financial
Statistics and ABS 2015b
(d) The underlying cash balance is used which excludes earnings from the Future Fund (as such earnings
(as such earnings are not paid to the government until 2020).
As established in Appendix 1, the formula for reducing the debt to GDP ratio to a target level over a
defined number of years is given by (refer equation 22):
where is the primary balance to income ratio and is the current period public debt to income ratio
is the proportion of the targeted debt to GDP ratio to the current ratio and n is the number of years
allowed to achieve the target ratio.
When the target is lower than the current level (i.e < 1) and the interest rate is less than the nominal
growth rate, the required primary balance is higher:
if the current period debt/GDP , , is higher;
if the target debt ratio to the current ratio, , is lower; and
 
n
1j
jn
nn
i)(1
νg)(1i)(1
.pb
pb
16
the shorter is the number of years, n , in which the target is be achieved.
For this medium-term analysis, we have used the average growth in nominal GDP for the 20 years to 2015-
16 (of 6.1% pa) and the average monthly 10 year bond yield of 5.5% (see footnote (d) in Table 2 for
sources). On this basis, as shown in Table 3 below, the primary balance to GDP ratio projected to be
achieved in 2018-19 is well short of that required to achieve any of these medium term targets, even after
the span of 15 years.
Based on the Australian Governments medium term projections, with a much more favourable relationship
between interest rates and nominal GDP growth than the 20 year average, even the least restrictive of
these targets is not met by 2025-26 as net debt is projected to reach 9.6% of GDP in that year which be
consistent with net worth to GDP of negative 7 per cent
7
.
Table 3: Primary balance required to achieve target debt/GDP ratio (a)
(current projected primary balance is 0.2% of GDP in 2018-19)
Restoring
solvency/net
assets zero(b)
Eliminating
foreign public
debt (c)
Net debt to
zero/balance
over the cycle
(d)
Years to achieve target
5 years
3.5
4.7
5.9
10 years
1.9
2.6
3.3
15 years
1.4
1.9
2.5
(a) Based on the average growth rate for GDP of 6.1% over the 20 years to 2014-15 and the average monthly
10 year bond rate of 5.5% over the same period
(b) Equivalent to gross debt being reduced to 16.7% of GDP from 32.1%, all other assets and liabilities
remaining the same to GDP
(c) Equivalent to reducing gross debt to 11.7% of GDP (or to holding non-resident assets of 20.4% of GDP to
offset non-resident holdings of Commonwealth debt)
(d) Equivalent to reducing gross debt to 6.6% of GDP. Excludes Future Fund assets as these are offset against
superannuation liabilities which are not part of net debt.
Data sources: Australian Government 2015b MYEFO, Future Fund, January 2016; RBA Financial Statistics and
ABS 2015b author calculations
7
The calculation assumes that net assets in total remain the same relative to GDP as projected in 2018-19 (source: Australian
Government, 2015b MYEFO, p 24 and author calculations).
17
Conclusion
Commentators often observe that Australian policy makers should be relaxed about the current public
debt to GDP ratio since it is low by the standards of other advanced economies. In economies where
government borrowing has funded productive capital expenditure, a higher public debt level would be of
limited concern (though it still heightens risks for the economy). In Australia’s case, borrowing has been
used to fund recurrent expenditure and sourced substantially from non-residents and so results in a
income transfer overseas.
Higher government spending in response to the GFC proved counterproductive as it ensured market
interest rates and the exchange rate tended to be higher than they should have been over a critical and
prolonged period. Australia’s current fiscal problems stem from this policy decision and by the failure by
subsequent budgets to curb growth in expenditure. This stands in stark contrast to the trends over
previous economic cycles when federal public sector expenditure growth (and expenditure as a share of
the economy) has been reined in. With the expected trends for revenue broadly in line with previous
cycles, expenditure policy decisions have been the main reason Australia faces a period of sustained
deficits and the resultant sharp rise in debt rising.
The federal government’s net worth and net financial worth have deteriorated markedly by historical
standards since the GFC because the rise in public debt has not been matched by a rise in public assets or
wealth, nor in assets that produce a return capable of servicing and repaying the debt, but instead has
been used to finance recurrent expenditure including transfer payments. Furthermore, with the limited
effectiveness of fiscal policy in a small open economy like Australia, the debt has not produced a more
stable path for income.
Even at historically low interest rates, the public debt interest is expected to rise to one per cent of GDP
and has begun to loom large in total government spending. With two-thirds of debt held by foreigners,
interest payments on such debt represent a direct loss to national income.
Government projections estimate that debt/GDP will stabilise in 2018-19, but these projections are based
on interest rate assumptions which are very low by historical standards, especially relative to projected
growth in nominal GDP. Should a more normal relationship between interest rates and nominal GDP
growth apply, then debt stability will not be achieved. Over the medium term, lower levels of debt/GDP
are optimal, such as net debt zero, net foreign debt holdings zero or net worth back to zero from negative.
18
The projected fiscal stance does not meet any of these target levels, even on the basis of historically low
interest rates.
Australia is also a small open economy heavily reliant on foreign borrowing. This increases the risk of a
federal government creditworthiness downgrade which would not only raise the public debt interest bill
but affect the entire economy by raising the risk premium on foreign loans to domestic private firms
undertaking productive investment. Moreover, Australia is heavily exposed to commodity market volatility
which, as evidenced by the recent commodity price boom and bust, markedly affects nominal and real
incomes as well as government revenues.
Taken together, these risk factors suggest Australia needs to adopt a lower debt profile than other
economies less reliant on foreign funds and less exposed to commodity cycles. To avoid these risks, far
more robust fiscal consolidation than currently planned is required.
19
Appendix 1: Derivation of the public debt stabilisation and reduction formulae
In this Appendix we derive the formula for defining the requirements firstly for debt stability to GDP at the
current level of debt to GDP and then the formula for stability of public debt at a target level that differs
from the current debt to GDP ratio. Both derivations follow that in Makin and Pearce (2014).
Arithmetic Foundations for Stabilising Debt to GDP
The government budget identity provides the basis for determining the path for public debt dynamics and
for determining the fiscal response needed for debt stabilization. This identity simply states that public
debt (D) in the present period equals previously accumulated debt, plus public debt interest, paid at an
effective interest rate of i, plus the Primary Deficit (or less the PB). In discrete time, this can be expressed
as
(1)
Dividing by nominal (or )
(2)
or alternatively, this can be rewritten as
(3)
where g is the nominal rate of economic growth.
Taking the change in the public debt to national income ratio
(4)
Setting
(5)
and simplifying
(6)
Equation (6) shows that public debt to GSDP rises, as the primary deficit and interest rate rise and as the
rate of nominal economic growth (g) falls. To stabilize public debt to national income,
t1t1tt PBiDDD
GSDP
t
Y
t
t
t
1t
t
tY
PB
Y
D
)i1(
Y
D
t
t
1t
1t
t
tY
PB
Y
D
)g1( )i1(
Y
D
t
t
1t
1t
1t
1t
1t
1t
t
tY
PB
Y
D
Y
D
)g1( )i1(
Y
D
Y
D
1t
1t
t
tY
D
Y
D
)
Y
D
(
t
t
1t
1t Y
PB
Y
D
g1 gi
)
Y
D
(
20
(7)
or simply
(8)
where is the primary balance to income ratio and is the previous period debt to income ratio.
The relationship between nominal and real interest rates is
(9)
where is the real interest rate and is the inflation rate, and the relationship between nominal and real
growth is
(10)
Hence, through substitution, and assuming small product terms are negligible, (8) can also be written as
(11)
If the interest rate exceeds the growth rate, a primary surplus is required for debt stabilization, whereas if
the growth rate exceeds the interest rate, a primary deficit is possible. Hence, we have shown that in
estimating the requisite primary balance, it makes no significant difference if nominal or real values are
used for the interest and growth rates, the key driver being the difference between these respective
values.
Arithmetic Foundations for Reducing Sub-national Public Debt to a Target Level
The foregoing analysis has estimated the primary balances necessary to stabilise debt ratios at existing
levels. However, if very high, a level that has been stabilised may not necessarily be sustainable into the
future. Instead, a lower target value may need to be achieved by a certain time, for example within five
years or ten years. If so, the fiscal consolidation has to be greater. The following derives a key formula for
estimating the primary balance required to achieve targeted debt levels at some time in the future.
1t
1t
t
tY
D
g1 gi
Y
PB
g1 gi
μpb
pb
μ
1)1)(r1(i *
*
r
1)1)(g1(g *
πg1 gr
μpb *
**
21
4.1 Arithmetic Foundations
Solvency requires that present debt, can eventually be repaid at some time in the future, , such
that This means that the present value of budget surpluses over the period must equal the debt
stock at
Hence,
(12)
or
(13)
Solving for the constant primary balance to achieve solvency,
(14)
Now the stock of public debt at some time hence will depend on the pre-existing debt less the discounted
sum of future primary surpluses, such that
(15)
Dividing (15) by and noting that
(16)
Yields
(17)
If the debt to income ratio is reduced to a proportion of the existing ratio between and
where (18)
Hence, substituting in (17)
(19)
t
D
nt
.0D nt
.t
n
nt
3
3t
2
2t1t
t)i1(PB
...
)i1(PB
)i1(PB
)i1(
PB
D
n
jt
n
1j
jn
t)i1(
PB)i1(
D
PB
n
1j
jn
n
t
)i1(
)i1(D
PB
n
tnt )i1(DD
jt
n
1j
jn PB)i1(
nt
Y
ntt
nYY)g1(
t
nt
)
Y
D
ν(
Y
D
t
t
nt
nt
1ν0
t
n
n
1j jt
jnn
t
t
tY)g1(
PB)i1()i1(D
)
Y
D
(
1
(1 ) (1 )
(1 )
n
n n j
t t j
j
tn n
t n t
D i i PB
D
Y g Y
 
22
Solving for and re-dividing by , it follows that
(20)
Solving (20) for the constant primary balance as a proportion of national income that would satisfy
condition (18)
(21)
or
(22)
where is the primary balance to income ratio and is the current period public debt to income ratio
is the proportion of the targeted debt to GDP ratio to the current ratio and n is the number of years
allowed to achieve the target ratio.
t
D
t
Y
 
t
nn
n
1j jt
jn
t
tY)i1()g1(
PB)i1(
Y
D
)PB(
 
n
1j
jn
nn
t
t
ti)(1
νg)(1i)(1
.
Y
D
Y
PB
 
n
1j
jn
nn
i)(1
νg)(1i)(1
.pb
pb
23
Appendix 2: Interest rates and nominal GDP growth the Australian experience
Source: RBA Financial Statistics, ABS 2015b
-5
0
5
10
15
20
Interest rates (10 yr bonds) and Nominal GDP growth - %
10 year bond rate less nominal GDP growth Nominal GDP growth 10 year bond rates
24
References
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2006), ‘Treatment of the Future Fund in ABS Statistics’, Government
Finance Statistics, Australia, Quarterly, Mar 2006, Cat 5519.0
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2015a), Australian Demographic Statistics, Jun 2015, Cat no 3101.0
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2015b), Australian National Accounts: National Income, Expenditure
and Product, Sep 2015, Cat no 5206.0
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2015c), Balance of Payments and International Investment Position,
Australia, Dec 2015, Cat no 5302.0
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2015d) Consumer Price Index, Australia, Dec 2015, Cat no 6401.0
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2015e) Government Finance Statistics, 2013-14, Australia, 5512.0
Australian Capital Territory Government (2015), Budget Review 2015-16, Canberra, December
Australian Government (2015a), Budget Strategy and Outlook, 2015-16, Budget Paper No. 1, Canberra
Australian Government (2015b), Mid-Year Economic and Fiscal Outlook 2015-16, Canberra
Australian Government (2014), Charter of Budget Honesty Act 1998 No. 22, 1998 as amended 2014
Australian Office of Financial Management, www.aofm.gov.au
Australian Treasury (2016), Presentation Slides, National Press Club Address, Canberra, Scott Morrison,
Treasurer, 17 February 2016
Chinn, M. and Prasad, E. (2003) “Medium Term Determinants of Current Accounts in Industrial and
Developing Countries: An Empirical Exploration” Journal of International Economics 59, 47-76
Escolano, J., 2010. A Practical Guide to Public Debt Dynamics, Fiscal Sustainability and Cyclical Adjustment
of Budgetary Aggregates in IMF Technical Notes and Manuals. IMF, Washington, DC
Fleming, J. (1962) “Domestic Financial Policy under Fixed and Floating Exchange Rates” IMF Staff Papers,
9, 3, 36979
Future Fund, Annual Report 2014/15, Canberra, 2015
Future Fund, Portfolio update at 31 December 2015, Media Release, 27 January 2016
Guest, R. and Makin, A. (2013) “The Dynamic Effects of Fiscal Stimulus in a Two Sector Open Economy”
Review of Development Economics 17(3), 609-626.
International Monetary Fund (2015) Fiscal Monitor, Now Is the Time Fiscal Policies for Sustainable Growth,
April, IMF, Washington DC
Makin, A. (2015) “Has Excessive Public Debt Slowed World Growth?”(2015) World Economics 16(4), 235-
267.
25
Makin, A. and Narayan, P. (2013) “Re-examining the ‘Twin Deficits’ Hypothesis: Evidence from Australia”
Empirical Economics 45, 817-829
Makin, A. and Pearce, J. (2014) How Sustainable is Sub-national Public Debt in Australia?, Economic
Analysis and Policy, 44, 364375
Makin, A. and Ratnasiri, S. (2015) “Competitiveness and Government Expenditure: The Australian Example”
Economic Modelling 49, 154-161
Moody’s Investors Services, Rating Action: Moody’s downgrades Western Australia’s rating Aa2 to Aa1,
Global Credit Research, Sydney, 8 February 2016
Mundell, R. (1963) “Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates.”
Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 29,4, 47585
New South Wales Government (2015), NSW Budget 2015-6 Half-Yearly Review, Sydney, 2015
New South Wales Government (2015), Budget Statement 2015-15, Budget Paper No. 1, Sydney, June 2015
Northern Territory Government I2015), Budget Paper No 2: Budget Strategy and Outlook, Darwin, April
2015
Northern Territory Government (2015), Mid Year Report 2015-16t, November, Darwin, 2015
Novak, M. (2015) Canberra’s Debt Problem, Institute of Public Affairs, Occasional Paper, Melbourne, July
Queensland Government (2015), Mid Year Fiscal and Economic Review 2015-16, Brisbane, 2015
Parliamentary Budget Office (2016a), Impact of policy decisions and parameter variations on Australian
Government revenue and spending estimates, As at 201516 Mid-Year Economic and Fiscal Outlook,
Canberra, date issued: 24 February 2016
Parliamentary Budget Office (2016b), Unlegislated measures carried forward in the budget estimates
February 2016 update, Canberra, date issued: 3 February 2016
Reserve Bank Australia, Financial Statistics, www.rba.gov.au/statistics
South Australian Government (2015), Mid-Year Budget Review, 2015-16 Budget, Adelaide, 2015
South Australian Government (2015), Budget Statement 2015-16, Budget Paper 3, 2015
Tasmanian Government (2016), Revised Estimates Report 2015-16 (including December Quarterly Report),
Hobart, February 2016
Uhlig, H. (2010) Some Fiscal Calculus. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, May, 30-34.
Victorian Government (2015), Budget Update 2015-16, Melbourne, November 2015
Victorian Government (2015), Statement of Finances 2015-16, Budget Paper No. 5, Melbourne, May 2015
Western Australian Government (2015), Government Mid-year Financial Projections Statement, Perth,
December 2015
... Makin and Pearce (2016) provides more detailed analysis.Financial Transformations Beyond the COVID-19 Health Crisis Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com by 178.171.17.212 on 11/23/22. ...
... See Tanzi and Schuknecht (2000) andMakin and Pearce (2016).Financial Transformations Beyond the COVID-19 Health Crisis Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com by 178.171.17.212 on 11/23/22. ...
... The fiscal literature after Bohn (1998) can be classified into categories, including (1) the general framework of Bohn (Bohn 1998;Valderrama 2005;Greiner et al. 2007;Icaza 2018;Mauro et al. 2015; Ramos-Herrera and Sosvilla-Rivero 2020), (2) single threshold (Bajo-Rubio et al. 2004;Reinhart and Rogoff 2010;Legrenzi and Milas 2013;Herndon et al. 2014;Égert 2015), (3) public debt overhand (Cecchetti et al. 2011;Reinhart et al. 2012), (4) the fiscal vulnerability index (Ghezzi et al. 2010;Baldacci et al. 2011;Hayes 2011), (5) the financial net worth or balance sheet approach (Mellor 1996;Barnhill and Kopits 2004;Makin and Pearce 2016), (6) classification and regression tree (Manasse and Roubini 2009), and (7) other approaches (Afonso and Rault 2010;Chen 2014;Robinson 2002;Gruen and Sayegh 2005;Stoian et al. 2018;Hemming and Petrie 2000). ...
... Some studies on Australian fiscal vulnerability (Mellor 1996;Robinson 2002;Gruen and Sayegh 2005;Di Marco et al. 2009;Makin and Pearce 2016) have suggested different measures to assess the fiscal vulnerability of the economy. The Australian government changed its accounting of fiscal policy measures in 1996. ...
Article
Full-text available
Fiscal vulnerability, like a contagion, poses a threat to financial sector stability, which can lead towards sovereign default. This study aimed to assess fiscal vulnerability to crisis by investigating the Australian economy’s gross public debt, net public debt, and net financial liabilities. We used a threshold regression model and compared results with the baseline deficit–debt framework of analysis. The results of the base model suggested that the economy is fiscally sustainable, and that the primary surplus remains unaffected by increasing levels of public debt. In contrast, the threshold regression model indicated that the increasing level of debt has eroded primary surplus below the threshold level of 30.89% of public debt to GDP. These results need further investigation. Therefore, we modified our basic threshold model to capture budget deficit and surplus as a threshold in response to changes in public debt. The results from the sequential threshold regression model using the debt to GDP ratio and primary budget surplus identifying the periods of 1991, 1992, 2008, 2009, 2011 and 2019 as times of likely vulnerability to fiscal crisis. The overall results confirmed that the primary surplus remained sustainable over the estimated threshold level of public debt in all other sample periods and these findings persisted across alternative measures of public debt.
... Yet there are theoretical grounds for believing that fiscal consolidation can improve subsequent macroeconomic performance over the medium to longer term. 28 Just as fiscal stimulus has negative repercussions according to the perspectives canvassed above, fiscal repair has corresponding positive 27 Makin and Pearce (2016) exposits the methodology for estimating primary budget surpluses required to reduce debt to targeted levels. 28 Alesina, Favero and Giavazzi (2015) examine fiscal consolidation programs in 16 OECD economies over a 30 year period and find that output losses associated with expenditure reduction are on average zero, whereas tax-based adjustments are associated with deep and lasting recessions. ...
... Budget Surpluses Required for Targeted Public Debt LevelsSource:Makin and Pearce (2016) ...
Technical Report
Full-text available
Australia has experienced one of the fastest rises in public debt in the world since the Global Financial Crisis. Federal budget deficits have persisted for longer than previous fiscal stimulus episodes in the 1980s and 1990s. Subsequent fiscal repair has also been weaker and less than in the United States, United Kingdom, New Zealand and the Euro area. This paper briefly introduces a range of alternative perspectives on the efficacy of fiscal stimulus as a macroeconomic policy instrument, including the loanable funds, Mundell-Fleming, dependent economy, Ricardian and intergenerational equity approaches. Each of these perspectives suggest fiscal stimulus has damaging offsetting effects that eventually minimise or neutralise its effectiveness in stabilising national income and employment. The paper then examines how effective Australia’s fiscal stimulus response to the GFC actually was in light of the economy’s robust banking system, floating exchange rate, openness to international trade and capital flows, and dependence on mineral exports to Asia. What prevented Australia from experiencing a technical recession at the critical juncture in 2008-09 was a combination of lower interest rates, a major exchange rate depreciation, strong foreign demand for mining exports, especially from China, and a then more flexible labour market. There is no evidence fiscal stimulus benefited the economy over the medium term. Largely implemented after the worst of the GFC had passed, fiscal stimulus countered the effectiveness of monetary policy by keeping market interest rates higher than otherwise and therefore contributed to a strong exchange rate. This worsened Australia’s international competitiveness and damaged industries in the economy’s internationally exposed sector, including manufacturing. Although Australia’s federal public debt to GDP ratio is not high by OECD standards, unlike other advanced economies it is mostly owed to foreign bondholders and has become a significant component of Australia’s total foreign debt, unmatched by domestic asset accumulation. Public debt interest now exceeds budgetary outlays on the Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme, unemployment benefits, higher education and foreign aid and could reach 1 per cent of GDP by 2020 on present fiscal settings. The servicing cost on foreign debt incurred to fund unproductive budgetary outlays is a net drain on national income and future budgets, and could potentially spark a vicious circle of deficits and debt requiring emergency fiscal remedies if higher world interest rates combine with an interest risk premium arising from a credit rating downgrade. Higher interest rates would also reduce private investment, reducing potential future national income. Reducing foreign public debt would staunch the national income loss arising from unrequited interest paid abroad. The scale of the fiscal consolidation effort required to improve the sustainability of federal public debt is around twice that currently projected. Necessary fiscal consolidation focused on reducing government consumption would exert downward pressure on market interest rates, lessen foreign investment in government bonds, lower the exchange rate, and hence lift international competitiveness. Fiscal repair can also be expected to lift business confidence, boost private investment and strengthen medium term economic growth. For these reasons, reducing public debt should be a top priority of fiscal policy.
... The debt path is determined by the path of overall fiscal balances, or primary balances and interest bill (Escolano, 2010). A necessary condition for stabilising the ratio of public debt to GDP is (Makin & Pearce, 2014): ...
... As suggested in Makin and Pearce (2016), these interest payments on public debt owed to foreigners directly reduces national income to the same extent and could lead to a vicious cycle of deficits and debt calling for emergency fiscal action should rising world interest rates combine with an interest risk premium due to a credit rating downgrade. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper proposes lessons for macroeconomic policy stemming from the monetary and fiscal responses to the 2008–09 Global Financial Crisis, with an emphasis on Australia’s experience. After canvassing hitherto underemphasised global factors leading up to the crisis, including China’s rise and its effect on global saving, external imbalances and world interest rates, the paper critically evaluates the G20’s macroeconomic policy response to the crisis and its public debt legacy, especially for advanced economies. It then revisits Australia’s GFC performance, highlighting its macroeconomic behaviour at the time and the effectiveness of the monetary and fiscal responses. Lastly, it summarises what the episode implies for any future macroeconomic policy response to a crisis.
Chapter
Full-text available
James Buchanan and Richard Wagner in their famous book “Democracy in Defi cit” note that democracy has not enough fi scal discipline because the citizens’ representatives are chosen in the election and they take the budgetary decisions seeking the re-election. Th eir theory of public choice may suggest the existence of a positive relationship between the democracy’s quality and the public debt level refl ecting the long-lasting consequences of the budgetary decisions of policy-makers. Th us, we formulate the following research question: Is democratic system harmful for public fi nance? To operationalize the democratic system, we use fi ve democracy indices (i.e., electoral, liberal, participatory, deliberative, and egalitarian), and the public debt to operationalize the threat for public fi nance. Conclusions put in a new light the theory, as fi rst the study confi rmed that there are statistically signifi cant relationships between democracy’s quality and public debt and, however not in case of every democracy index and every European country.
Conference Paper
The article deals with the property taxation of investment apartments and dwelling houses. This paper's main aim is to verify the hypothesis that to increase tax on investment apartments and investment dwelling houses, it is necessary to amend the Immovable Property Tax Act. To confirm or disprove the hypothesis, the investment property was defined as the second home if used for long-term or short-term rent or not used at all. The article briefly focuses on other taxes connected with the acquisition of immovable property, analyses de lege lata regulation of recurrent property tax on investment apartments and investment dwelling houses in the Czech Republic, and briefly introduces two main systems of property taxation (based on values and area). The hypothesis was disproved. If the property is used as the first home, the taxation is, in line with the policy at the national and local level, lower. These rules apply to the property, both taxpayer-owned and long-term rented, as the criteria are the usage of the property. Concerning the dwelling houses and apartments used for short-term rents (typically Airbnb type of accommodation) or other businesses, they should be taxed at a higher rate. However, the tax administration must strictly follow the legal text as the crucial for taxation is how the property is actually used. It is also necessary to check the periodicity of the contracts and who the tenants are, the service provided for the guests, the purpose of accommodation, who is responsible for routine maintenance and minor repairs, etc.
Article
The COVID‐19 pandemic saw governments around the world suddenly accumulate substantially higher levels of public debt. We consider the level of debt entered into by Australia's federal, state and territory governments and compare this against three metrics for debt sustainability. Using these measures, we find that current and future public debt levels sit within what is regarded as sustainable by scholarly and practitioner opinion. However, we note that recent increases in interest rates will challenge this. We conclude by outlining a range of economic, social and policy challenges arising from the new high public debt environment.
Article
In this study, I employ a SVAR method that filters out the business cycle and monetary policy to produce conservative but realistic estimates of fiscal responses and multipliers for Australia that are unavailable in the literature. The expenditure and tax multipliers reach a maximum of 0.73 and 0.54, respectively, but their comparison alternates depending on the time horizon. Using a linear combination of fiscal shocks, I construct conjectural variations to analyse the data dynamics and inform policymaking on ways of restoring economic activity post-Covid-19. Importantly, it is demonstrated that a policy that simultaneously increases expenditure and taxes can serve as both a fiscal stimulus and a debt reduction instrument in the medium run, with dynamics subject to a transitory reverse overshooting. This finding is particularly relevant for policymakers that are adverse to increasing public debt with discretionary fiscal measures.
Article
Full-text available
This paper contends that worldwide fiscal excess, as embodied in heightened public debt levels, is central to understanding why global growth has been sub-optimal since the transatlantic crisis. It notes that in the five years before the 2009-10 financial crisis average world economic growth was close to 5 per cent per year, but has since averaged only 3 per cent. The author states that government expenditure spiked notably more in advanced economies in response to the crisis and remains around 9 percent higher as a share of GDP in G20 advanced economies on average than in emerging economies. The paper explores recent literature which focused explicitly on the crowding out effects of fiscal stimulus in contrast to the Keynesian orthodox view. Attention is focussed on the impact of beneficial austerity on growth and also notes that additional government spending on infrastructure without regard to its productivity is risky.
Article
Full-text available
This paper proposes a new measure of competitiveness based on the ratio of non-tradable goods and services prices to tradable goods and services prices. It first presents a straightforward framework for understanding how key macroeconomic variables determine this alternative competitiveness measure with reference to output and expenditure behaviour in a two sector open economy. It then econometrically examines its most significant determinants with reference to private and public sector consumption and investment in Australia. Results based on quarterly data from 1998 to 2013 suggest that government expenditure on non-tradable goods and services was the most significant factor to worsen Australia's competitiveness. This provides an alternative perspective on the efficacy of fiscal policy to those previously advanced in standard international macroeconomic models.
Article
Full-text available
Since the Global Financial Crisis the public indebtedness of Australia’s States and Territories has risen significantly due to sizeable fiscal deficits. This paper examines the stability of sub-national governments’ indebtedness before gauging the fiscal effort needed to scale back public debt to GSP ratios to ten-year average levels. To do this, we first derive key debt sustainability formulae which are then applied to relevant sub-national data. The analysis reveals that under macroeconomic conditions and fiscal settings in 2012-13, debt levels were unstable for all State and Territory general governments. Moreover, virtually all sub-national governments in Australia need to turn existing primary budget deficits into substantial surpluses to restore public debt to levels experienced on average over the previous decade. This is not in prospect without even more substantial fiscal consolidation than currently envisaged in State and Territory budgets.
Article
Full-text available
This article theoretically examines the impact of different forms of government spending on national income in a financially open economy with a significant net international investment position the central bank of which sets domestic interest rates to target inflation. It shows that whether government spending is expansionary or contractionary ultimately depends on the productivity of that expenditure, a result that has major implications for the efficacy of fiscal policy deployed for either stimulus or austerity reasons. The key prediction of the model is that public consumption and unproductive public investment are procyclical, whereas only productive public investment is countercyclical. (JEL F41)
Article
Full-text available
This paper re-examines the relationship between fiscal imbalances and net foreign borrowing. A general analytical approach is first developed which suggests that, other things equal, a rise (fall) in any advanced economy’s fiscal deficit should be fully matched by a rise (fall) in its net foreign borrowing, in accordance with the so-called twin deficits hypothesis. In the case of Australia, one of the world’s largest foreign borrower economies for its size, empirical estimation yields the novel result that Australia’s consolidated budget imbalance and its foreign borrowing were approximately twinned on the basis of quarterly data for 1983–2009, when Australia’s exchange rate floated and international capital mobility was high. This result is consistent with the conceptual framework and suggests that fiscal policy is likely to be ineffective as an instrument for influencing the real economy.
Article
In 2009-10 governments around the world implemented unprecedented fiscal stimulus in order to counter the impact of the Global Financial Crisis of 2008-09. This paper analyses the impact of fiscal stimulus using a dynamic open economy, overlapping generations model that allows for feedback effects of fiscal stimulus on private sector expenditure via changes in the tax rate and the interest rate. There are two types of goods – traded (T) and non-traded (N) goods, which differ in their capital intensities. The main qualitative result is that the dynamic output gains from fiscal stimulus depend on the productivity of the initial stimulus spending, on the speed of repayment of debt, on the sensitivities of the interest rate to government debt and of labour supply to the tax rate. Also, the overlapping generations framework allows an intergenerational welfare analysis. Among the biggest winners from stimulus are those about to retire. The biggest losers are those near the start of their working lives when the stimulus is implemented.
Article
The world is still a closed economy, but its regions and countries are becoming increasingly open. The trend, which has been manifested in both freer movement of goods and increased mobility of capital, has been stimulated by the dismantling of trade and exchange controls in Europe, the gradual erosion of the real burden of tariff protection, and the stability, unparalleled since 1914, of the exchange rates. The international economic climate has changed in the direction of financial integration and this has important implications for economic policy. My paper concerns the theoretical and practical implications of the increased mobility of capital. In order to present my conclusions in the simplest possible way, and to bring the implications for policy into sharpest relief, I assume the extreme degree of mobility that prevails when a country cannot maintain an interest rate different from the general level prevailing abroad. This assumption will overstate the case but it has the merit of posing a stereotype towards which international financial relations seem to be heading. At the same time it might be argued that the assumption is not far from the truth in those financial centres, of which Zurich, Amsterdam, and Brussels may be taken as examples, where the authorities already recognize their lessening ability to dominate money market conditions and insulate them from foreign influences. It should also have a high degree of relevance to a country like Canada whose financial markets are dominated to a great degree by the vast New York market.