ChapterPDF Available

Abstract

The illegal wildlife trade is a growing problem driven by a number of factors (e.g. subsistence, alternative medicine, accessories, the pet trade). High demand for illicit wildlife products is threatening the existence of many of the most-endangered species. By unsustainably removing coveted species from the wild, communities that depend on such species for subsistence or eco-tourism will be adversely impacted by depleting populations. Laws and regulations have been implemented over the years, most notably CITES, to regulate the commercial trade in wildlife and prohibit trade in other species that are at-risk of overexploitation albeit with mixed success. Criminologists have recently entered the fold and provided insight to the wildlife trade through various perspectives. Researchers are beginning to better understand why and how the trade operates and what solutions might be implemented to reduce it. The article ends with implications for future research.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 1 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Stephen F. Pires and William D. Moreto
Abstract and Keywords
The illegal wildlife trade is a growing problem driven by a number of factors (e.g.
subsistence, alternative medicine, accessories, the pet trade). High demand for illicit
wildlife products is threatening the existence of many of the most-endangered species. By
unsustainably removing coveted species from the wild, communities that depend on such
species for subsistence or eco-tourism will be adversely impacted by depleting
populations. Laws and regulations have been implemented over the years, most notably
CITES, to regulate the commercial trade in wildlife and prohibit trade in other species
that are at-risk of overexploitation albeit with mixed success. Criminologists have
recently entered the fold and provided insight to the wildlife trade through various
perspectives. Researchers are beginning to better understand why and how the trade
operates and what solutions might be implemented to reduce it. The article ends with
implications for future research.
Keywords: wildlife crime, environmental criminology, green criminology, conservation criminology, poach,
trafficking
Introduction
The illegal wildlife trade has long been a problem that only recently has captured the
attention of the public and academics across disciplines. Criminologists and criminal
justice scholars are increasingly researching the topic from a variety of perspectives with
the aim of understanding the nature of the trade and how to mitigate it. Section I
discusses the nature of the illegal wildlife trade and its impact on fauna and flora. An in-
depth examination of international agreements and regulations is the focus of Section II.
Section III examines the theoretical perspectives to understanding the illegal trade in
wildlife. The types of offenders involved and the organization of the trade is detailed in
Section IV. Section V identifies supply markets, or where poaching disproportionately
Subject: Criminology and Criminal Justice, International and Comparative Criminology,
Organizational and White-Collar Crime
Online Publication Date: Jul 2016 DOI: 10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199935383.013.161
Oxford Handbooks Online
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 2 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
occurs, along with where major demand markets are found. Section VI identifies the
reasons why wildlife is trafficked and covers three commonly poached animals in the
illegal wildlife trade—rhinos, pangolins, and parrots—in greater depth. The final section
offers implications for future research.
I. Nature and History of the Problem
According to Interpol (2015), “Wildlife crime is the taking, trading, exploiting or
possessing of the world’s wild flora and fauna in contravention of national and
international laws.” Whether species are poached for subsistence (e.g., bushmeat) or
personal ownership (e.g., ivory bangles), for local or international trade, cultural or
religious beliefs, or as a result of human-animal conflict, a wildlife crime has occurred.
Such a definition, however, does not cover “harms” to animals that may lead to
diminished populations but is otherwise legal (also see Section III; White 2008). Such
harms commonly come in the form of habitat loss (or deforestation), the practice of
clearing a large number of trees for agricultural purposes or for human settlement (Geist
and Lambin 2002). Deforestation is the primary threat of extinction for the majority of
wildlife on earth because it removes suitable habitat for millions of species (Pimm and
Raven 2000) and exacerbates climate change (MEA 2005). Because deforestation is
commonly sanctioned by governments, it is not a crime in the traditional sense and will
not be the focus of this systematic review.
For centuries, wildlife was taken from the wild for profit, personal use, or killed because
they were a nuisance. Retaliatory killing of elephants, tigers, and lions, for example, has
been a common practice in range states after attacking humans and/or their livestock
(Omondi et al. 2004). Many of these actions were not against the law. Even in times or
places where it was unlawful, it was often overlooked or ignored by law enforcement. In
cases where animals were trapped or poached for profit, much of this trade was for local
markets. As the world became more globalized in the latter decades of the 20th century,
so too did the illegal wildlife trade. Species once poached for local or national demand
are now trafficked through multiple countries and ports to reach markets on the other
side of the world. Poachers may no longer be exclusively locals; outsiders are now
sometimes involved in search of highly endangered and valuable species such as rhinos
and elephants. Because of this international demand in combination with accelerated
habitat loss, the illegal wildlife trade is significantly contributing to the decline of many
species (Broad et al. 2003, Butchart et al 2010; Phelps et al. 2010; Sutherland et al.
2009), and in particular, a significant proportion of endangered species (Rosser and
Mainka 2002). Some have claimed that we are currently experiencing the sixth mass
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 3 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
extinction, where up to 100,000 species go extinct on an annual basis due to human-
based activity (Barnosky et al. 2011; Ceballos et al. 2015).
Assessing the extent of the illegal wildlife trade is made difficult due to the clandestine
nature of illicit activity. Economic estimates suggest the illegal wildlife trade, excluding
the illegal timber trade and illegal fishing, is valued between US$7.8 and 10 billion a year
(Haken 2011). The illegal fishing industry is estimated to be between US$10 and 23
billion a year (Agnew et al. 2008), and illegal timber is valued at US$7 billion a year
(Haken 2011). Estimates such as these make the illegal wildlife trade one of the most
profitable illicit trafficking industries behind the trafficking of drugs, guns, and humans
(Vince 2002).
The illicit trade has severe repercussions for both humans and wildlife. Unregulated
taking of natural resources depletes resources for nations and the local communities that
depend on them for their livelihoods (TRAFFIC 2008). The illegal wildlife trade also
happens to have a high mortality rate due to the clandestine nature of trafficking live
species (Cantu et al. 2007; Clark, Van Thai, and Phuong 2008; Franke and Telecky 2001).
Often poachers take more than what isnecessary as there is an expectation that many
wildlife individuals will perish en route to markets. Apart from the economic and
population losses, poachers also damage the environments of species by using
destructive practices such as felling trees (Gonzalez 2003), using cyanide to stun fish,
and employing “blast fishing” (i.e., use dynamite) that causes coral degradation
(McClellan et al. 2008).
Since at least the 1970s, there has been growing consensus that the wildlife crime
problem needs to be addressed in the form of new policies, regulations, protected parks,
enforcement, and public education. In addition to this, conservationist organizations,
such as TRAFFIC, the World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF), and the International Union
for Conservation of Nature (IUCN), have been at the forefront of protecting endangered
species and their habitats while studying the global illegal wildlife trade problem in
greater depth (see Schneider 2012). The following section examines regulations and laws
put forth at the international and national levels.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 4 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
II. Regulations and Laws
A. International Regulations
Despite the best intentions and efforts, combating the illegal wildlife trade effectively
cannot fall upon a single nation in the world. Most wildlife is not endemic to one country,
and wildlife often migrates across geopolitical boundaries. Criminals in the trade often
facilitate this migration by poaching, trafficking, processing, and selling wildlife to
consumers that span several countries and regions of the world. For these reasons,
combating the illegal wildlife trade must be a coordinated effort that utilizes local,
national, regional, and international cooperation (Schneider 2012; Pires and Moreto
2011; Moreto 2015).
A number of bilateral and multinational agreements have been put in place over the last
century or so to conserve species in danger of extinction (Mitchell 2003; Schneider 2012).
In the first half of the 20th century, such agreements, in addition to national legislation,
restricted hunting and trading of wildlife in various ways. Many of these agreements and
national regulations were unsuccessful in their objectives, which allowed unsustainable
wildlife poaching and trafficking to persist. For example, the International Agreement for
the Regulation of Whaling signed in 1937 was seen as a failure because it did not impose
size or catch limits (Schneider 2012).
The failure of national regulations and international agreements, along with the rise in
the illegal wildlife trade of threatened species, instigated the 1973 drafting of the
Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora
(CITES). This was subsequently put into effect in 1975 with 80 nations agreeing to
regulate trade in wildlife and prohibit the trade of the most at-risk species from
overexploitation. Since then, 181 nations have become part of the CITES agreement and
have adopted CITES policies at the national level (Moyle 2003) through a licensing
system that subjects certain wildlife to varying degrees of controls. To this day, CITES is
considered to be the most effective international agreement in history in regulating the
wildlife trade (Phelps et al. 2010; Huxley 2000; Schneider 2012).
CITES introduced three appendices in which listed species are afforded greater
protection when traded between countries (see Table 1). Appendix I species are
prohibited in international commercial trade because the trade may greatly impact these
vulnerable species. The African elephant, cheetah, giant panda, tigers, and most rhino
species are among the most notable species listed under Appendix I. Appendix II species
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 5 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
are not always at-risk of extinction but can be at-risk without a system of regulations.
Such species may be commercially traded only if export permits are procured, and
depending on the import nation, may also require import permits. Appendix III is
reserved for species that are requested to be listed and protected by a member nation so
that other member nations avoid exploitation of said species (CITES 2015a).
Table 1 CITES Appendices and Restrictions on Trade
CITES
Appendices
Restrictions on Trade Number of
Species
Covered
CITES I Species afforded greater protection because they
are threatened with extinction. Species cannot be
traded for commercial purposes. If they are traded,
both import and export permits are required that
demonstrate the trade “is not detrimental to their
survival.”*
931
CITES II Species may or may not be threatened with
extinction, but the trade of such species needs to be
highly regulated. Most species can be commercially
traded with a required export permit.
34,419
CITES III Species are protected in at least one country, and
this country or set of countries has asked others to
help regulate the trade to avoid overexploitation.
147
(*) According to CITES 2015c.
(**) CITES, 2015b.
The effectiveness of CITES trade controls on saving species from extinction is mixed.
Many claim CITES is highly effective (e.g., Cole 2012; Fuchs 2010; Huxley 2000), but this
is difficult to conclude in the absence of a systematic study examining the impact of
listing species under CITES (Weber et al. 2015; Roe 2008; Martin 2000). The evidence
available is restricted to species-specific studies and the impact CITES trade controls
have at the macrolevel. From this, evidence has shown that trade bans, that is, listing
species under Appendix I, have resulted in less trade and rebounding populations in some
species such as the African elephant, vicunas, the southern white rhino, and the greater
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 6 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
one-horned rhino (WWF 2015; Eloff and Lemieux 2014; Cole 2012; Lemieux and Clarke
2009; Mcallister et al. 2009). Often this success is in combination with conservation
efforts on the ground (WWF 2015; Eloff and Lemieux 2014), and where it includes a
recovery plan that calls for consultation with local communities and range states
(Larriera et al. 2010; Lichtenstein 2009; Frisina and Tareen 2009; Mcallister et al. 2009;
Hutton and Webb 2003; Leader-Williams 2003).
Critics of CITES actions suggest that declines are more common than recoveries for
species listed under CITES (’t Sas-Rolfes 2010, 2012; Dickson 2003; Kievit 2000; Martin
2000; ERM 1996). Even when utilizing trade bans, populations do not automatically
recover once commercial trade and poaching cease (Leader-Williams 2003; Jachmann
2003). A number of other factors, such as habitat loss and human-animal conflict, can
impact population recoveries independent of the reduction in the illegal wildlife trade. In
addition to these critiques, the complexity of demand and market dynamics is not always
considered by CITES policymakers when implementing trade bans (Challender et al.
2015a; 2015b; Rosen and Smith 2010; Hall et al. 2008). This suggests trade bans, the
most important tool CITES has in its arsenal to combat the illegal wildlife trade, may be
an overly simplistic response to a very complex problem (Bowman 2013; Briggs et al.
2013; Couzens 2013; Moore 2011a; Cooney and Jepson 2006; Dickson 2003; Moyle 2003).
Because of the possible overuse of trade bans in the absence of viable conservation
policies on the ground, endangered species may not recover from dwindling populations,
which has been the case with tigers (Project Tiger 2005) and pangolins (Pantel and Chin
2009) in particular. Overall, trade bans have the potential to be a useful tool in the short-
term but may lead to poaching and wildlife trafficking in the long-term if no other
strategies are implemented (Hutton and Webb 2003; Conrad 2012).
CITES has the ability to save some species from extinction and protect others from being
at-risk, however, the success of CITES is contingent on a number of working parts that
may be lacking or failing altogether. First, the lack of enforcement and compliance of
CITES objectives at the national and local levels has hindered its overall effectiveness
(Han 2014; Schneider 2012; Rosen and Smith 2010; Leader-Williams 2003; Vasquez
2003). This lack of enforcement and compliance disproportionately occurs on the
continent of Africa where many of the most biodiverse regions of the world are.
Noncompliance and enforcement problems in Africa are due to a myriad of problems that
include (1) corruption, (2) wars, (3) limited resources, (4) lack of political commitment
and stability, and (5) domestic conflict (Schneider 2012; Fiadjoe 2004). Second,
evaluating whether CITES policies are effective is difficult given data limitations. For
example, population counts are not collected for many threatened species that are listed
under CITES (Abensperg-Traun et al. 2009; Phelps et al. 2010; Parsons et al. 2010).
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 7 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Third, trade bans may increase black market prices for threatened and endangered
species, which can exacerbate poaching (MacMillan and Han 2011; Pires and Moreto
2011; Hall et al. 2008; Courchamp et al. 2006; ’t Sas-Rolfes 2000). Fourth, locals may not
be incentivized to preserve wildlife when the ability to legally trade them is removed.
Some suggest that people only value and protect wildlife if they can benefit from using it
(Dickson 2003; Leader-Williams 2003; Martin 2000). Finally, CITES is limited because it
is designed to address only the illegal international trade in wildlife and not intranational
trade. Recent research shows the domestic trade in illegal wildlife is quite substantial
(Pires 2012; Pires and Moreto 2011; Nijman 2010; Tilson et al. 2010; Du Plessis 2000) and
may even be larger than the international trade for some species (see also Section VI).
B. National Regulations
Typically nations will either impose poaching (and trade) bans for all species of a
particular animal or regulate the trade in the form of catch-quotas. Catch-quotas allow a
certain number of species to be trapped every year as long as appropriate permits have
been obtained. The lobster industry, for example, illustrates this scheme quite well:
fishermen are required to obtain permits and/or licenses to trap lobsters during
particular times of the year and are restricted by catch limits and size. The purpose of
such a regulatory scheme is to allow certain members of the community to profit from
historical practices while ensuring species’ populations are healthy. Ideally, catch-quotas
are based on scientific assessments of populations so that legal trapping, or catches, of
wildlife are sustainably based, but this may not always be the case (Cantu et al. 2007).
To date, no systematic study has analyzed the effects of either poaching bans or catch-
quota regulations on species’ populations (Smith and Walpole 2005). One recent study
suggests that export quotas of birds had no influence on the domestic bird trade in a neo-
tropical country (Daut et al. 2015). However, other parrot-trade-related studies have
found catch-quotas can lead to overtrapping due to lack of enforcement (Cantu et al.
2007; Gastanaga et al. 2011). There is similarly mixed evidence regarding the
effectiveness of poaching bans. Many of the most-endangered and trafficked species have
habitats in nations with total poaching and trade bans. Clearly, a systematic review or
meta-analysis study is needed to shed light on which approach is better at diminishing
the risk of extinction in species at the national level.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 8 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
III. Theoretical Perspectives to Understanding the Illegal Wildlife Trade
We now shift our attention to discussing the criminological and criminal justice
perspectives that have been used to examine illegal wildlife trafficking and related
wildlife crime (e.g., poaching). For ease, we focus on the four main perspectives that have
dominated the literature: environmental criminology and crime science, green
criminology, conservation criminology, and criminal justice. However, it is worth noting
that scholars have used other criminological perspectives to examine wildlife crimes that
go beyond the following (e.g. techniques of neutralization, differential association theory,
etc.; see Eliason 1999; Eliason and Dodder 1999).
A. Environmental Criminology and Crime Science
Although, the term “environmental criminology” has also been used to specifically
describe the study of crimes against the environment (White 2008), in order to avoid
confusion (see Brisman and South 2013; Herbig 2014), we adhere to the original and
traditional conceptualization and use of environmental criminology. With its roots in
crime prevention (Andresen 2014), environmental criminology is made up of established
theoretical frameworks, including the routine activity approach, geometric theory of
crime, rational choice perspective, and pattern theory. In a similar vein, crime science is
a multidisciplinary applied action-research perspective that is outcome focused and based
on understanding the “how” of crime as opposed to the “why” in order to develop
preventative strategies for immediate crime reduction (Clarke 2004; Laycock 2005).
Research over the years has consistently shown crime disproportionately occurs as it
relates to target selection (Cornish and Clarke 1986), space (Sherman et al. 1989), time
(Felson and Poulsen, 2003), and products (Clarke 1999). By knowing how crime is
concentrated, opportunity-mitigating strategies can be implemented to have immediate
crime reduction effects. Arguably, one of the most widely known crime prevention
strategies is situational crime prevention (Clarke 1980, 1997, 2009), which aims to alter
the immediate environment for a specific crime type in order to increase the effort and
risk for crime commission, while also reducing or removing rewards, provocations, and
excuses.
To date, a number of studies have been conducted on the illegal wildlife trade from an
environmental criminology and crime science perspective. For example, the routine
activities approach (Cohen and Felson 1979) has been used to examine wildlife poaching
in protected areas in South Africa (Herbig 2011) and trophy poaching in Montana in the
United States (Eliason 2012). Recently, Moreto and Lemieux (2015b) extended the
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 9 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
routine activity framework to incorporate the existence and role of proxy offenders (i.e.,
wire snares initiating contact with wildlife as opposed to poachers) in their research of
poaching in Uganda.
Crime scripts, also known as the procedural analysis of offending, which attempts to
generate and organize the procedural activities and requirements of crime commission
(Cornish, 1994), has been used to examine wildlife trafficking (Lavorgna 2014; although
see Moreto and Clarke 2013). Additionally, the concept of “hot products,” or products
that are “most attractive to thieves” (Clarke 1999: 1), and the related conceptual
CRAVED framework (concealable, removable, available, valuable, enjoyable, and
disposable) has been applied to several wildlife crimes, including parrot poaching (Pires
and Clarke 2011, 2012), parrot trafficking (Pires and Petrossian 2016), illegal fishing
(Petrossian and Clarke 2014), and livestock theft (Sidebottom 2013). With respect to the
illegal wildlife trade, Moreto and Lemieux (2015a) recently argued that the CRAVED
model may be limited in fully assessing the dynamic nature of some wildlife products as
they maneuver through an illegal market continuum. They therefore proposed an
extended model referred to as CAPTURED (concealable, available, processable,
transferrable, useable, removable, enjoyable, and desirable).
Lastly, crime reduction and prevention frameworks have also been introduced within the
scope of wildlife crimes, especially situational crime prevention (Petrossian et al. 2016;
Lemieux 2014; Pires and Moreto 2011). For instance, the situational crime prevention
framework has been used to investigate the impact of the international ban on ivory sales
on elephant poaching in Africa (Lemieux and Clarke 2009) and illegal fishing (Petrossian
2015). Additionally, the market reduction strategy, which was initially conceived to
reduce and disrupt stolen goods markets, has also been discussed within the scope of
wildlife trafficking (Schneider 2008).
B. Green Criminology
Considered to be within the “margins of criminological research [and a] distinctive
subfield that challenges traditional approaches in criminological inquiry” (Wyatt 2013:
13), green criminology originally developed as an extension of radical criminology. In
essence, green criminology was proposed as a means to investigate the underlying and
overreaching political economic origins of environment-related criminal activity
(Stretesky, Long, and Lynch 2013). From this perspective, it is argued that the causes of
environmental harms are similar to factors that result in social injustice in that
inequalities associated with gender, race, and class result in harms against both humans
and the environment. In other words, environmental and social injustice is perpetuated
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 10 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
by established power dynamics and by those who control the means of production (White
2008; Stretesky et al. 2013).
While some green criminologists still operate from a political economy perspective,
including more recently in relation to the role of the treadmill of production and
ecological disorganization on environmental crimes (Lynch et al. 2013; Stretesky et al.
2013), green criminology has been expanded to better account for “environmental
justice, with a special focus on human rights and social equity; and ecological justice,
with a special focus on the biosphere generally and the rights of non-human as well as
human” (White 2008: 50). Notably, most of those who adhere to a green criminological
viewpoint argue that solely focusing on criminal violations is too restrictive and that a
harm perspective is needed to account for activities that cause significant environmental
destruction but may fall outside the purview of criminal law (Lynch and Stretesky 2003;
White 2008). As such, it has been argued that the broad scope and purpose of green
criminology is to
provide a space within criminology to examine the nexus between environmental
problems, the definition of harms against nature as crimes, the need to reconsider
criminal justice practices and policies in relationship to the environmental harms
they produce, the variety of victims environmental offenses create … and the
effect of environmental toxins on ecological systems and species’ health and
behavior.
(Lynch and Stretesky 2014: 2)
Acknowledging the importance of environmental harms, green criminologists also
recognize the importance of distinguishing between different levels of eco-justice,
including environmental justice (i.e., emphasis on human well-being), ecological justice
(i.e., focus on investigating human interaction with the environment as it relates to harms
and risks), and species justice (i.e., consideration of the welfare and rights of nonhuman
animals) (White 2008; White and Heckenberg 2014). Additionally, green criminologists
have also proposed the importance of developing a nonspeciesist perspective (Beirne
1999), exploring the link between cultural meanings and perspectives as it relates to
environment-related crimes (Brisman and South 2013) and linkages between
environmental harm and racial and socioeconomic inequalities (Brisman 2015).
Moreover, the transnational nature of environmental crimes/harms has been recognized
within the promotion of an eco-global criminology framework (White 2011). With
reference to wildlife trafficking, a green criminological perspective has been used to
examine the trade in Vietnam (Ngoc and Wyatt 2013) and in Russia (Wyatt 2009).
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 11 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
C. Conservation Criminology
Partly in response to some of the criticisms and limitations levied against green
criminology (see Halsey 2004 for example), Gibbs and colleagues (2010) introduced
conservation criminology as an interdisciplinary conceptual framework that integrates
criminology, natural science disciplines, and risk and decision science. Similar to green
criminology, conservation criminology recognizes the importance of examining behaviors
that do not violate criminal law, however, conservation criminologists “reject previous
definitions and typologies of conservation crime” that can be found within the green
criminological literature that emphasized social justice and biocentric perspectives
(Gibbs et al. 2010: 129).
The primary starting point for conservation criminologists is to determine and ascertain
the manifestation and level of environmental risk from the perspectives of different
stakeholders. By focusing on risk, as opposed to crime for example, it is argued that the
inclusion of different perspectives can be attained, potential consequences can be better
articulated, and different solutions can be developed. Conservation criminology also
operates from multiple scales (e.g., individual to collective) and domains (e.g., local to
global) thereby providing a comprehensive examination of environmental risks, both
direct and indirect (Gibbs et al. 2010).
In addition to incorporating risk and decision sciences, conservation criminology
explicitly integrates the natural science disciplines in order to better understand and
respond to environmental crimes. Given the expansive scope of environment-related
crimes and the overall lack of familiarity of criminologists or criminal justice scholars in
measuring, managing, and conserving natural ecosystems, it is argued that natural
science disciplines have a very important role in examining environmental crimes. As put
by Gibbs and colleagues (2010):
Criminologists are knowledgeable about the legal system, but are not trained to
scientifically assess threats to the natural environment. Thus, criminologists could
provide information on the circumstances under which legal versus other tools
may be most effective while natural resource scientists offer insight into the
impact of various stimuli on natural resources and ecosystems. (133)
By incorporating three distinct disciplines, conservation criminology therefore “offers a
model for understanding this type of illicit human behavior (environmental crimes) and
the emotions, cognitions, and institutions that affect human relations with the
environment” (Gore 2011: 659). Within the scope of wildlife crimes, conservation
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 12 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
criminologists have examined poaching risks (Kahler, Roloff, and Gore 2013) and
noncompliance with poaching laws (Kahler and Gore 2012) in Namibia.
D. Criminal Justice Perspectives
In addition to criminologists, criminal justice scholars have provided important
contributions to the study of wildlife crimes, particularly within the scope of wildlife law
enforcement. Not only has this research provided insight into better understand the
human dimensions of conservation policy (Jacobson and Duff 1998; Gore 2011) and
central aspects of wildlife law enforcement (see Forsyth 1993; Eliason 2003, 2006;
Shelley and Crow 2009; Patten 2010; Warchol and Kapla 2012; Moreto 2015; Moreto,
Brunson, and Braga 2015, Forthcoming), but such frontline perspectives have been vital
for research on wildlife crime as well, including the development of poaching typologies
(Forsyth, Gramling, and Wooddell 1998; Eliason 2008). Moreover, such research has
provided valuable insight into conditions that may contribute to the development and
continuance of wildlife crimes, such as ranger deviance (Moreto et al. 2015).
IV. Actors in the Trade
A. The Market Continuum from an Actor-based Perspective
The number of individuals required for a wildlife product to maneuver through a market
will vary and depend on a number of factors, including the expected end market and
anticipated consumer, the unique characteristics of the products, and the capabilities and
limitations of actors already involved in the trade. While the illegal wildlife trade can be
examined in various ways, including a stage-based (Tailby and Gant 2002) or a product-
based approach (Moreto and Lemieux 2015a), we focus our attention on the actors in the
trade, in part because the emphasis in the literature is on the individuals involved.
Indeed, “the journey of any given wildlife product from the collector at the source to the
final consumer can involve a wide range of intermediaries and other stakeholders” (Broad
et al. 2003: 15). It is important to note that the following categories are not mutually
exclusive and that individuals may fulfill multiple roles throughout the trade.
Furthermore, we explicitly refer to these individuals as actors as opposed to offenders
given the potential conceptual overlap between offender/victim as it pertains to broader
societal changes and cultural pressures (i.e., legal hunting deemed illegal; see Wyatt
2013).
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 13 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
B. Poachers
In comparison to other actors involved in the illegal wildlife trade, poachers have
received the most empirical attention. Research suggests that poachers vary; they are
influenced by different motivations and motives, utilize different techniques, and can use
a variety of equipment. As evidenced in the literature, different wildlife species may be
targeted for different reasons and therefore, specific techniques may be preferred over
others. For example, if a tiger is targeted for its skin, poison may be used instead of
hunting techniques that may damage the pelt (e.g., guns). Broadly speaking, research
suggests that poachers are driven to poach because of necessity/subsistence, profit/
commercial, traditional or cultural practices, religious beliefs, boredom, protection of self
and property, rebellion, thrill killing, trophy hunting, research, zoos, exploitation of legal
hunting practices, and gamesmanship (Muth and Bowe 1998; McMullan and Perrier
2002; Raymakers 2002; Tailby and Gant 2002; Zimmerman 2003; Shepherd and Magnus
2004; Bell, Hampshire, and Topalidou 2007; Ahmed 2010; Wilson-Wilde 2010; Wyatt
2013; Moreto and Lemieux 2015b; von Essen et al. 2014).
C. Middlemen/Traders
In wildlife trafficking, Wyatt (2013) argues that middlemen are akin to a “fence [or]
someone who moves stolen goods within networks” (87). Middlemen are involved in
brokering transactions between different parties, acting as wholesalers, and when
necessary, keeping in storage illegal wildlife contraband (Broad, Mulliken, and Roe
2003). Often middlemen are locals (Broad et al. 2003; WWF 2012) who may be trading
due to their familiarity with the underground trade or individuals with a vested interest in
specific products; however, within the scope of organized crime groups (discussed later),
middlemen may simply be an extension of a larger trafficking operation, albeit one that is
based more on loose networks rather than a hierarchical one (Wyatt 2013).
D. Processors
As mentioned earlier, prior research suggests that the characteristics of wildlife products
should be taken into consideration when investigating the entirety of an illegal trade. For
example, a poached tiger can be redistributed via the illegal market in several ways: from
a live pet to different products used for traditional Asian medicine (TAM). Both a live
tiger and tiger parts will require individuals who are familiar with specialized knowledge
and techniques. In other words, wildlife may need to be modified to ensure that it is a
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 14 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
“saleable product” (Wyatt 2013: 6), or, more broadly, the “alteration, refinement, or
conversion of a product’s form or status” (Moreto and Lemieux 2015a: 311) may need to
be performed for the product to successfully move along the trade. Notably, the latter
definition recognizes that the illegal wildlife trade is not simply based on monetary
transactions; it may involve customary or traditional practices and is therefore wider in
definition. Moreover, this definition explicitly highlights how the physical form of a
product can be changed as well as its legal or regulatory status. The reality that some
wildlife products may need to be processed demonstrates how the product also dictates
who needs to be involved in the trade. For example, unique skills are required to
successfully convert raw ivory into decorative items (Vira et al. 2014) and sturgeon roe
into caviar (Saffron 2002).
E. Transporters
Transporters are responsible for transporting the wildlife product to its next destination
in the market chain. Given the variability in both domestic and transnational forms of
wildlife trafficking, transporters can operate within countries and across borders (Wyatt
2013). At times referred to as “mules” (IFAW 2013), transporters can travel using a
variety of transportation modes and use a number of techniques for concealing wildlife
products. For example, transporters have attempted to smuggle wildlife on their persons
and through luggage. Notably, not all transporters may realize that they are participating
in the illegal wildlife trade. For instance, legitimate shipping companies may be
transporting wildlife products unknowingly due to the sheer number of consignments.
Indeed, it has been argued that “transportation is the backbone of global trade, and
traffickers in wild animals and wildlife products rely heavily on logistics, land, air and sea
carriers to smuggle illicit goods” (TRAFFIC 2015).
F. Sellers
Those involved in selling illegal wildlife products vary significantly—from those working
in local markets to well-established, legitimate collectors organizations. For example, an
individual who works in a local market may sell captured live animals in addition to other
goods (Leberatto 2016), while (illegal) caviar may only be sold by trusted sellers to
extravagant restaurants (Saffron 2002).
In addition to physical markets, the expansion and use of the Internet has contributed to
the development of the illegal wildlife trade (Laufer 2010). Despite increased awareness
and vigilance by some online companies, the proliferation of illegal wildlife products
continues on the Internet (e.g., Hastie and McCrea-Steele 2014). Moreover, it is believed
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 15 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
that the existence of the “dark web” provides another avenue for sellers to interact with
would-be buyers (Khan 2013).
G. Organized Crime, Terrorist, and Rebel Groups
The belief that organized crime syndicates are directly involved in the illegal wildlife
trade is fueled by the high profits associated with specific wildlife products (e.g., ivory,
rhino horn) and the ability to utilize established criminal networks and personnel,
smuggling routes, and resources to entice corrupt officials (Zimmerman 2003; Elliot
2012; IFAW 2013). Media accounts further add fodder to the belief that organized crime
syndicates are actively engaged in wildlife trafficking (Morelle 2014). However, the
extent of organized crime groups involvment in the illegal wildlife trade is still up for
debate. While some scholars have noted the existence of organized crime groups in
particular stages (Wyatt 2009) or for specific species (Warchol 2004), others have found
little or no evidence suggesting that organized crime syndicates are involved in the illegal
wildlife trade (Leberratto 2016; Pires et al. 2015). Factoring in what is currently known
about the role of organized crime in the illegal wildlife trade, it is sensible to state that
more research is required, especially from a species- or product-specific perspective (see
Moreto and Lemieux 2015a). Moreover, it is important to note that the level of
organization required for a trade to operate does not equate to the overall trade being
within the stronghold of organized crime groups. While organized crime may be present
at certain stages of the illegal wildlife crime and organized-crime indicators may be
present (see Sellar, 2007), it does not seem to be evident at all stages of the trade.
Finally, anecdotal evidence suggests that terrorist and rebel groups may also be involved
in wildlife trafficking (Neme 2009; WWF 2012). It is believed that such groups hunt,
trade, and smuggle wildlife products to fund their operations (Lawson and Vines 2014).
For example, in 2013, the UN Secretary-General’s report emphasized the potential role
that the Lord’s Resistance Army may have in elephant poaching and the illegal ivory
market.
H. Consumers
The consumers of the illegal wildlife market are quite diverse and include those who seek
wildlife products for cultural medicines and traditions, luxurious clothing, textiles, food
delicacies, and exotic pets. Although much of the literature tends to focus on the
transnational nature of the illegal wildlife trade, it is important to note that local
individuals can also be consumers, and, in some instances, the local underground market
1
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 16 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
may be significant, as is the case for illegal caviar in Russia (see http://assets.panda.org/
downloads/Sturgeon_factsheet.pdf).
V. Supply Markets, Transit Countries, and Demand Markets
Similar to the actors, the supply and demand markets will vary among the different
wildlife products. In general, however, it is believed that both the legal and illegal wildlife
market flow from emerging to developed countries (Reeve 2002; Roe et al. 2002; Duffy
2010; Rosen and Smith 2010; Lawson and Vines 2014). Open-air illicit markets are
typically found in cities large and small throughout biodiverse regions, such as Latin
America, Africa, and Southeast Asia, where an abundance of wildlife is for sale. Locals
and indigenous people, often from impoverished communities, have historically trapped
and traded (or poached and trafficked) wildlife to supply such markets and supplement
their incomes (Leberatto, 2016; Pires et al. 2016; Roe, 2002; TRAFFIC, 2008). From the
demand perspective, the main destination areas are believed to be China, the United
States, and the European Union (Wyatt 2013). However, this will also differ based on the
mode of transaction (e.g., Internet), which further highlights the challenges in
generalizing the illegal market. Lastly, due to their geographical location, lax laws, and
number of available ports of entry, several countries are considered to be transit
countries. For instance, the illegal trade in both ivory and rhino horn have demonstrated
several transit countries within the overall market (Milliken 2014).
VI. Types of Wildlife Trafficking and Commonly Trafficked Wildlife
Wildlife is poached and trafficked for a number of reasons, which include alternative
medicines, accessories or luxury items, bushmeat, and the live pet trade. Poaching and
trafficking wildlife for their supposed medicinal qualities, otherwise known as traditional
Asian medicines (TAM), is one of the largest contributors to the animal parts trade both
in terms of volume and species affected. For example, animal parts, such as tiger bones
and genitals, bear gallbladders, deer fetuses, elephant skins and other parts, antelope
horns, rhino horns, pipehorses, and snakes are trafficked for use in TAMs (Martin-Smith
et al. 2003; Li and Wang 1999). Wild birds, shark fins, bear paws, and dried abalone are
trafficked as a delicacy in Asia and Europe (Shepherd and Shepherd 2010; Forero 2006;
Papp 2008; To et al. 2006). Other animal parts, such as skins (e.g., leopards, crocodiles)
and scales (e.g., pangolins) are used as wearing apparel (Hutton and Webb 2003;
Bräutigam et. al. 1994); while elephant ivory is used to make pendants, necklaces, rings,
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 17 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
and other fashion accessories (Martin and Vigne 2011; Martin and Stiles 2004). Finally,
wild animals, such as parrots, tortoises, and macaques, are traded live as pets (Broad et
al. 2003; van Lavieren 2008) and are sold to private collectors as well as circuses
(Burgener 2002; Speart 1993, as cited in Warchol et al. 2003). The plowshare tortoise, for
example, is the most-sought animal in the world for the live pet trade in part because of
its extreme rarity. One plowshare tortoise can sell upward of US$100,000 (IUCN,
2015a; Finnegan, 2012) as a consequence of so few remaining in the world.
A great variety of species are routinely poached and trafficked, but some much more
often than others. Of the studies that have examined poaching variation among wildlife,
they have all found an unequal distribution of poaching. That is, some species are highly
poached and trafficked while others are not (Petrossian et al. 2016; Petrossian and Clarke
2014; Pires and Clarke 2012; Nijman, 2010; Robbins 2003). The distribution of poached
species appears to resemble the 80-20 rule (Clarke and Eck 2005), in that a small
percentage of the world’s species account for a great majority of total poaching. For
example, only a few groups of wildlife, namely mammals and reptiles, account for the
great share of wildlife seized entering the United States (Petrossian et al. 2016). The
following section will focus on the most commonly poached animals that have garnered
the most attention from conservationists and policymakers either because they have
experienced a rapid population decline or are on the brink of extinction.
A. Rhinos
Once widely abundant and dispersed, rhino populations currently number only in the
thousands and are only found in protected parks in a few Asian and African countries (see
www.savetherhino.org). Five species of rhino remain today, three of which are critically
endangered, and the remaining two are vulnerable and near threatened (IUCN 2015b).
While there are several threats rhinos face, poaching is the most serious among them.
Rhinos are presently one of the most hunted animals on the planet for their rhino horn,
and this is predominantly occurring in South Africa, where the largest population of
rhinos exist (www.savetherhino.org). The main demand markets for rhino horn are China
and Vietnam (Beech and Perry 2011; TRAFFIC 1997; Wilson-Wilde 2010), where people
believe rhino horn can cure a variety of ailments, which recently includes cancer (Moore
2011b; Wilson-Wilde 2010). Evidence, however, casts doubt on whether rhino horn
ameliorates any ailments (Nowell 2012; Moore 2011b). In addition to using horn for TAM,
wealthy individuals in Asia acquire it simply to show status (Mander 2012). Rhino horn is
also used for jambiya dagger handles in Yemen (www.savetherhino.org).
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 18 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Rhino horn cannot be commercially traded in international markets since CITES outlawed
it in 1977. As a result of this and conservation efforts on the ground, the white rhino and
the greater one-horned rhino experienced incredible growth during the following three
decades. Until 2008, rhino poaching was relatively rare in South Africa with an average
of 15 losses per year (Eloff and Lemieux 2014). In 2008, however, poaching escalated to
83 losses and has increased every year since. By 2014, 1,215 rhinos were poached in
South Africa alone (www.savetherhino.org). With diminishing populations and a growing
demand from Vietnam, the price of rhino horn has increased dramatically. Rhino horn
was recently valued at US$35,000–$60,000 per kilo (Eustace 2011; Mander 2012; Moore
2011b), making the average rhino horn (2.5 kilos) (Stoddard 2012) cost between US
$87,500 and $150,000. Rhino horn is now worth more than elephant ivory or any other
animal part in the world.
Given its current price in international markets, there is a tremendous incentive to be
involved in either poaching, trafficking, or selling rhino horn to consumers (Eloff and
Lemieux 2014). According to Jackson (2012), there are four types of poachers:
subsistence, commercial, skilled, and chemical. The least skilled are subsistence
poachers, who are generally poor locals who often use snares and machetes to trap and
kill rhinos (Eloff and Lemieux 2014). Commercial poachers are suspected of being the
most common, and they largely account for the drastic increase in poaching in South
Africa since 2008. They are more likely to use high-powered guns and work in teams of
four to six individuals with military backgrounds. Once the rhino is killed, they can
quickly dispose of the horn to middlemen. Skilled poachers are far more sophisticated
and will often kill rhinos with one shot. They will quickly remove the horn and exit the
area before rangers are aware of the loss. Finally, chemical poachers use tranquilizer
darts to sedate rhinos, which sometimes emanates from a helicopter. While a highly
sophisticated form of removing rhino horn, it is relatively rare compared to commercial
poaching (Jackson 2012; www.stoprhinopoaching.com).
Apart from poaching rhinos, there are other ways that rhino horn is obtained to supply
demand markets in Asia. “The very people responsible for ‘protecting’ rhinos are
sometimes exploiting their professional networks and unrestricted access to the animals
to earn large sums of money” (Eloff and Lemieux 2014: 21). This can take the form of
pseudo-conservation (e.g., mismanaging rhino horn stockpiles) or pseudo-hunting —both
have become increasingly common in South Africa (Ayling 2013; Milliken and Shaw 2012;
Beech and Perry 2011; Eloff and Lemieux 2014). In addition to these two methods,
stealing horns from museums, safari lodges, game reserves, and taxidermies has become
more commonplace (Milliken and Shaw 2012).
A number of initiatives can be implemented to reduce the likelihood of rhino poaching. A
recent study found that rhino poaching is spatially concentrated within Kruger National
2
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 19 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Park in South Africa and that it occurs more often near roads and the Mozambique
border (Eloff and Lemieux 2014). Eloff and Lemieux (2014) suggest a number of
solutions, particularly technologically savvy ones (e.g., remote sensing, gunshot
detectors, unmanned aerial systems or drones) that can alert rangers to where suspicious
activity is occurring in real-time thereby increasing the risk of apprehension of offenders.
On the prevention side, Eloff and Lemieux (2014) recommend controlling access to parks
so that there only a few ways in or out of the park. Authorities can also digitally record
license plate numbers of cars and visitor identification information to deter poachers
from using vehicles. Lastly, routine vehicle searches at park exits can be conducted to
look for rhino horn. In addition to these recommendations, more needs to be done about
reducing demand for rhino horn. Public education campaigns aimed at the Chinese and
Vietnamese people could theoretically reduce demand by alerting them to the extinction
risk of rhinos and the lack of medicinal benefits from rhino horn ingestion.
B. Pangolins
Pangolins, also known as scaly anteaters, are mammals (Nowak and Paradiso 1983) that
play an important ecological role by feeding on ants, termites, and the like. While
pangolins do not receive as much media attention as overexploited photogenic species,
they are among the most poached mammals in the world (Sutter 2014). About 100,000 to
135,000 pangolins per year are needed to meet the demand in China, which is the largest
demand market in the world (Shibao, Guangzhi, and Qianxiang 2005). China has had a
long history of using pangolin for consumption and as a traditional Chinese medicine
(TCM) (Pantel and Chin 2009; Shepherd 2009; Wu et al. 2004). Pangolin scales are
believed to be an important ingredient for treating a variety of ailments (Yue 2009;
Acosta-Lagrada 2008; Phalla 2008; Wang 2008) and are also used to make leather
accessories (Phalla 2008). As a result of this unsustainable demand, pangolins are
commercially extinct in the wild in China (Wu et al. 2004). China’s neighbors have also
been depleted of their pangolin population with the supply currently coming from
Indonesia and Malaysia (Semiadi, Darnaedi, and Arief 2008).
There are eight different species of pangolin worldwide, four located in Southeast Asia
and four located in Africa. The two most commonly traded pangolin species in Asia are
the Manis javanica and Manis pentadactyla, and both species are listed as “critically
endangered” by the IUCN (2015b). The other two Asian species of pangolins—Manis
culionensis and Manis crassicaudata—are considered “endangered.” In Africa, all four
pangolin species, Smutsia temminckii, Phataginus tricuspis, Uromanis tetradactyla, and
Smutsia gigantea, are classified as “vulnerable.” The African species’ decline is attributed
to bushmeat exploitation and the exportation of pangolin meat and scales used for TCM
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 20 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
in Asia (IUCN 2015b). While the African pangolin species are commonly poached, they
may be less endangered than their counterpart Asian species for a number of reasons.
Trafficking pangolins from Africa to China is not easy, especially if they are alive. There is
some difficulty in trafficking live pangolins far distances as they are very hard to keep in
captivity and are easily detected. Live pangolins often die in transit to their destination
market due to disease and unsanitary conditions (Clark, Van Thai, and Phuong 2008).
Additionally, the Chinese demand is generally supplied with pangolins and their
byproducts from neighboring countries because the distance between supply and demand
markets is much closer and thereby easier.
The price increase of pangolins over time is directly related to their declining population
in the wild, making it difficult to disincentivize hunters from poaching. A study conducted
in China revealed that prices are 100 times higher than those in the early 1980s and 20
times higher than in the 1990s (Challender et al. 2015a; Shibao et al. 2005). A kilogram
of pangolin scales will now sell for around US$199 (Guilford 2014). Served as meat, one
pangolin can sell for upward of US$1,000 (Allgood 2013), which can demonstrate a
person’s socioeconomic status.
Pangolins are exceptionally vulnerable to overexploitation because they have a very slow
reproduction rate, do not breed easily in captivity (Lim and Ng 2007; Shepard 2009), and
are easily hunted. Pangolins main defense against predators is to roll up in a ball, which
is highly effective when encroached by a nonhuman predator, but highly ineffective
against humans (Lekagul and McNeely 1977; Pantel and Awang Anak 2010). Once a
hunter finds a pangolin, no real effort or skill is required to capture them. Various
poaching methods are used to capture pangolins and are contingent on the country’s
landscape and the species being hunted, as some species are arboreal and others are
terrestrial. Hunters find pangolins through six common techniques: trained dogs,
tracking strategies, pangolin-specific traps, nonselective traps, spotlights, and
opportunistic encounters (Newton et al. 2008). Opportunistic encounters come in the
form of hunters stumbling upon the opportunity to capture a pangolin while hunting
other animals or cutting down a tree for firewood (Sterling, Hurley and Le 2006).
All Southeast Asian countries already have laws in place that make hunting pangolins
illegal. Additionally, all Asian species are listed under Appendix II of CITES and have a
zero trade quota (Challender et al. 2015b; Kang and Phipps 2003). Antipoaching laws and
international treaties have done little to thwart the trade in pangolins—most species are
in danger of becoming extinct. The incentive to poach and traffic pangolins will be
difficult to eradicate or reduce as the ever increasing price per kilo only further
incentivizes poaching. A number of solutions that target both the demand- and supply-
sides of the equation can theoretically reduce the trade. Reducing demand can come in
the form of public education campaigns in China and other Southeast Asian countries
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 21 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
where demand is the greatest. Also, medicinal alternatives to pangolin scales can be
provided in the form of dry seeds of cowherb, known as Wang Bu Liu Xing, which has the
same effectiveness (Wang 2008). On the supply side, law enforcement can make it more
difficult to poach and traffic pangolins by targeting hot areas (i.e., forests, roads, borders,
ports) where pangolin poaching and trafficking disproportionately occur. One study found
that setting up road stops on a major road used for trafficking pangolins and other
wildlife led to a considerable seizure amount (Lee et al. 2005). Unfortunately, research on
hot spots related to the illicit pangolin trade has been largely ignored, and this is where
future research could aid law enforcement strategies in thwarting the trade.
C. Parrots
Unlike other commonly poached animals, parrots are among the few that are poached
live for the pet trade. Wild parrots are found throughout most regions of the world but
are more typical in areas with warmer climates. While their presence is vast, parrot
poaching disproportionately occurs in Central and South America, otherwise known as
the neotropics. Historically, parrots have been taken from the wild in the neotropics laws
permitting or not. Parrot poaching was largely committed for personal ownership or for
local sale (Cantu et al. 2007). Such practices did not push many species to the brink of
extinction, because it was limited in scope and parrots were far more abundant in prior
decades and centuries. It was not until the 1970s that poaching became an industrialized
enterprise in large part to the demand from the United States and European nations
(Pires and Clarke 2012; Cantu et al. 2007). Once the illegal parrot trade became a global
phenomenon, coupled with deforestation, parrot populations began to rapidly decline for
a great many species (Clarke and Rolf 2013; Juniper and Parr 1998; Howell and Webb
1995), making parrots one of the most-endangered group of birds on the planet (Cockle
et al. 2007; Pain et al. 2006; Wright et al. 2001).
By the end of the 20th century, CITES banned the trade of most parrot species and the
United States banned the importation of wild parrots (Armstrong et al. 2001). Ostensibly,
this resulted in a large decline in the illegal parrot trade at the international level
(Cooney and Jepson 2006; Wright et al. 2001). Recent studies, however, have shown that
the domestic trade in parrots is a far greater problem than the international trade. A
Mexican report based on interviews with trappers (Cantu et al. 2007) found upward of
78,500 parrots were being poached annually and the vast majority were for domestic
demand. Three separate market surveys in Bolivia (Herrera and Hennessey 2007), in
Peru (Gastanaga et al. 2011), and in Brazil (Regueira and Bernard 2012) found similar
results in terms of the volume and the domestic nature of the trade. Such evidence
suggests that demand for pet ownership of parrots within neotropical countries is very
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 22 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
high (Weston and Memon 2009; Cantu et al. 2007; Gonzalez 2003), and current poaching
levels are unsustainable for the great majority of species in these countries (Gastanaga et
al. 2011; Pires 2012; Cantu et al. 2007).
While a majority of species are affected by the illegal parrot trade, some are more
affected than others. Recent criminological research has applied the theft variation
model, CRAVED (Clarke 1999), to understand why poaching variation exists among the
more than 330 parrot species in the world. The conventional wisdom in the field of
conservation was that parrot species that are disproportionately poached would be the
most attractive, valuable, and/or rare. Such thinking insinuates that poachers will target
a particular type of species based on profitability and/or their perception of consumer
demand (Pires and Clarke 2012). While offenders might seek such species in the wild,
they may not be as available or accessible as other species (Pires 2012). In fact, several
criminological studies have found this to be the case. Species that are less valuable, less
rare, and that are average appearing in terms of “attractiveness” are the ones that are
poached and trafficked most frequently (Pires 2015a; Pires and Petrossian 2016; Pires
and Clarke 2012, 2011). Factors of opportunity actually explain poaching variation the
best. That is, species that are closer to illicit markets, have larger ranges, are more
abundant, nest closer to the ground, and are more concealable are significantly related to
higher poaching counts in several countries (Pires 2015a, 2015b; Pires and Petrossian
2016; Pires and Clarke 2012, 2011). However, one study has found that the more
attractive species in Mexico were poached more often even while controlling for
opportunistic factors (Tella and Hiraldo 2014).
More recent criminological research has been able to map where and when poaching is
occurring in Bolivia. Pires et al. (2015b) found that parrot poaching is highly
concentrated in space, in time, on particular species, and on particular methods of
obtaining them. Just seven municipalities, or 11 percent of the total area in a department
of Bolivia (the political equivalent of a US state), accounted for over 80 percent of
poaching. Further, about 50 percent of poaching occurred in a three-month window
during the summer. Overall, the implications of such findings are to allocate conservation
and law enforcement resources to particular areas, at particular times, and protect the
most-endangered species along with the most poached ones. In doing so, the largest
reduction in the illegal parrot trade can be achieved while using limited resources more
prudently.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 23 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
VII. Implications for Future Research
As this systematic review of the literature has shown, the illegal wildlife trade varies
greatly in nature and in scope. There are some common patterns among species in the
trade in relation to methods used, actors involved, demand and supply countries, and
purposes of the trade; but the trade also operates uniquely for each species.
Acknowledging that the trade operates in slightly different ways for each species is
important to consider as it relates to interventions to reduce the trade. Policymakers
cannot simply reduce the trade in all species using the same tool. What works with one
species may not work with another because there are numerous contextual factors
involved. Policymakers need to use a myriad of tools that are tailored toward a specific
species and the larger problem at hand.
Most research on the topic emanates from the conservation sciences as they regularly
obtain grants, conduct field research, and, even at times, implement solutions to reduce
wildlife crime. Evaluations of such interventions are lacking and need to be conducted on
a frequent basis going forward so that both the academic and policy communities can
learn what works with respect to how, why, and with which species. Criminologists and
criminal justice scholars have a role to play in these evaluations since they are best suited
to understand why crime occurs and how it may be prevented through a number of ways.
Hopefully, interdisciplinary collaborations, such as those between conservationists and
criminologists, can foster a better understanding of how to mitigate the illegal wildlife
trade and conserve at-risk species.
References
Abensperg-Traun, M. (2009). CITES, sustainable use of wild species and incentive-driven
conservation in developing countries, with an emphasis on southern Africa. Biol. Conserv.
142, 948–963.
Acosta-Lagrada, L. (2008). Conservation and management of the Malayan pangolin in
Palawan Providence, Philippines. TRAFFIC Southeast Asia. Proceedings of the workshop
on trade and conservation of pangolins Native to South and Southeast Africa, 29–39.
Agnew, D., Pearce, J., Peatman, T., Pitcher, T. J., and Pramod, G. (2008). The global
extent of illegal fishing. Fisheries Ecosystems Restoration Research Fisheries Centre,
University of British Colombia and Marine Resources Assessment Group, Vancouver and
London.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 24 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Ahmed, A. (2010). Imperiled custodians of the night: A study on the illegal trade, trapping
and use of owls in India. TRAFFIC India. .
Allgood, B. (2013, June 6). Criminal nature—the dangerous links between poaching and
organized crime. International Fund for Animal Welfare. Retrieved Oct 1, 2015, .
Andresen, M. A. (2014). Environmental criminology: Evolution, theory, and practice. New
York: Routledge.
Armstrong, M. C., Farinato, R. H., and Telecky, T. M. (2001). A wing and a prayer: Birds
and their protection under law. Journal of Avian Medicine and Surgery, 15(4), 310–315.
Ayling, J. (2013). What sustains wildlife crime? Rhino horn trading and the resilience of
criminal networks. Journal of International Wildlife Law and Policy, 16(1), 57–80.
Barnosky, A. D., Matzke, N., Tomiya, S., Wogan, G. O., Swartz, B., Quental, T. B., and
Mersey, B. (2011). Has the Earth/’s sixth mass extinction already arrived?. Nature,
471(7336), 51–57.
Beech, H., and Perry, A. (2011). Killing fields: How Asia’s growing appetite for traditional
medicine is threatening Africa’s rhinos. Time, 177 (24), 40–47.
Beirne, P. (1999). For a Nonspeciesist Criminology: Animal Abuse as an Object of Study.
Criminology, 37: 117–148.
Bell, S., Hampshire, K. and Topalidou, S. (2007). The political culture of poaching: A case
study from northern Greece. Biodiversity and Conservation, 16: 399–418.
Bowman, M. (2013). A tale of two CITES: Divergent perspectives upon the effectiveness
of the wildlife trade convention. Review of European, Comparative and International
Environmental Law, 22(3), 228–238.
Bräutigam A., Howes, J., Humphreys, T., Hutton, J. (1994). Recent Information on the
Status and Utilization of African Pangolins. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 15(1), 15–22.
Briggs, D., Courchamp, F., Martin, R., Possingham, H. P. (2013). Legal trade of Africa’s
rhino horns. Science, 339, 1038–1039.
Brisman, A. (2015). “Multicolored” green criminology and climate change’s
achromatopsia. Contemporary Justice Review, 18, 178–196.
Brisman, A. and South, N. (2013). A green-cultural criminology: An exploratory outline.
Crime Media Culture: An International Journal, 9, 115–135.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 25 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Broad, S., Mulliken, T., Roe, D. (2003). The nature and extent of legal and illegal trade in
wildlife. In The trade in wildlife regulation for conservation, ed. S. Oldfield, 3–22. London:
Earthscan.
Burgener, M. (2002). The Law and Policy Working Group. Endangered Wildlife, 39, 69.
Butchart, S., et al. (2010). Global biodiversity: Indicators of recent declines. Science 328,
1164–1168.
Cantu, J. C. G., Saldana, M. E. S., Grosselet, M., and Gamez, J. S. (2007). The illegal
parrot trade in Mexico: A comprehensive assessment. Mexico and Washington, DC:
Defenders of Wildlife.
Ceballos, G., Ehrlich, P. R., Barnosky, A. D., García, A., Pringle, R. M., and Palmer, T. M.
(2015). Accelerated modern human–induced species losses: Entering the sixth mass
extinction. Science Advances, 1(5), e1400253.
Challender, D. W., Harrop, S. R., and MacMillan, D. C. (2015a). Understanding markets
to conserve trade-threatened species in CITES. Biological Conservation, 187, 249–259.
Challender, D. W., Harrop, S. R., and MacMillan, D. C. (2015b). Towards informed and
multi-faceted wildlife trade interventions. Global Ecology and Conservation, 3, 129–148.
CITES (2015a). The CITES Appendices. Retrieved Dec. 1, 2015, .
CITES (2015b). How CITES works. Retrieved Dec. 1, 2015, .
CITES (2015c). The CITES species. Retrieved Dec. 1, 2015, .
Clark, L., Van Thai, N., and Phuong, T. Q. (2008). A long way from home: The health
status of Asian pangolins confiscated from the illegal wildlife trade in Vietnam. TRAFFIC
Southeast Asia. Proceedings of the workshop on trade and conservation of pangolins
native to South and Southeast Africa, 111–118.
Clarke, R. V. (1980). “Situational” crime prevention: Theory and practice. British Journal
of Criminology, 20, 136–147.
Clarke, R. V., ed. (1997). Situational crime prevention: Successful case studies, 2nd ed.
Monsey, NY: Criminal Justice Press.
Clarke, R. V. (1999). Hot products: Understanding, anticipating and reducing demand for
stolen goods. Police Research Series, Paper 112: Home Office.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 26 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Clarke, R. V. (2004). Technology, criminology, and crime science. European Journal of
Criminal Policy and Research 10, 55–63.
Clarke, R. V. (2009). Situational crime prevention: Theoretical background and current
practice. In Handbook on Crime and Deviance ed. M. D. Krohn, A. J. Lizotte. and G. P.
Hall, 259–276. New York: Springer.
Clarke, R. V., and Rolf, A. (2013). Poaching, habitat loss and the decline of neotropical
parrots: A comparative spatial analysis. Journal of Experimental Criminology, 9(3), 333–
353.
Cockle, K., Capuzzi, G., Bodrati, A., Clay, R., Del Castillo, H., Velázquez, M., … and
Farina, R. (2007). Distribution, abundance, and conservation of Vinaceous Amazons
(Amazona vinacea) in Argentina and Paraguay. Journal of Field Ornithology, 78(1), 21–39.
Cohen, L. E., & Felson, M. (1979). Social change and crime rate trends: a routine activity
approach. American Sociological Review, 44(4), 588–608.
Cole, R. (2012). The effect of international trade bans on the population of endangered
species. Penn State Journal of International Affairs, 2(1), 35–53.
Conrad, K. (2012). Trade bans: A perfect storm for poaching. Tropical Conservation
Science, 5(3), 245–254.
Cooney, R., and Jepson, P. (2006). The international wild bird trade: What’s wrong with
blanket bans?. Oryx, 40(1), 18–23.
Cornish, D. B. (1994). The procedural analysis of offending and its relevance for
situational prevention. In Crime prevention studies, vol. 3, ed. R. V. Clarke, 151–196.
Monsey, NY: Criminal Justice Press.
Cornish, D., and Clarke, R. (1986). The reasoning criminal. New York: Springer.
Courchamp, F., Angulo, E., Rivalan, P., Hall, R. J., Signoret, L., Bull, L., and Meinard, Y.
(2006). Rarity value and species extinction: the anthropogenic allee effect. Plos One:
Biology, 4(12), e415.
Couzens, E. (2013). CITES at forty: Never too late to make lifestyle changes. Review of
European, Comparative and International Environmental Law, 22(3), 311–323.
Daut, E. F., Brightsmith, D. J., Mendoza, A. P., Puhakka, L., and Peterson, M. J. (2015).
Illegal domestic bird trade and the role of export quotas in Peru. Journal for Nature
Conservation, 27, 44–53.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 27 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Dickson, B. (2003). What is the goal of regulating wildlife trade? Is regulation a good way
to achieve this goal? In The trade in wildlife regulation for conservation, ed. S. Oldfield,
23–32. London: Earthscan.
Duffy, R. (2010). Nature crime: How we’re getting conservation wrong. New Haven, CT:
Yale University Press.
du Plessis, M. A. (2000). CITES and the causes of extinction. In Endangered species
threatened convention: The past, present and future of CITES, ed. J. Hutton, B. Dickson,
13–25. London: Earthscan.
Clarke, R. V., and Eck, J. E. (2005). Crime analysis for problem solvers. Washington, DC:
Center for Problem Oriented Policing.
Eliason, S. L. (1999). The illegal taking of wildlife: Toward a theoretical understanding of
poaching. Human Dimensions of Wildlife, 4, 27–39.
Eliason, S. L. (2003). Throwing the book versus cutting some slack: Factors influencing
the use of discretion by game wardens in Kentucky. Deviant Behavior, 24, 129–152.
Eliason, S. L. (2006). Factors influencing job satisfaction among state conservation
officers. Policing: An International Journal of Police Strategies and Management, 29, 6–
18.
Eliason, S. L. (2008). Wildlife crime: Conservation officers’ perceptions of elusive
poachers. Deviant Behavior, 29: 111–128.
Eliason, S. L. (2012). Trophy poaching: A routine activities perspective. Deviant Behavior,
33, 72–87.
Eliason, S. L. and Dodder, R. A. (1999). Techniques of neutralization used by deer
poachers in the western U.S.: A research note. Deviant Behavior, 20, 233–252.
Elliot, L. (2012). Fighting transnational environmental crime. Journal of International
Affairs, 66: 87–104.
Eloff, C. and Lemieux, A. M. (2014). Rhino poaching in Kruger National Park, South
Africa. In Situational Prevention of Poaching, ed. A. M. Lemieux, 18–43. New York, New
York: Routledge.
Environmental Resources Management (ERM) (1996). Study on how to improve the
effectiveness of CITES. Final Report to the Standing Committee of CITES, Lausanne.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 28 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Eustace, M. (2011). Current supply and demand in the rhino horn market—A model for
regulating the rhino horn trade (rewards to trade). In Perspectives on Dehorning and
Legalized Trade in Rhino Horn as Tools to Combat Rhino Poaching, ed. B. G. A. Daly, et
al. Proceedings of a workshop assessing legal trade in rhino horn as a tool in combating
poaching as well as a detailed assessment of the efficacy of dehorning as a deterrent to
poaching, 10. Johannesburg, South Africa: Endangered Wildlife Trust.
Felson, M., and Poulsen, E. (2003). Simple indicators of crime by time of day.
International Journal of Forecasting, 19(4), 595–601.
Fiadjoe, Y. (2004). Cities in Africa: An examination of domestic implementation and
compliance. Sustainable Development and Policy, 4, 38–46.
Finnegan, W. (2012, Jan 23). Slow and steady: A Manhattan night-life baron’s race to
save an ancient species. The New Yorker.
Franke, J., and Telecky, T. M. (2001). Reptiles as pets: An examination of the trade in live
reptiles in the United States. Humane Society of the United States.
Frisina, M. R., and Tareen, S. N. A. (2009). Exploitation prevents extinction: Case study of
endangered Himalayan sheep and goats. Recreational Hunting, Conservation and Rural
Livelihoods: Science and Practice, 141–156.
Forero, J. (2006, Jan 5). Hidden Cost of Shark Fin Soup: Its Source May Vanish. The New
York Times, International. Retrieved from: .
Forsyth, C. J. (1993). Chasing and catching “bad guys”: The game warden’s prey. Deviant
Behavior, 14, 209–226.
Forsyth, C. J., Gramling, R. and Wooddell, G. (1998). The game of poaching: Folk crimes
in Southwest Louisiana. Society and Natural Resources, 11, 25–38.
Fuchs, C. (2010). Convention in international trade in endangered species of wild and
flora (CITES)—conservation efforts undermine the legality principle. In: von Bogdandy,
A., et al. (Eds.), The Exercise of Public Authority by International Institutions. In: Beiträge
zum Auslandischen Öffentlichen Recht und Völkerrecht, vol. 210.
Gastanaga, M., MacLeod, R., Hennessey, B., Nunez, J. U., Puse, E., Arrascue, A., and
Engblom, G. (2011). A study of the parrot trade in Peru and the potential importance of
internal trade for threatened species. Bird Conservation International, 21(1), 76–85.
Geist, H. J., and Lambin, E. F. (2002). Proximate causes and underlying driving forces of
tropical deforestation tropical forests are disappearing as the result of many pressures,
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 29 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
both local and regional, acting in various combinations in different geographical
locations. BioScience, 52(2), 143–150.
Gibbs, C., Gore, M. L., McGarrell, E. D., and Rivers, L, III. (2010). Introducing
conservation criminology: Towards interdisciplinary scholarship on environmental crimes
and risks. The British Journal of Criminology, 50, 124–144.
Gonzalez, J. A. (2003). Harvesting, local trade, and conservation of parrots in the
Northeastern Peruvian Amazon. Biological Conservation, 114(3), 437–446.
Gore, M. L. (2011). The science of conservation crimes. Conservation Biology, 25, 659–
661.
Guilford, G. (2014, Jan 27). Demand for traditional Chinese medicine is killing off the
world’s quirkiest animal. Quartz. .
Hall, R. J., Milner‐Gulland, E. J., and Courchamp, F. (2008). Endangering the endangered:
The effects of perceived rarity on species exploitation. Conservation Letters, 1(2), 75–81.
Halsey, M. (2004). Against “green” criminology. The British Journal of Criminology, 44,
833–853.
Haken, J. (2011). Transnational crime in the developing world. Global Financial Integrity.
Han, C. (2014). A survey of customs administration perceptions on illegal wildlife trade.
WCO Research Paper, No. 34.
Hastie, J. and McCrea-Steele, T. (2014). Wanted—dead or alive: Exposing online wildlife
trade. London: IFAW.
Herbig, F. J. W. (2011). South African conservation crime and routine activities theory: A
causal nexus. Inaugural lecture, July 20. University of South Africa, Pretoria.
Herbig, F. J. W. (2014). The phronesis of conservation criminology phraseology: a
genealogical and dialectical narrative. Phronimon, 15(2), 1–17.
Herrera, M., and Hennessey, B. (2007). Quantifying the illegal parrot trade in Santa Cruz
de la Sierra, Bolivia, with emphasis on threatened species. Bird Conservation
International, 17(4), 295–300.
Howell, S. N., and Webb, S. (1995). A guide to the birds of Mexico and northern Central
America. Oxford University Press.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 30 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Hutton, J., and Webb, G. (2003). Crocodiles: Legal trade snaps back. The Trade in
Wildlife: Regulation For Conservation, 108, 114.
Huxley, C. (2000). CITES: The vision. In Endangered species, threatened convention: The
past, present and future of CITES, ed., J. Hutton and B. Dickson, 3–12. London:
Earthscan.
IFAW. (2013). Criminal nature: The global security implications of the illegal wildlife
trade. Washington, DC: IFAW.
Interpol (2015). Wildlife crime. Retrieved Dec 1, 2015, .
IUCN (2015a). Assessment of the Astrochelys Yniphora. Retrieved Dec 2, 2015, .
IUCN (2015b). IUCN red list of threatened species. Retrieved Dec 2, 2015, .
Jachmann, H. (2003). Elephant poaching and resource allocation for law enforcement. In
The trade in wildlife regulation for conservation, ed. S. Oldfield, 100–107. London:
Earthscan.
Jackson, T. (2012). The crisis. Africa Geographic, 20 (3), 30–36.
Jacobson, S. K., and Duff, M. D. (1998). Training idiot savants: The lack of human
dimensions in conservation biology. Conservation Biology, 12, 263–267.
Juniper, T., and Parr, M. (1998). Parrots: A guide to the parrots of the world. Pica, Sussex.
Kang, S., and Phipps, M. J. (2003). A question of attitude: South Korea’s traditional
medicine practitioners and wildlife conservation. TRAFFIC East Asia.
Kahler, J. S. and Gore, M. L. (2012). Beyond the cooking pot and pocket book: Factors
influencing noncompliance with wildlife poaching rules. International Journal of
Comparative and Applied Criminal Justice, 36, 103–120.
Kahler, J. S., Roloff, G. J. and Gore, M. L. (2013). Poaching risks in community-based
natural resource management. Conservation Biology, 27, 177–186.
Khan, D. (2013, May 28). Slipping through the net: The illegal online wildlife trade.
Retrieved Dec 22, .
Kievit, H. (2000). Conservation of the Niles crocodile: Has CITES helped or hindered? In
Endangered species threatened convention: The past, present and future of CITES, ed. J.
Hutton, B. Dickson, 88–97. London: Earthscan.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 31 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Larriera, A., Siroski, P., and Imhof, A. (2010). Crocodilians ranching program in
Argentina: Twenty years of success. Crocodiles: Proceedings of the 20th Working
Meeting of the Crocodile Specialist Group. IUCN, Gland, Switzerland, and Cambridge,
UK, 73–76.
Laufer, P. (2010). Forbidden creatures: Inside the world of animal smuggling and exotic
pets. Guildford, CT: Lyons Press.
Lavorgna, A. (2014). Wildlife trafficking in the internet age. Crime Science, 3, 5.
Lawson, K., and Vines, A. (2014). Global impacts of the illegal wildlife trade: The costs of
crime, insecurity, and institutional erosion. London: The Royal Institute of International
Affairs.
Laycock, G. (2005). Defining crime science. In Crime Science: New approaches to
preventing and detecting crime, ed. M. J. Smith and N. Tilley, 3–34. Portland, OR: Willan.
Leader-Williams, N. (2003). Regulation and protection: successes and failures in
rhinoceros conservation. In The trade in wildlife regulation for conservation, ed. S.
Oldfield, 89–99. London: Earthscan.
Leberatto, A. C. (2016). Understanding the illegal trade in live wildlife species in Peru.
Trends in Organized Crime. doi: 10.1007/s12117-015-9262-z.
Lee, R. J., Gorog, A. J., Dwiyahreni, A., Siwu, S., Riley, J., Alexander, H., and Ramono, W.
(2005). Wildlife trade and implications for law enforcement in Indonesia: A case study
from North Sulawesi. Biological Conservation, 123(4), 477–488.
Lekagul, B., and McNeely, J. A. (1977). Mammals of Thailand. Mammals of Thailand.
Lemieux, A. M. ed. (2014). Situational Prevention of Poaching. New York: Routledge.
Lemieux, A. M., and Clarke, R. V. (2009). The international ban on ivory sales and its
effects on elephant poaching in Africa. British Journal of Criminology, 49(4), 451–471.
Li, W. and Wang, H. (1999). Wildlife Trade in Yunnan Province, China, at the Border with
Vietnam. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 18(1), 21–30.
Lichtenstein, G. (2009). Vicuña conservation and poverty alleviation? Andean
communities and international fibre markets. International Journal of the Commons, 4(1),
100–121.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 32 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Lim, N. T., and Ng, P. K. (2007). Home range, activity cycle and natal den usage of a
female Sunda pangolin Manis javanica (Mammalia: Pholidota) in Singapore. Endangered
Species Research, 3, 1–8.
Lynch, M. J., Long, M. bA., Barrett, K. L and Stretesky, P. B. (2013). Is it a crime to
produce ecological disorganization? Why green criminology and political economy matter
in the analysis of global ecological harms. The British Journal of Criminology 55, 997–
1016.
Lynch, M. J. and Stretesky, P. B. (2003). The meaning of green: Constrasting
criminological perspectives. Theoretical Criminology, 7, 217–238.
Lynch, M. J. and Stretsky, P. B. (2014). Exploring green criminology: Toward a green
criminological revolution. Burlington: Ashgate.
McAllister, R. R., McNeill, D., and Gordon, I. J. (2009). Legalizing markets and the
consequences for poaching of wildlife species: The vicuña as a case study. Journal of
Environmental Management, 90(1), 120–130.
McClellan, K., Charles, A., and Wilson, L. (2008). Coral degradation through destructive
fishing practices. The Encyclopedia of Earth. .
McMullan, J. L. and Perrier, D. C. (2002). Lobster poaching and the ironies of law
enforcement. Law and Society Review, 36: 679–718.
MacMillan, D. C., and Han, J. (2011). Cetacean by-catch in the Korean Peninsula—by
chance or by design?. Human Ecology, 39(6), 757–768.
Mander, D. (2012). Damned if you do and damned if you don’t—legalizing the rhino horn
trade: My journey to Vietnam. Victoria: Australia: International Anti-Poaching
Foundation.
Martin, R. B., 2000. When CITES works and when it does not. In Endangered species
threatened convention: The past, present and future of CITES, ed. J. Hutton and B.
Dickson, 29–37. London: Earthscan.
Martin, E. and Vigne, L. (2011). Illegal Ivory Sales in Egypt. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 23(1), 17–
122.
Martin, E. and Stiles, D. (2004). The Ivory Markets of East Asia. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 20(1),
9–12.
M. E. A. (2005). Ecosystems and human well-being scenarios: Findings of the Scenarios
Working Group. vol. 2. Washington: Island Press.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 33 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Milliken, T. (2014). Illegal trade in ivory and rhino horn: An assessment to improve law
enforcement under the wildlife traps project. USAID and TRAFFIC.
Milliken, T., and Shaw, J. (2012). The South Africa-Viet Nam rhino horn trade nexus: A
deadly combination of institutional lapses, corrupt wildlife industry professionals, and
Asian crime syndicates. TRAFFIC.
Mitchell, R. B. (2003). International environmental agreements: A survey of their
features, formation, and effects. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 28(1),
429–461.
Martin-Smith, K., Lam, T., and Lee, S. (2003). Trade in Pipehorses solegnathus spp. for
Traditional Medicine in Hong Kong. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 19(3), 139–148.
Moore, A. (2011b). “Drivers of the trade in rhino horn.” In Perspectives on dehorning and
legalized trade in rhino horn as tools to combat rhino poaching, ed. B. G. Daly, et al.
Proceedings of a workshop assessing legal trade in rhino horn as a tool in combating
poaching as well as a detailed assessment of the efficacy of dehorning as a deterrent to
poaching, 8. Johannesburg, South Africa: Endangered Wildlife Trust.
Moore, L. (2011a). The neoliberal elephant: Exploring the impacts of the trade ban in
ivory on the commodification and neoliberalisation of elephants. Geoforum, 42(1), 51–60.
Morelle, B. (2014, Feb 12). Organised crime sets sights on wildlife. BBC World Service.
Retrieved Apr 12, 2015, .
Moreto, W. D. (2015). Introducing intelligence-led conservation: bridging crime and
conservation science. Crime Science, 4, 15. doi: 10.1186/s40163-015-0030-9.
Moreto, W. D., Brunson, R. K., & Braga, A. A. (2015). “Such misconducts don’t make a
good ranger”: Examining law enforcement ranger wrongdoing in Uganda. British Journal
of Criminology, 55(2), 359–380.
Moreto, W. D., Brunson, R. K., & Braga, A. A. (Forthcoming). “Anything we do, we have to
include the communities”: Law enforcement rangers’ attitudes towards and experiences
of community-ranger relations in wildlife protected areas in Uganda. British Journal of
Criminology. doi: 10.1093/bjc/azw032.
Moreto, W. D., and Clarke, R. V. (2013). Script analysis of the transnational illegal market
in endangered species: Dream and reality. In Cognition and crime: Offender decision-
making and script analysis, ed. B. Lecrec and R. Wortley, 209–220. London: Routledge.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 34 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Moreto, W. D., and Lemieux, A. M. (2015a). From CRAVED to CAPTURED: Introducing a
product-based framework to examine illegal wildlife markets. European Journal on
Criminal Policy and Research, 21, 303–320.
Moreto, W. D., and Lemieux, A. M. (2015b). Poaching in Uganda: Perspectives of law
enforcement rangers. Deviant Behavior, 36, 853–873.
Moyle, B. (2003). Regulation, conservation, and incentives. In The trade in wildlife
regulation for conservation, ed. S. Oldfield, 41–51. London: Earthscan.
Muth, R. M. and Bowe, J. F., Jr. (1998). Illegal harvest of renewable natural resources in
North America: Toward a typology of the motivations for poaching. Society and Natural
Resources: An International Journal, 11, 9–24.
Neme, L. A. (2009). Animal investigators. New York: Scribner.
Newton, P., Van Thai, N., Roberton, S., and Bell, D. (2008). Pangolins in peril: Using local
hunters’ knowledge to conserve elusive species in Vietnam. Endangered Species
Research, 6(1), 41–53.
Ngoc, A. C. and Wyatt, T. (2013). A green criminological exploration of illegal wildlife
trade in Vietnam. Asian Journal of Criminology, 8, 129–142.
Nijman, V. (2010). An overview of international wildlife trade from Southeast Asia.
Biodiversity and Conservation, 19(4), 1101–1114.
Nowak, R. M., and Paradiso, J. L. (1983). Walker’s mammals of the world. Vol. 2.
Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Nowell, K. (2012). Assessment of rhino horn as a traditional medicine. TRAFFIC report to
CITES Secretariat pursuant to contract CITES Project No. S-389, Geneva, Switzerland.
Omondi, P., Bitok, E., and Kagiri, J. (2004). Managing human-elephant conflicts: The
Kenyan experience. Pachyderm, 36, 80–86.
Pain, D. J., Martins, T. L. F., Boussekey, M., Diaz, S. H., Downs, C. T., Ekstrom, J. M. M.,
… and Rouys, S. (2006). Impact of protection on nest take and nesting success of parrots
in Africa, Asia and Australasia. Animal Conservation, 9(3), 322–330.
Pantel, S. and Anak, N. A. (2010). A preliminary assessment of sunda pangolin trade in
Sudah. TRAFFIC Southeast Asia Report.
Pantel, S. and Chin, S. Y. (2009). Proceedings of the workshop on trade and conservation
of pangolins native to South and Southeast Asia. TRAFFIC Southeast Asia, Petaling Jaya.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 35 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Papp, D. (2008). The illegal trade in Wild Birds from South-East and Central Europe for
Food in the EU. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 22(1), 10–12.
Parsons, E. C. M., Rose, N. A., and Telecky, T. M. (2010). The trade in live Indo-Pacific
bottlenose dolphins from Solomon Islands—A CITES decision implementation case study.
Marine Policy, 34(3), 384–388.
Patten, R. (2010). Policing in the wild: The game wardens’ perspective. Policing: An
International Journal of Police Strategies and Management, 33, 132–151.
Petrossian, G. A. (2015). Preventing illegal, unreported and unregulated (IUU) fishing: A
situational approach. Biological Conservation, 189, 39–48.
Petrossian, G. A., and Clarke, R. V. (2014). Explaining and controlling illegal commercial
fishing an application of the CRAVED theft model. British Journal of Criminology, 54(1),
73–90.
Petrossian, G., Pires, S. F., and van Uhm, D. P. (2016). An overview of seized illegal
wildlife entering the United States. Global Crime, online first, doi:
10.1080/17440572.2016.1152548.
Phalla, S. (2008). Conservation and management of pangolins in Cambodia. TRAFFIC
Southeast Asia. Proceedings of the workshop on trade and conservation of pangolins
native to South and Southeast Africa, 44–48.
Phelps, J., Webb, E. L., Bickford, D., Nijman, V., and Sodhi, N. S. (2010). Boosting CITES.
Science, 330(6012), 1752–1753.
Pimm, S. L., and Raven, P. (2000). Biodiversity: Extinction by numbers. Nature,
403(6772), 843–845.
Pires, S. F. (2012). The illegal parrot trade: A literature review. Global Crime, 13(3), 176–
190.
Pires, S. F. (2015a). A CRAVED analysis of multiple illicit parrot markets in Peru and
Bolivia. European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research, 21(3), 321–336.
Pires, S. F. (2015b). The heterogeneity of illicit parrot markets: An analysis of seven neo-
tropical open-air markets. European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research, 21(1), 151–
166.
Pires, S. F., and Clarke, R. V. (2011). Sequential foraging, itinerant fences and parrot
poaching in Bolivia. British Journal of Criminology, 51(2), 314–335.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 36 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Pires, S., and Clarke, R. V. (2012). Are parrots CRAVED? An analysis of parrot poaching
in Mexico. Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency, 49(1), 122–146.
Pires, S. F., and Moreto, W. D. (2011). Preventing wildlife crimes: Solutions that can
overcome the “Tragedy of the Commons.” European Journal on Criminal Policy and
Research, 17(2), 101–123.
Pires, S. F., & Petrossian, G. A. (2016). Understanding parrot trafficking between illicit
markets in Bolivia: an application of the CRAVED model. International Journal of
Comparative and Applied Criminal Justice, 40(1), 63–77.
Pires, S. F., Schneider, J. L. and Herrera, M. (2016). Organized crime or crime that is
organized? The parrot trade in the neotropics. Trends in Organized Crime, 19(1), 4–20.
Pires, S. F., Schneider J., M. Herrera, and J. Tella. (2015). Spatial, temporal and age
sources of variation in parrot poaching in Bolivia. Bird Conservation International, 1–14.
Project Tiger. (2005). The report of the Tiger Task Force: Joining the dots. New Delhi:
Union Ministry of Environment and Forests.
Raymakers, C. (2002). Study on the social and economic aspects of illegal fishing in the
Caspian Sea. TRAFFIC Europe: WWF.
Reeve, R. (2002). Policing International Trade in Endangered Species: The CITES Treaty
and Compliance. London: Earthscan Ltd.
Regueira, R. F. S., and Bernard, E. (2012). Wildlife sinks: Quantifying the impact of illegal
bird trade in street markets in Brazil. Biological Conservation, 149(1), 16–22.
Robbins, C. S. (2003). Prickly trade: Trade and conservation of Chihuahuan desert cacti.
TRAFFIC North America: WWF.
Roe, D. (2002). Making a killing or making a living: Wildlife trade, trade controls, and
rural livelihoods (No. 6). IIED.
Roe, D. (2008). Trading nature: A report, with case studies, on the contribution of wildlife
trade management to sustainable livelihoods and the Millennium Development Goals.
TRAFFIC international.
Roe, D., Mulliken, T., Milledge, S., Mremi, J., Mosha, S., and Grieg-Gran, M. (2002).
Making a killing or making a living: Wildlife trade, trade controls and rural livelihoods.
London: IIED, and Cambridge: TRAFFIC.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 37 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Rosen, G. E., and Smith, K. F. (2010). Summarizing the evidence on the international
trade in illegal wildlife. EcoHealth, 7(1), 24–32.
Rosser, A. M., and Mainka, S. A. (2002). Overexploitation and species extinctions.
Conservation Biology, 16(3), 584–586.
Saffron, I. (2002). Caviar: The strange history and uncertain future of the world’s most
coveted delicacy. New York: Broadway Books.
Schneider, J. L. (2008). Reducing the illicit trade in endangered wildlife: The market
reduction approach. Journal of Contemporary Criminal Justice, 24, 274–295.
Schneider, J. L. (2012). Sold into extinction: The global trade in endangered species. ABC-
CLIO.
Sellar, J. M. (2007). International illicit trafficking in wildlife. The Police Chief, 74(6), 26–
32.
Semiadi, G., Darnaedi, D., and Arief, A. J. (2008). Sunda pangolin manis javanica
conservation in Indonesia: Status and problem. TRAFFIC Southeast Asia. Proceedings of
the workshop on trade and conservation of pangolins native to South and Southeast
Africa, 12–17.
Shelley, T. O., and Crow, M. S. (2009). The nature and extent of conservation policing:
Law enforcement generalists or conservation specialists. American Journal of Criminal
Justice, 34, 9–27.
Shepherd, C. R. (2009). Overview of pangolin trade in Southeast Asia. TRAFFIC
Southeast Asia. Proceedings of the workshop on trade and conservation of pangolins
native to South and Southeast Africa, 6–9.
Shepherd, C. R., & Magnus, N. (2004). Nowhere to hide: the trade in Sumatran Tiger.
TRAFFIC.
Shepherd, C. R., & Shepherd, L. A. (2010). The poaching and trade of Malayan un Bears
in Peninsular Malaysia. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 23(1), 49–52.
Sherman, L. W., Gartin, P. R., and Buerger, M. E. (1989). Hot spots of predatory crime:
Routine activities and the criminology of place*. Criminology, 27(1), 27–56.
Shibao, W., Guangzhi, M., and Qianxiang, L. (2005). Research on the conservation biology
of Chinese pangolin Manis pentadactyla. Beijing: China Forestry Publishing House.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 38 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Sidebottom, A. (2013). On the application of CRAVED to livestock theft in Malawi.
International Journal of Comparative and Applied Criminal Justice, 37(3), 195–212.
Smith, R. J., and Walpole, M. J. (2005). Should conservationists pay more attention to
corruption? Oryx, 39(3), 251–256.
Speart, J. (1993). War Within. Buzzworm: The Environmental Journal, 5(4), 36–45.
Sterling, E. J., Hurley, M. M., and Le, M. D. (2006). A natural history. New Haven, CT:
Yale University Press.
Sutherland, W. J., Adams, W. M., et al. 2009. One hundred questions of importance to the
conservation of global biological diversity. Conservation Biology, 23(3), 557–567.
Sutter, J. (2014). The most trafficked mammal you never heard of. Retrieved Sep 1, 2015,
.
Stoddard, E. (2012, Apr 26). Legalising rhino horn, ivory trade in focus. Retrieved Jan 10,
2016, .
Stretesky, P. B., Long, M. A. and Lynch, M. J. (2013). The treadmill of crime: Political
economy and green criminology. New York: Routledge.
Tailby, R., and Gant, F. (2002). The illegal market in Australian abalone. Trends and
Issues in Crime and Criminal Justice. Canberra: Australian Institute of Criminology.
Tella, J. L., and Hiraldo, F. (2014). Illegal and legal parrot trade shows a long-term, cross-
cultural preference for the most attractive species increasing their risk of extinction.
PLoS One, 9(9), 1–10.
Tilson, R., Nyhus, P. J., Sriyanto, Rubianto, A. (2010). Poaching and poisoning of tigers in
Sumatra for the domestic market. In Tigers of the world: The science, politics and
conservation of Panthera tigris, ed. R. Tilson, P. J. Nyhus, 2nd ed., 101–112. London:
Academic Press.
To A. W. L., Hau, B. C. H. and Lee, S. K. H. (2006). A Study on the Trade in Dried Abalone
in Hong Kong. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 21(1), 25–34.
’t Sas-Rolfes, M. (2000). Assessing CITES: Four case studies. In Endangered species
threatened convention: The past, present and future of CITES, 69–87. London: Earthscan.
’t Sas-Rolfes, M. (2010). Tigers, economics, and the regulation of trade. In Tigers of the
world: The science, politics, and conservation of Panthera tigris, ed. R. Tilson and P. J.
Nyhus, 2nd. ed., 477–490. Amsterdam: Academic Press.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 39 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
’t Sas-Rolfes, M. (2012). The rhino poaching crisis: A market analysis. Retrieved Dec 1,
2015, .
TRAFFIC. (1997). Rhino progress? The response to CITES resolution conference 9.14: A
TRAFFIC network report. June: 1–5.
TRAFFIC. (2008). What’s driving the wildlife trade? A review of expert opinion on
economic and social drivers of the wildlife trade and trade control efforts in Cambodia,
Indonesia, Lao PDR and Vietnam. East Asia and Pacific Region Sustainable Development
discussion papers. East Asia and Pacific Region Sustainable Development Department.
Washington DC: World Bank.
TRAFFIC. (2015, Jan 28). Transportation and logistics sector lends support to global
efforts tackling wildlife crime. Retrieved Jan 2, 2016, .
van Lavieren, E. (2008). The Illegal Trade in Barbary Macaques from Morocco and Its
Impact on the Wild Population. TRAFFIC Bulletin, 21(3), 123–130.
Vasquez, J. C. (2003). Compliance and enforcement mechanisms of CITES. In The trade in
wildlife regulation for conservation, ed. S. Oldfield, 63–69. London: Earthscan.
Vince, G. (2002). Organized gangs target wildlife trade. New Scientist. Retrieved Sep 1,
2015 at: .
Vira, V., Ewing, T. and Miller, J. (2014). Out of Africa: Mapping the global trade in illicit
elephant ivory. Center for Advanced Defense.
Von Essen, E., Hansen, P. H., Kallstrom, H. N., Peterson, M. N. and Peterson, T. R.
(2014). Deconstructing the poaching phenomenon: A review of typologies for
understanding illegal hunting. The British Journal of Criminology, 54, 632–651.
Wang, G. B. (2008). Pangolin conservation in Taiwan. TRAFFIC Southeast Asia.
Proceedings of the workshop on trade and conservation of pangolins native to South and
Southeast Africa, 80–83.
Warchol, G. (2004). The transnational illegal wildlife trade. Criminal Justice Studies, 17,
57–73.
Warchol, G. and Kapla, D. (2012). Policing the wilderness: A descriptive study of wildlife
conservation officers in South Africa. International Journal of Comparative and Applied
Criminal Justice, 36, 83–101.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 40 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Warchol, G., Zupan, L., and Clack, W. (2003). Transnational Criminality: An Analysis of
the Illegal Wildlife Market in Southern Africa. International. Criminal Justice Review, 13,
1–27.
Weber, D. S., Mandler, T., Dyck, M., De Groot, P. J. V. C., Lee, D. S., and Clark, D. A.
(2015). Unexpected and undesired conservation outcomes of wildlife trade bans—An
emerging problem for stakeholders?. Global Ecology and Conservation, 3, 389–400.
Weston, M. K., & Memon, M. A. (2009). The illegal parrot trade in Latin America and its
consequences to parrot nutrition, health and conservation. Bird populations, 9, 76–83.
White, R. (2008). Crimes against nature: Environmental criminology and ecological
justice. Portland, OR: Willan.
White, R. (2011). Transnational Environmental Crime: Toward an eco-global criminology.
New York: Routledge.
White, R. and Heckenberg, D. (2014). Green criminology: An introduction to the study of
environmental harm. New York: Routledge.
Wilson-Wilde, L. (2010). Wildlife crime: A global problem. Forensic Science, Medicine,
and Pathology, 6(3), 221–222.
Wright, T. F., Toft, C. A., Enkerlin‐Hoeflich, E., Gonzalez‐Elizondo, J., Albornoz, M.,
Rodríguez‐Ferraro, A., and Brice, A. T. (2001). Nest poaching in neotropical parrots.
Conservation Biology, 15(3), 710–720.
Wu, S., Liu, N., Zhang, Y., and Ma, G. Z. (2004). Assessment of threatened status of
Chinese Pangolin (Manis pentadactyla). Chinese Journal of Applied and Environmental
Biology, 10(4), 456–461.
WWF (2015). Greater one-horned rhino. Retrieved Dec 1 2015 from: .
WWF. (2012). Fighting illicit wildlife trafficking: A consultation with governments. Gland,
CH: WWF International.
Wyatt, T (2009). Exploring the organization of Russia Far East’s illegal wildlife trade: Two
case studies of the illegal fur and illegal falcon trades. Global Crime, 10(1–2), 144–154.
Wyatt, T. (2013). Wildlife trafficking: A deconstruction of the crime, the victims and the
offenders. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Yue, Z. (2009). Conservation and trade control of pangolins in China. Workshop on trade
and conservation of pangolins native to South and Southeast Asia, 66.
The Illegal Wildlife Trade
Page 41 of 41
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). (c) Oxford University Press, 2015. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy).
Subscriber: Florida International University; date: 07 July 2016
Zimmerman, ME (2003). The black market for wildlife: Combating transnational
organized crime in the illegal wildlife trade. Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law, 36,
1657–1689.
Notes:
() Retrieved on January17. 2016 https://cites.org/eng/news/pr/
2013/20130523_un_lra.php. A recent National Geographic also investigated this potential
link: http://www.nationalgeographic.com/tracking-ivory/article.html.
() Pseudo-hunting comes in the form of nonhunters, such as Vietnamese citizens, getting
hunting permits in order to obtain rhino horn and take it home legally. Many of such
hunters had to be trained to shoot a gun and, sometimes, had the guide shoot the rhino
on their behalf. Between 2009 and 2012, nearly half of all foreign permit holders in South
Africa were from Vietnam (Milliken and Shaw 2012).
Stephen F. Pires
Assistant Professor, Department of Criminal Justice, Florida International University
William D. Moreto
Assistant Professor, Department of Criminal Justice, University of Central Florida
1
2
... Population density varies from one to ten bearper 10 km², with an average of two bear/ 10 km² (Kolenosky et al., 1992;Hwang, 2000;Waseem and Ali, 2011;Garshelis and Steinmetz, 2016). The conservation status of Asiatic black bear is vulnerable under the International Union for Conservation of Nature (IUCN) Red List (Hwang, 2000;Zahler et al., 2004;Garland et al., 2016;Pires and Moreto, 2016). The population diversity of black bear depends upon their home range in a specific region, and it varies among different species of bears (Garland et al., 2016). ...
... The presence of black bear can also be determined from the pattern of feeding including claw marks, broken branches, soil digging for termites, and bark removal from the trees that are used as a food source during the winter season (Servheen, 1990;Crooks et al., 2011;Cardinale et al., 2012). IUCN Bear Specialists Group (BSG) points out that, Asiatic black bears are at high risk in a different part of Southeast Asia (Servheen, 1990;Hwang, 2000;Fujiwara et al., 2013;Pires and Moreto, 2016). The species declined due to habitat destruction, and increase in human activities like cultivation shifting, grazing of livestock, illegal killing for sport, poaching, reactive killings against crops depredation (Servheen, 1990;Garland et al., 2016). ...
Article
Full-text available
Population estimation survey of Asiatic black bear (Ursus thibetanus G. (Baron) Cuvier, 1823) was conducted in Kaghan and Siran Valleys of Khyber Pakhtunkhwa (KP) province of Pakistan. The different surveys (questionnaire, sighting, and sign survey) were conducted in all sites of the forests from June to November 2018. Thirteen different types of signs were observed during the field survey. Potential site selection was based on sign observation (Encounter Rate; ER). Four black bears were observed from three different spots. Two mature male bears were seen in Kaghan Valley (Kamal Bann and Malakandi Reserve Forest) and a mother with a single cub was observed in Siran Valley during dusk. Population estimation was carried out by transect method, with 18 transects were in Kaghan and 15 transects in Siran Valley. A total of 1858 signs were recorded during the field survey; among these 1213 dig marks, 186 plants uprooting and two setting places. An average of 49.95 signs/km2 was recorded; this is a very high encounter rate. According to BBC (British Broadcasting Corporation) Science and Nature, the home range size of Asiatic black bears is 10 to 20 km2 , so we concluded that more than 24 black bear were present in both valleys.
... As such, the availability of advanced means of transportation influences the trade flow of wildlife products [12]. Meeting subsistence needs, acquisition of traditional medicines, spiritual or religious beliefs, and clothing constitute some of the major uses of wildlife products which are reported as the key driving factors in the trade flow from one location to another [3] [13]. ...
... It has been noted that the presence of advanced transportation networks increases the speed of illegal trade of wildlife products from one place to another [13] [20]. However, the abundance of facilitation methods and corruption in the transportation sectors aided the existing illegal trade in many places [10] [15]. ...
... Population density varies from one to ten bearper 10 km², with an average of two bear/ 10 km² (Kolenosky et al., 1992;Hwang, 2000;Waseem and Ali, 2011;Garshelis and Steinmetz, 2016). The conservation status of Asiatic black bear is vulnerable under the International Union for Conservation of Nature (IUCN) Red List (Hwang, 2000;Zahler et al., 2004;Garland et al., 2016;Pires and Moreto, 2016). The population diversity of black bear depends upon their home range in a specific region, and it varies among different species of bears (Garland et al., 2016). ...
... The presence of black bear can also be determined from the pattern of feeding including claw marks, broken branches, soil digging for termites, and bark removal from the trees that are used as a food source during the winter season (Servheen, 1990;Crooks et al., 2011;Cardinale et al., 2012). IUCN Bear Specialists Group (BSG) points out that, Asiatic black bears are at high risk in a different part of Southeast Asia (Servheen, 1990;Hwang, 2000;Fujiwara et al., 2013;Pires and Moreto, 2016). The species declined due to habitat destruction, and increase in human activities like cultivation shifting, grazing of livestock, illegal killing for sport, poaching, reactive killings against crops depredation (Servheen, 1990;Garland et al., 2016). ...
Article
Full-text available
Authors' Contribution ZU conducted field surveys and collected data into a meaningful manuscript under the supervision of SM and ZI. FA and NA reviewed the manuscript for grammatical mistakes. AMK helped in tables formation and scientifically proofread and formatted the manuscript. Population estimation survey of Asiatic black bear (Ursus thibetanus G. (Baron) Cuvier, 1823) was conducted in Kaghan and Siran Valleys of Khyber Pakhtunkhwa (KP) province of Pakistan. The different surveys (questionnaire, sighting, and sign survey) were conducted in all sites of the forests from June to November 2018. Thirteen different types of signs were observed during the field survey. Potential site selection was based on sign observation (Encounter Rate; ER). Four black bears were observed from three different spots. Two mature male bears were seen in Kaghan Valley (Kamal Bann and Malakandi Reserve Forest) and a mother with a single cub was observed in Siran Valley during dusk. Population estimation was carried out by transect method, with 18 transects were in Kaghan and 15 transects in Siran Valley. A total of 1858 signs were recorded during the field survey; among these 1213 dig marks, 186 plants uprooting and two setting places. An average of 49.95 signs/km 2 was recorded; this is a very high encounter rate. According to BBC (British Broadcasting Corporation) Science and Nature, the home range size of Asiatic black bears is 10 to 20 km 2 , so we concluded that more than 24 black bear were present in both valleys.
... These activities will continue to grow in several countries depending on the high-demand market, population growth, and economic growth [1,4]. Wildlife trade will affect species decline [5], change of behavior [6], biodiversity decline [7], and diseases [8]. Wildlife trade activities are regulated in the Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora (CITES) with 183 countries as parties. ...
... Address: Department of Biology, Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences, Universitas Brawijaya, Malang, Indonesia secretariat which has been regulated in article VIII CITES [9]. Although the legal trade is regulated by CITES, the illegal wildlife trade still occurs [5,10]. Among vertebrate groups, turtles are the most threatened taxa [11]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Harvest monitoring is an alternative strategy to determine the impacts of exploitation which is useful for conservation strategies. One of the exploited turtles, C. amboinensis in three Indonesia provinces that have high rates of turtle harvesting, North Sumatra, South Sumatra, and Central Kalimantan were moniotored and reported here. The harvest monitoring was carried out by measuring harvested specimens based on three characters comprising median carapace length (MeCL), maximum carapace width (MaCW), and biomass of turtle (Wt). The collected data were compared with the previous monitoring in 2006. This study showed that the harvested size turtle was relatively similar to that of 2006 monitoring, in North Sumatra and Central Kalimantan. Furthermore, in North Sumatra, bigger individuals and larger quantities of the juvenile were recorded whereas in Central Kalimantan the harvest characteristics showed a similar pattern compared to previous monitoring. The female individuals were dominantly harvested in all locations, with detailed sex ratio male: female 1:1.7 (North Sumatra), 1:1.6 (South Sumatra), and 1:1.1 (Central Kalimantan). In the current monitoring, there was no evidence of a decline in harvest size that might indicate that the harvest activities of C.amboinensis in Indonesia are not yet detrimental to the wild populations. However, to reveal the sustainable harvest of this species in the future, long-term monitoring and intense supervision are needed.
... In particular, the exchangeable goods encompass animal derivatives such as corals, reptile skins, timber and fisheries products and live animals as parrots, raptors and primates for the pet trade (Pires & Moreto, 2016). ...
... First and foremost, it is important to identify the different parameters that wildlife trafficking consists of. As it is clear from the above definition, wildlife trafficking refers to the sale and exchange of plants and animals (Pires & Moreto, 2016). In order for this business to be as profitable as possible, the traders mistreat and sell at exorbitant prices large quantities of plants, animals and animal derivatives, leaving them at the verge of extinction. ...
... The unsustainable harvest and trade of wildlife species is among the main drivers of biodiversity change (Scheffers et al., 2019). Thousands of plant and animal species, including live individuals and their derivatives, are over-exploited and illegally traded (Pires and Moreto, 2016). Global wildlife trade generates yearly revenues of ca. ...
Article
Full-text available
E-commerce has become a booming market for wildlife trafficking, as online platforms are increasingly more accessible and easier to navigate by sellers, while still lacking adequate supervision. Artificial intelligence models, and specifically deep learning, have been emerging as promising tools for the automated analysis and monitoring of digital online content pertaining to wildlife trade. Here, we used and fine-tuned freely available artificial intelligence models (i.e., convolutional neural networks) to understand the potential of these models to identify instances of wildlife trade. We specifically focused on pangolin species, which are among the most trafficked mammals globally and receiving increasing trade attention since the COVID-19 pandemic. Our con-volutional neural networks were trained using online images (available from iNaturalist, Flickr and Google) displaying both traded and non-traded pangolin settings. The trained models showed great performances, being able to identify over 90 % of potential instances of pangolin trade in the considered imagery dataset. These instances included the showcasing of pangolins in popular marketplaces (e.g., wet markets and cages), and the displaying of commonly traded pangolin parts and derivates (e.g., scales) online. Nevertheless, not all instances of pangolin trade could be identified by our models (e.g., in images with dark colours and shaded areas), leaving space for further research developments. The methodological developments and results from this exploratory study represent an advancement in the monitoring of online wildlife trade. Complementing our approach with other forms of online data, such as text, would be a way forward to deliver more robust monitoring tools for online trafficking.
... The implication of this analysis is that the inclusion of Pristis spp. in Appendix I of CITES may have been disadvantageous for these species. The prices of sawfish saws appears to have increased after 2007, and may have led to the emergence of a black market for sawfish parts, especially the saws (Pires and Moreto, 2016). Black markets may have been more problematic for conservation efforts, because in driving the market underground, it becomes harder to control and monitor accidental capture, and to accurately perform market analysis. ...
Article
Full-text available
The durability of animal parts that are collected and traded as trophies has an impact on species sustainability, especially when animals are slow-growing, have low fecundity, or are particularly vulnerable to capture. CITES (the Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora), aims to control the trade of wild fauna and flora specifically by using trade restrictions as a policy option. However, specialists in international trade have advised against using trade restrictions to correct social cost issues. The reasons for this advice have to do with the unintended economic consequences of animals being placed on an endangered species list, coupled with the trade restrictions themselves. We focused on Pristis spp. (sawfish), a species in danger of extinction found in Appendix I of the CITES convention. An extensive search of sawfish saws for sale on the internet was performed during 2016 and 2017. A total of 174 observations of market prices were collected. We estimated several models linking prices to the size of the saw with other variables that might explain price variability using OLS regression, and which included data from both the original internet searches and additional variables, including a dummy variable which indicated the year in which the species group was placed in Appendix I. These models show that rather than slow down the extinction pathway for this species, CITES may have sped it up, as well as driving the sawfish trophy markets underground.
Article
Full-text available
Alternatif turizm türlerinden biri olan yaban hayatı turizmi, biyoçeşitliliği ve ekosistemi zengin olan bölgelerde yapılan yaban hayatın gözlenmesi ve fotoğraflanması gibi faaliyetleri kapsamaktadır. Biyokaçakçılık, yaban hayatına ait canlıların ve bunlara ait parçaların, çeşitli amaçlarla yasadışı olarak yaşadığı bölge dışına çıkarılmasıdır. Bu çalışmada, biyokaçakçılık ve turizm arasındaki ilişkiyi ortaya çıkarmak için bir alanyazın taraması yapılmıştır. Araştırma sonucunda, turist görünümlü biyokaçakçıların canlı türlerini kaçırmakla birlikte nesli tehlike altında olan canlılardan elde edilen ürünleri de satın aldığı anlaşılmıştır. Biyokaçakçılığa karşı ulusal ve uluslararası çabalar olmasına rağmen vakalar artış eğilimindedir. Biyokaçakçılığın önüne geçilmesinin yanı sıra ekonomik getirisi yüksek olduğundan para cezaları haricinde çeşitli yaptırımlar uygulanmalıdır. Turistlere biyokaçakçılık ile ilgili bilgilendirmeler yapılmalı ve turizm paydaşları arasındaki iş birliği ve iletişim çoğaltılmalıdır. Biyolojik materyallerin sürdürülebilirliği ve korunması, tüm insanlığın ortak görevi olduğu unutulmamalıdır.
Article
Full-text available
The abundance of many large-bodied vertebrates, both in marine and terrestrial environments , has declined substantially due to global and regional climate stressors that define the Anthropocene. The development of genetic tools that can serve to monitor population's health non-intrusively and inform strategies for the recovery of these species is crucial. In this study, we formally evaluate whether whole mitochondrial genomes can be assembled from environmental DNA (eDNA) metagenomics scat samples. Mitogenomes of four different large vertebrates, the panda bear (Ailuropoda melanoleuca), the moon bear (Ursus thibetanus), the Java pangolin (Manis javanica), and the the North Atlantic right whale (Eubalaena glacialis) were assembled and circularized using the pipeline GetOrganelle with a coverage ranging from 12x to 480x in 14 out of 18 different eDNA samples. Partial mitochondrial genomes were retrieved from three other eDNA samples. The complete mitochondrial genomes of the studied species were AT-rich and comprised 13 protein coding genes, 22 transfer RNA genes, two ribosomal RNA genes, and a putative D-loop/control region. Synteny observed in all assembled mitogenomes was identical to that reported for specimens of the same and other closely related species. This study demonstrates that it is possible to assemble accurate whole mitochondrial chromosomes from eDNA samples (scats) using forthright bench and bioinformatics workflows. The retrieval of mitochondrial genomes from eDNA samples represents a tool to support bioprospecting, bio-monitoring, and other non-intrusive conservation strategies in species considered 'vulnerable', 'endangered', and/or 'critically endangered' by the IUCN Red List of Threatened Species.
Article
Full-text available
Vicuna (Vicugna vicugna) fiber is produced by extremely low-income communities that inhabit the harsh environment of the Andes in Argentina, Chile, Peru and Bolivia. At the other end of the social scale, affluent consumers are willing to pay high prices for vicuna-made accessories and clothes. Vicuna management projects follow the logic of community-based wildlife management. The rationale for seeking to conserve vicuñas through sustainable use is that commercial utilization of the fiber (obtained from live-shorn animals) will generate sufficient economic benefits to outweigh the costs of conservation, and contribute to community development and poverty alleviation. However, although conservation efforts have been extremely successful with vicuñas having recovered from the brink of extinction, the socio-economic achievements have thus far proved modest. This paper explores multiple-objective projects that address vicuña conservation and poverty alleviation in Andean countries. In doing so it analyses the tensions that exist between these objectives, as well as the factors that limit a more equitable distribution of benefits among stakeholders. Examples are drawn from vicuna management under common-property in Peru and Bolivia, and vicuna captive management under private property in Argentina. These case studies enable us to illustrate the complex relationship between local communities and the global market, and the importance of community enterprises and supportive government policy in managing a common pool resource.
Article
Full-text available
Over the last few years the wholesale slaughter of rhinoceroses (rhinos) in South Africa has unceremoniously thrust conservation crime into the news. Not only is the wanton massacre of these animals abhorrent in itself, but it becomes even more so when one considers that they are generally being decimated on managed protected areas and nature reserves. During 2010, for example, 333 rhinos were poached across South Africa, 146 of them from within the precincts of the Kruger National Park, South Africa's premier wildlife conservation area. By April 2011 South Africa had lost a further 114 rhinos to poaching and current estimates are that in South Africa we will, on average, lose one rhino per day. Conservation law violations encompass many offences against the natural environment, a common one being wildlife poaching. Previous research has often described the extent and impact of poaching as offender behaviour. While it has indisputably contributed to an understanding of this crime and what motivates poachers, more research is needed to examine why protected conservation areas are so easily penetrated and wildlife populations victimised on a regular basis. Theory-based studies focusing on all elements of a crime, would add to the understanding of poaching. The qualitative enquiry in this article examines the efficacy of the Routine Activities Theory in order to assist the understanding of the phenomenon of poaching in protected conservation areas in South Africa. Data collected at conservation areas threatened by poaching, were analysed via this theory. Wildlife custodianship problems were identified with a view to both developing a framework for understanding the challenges being faced in this arena and empowering policy makers to more resourcefully initiate intervention strategies and control illegal hunting in these conservation areas.
Chapter
Full-text available
We argue in this chapter for a political economic approach to the study of global ecological crimes. Green criminological studies often employ case-study approaches that help explain a particular green crime; however, these studies lack a coherent theoretical basis. Based on ecological Marxism and treadmill of production (ToP) approaches, we outline a theoretical approach for green criminology that focuses on crimes of ecological disorganization-that is, green harms that are the result of organizing the productive forces of the economy in a manner that is consistent with capitalism. We conclude that, to truly understand and remedy green harms, a focus on political economy is necessary.
Book
This book provides a comprehensive, global exploration of the scale, scope, threats, and drivers of wildlife trafficking from a criminological perspective. Building on the first edition, it takes into account the significant changes in the international context surrounding these issues since 2013. It provides new examples, updated statistics, and discusses the potential changes arising as a result of COVID-19 and the IPBES 2019 report. It also discusses the shift in trafficking ‘hotspots’ and the recent projects that have challenged responses to wildlife trafficking. It undertakes a distinctive exploration of who the victims and offenders of wildlife trafficking are as well as analysing the stakeholders who are involved in collaborative efforts to end this devastating green crime. It unpacks the security implications of wildlife trade and trafficking and possible responses and ways to combat it. It provides useful and timely information for social and environmental/life scientists, law enforcement, NGOs, and policy makers. Tanya Wyatt is Professor of Criminology at Northumbria University, UK. Her research focuses on green crimes, such as wildlife trafficking and animal welfare, and these crimes' intersection with organized crime, corporate crime, and corruption.
Article
During the last decade natural resource crime and criminality have received growing attention from criminological scholars. There remains, however, a spirited subterranean and unresolved debate regarding the most appropriate nomenclature/diction to portray this form of crime and its study. Varying views exist among criminological scholars regarding the most appropriate terminology to describe the study of crime in the natural resource arena which has, over the years, produced somewhat of a semantical farrago. It appears therefore that the time is ripe to interrogate this issue more methodically in an attempt to lobby criminological scholars and conservation protagonists alike to galvanise behind one cognate indicator that passes onomastical muster. An apposite truism attributed to Socrates, which can be related to the issue at hand, was in fact: " Η αρχή της σοφίας είναι ο καθορισμός των όρων " , literally translated as " The beginning of wisdom is the definition of terms " , encapsulating the intrinsic thrust of this narrative. In order to probe this linguistic issue and ruminate on its constituents, it was deemed prudent to seek guidance from the wisdom of certain ancient Hellenic philosophers, the prominent Spinozian, Gilles Deleuze, the Cartesian and father of modern Western philosophy, René Descartes, as well as customary English language conventions. In the form of a four-pronged alliance these resources were marshalled to underscore and unravel the present-day diachronic dichotomies and, to a certain extent, resolve the ossifying impasse. An attempt is made to dispel the factoids and ersatz definitions/terminology permeating the criminological discourse in relation to the study of natural resource crime and criminality, to wit, green, environmental and ecological criminology. Moreover, a case is made for pp 1–17 2 Friedo JW Herbig the recognition and entrenchment of an unambiguous sub-field of study, namely conservation criminology.
Book
"'A critical and unique contribution to the study of nature conservation'-Professor Steven Brechin, Syracuse University" "The perilous state of endangered species such as tigers and rhinos, and the worldwide illegal trade in ivory, diamonds, bushmeat and many other rare and valuable commodities, are familiar issues in the West. The heroes in these narratives are those who work to create protected areas for wildlife; the villains the shadowy poachers and smugglers who destroy endangered animals and their habitats for the sake of profit." "In this groundbreaking book, Rosaleen Duffy argues that the story is much more complex than this. She analyses the workings of the black-market wildlife industry, pointing out that illegal trading is often the direct result of Western consumer desires, from coltan for mobile phones to caviar for the global elite. She looks at how tourists contribute, often unwittingly, to the destruction of natural environments. Most strikingly, she argues that the imperatives of Western-style conservation often result in serious injustice to local people, who are at risk of losing not only heir land but sometimes even their lives." "The result of many years of first-hand research, this book is essential reading for anyone who wants to understand the complex realities of nature conservation.".