ArticlePDF Available

Mitigating the Gender Gap in the Willingness to Compete: Evidence from a Randomized Field Experiment

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

The lower willingness of females to compete is extensively documented, and has a wide range of implications including gender gaps in occupational choice, achievement and labor market outcomes. In this paper, we show that one of the driving forces of competitive behavior is grit, a skill that is highly predictive of achievement, and evaluate the impact on competitiveness of a randomized educational intervention that aims to foster grit. The intervention is implemented in a sample of elementary schools, and we measure its impact using a dynamic competition task with interim performance feedback. We find that when children are exposed to an optimistic worldview that emphasizes the role of effort in achievement and encourages perseverance, the gender gap in the willingness to compete disappears. We propose the effect of this treatment on self-confidence and perseverance as a potential mechanism to explain the results.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Mitigating the Gender Gap in the Willingness to Compete:
Evidence from a Randomized Field Experimentú
Sule Alan, University of Essex
Seda Ertac, Koc University
May 2016
Abstract
The lower willingness of females to compete is extensively documented, and has a wide range of
implications including gender gaps in occupational choice, achievement and labor market outcomes.
In this paper, we show that one of the driving forces of competitive behavior is grit, a skill that
is highly predictive of achievement, and evaluate the impact on competitiveness of a randomized
educational intervention that aims to foster grit. The intervention is implemented in a sample of
elementary schools, and we measure its impact using a dynamic competition task with interim
performance feedback. We find that when children are exposed to an optimistic worldview that
emphasizes the role of eort in achievement and encourages perseverance, the gender gap in the
willingness to compete disappears. We propose the eect of this treatment on self-confidence and
perseverance as a potential mechanism to explain the results.
JEL Categories: C91, C93, D03, I28
Keywords: competition, gender, grit, randomized interventions, experiments
úContact information: Sule Alan: salan@essex.ac.uk, Seda Ertac: sertac@ku.edu.tr. We would like to thank the ING
Bank of Turkey for providing funding. Ertac thanks the Turkish Academy of the Sciences (TUBA-GEBIP program)
and Alan thanks the ESRC Research Center on Micro-Social Change (MISOC) for financial support. We thank Thomas
Crossley, Thomas Dohmen, Uri Gneezy, Jonathan Meer and participants at the ASSA 2016 San Francisco meetings,
MISOC Workshop, UCSD Rady School of Management strategy and economics seminar, and the ROA Conference in
Maastricht University for comments and suggestions. We would also like to thank Elif Kubilay, Ipek Mumcu, Nergis
Zaim, Banu Donmez and Enes Duysak, as well as numerous other students who provided excellent research assistance.
All errors are our own.
1
1 Introduction
It is well-known that fewer women than men occupy top leadership positions in politics and the
corporate world, and fewer women are represented in high-paying occupations that involve competitive
paths. Gender dierences in attitudes and preferences towards competition have been put forward as
an explanation for these findings; since if fewer women choose to compete, there will be less female
winners in the competition for top positions, or in ambitious careers that usually involve competitive
paths; see, for example, Gneezy et al. (2003), Niederle and Vesterlund (2007, 2011), Buser et al. (2014)
for lab evidence and Flory et al. (2014) for field evidence. A number of studies also point out that
these dierences emerge quite early in the life cycle and persist into adulthood1. From an economic
standpoint, an important concern here is eciency: if males and females are equally able in tackling
a task and if females shy away from competition involving such a task, then winners of tournaments
will on average be less able than if males and females had similar entry rates2.
In the economics literature, a number of papers use laboratory experiments to explore the eective-
ness of policies that aim to mitigate gender dierences in competitiveness. For example, one strand
of the literature considers armative action and preferential treatment through changes in tourna-
ment rules favoring women (e.g. Balafoutas and Sutter (2012), Niederle et al. (2013), Sutter et al.
(2015)). These studies find that women enter tournaments more frequently with such policies, without
sacrificing eciency. Booth and Nolen (2012) show that single-sex schooling might eliminate gender
dierences in competitiveness while Petrie and Segal (2014) find that the gender dierence disappears
if tournament prizes are high enough3. Implicit in these studies is that competitiveness may not be a
fixed trait and is likely to be responsive to external and environmental factors. Consistently with this,
Almas et al. (2014) highlight the role of family background and socio-economic status in determining
competitive behavior. Gneezy et al. (2009) and Andersen et al. (2013) show that social structure
may influence competitiveness, with gender gaps being non-existent in matrilineal societies with more
gender equality.
In this paper, we take a unique approach to the issue of competitiveness. We conjecture that one
of the driving forces of competitive behavior is grit, a non-cognitive skill that has been shown to be
1There is a growing literature studying gender gaps in the willingness to compete among children and adolescents.
While some studies find no gender dierences at young ages in some countries (e.g. Cardenas et al. (2012), Khachatrian
et al. (2015)), in many societies a gender gap will have become apparent by the time adolescence is reached and will
persist (Andersen et al. (2013), Dreber et al. (2014), Sutter and Glatzle-Ruetzler (2015), Sutter et al. (2015)).
2Eckel and Fullbrunn (2015) show that one such implication of gender dierences in attitudes relates to asset price
bubbles in financial markets where all-male markets generate significantly higher speculative bubbles than all-female
markets.
3Lee et al. (2014), on the other hand, find that single-sex schooling has no eect on the gender gap.
2
highly predictive of educational and occupational achievement; see Duckworth et al. (2007), Duckworth
and Quinn (2009), Maddie et al. (2012) and Eskreis-Winkler et al. (2014). Grit involves challenge-
seeking and passion for long-term goals, and it is closely linked to perseverance and tenacity. What
distinguishes a gritty individual is her beliefs regarding the role of eort in the performance process and
her interpretation of performance feedback. A gritty individual tends to set ambitious performance
goals with the belief that those goals are attainable through persistent eort, and attributes success
to hard work4. Choosing to compete essentially means setting an ambitious performance goal, and
sustained competitiveness in many cases requires perseverance in the competitive path by interpreting
failure and success constructively, rather than immediately attributing failures to a lack of ability and
successes to ability or luck. This is why we conjecture that there can be important interactions between
grit and competitiveness, especially in dynamic performance settings.
The aim of the paper is to explore whether the gender gap in the willingness to compete can be
mitigated in childhood by fostering grit. For this, we evaluate a unique educational program targeted
at elementary school children in Turkey. The program is implemented by children’s own (trained)
teachers for about a semester, with the help of a carefully designed curriculum5.Weprovideabrief
review of the content of the curriculum in Section 3. The intervention is designed as a randomized-
controlled trial and implemented twice in this manner using two independent samples. Each study
follows the same randomization procedure and uses the same education materials, providing us with
two large independent samples to estimate the treatment eect on the willingness to compete.
Our outcome measures come from an incentivized mathematical real-eort task, whereby children
choose to compete, receive performance feedback, then make a choice again. The dynamic nature of our
experimental task suits our purposes well, as in real-life performance settings individuals usually do not
make one-time, permanent choices but rather can observe how they fared, interpret the feedback they
receive and revise their decisions. Choosing whether to stick with or quit a dicult degree program or a
competitive career after receiving negative performance feedback, or choosing whether to pursue more
ambitious and competitive paths after doing well in less ambitious ones are important decisions. Using
a competition task with interim feedback given to everyone regardless of the chosen incentive scheme
helps us explore the relationship between competitiveness and grit, as well as the potential mechanisms
4Recent research in psychology shows that believing that skills are not fixed but malleable through eort, i.e. having
a “growth mindset” can increase motivation, perseverance and achievement; see Dweck (2006), Blackwell et al (2007).
5Alan, Boneva and Ertac (2016) show that this intervention is highly eective in inducing ambitious goal-setting,
perseverance and eventual skill accumulation. It also leads to a significant increase in standardized test scores, without
any heterogeneity in such eects with respect to gender.
3
through which an intervention that targets grit might be aecting the willingness to compete6.
We first show that, consistently with the literature, the decision to compete in the first stage and in
the second stage are highly correlated with self-confidence, risk tolerance and cognitive ability in the
baseline. We add to that a new piece of evidence that grit is also highly predictive of competitiveness:
a one standard deviation increase in the grit score is associated with a 3 percentage point increase in
the probability of competing in the first stage, and a 5 percentage point increase in the second stage7.
We then turn to competitive behavior across gender. In our control sample, there is a statistically
significant 8 percentage point gender gap in the willingness to compete in the first stage of the com-
petition task. Despite the fact that there is no gender dierence in actual performance and therefore
in the probability of receiving negative performance feedback, this gap slightly widens and becomes
10 percentage points in the second stage competition, after feedback. The size of this gap appears to
be independent of the type of feedback received in the first stage.
We proceed by documenting that there is no gender gap in the willingness to compete in the
treatment group, either in the first or in the second stage. We estimate a statistically significant
treatment eect on the willingness to compete for both boys and girls in the first stage and this eect
is larger for girls, mitigating the first stage gender gap. Moreover, we find a statistically significant
treatment eect on competitiveness after feedback only for girls, entirely eliminating the second stage
gender gap. The eect on girls is of considerable size: the propensity to compete in the second stage
is about 16 percentage points higher for treated girls relative to untreated girls. These results provide
strong evidence that fostering grit in the classroom environment goes a long way in mitigating the
gender gap in the willingness to compete. Finally, we also show that the higher willingness to compete
induced by the treatment brings significantly higher rewards to treated girls relative to the girls in the
control group, implying significant eciency gains. Our rich data allow us to contemplate a potential
mechanism that points to improved self-confidence and grit in girls, to explain these results.
The paper contributes to several distinct strands of the literature. First, by being the first study
that documents a strong link between grit, an important but understudied non-cognitive skill, and the
willingness to compete, it contributes to the growing literature that strives to understand the role of
non-cognitive skills in achievement outcomes; see Borghans (2008), Heckman et al (2006, 2010, 2013,
2014), Almlund et al (2011), Kautz et al (2014). Second, by using a randomized-controlled design
6Andersen et al. (2014) consider a setting with dynamic competition in a matrilineal and patriarchal society, and
find that women in the matrilineal society are more motivated by positive performance feedback.
7The grit score is a standardized factor extracted using a number of item-set questions mostly adapted from the
Duckworth grit scale; see Duckworth (2009). The specific questions we use to obtain this score are given in the Appendix.
4
and showing for the first time the causal impact of an educational intervention on the gender gap
in competitiveness, it contributes to the large literature on gender and competition; see Croson and
Gneezy (2009) and Niederle and Vesterlund (2011) for reviews. Besides opening new and promising
research avenues, the evidence documented in this paper also provides crucial input into policy actions
targeting gender gaps in achievement, and oers specific cost-eective recommendations that can be
implemented in the classroom environment. Finally, our two-stage design and related results highlight
the importance of considering competitiveness in a dynamic context, and makes novel contributions to
the recent literature on performance feedback and its eects on choices and performance (Azmat and
Iriberri (2010), Barankay (2011), Eriksson et al. (2009), Ertac and Szentes (2011), Gill and Prowse
(2014), Wozniak et al. (2014)).
The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 provides background information on
the program we evaluate and presents the evaluation design, Section 3 describes the content of the
intervention, Section 4 describes our experimental outcome measures, Section 5 presents the results,
and Section 6 provides a discussion and concluding remarks.
2 Program Background and Evaluation Design
The Turkish Ministry of Education encourages schools and teachers to participate in socially useful
extra-curricular programs oered by the private sector, NGOs, the government and international orga-
nizations. All elementary school teachers are given a maximum of 5 hours per week to be involved in
these programs. Their participation is voluntary and if they choose not to participate in any program,
there is no restriction on the way in which these hours are used. The program we evaluate in this paper
is implemented in state-run elementary schools in Istanbul as an extra-curricular project under the
oversight of the Education Directorate of Istanbul. The main objective of the program is to improve
key non-cognitive skills in elementary school children in the classroom environment by training their
teachers.
The program is designed as a randomized-controlled trial and implemented twice in this manner,
using two independent samples of elementary schools all across Istanbul. Our first sample comes
from an intervention that had two main treatment arms, each of which had a specific behavioral
target. The first arm aimed to improve the ability to make decisions in a forward-looking manner and
encourage patience; see the evaluation of this arm in Alan and Ertac (2014). The second arm, which
was implemented in the same schools after the implementation of the first arm, aimed to foster grit.
5
In the second sample, only the second arm of the first study, namely the grit arm, was implemented.
The first sample consists of 23 schools (about 1300 students), where a version of a phase-in design
was implemented. Initially, students in a randomly selected 9 schools received the patience treatment
for about 8 weeks, while others were in the control group. The same children in these 9 schools received
the grit treatment in the following semester. While the initial treatment group was receiving the grit
treatment, a randomly selected set of 6 schools, which were previously in the control group, received
the patience treatment. Remaining schools were kept as control8. With this design, we can evaluate
the independent impact of the patience treatment on our outcome measures, and indeed show that the
patience treatment by itself does not have any impact on competitiveness (see Table 16 in Appendix)).
Still, we would not be able to isolate or rule out potential complementarities across grit and patience
training using this study sample. Such an issue does not arise in the second study.
In the second study, we randomly assign only the grit training arm of the first study across a new
set of schools in Istanbul. The intervention follows the same procedures, with the same curricular
materials and the same teacher training approach. This sample consists of 16 schools (8 treatment, 8
control) and has a total of about 1,300 students.
In both studies, the randomization was performed in the following way. First, the Istanbul Direc-
torate of Education sent the ocial documentation of the program to all elementary schools in major
districts of Istanbul9. The teachers in these schools were then contacted in random sequence and
invited to participate in the program. Teachers were informed that upon participation they would be
assigned to dierent training phases within the coming two academic years. All teachers who agreed
to participate were promised to eventually participate in training seminars and receive all training
materials, but they were not told when within the next two academic years they would receive the
treatment until the random assignment was completed. The promise of the training oer was made
to the teacher and not to current students, i.e., while children in control groups never received the
training as they moved on to middle school after 4th grade, their teachers did, albeit at a later time.
This was done in order to allow for long-term follow-up.
Once a teacher stated a willingness to participate, we randomly assigned their school into the
8The original program sample of the first study includes 36 schools but a random subset of these schools (13 schools)
were exposed to another treatment (a role model exposure intervention) before we collected our follow-up data in May
2014, therefore we remove those schools from our current analysis. A previous version of this paper included evaluation
of that treatment as well as the one we evaluate here but it did not include sample 2 data. Sample 2 was collected later
with the purpose of replication and exploring complementarities that might have arisen in the first study. By increasing
the number of clusters, combining Sample 1 and Sample 2 allows us to make powerful inference.
9The program was titled “financial literacy, savings and economic decisions” and no further information on the
particulars of the program were disclosed to the teachers prior to the teacher training seminars.
6
treatment or the control group. Note that in both studies the unit of randomization was the school,
not classroom, in order to prevent potential spillovers across classrooms. In the first study, a given
school where there was a teacher willing to participate had a 40% ex-ante chance of being assigned
to the initial treatment group (patience+grit), a 30% chance to be in the second treatment group
(patience only) and 30% chance to be assigned to the control group. In the second study, a given
school where there was a teacher willing to participate had a 50% chance of being in the treatment
group. For each study, we stopped recruiting teachers when we hit the logistical constraint of being
able to physically visit the classrooms10.
The sample generated with this design contains schools in which at least one teacher stated their
willingness to participate in the program. Therefore, the estimated impact of the program is the average
treatment eect on the treated and in principle, is not readily generalizable to the population. However,
in the first study, approximately 60% of the contacted teachers accepted our oer and the most common
reason for non-participation was being “busy with other projects, although happy to participate in this
program at a later date” (about 20%). The rest of the non-participation was due to “impending transfer
to a school in another city, with a willingness to participate if the program is implemented there” (about
5%), and “not being in a position to participate due to private circumstances” (about 10%). In study
sample 2, acceptance of the training oer reached 80%. Given these numbers, we conjecture that the
external validity of our results is strong.
In the first study, baseline data were collected in Spring 2013, the first intervention (patience) was
implemented in Spring 2013, and the intervention on grit was implemented in Fall 2013. The follow-up
data were collected in May 2014. In the second sample, baseline data were collected in Spring 2015,
the intervention (grit only) was implemented in Fall 2015, and the follow-up data were collected in
January 2016. Full details of the evaluation design for each study sample are given in Table A in the
appendix.
After establishing that the two samples represent the same population using the baseline charac-
teristics, we pool them to increase the number of clusters (number of schools) and define the treated
child as one who received the grit treatment, either as grit only (as in Study 2) or grit plus patience (as
in Study 1). With this, we have a total of 17 schools in treatment and 22 schools in the control, giving
us about 2600 students in total. We provide additional analyses based on disaggregated treatment
10In order to ensure data quality, authors of the paper coordinated the field logistics, trained a select group of students
and experienced interviewers to assist with data collection, and physically visited all classrooms to implement the tasks
and collect data. All measurements were conducted with the approval of the local IRB and the permission of the Ministry.
7
status in the Appendix.
3 The Educational Intervention on Grit
The educational initiative required the production of a rich set of educational materials, which involved
a broad interdisciplinary endeavor. While the target concepts of the materials were determined by the
authors, specific contents (e.g. scripts) were shaped with input from an interdisciplinary team of
education psychologists, a voluntary group of elementary school teachers, children’s story writers and
media animation artists, according to the age and cognitive capacity of the students.
The program involves providing animated videos, mini case studies and classroom activities that
highlight i) the plasticity of the human brain against the notion of innately fixed ability, ii) the role
of eort in enhancing skills and achieving goals, iii) the importance of a constructive interpretation
of setbacks, failures and success, and iv) the importance of goal setting. The aim of the training is
to expose students to an optimistic worldview in which any one of them can set goals in an area of
their interest and can work towards these goals by exerting eort. The materials highlight the idea
that in order to achieve these goals, it is imperative to avoid interpreting immediate failures as a lack
of innate ability or intelligence. This worldview encompasses any productive area of interest, whether
it be music, art, science or sports11 . Visual materials and stories are supplemented by classroom
activities created and supervised by teachers, based on general suggestions and guidelines put forward
in teacher training. It should be noted that there is no mention of competitiveness or emphasis on
doing better than others in the materials, and success in the examples given to children means reaching
individualistic goals, such as mastering a task that one finds challenging.
Weekly topics, main materials and supplementary activities are very clearly defined and specific
guidelines on how to structure each lesson are prepared for the teachers (the teacher kit). However,
the program is not merely a set of materials to be covered in a specified period of time, like a common
curriculum item. Instead, it aims to change students’ beliefs about the role of eort in performance
processes and the potential return to perseverance partly by changing the mindset of the teachers and
the nature of the classroom environment. To this end, in addition to covering the curricular items
11To give an example, in an animated video, two students who hold opposite views on the malleability of ability engage
in a dialog. The student who believes that ability is innate and therefore there is no scope for enhancing it through
eort, points out that the setbacks she experiences are reminders of the fact that she is not intelligent. Following this
remark, the student who holds the opposite view replies that setbacks are usually inevitable on the way to success; she
interprets them as opportunities to learn, and therefore, they do not discourage her. The curriculum with all covered
topics and classroom activities are available upon request.
8
as suggested, teachers were strongly encouraged to adopt a teaching philosophy that emphasizes the
role of eort in everyday classroom tasks, e.g. while giving performance feedback and interpreting test
results.
4 The Outcome Measure: A Two-Stage Competition Task
Our outcome measure is designed to estimate the eect of the intervention on initial competitiveness
and competitiveness in response to performance feedback. The task we use is an addition task, which
involves adding two 2-digit numbers and one single-digit number. The task consists of three perfor-
mance periods and children are given 2.5 minutes per each period. One of these periods is selected
randomly at the end, and rewards are determined based on the performance and decisions in the se-
lected period. For all three periods, each student is matched with another student from a dierent
school (whom we will call “opponent” hereafter), who had done the same tasks before and whose
performance was recorded12.
In the first period, students perform the addition task under a piece-rate incentive scheme, whereby
they receive 1 token for every addition they are able to do correctly. In the second period (the first
competition choice stage), students have a choice between piece-rate and competing with their matched
opponent. If they choose the piece-rate, they are rewarded with one token per correct answer. If
they choose the tournament, they are rewarded with 3 tokens per correct answer, but only if their
performance exceeds that of the opponent. In the case of having a lower performance, a student that
chooses to compete receives zero tokens, whereas in the case of a tie, she gets 1 token per correct
answer.
After choosing the incentive scheme, we elicit beliefs with the purpose of exploring the role of
self-confidence in incentive scheme choices. Specifically, children are asked to state their beliefs about
(1) the number of correct answers they will have, (2) the number of correct answers of their opponent.
These beliefs are incentivized in the following way: Children are told that three people in their class
will be randomly chosen after the experiment ends, and these three will get an extra small gift for each
correct guess13. After performing the 2nd period task, they receive feedback about (1) the number of
additions they were able to do correctly, (2) whether their performance was better than, worse than,
12We implemented the same tasks in the same order in three classrooms in three pilot schools, and recorded perfor-
mances. Each student in our sample is randomly matched with one student from this “benchmark sample”.
13Children are also reminded that there is always an incentive to do as many additions as they can in the actual task
and it does not make sense to stop just to be consistent with their guess.
9
or equal to that of the opponent. In the 3rd period (the 2nd competition choice stage), children make
a choice again between piece-rate and competition against the same opponent, to be implemented if
that period is chosen for payment. After making this choice, they state beliefs again about their own
and opponent’s performance, in the same way as in the first choice stage. This allows us to understand
how children update their relative self-confidence in response to performance feedback. If the child
chooses to compete in any period, her results are compared with the performance of the opponent in
the corresponding period, and rewards are determined based on this comparison.
Children learn the gender of their (randomly assigned) opponent before making their initial com-
petition choice. That is, they know whether they are matched with a boy or a girl. Before this, there
is also an incentivized question that elicits gender stereotypes: children are told about one girl and one
boy, randomly selected from a dierent school/class, and are asked to guess whether the girl or the
boy has done better in this same task. If they guess who actually did better correctly, they get a small
extra gift. Children were given workbooks, and instructed to turn over pages only at specified times.
Each child’s workbook had a code that matched it to a set of actual performances (in the second and
third periods of the task) that came from a student in one of the pilot classes. The workbooks were
randomly distributed, rendering a random match in terms of opponent gender and opponent perfor-
mance. After the task is completed in the second period (the first choice stage), feedback was given to
children by experimenters by writing the child’s own actual performance and circling the outcome of
the performance comparison (the child having a worse, better or equal performance compared to the
matched child) on the sheet. Instructions are in the Appendix.
5 Results
We have data from approximately 2600 students in 39 schools. About 51% percent of our sample is
male, and the average age is about 9.5 years, as is typically the case for 4th graders in Turkey. We
collected baseline information on students using surveys, cognition tests and experimental elicitation
tasks. While some survey information come directly from children, some are obtained via teacher
assessment surveys. These variables allow us to test the balance of the treatment groups in our data
and provide us with useful covariates that are predictive of our outcome measures.
10
5.1 Internal Validity
We first check whether our pooled data are balanced across treatment status with respect to a number
of student characteristics, collected at the baseline stage. Table 1 shows results from ordinary least
squares regressions of baseline variables on the treatment dummy. While the first column gives the
mean of the control for the respective variable, column 2 shows the dierence from the control’s mean.
Panel 1 presents the balance results for demographic variables and baseline attitudes either reported
by the child or the teacher, and Panel 2 presents the balance results pertaining to three variables that
come from our competition task.
The variables in Panel 1 are constructed as follows: Age is reported by the student, while student’s
family income (wealth) and her overall academic standing (academic success) are reported by the
teacher using a 5-point scale. Cognitive ability is measured using Raven’s progressive matrices test
(Raven et al (2004)) and risk tolerance is measured using a task based on Gneezy and Potters(1997)14.
The grit score is a standardized factor extracted using a number of item-set questions mostly adapted
from the Duckworth grit scale; see Duckworth (2009). The specific questions we use to obtain this
score are given in the Appendix.
As can be seen from the table, dierences are not statistically dierent from zero across treatment
and control for any of the variables. This ensures us that the pooled data are balanced across treatment
status and our results are internally valid. An important finding to note in this table (Panel 2) is that
there is no dierence in piece-rate performance across our treatment groups. Nor is there any dierence
in the probability of receiving negative feedback after the first stage. We will refer to these findings
when we discuss the gender gaps in competitiveness we observe in the baseline in the next section.
5.2 Willingness to Compete and Gender Gaps in the Control Group
Before moving on to estimating the eect of the intervention, we study the gender gap in the baseline.
Focusing on elementary school children and using a dynamic version of a well-known experimental
task, this initial analysis provides new evidence on the prevalence of the gender gap in the willingness
to compete and gives us the baseline gender gap figures upon which our treatment operates. Table 2
presents marginal eects from logit regressions where the dependent variables are the binary competi-
14In this task, children have an endowment of 5 tokens, which they can allocate between a riskless and a risky option.
Tokens allocated into the risky option, which is conveyed as putting tokens in a “risky bowl”, are tripled with 50%
chance and lost with 50% chance, based on the color of a ball drawn from an opaque bag. Tokens that are not allocated
into the risky bowl are safe. The number of tokens placed into the risky option is a measure of risk tolerance.
11
tion choices in stage 1 and stage 2. The first point to note in this table is that there is a statistically
significant gender gap between girls and boys in the first stage, with girls about 8 percentage points
less likely to choose to compete (see column 1). The gender gap remains, and in fact slightly widens
in the second stage, after feedback: We estimate that girls’ willingness to compete is now about 10
percentage-points lower than boys, although the dierence in the gap between the two stages does not
reach statistical significance (p-value=0.38).
A major question that the gender-competition literature has focused on is the determinants of com-
petitiveness in girls and boys, which also provides insights about the nature of the gender gap. Columns
2 and 4 of Table 2 include the main potential determinants of competition choice as explanatory vari-
ables: risk tolerance and beliefs (relative self-confidence, defined as the expected number of correct
answers for oneself minus that for the opponent), in addition to opponent gender, teacher gender and
cognitive ability score (Raven score). We add to that the baseline grit score to show the relationship
between competitiveness and grit, which provides the basis for investigating the eect of grit training
on competitiveness, the main motivation of the paper. The variables relative self-confidence, Raven
score and grit score are normalized to facilitate the interpretation of the coecient estimates.
As expected, higher expected performance relative to the opponent, risk tolerance and cognitive
score increase the propensity to compete in both stages. Note that opponent gender seems to have no
eect on the willingness to compete in either stage. We find that the grit score is also highly predictive
of competition choice in both stages. The predictive power of the grit score in the second stage is of
considerable size, rivaling that of risk tolerance and cognitive score: a one standard deviation increase
in the grit score is associated with a 5 percentage-point increase in the willingness to compete after
feedback.
What is the reason for the persistent gender gap in the willingness to compete? One explanation is
that if girls perform generally worse than boys, we could observe girls (rationally) having a higher ten-
dency to shy away from competition. This would be especially true in the second stage, after receiving
performance feedback. However, there is absolutely no gender gap in either piece-rate performance or
the first stage performance. As can be seen in Table 3, the performance of boys and girls is not statis-
tically dierent in either the piece-rate stage or the first choice stage, and naturally, their propensity
to receive negative/positive feedback after the first stage is also statistically the same (41.1% of girls
and 43.6% of boys receive negative feedback, p-value of the dierence=0.38). Interestingly, as shown
in Table 4 the observed gender gap in the second stage seems independent of the type of feedback
12
received in the first stage: girls’ willingness to compete in the second stage is lower than boys among
the children that received positive feedback as well as those that received negative feedback. We now
turn to the question of whether this gap is also prevalent in the treatment group.
5.3 Willingness to Compete and Gender Gaps in the Treatment Group
Table 5 shows that in the treatment group, boys and girls are equally likely to compete, both in the
first and the second stage. That is, the gender gap is erased in the treatment group. Figure 1 shows
this in visual clarity: it depicts the coecient estimates and confidence bands on the male dummy
in logit regressions that are run separately for treatment and control, in each of the two stages of
competition (controlling for all covariates shown in Table 5). It can be seen here that the gender gap,
which exists already in the first stage and remains in the second stage in the control group, is closed
in the treatment group. Turning to Table 5, we observe that relative confidence, risk tolerance, Raven
score and grit score are predictive of competitiveness in the treatment group, with grit score emerging
again as a significant predictor in both stages. Table 6 shows that there is no gender gap in the second
stage, regardless of the type of feedback received after the first stage.
How does the grit treatment work to close the gender gap? Are boys’ competitiveness unaected
by treatment while girls’ is? Do both genders become more competitive, with girls more so? We now
turn to estimate the eect of our treatment on competitive behavior in the first and the second stage,
on the whole sample as well as for boys and girls separately.
5.4 Treatment Eects on Competition Choice
In order to test the null hypothesis that the treatment had no impact on the experimental outcome
ys, competition choice in stage s={1,2}, we estimate the average treatment eect by conditioning
on baseline covariates:
ys
ij =0+1T reatmentj+Xij +Áij
where the dependent variable ys
ij is a dummy variable which equals 1 if student iin school jchose to
compete in stage s. The binary variable T reatmentjindicates the treatment status of school j, and
Xij is a vector of observables for student iin school jthat are potentially predictive of the outcome
measures we use. These observables include opponent gender (randomly assigned across all students),
cognitive score and risk tolerance collected at the baseline, and teacher gender. Note however that the
13
estimated eect sizes are not expected to be aected by the inclusion of these covariates due to random
assignment. The estimated coecient of the treatment dummy ˆ1yields the average treatment eect
on the treated. Estimates are obtained via logit regressions since the outcome considered here is binary.
In all empirical analyses where we estimate treatment eects, standard errors are clustered at the level
of the school, which is the unit of randomization.
Table 7 presents the estimated treatment eects on the willingness to compete in the first stage. The
first finding to note here is that the first-stage competition choices of all children are very responsive to
the treatment. This shows that willingness to compete is malleable in children. The second column in
the same table shows that the intervention is quite eective in inducing competitive behavior among
girls: treated girls are about 15 percentage points more likely to compete than those in the control
group. Boys’ competitiveness also responds positively to the treatment. Treated boys are about 9
percentage points more likely to compete relative to those in the control group. Both eects are
statistically significant at the 1% level. Although the point estimate for girls is larger, the dierence
between the treatment eect sizes does not reach statistical significance (p-value=0.12). Note, however,
that the dierence in the treatment eects across gender is sucient to mitigate the first stage gender
gap observed in the control sample; see Table 5 and Figure 1.
5.5 Treatment Eects on Competition Choice after Feedback
The two-stage nature of our experimental task provides us with an outcome measure that is useful for
assessing the impact of the intervention on behavior after receiving performance feedback. Recall that
before making the second competition decision, students receive feedback. Specifically, they find out
their absolute performance (how many correct answers they had) and whether they did better, worse or
equally well relative to their opponents in the first stage. This feedback is given to everyone, regardless
of the choice of incentive scheme in the first stage. Performance in the first competition stage and the
feedback received based on this performance are balanced across treatment groups (p-value=0.72 and
0.38, respectively).
Table 8 presents the estimated treatment eects on the propensity to compete in the second stage.
Similar to the first-stage results, treatment leads to an overall increase in the propensity to compete in
the second-stage, after feedback. However, here, we see a significant gender dierence in the response
to treatment: Grit training is very eective in making girls more competitive in response to feedback.
The estimated eect is of considerable size: treated girls are about 16 percentage points more likely
14
to compete relative to untreated girls. In the case of boys, however, the treatment does not have a
statistically significant eect on competitive behavior after feedback. Contrary to the first stage results,
the estimated coecients for girls and boys are significantly dierent (p-value=0.002). These results
suggest that while the intervention influenced the competitiveness of all children, it has dierential
impact across gender in the second stage, after feedback. We will explore the possible factors behind
this result in Section 5.7.
5.6 Treatment Eects on Payos
Based on performance, for some children it is payo-maximizing to compete, while for others it is better
to stay out. One can be concerned that interventions such as the one we evaluate in this paper may
lead to unintended inferior outcomes for some children, by inducing decisions that turn out to be bad
for payos ex-post. Analyzing how children’s decisions fare in terms of expected material payos can
shed light on these issues. To do this, we first calculate the probabilities of winning and tying for any
given performance level, using the empirical distribution of performances. Using these probabilities
along with realized performances, we calculate each child’s expected payofrom competition, and
analyze whether the child’s actual choice was payomaximizing ex-post. We do this separately for
each competition stage15. We then estimate the treatment eects on this outcome for stage 1 and 2.
Table 9 presents the estimated treatment eects on the propensity to make payo-maximizing
choices. We first note that overall, a little more than half of all children make a pay-omaximizing
choice in the control group (52% for Stage 1 and 59% for Stage 2). Next, we observe that treatment
does not cause inferior outcomes on average. On the contrary, treated children appear to be more
likely than untreated children to make the best choice from an expected payostandpoint. Moreover,
this favorable result seems to be driven by girls: treated girls are about 5 to 6 percentage points more
likely to make a payo-maximizing choice than untreated girls in both stages. The eect on boys, on
the other hand, is not statistically dierent from zero in either stage.
Next, we look at the estimated treatment eects on expected payodierences between the chosen
and unchosen incentive scheme for each stage. The expected payogain from having chosen a certain
incentive scheme is constructed as the dierence between the expected payofrom choosing competition
and the (alternative) payofrom choosing piece-rate for a child who chooses competition, and vice
versa for a child who chooses piece rate. This measure gives us the child’s expected gain from choosing
15It should be noted that this analysis does not make utility comparisons and therefore it is not an optimality analysis
per se, as it disregards eort costs, which are unobservable.
15
competition over piece-rate (or the other way around), which may be positive or negative ex-post,
depending on the performance of the child16. In Table 10, we clearly see that treated girls fare
significantly better than untreated girls in terms of expected gains, while boys’ expected gains are
unaected by the treatment. This analysis provides further evidence that the treatment does not lead
to inferior outcomes on average, either for boys or for girls. On the contrary, it leads to better outcomes
on average for girls.
Although the results are quite positive, we acknowledge that these are average eects, which may
conceal undesired distributional eects. In order to see the distributional impact of the treatment, we
estimate quantile treatment eects on expected payogains. The four panels in Figure 2 depict the
coecient estimates and 95% confidence bands for expected payogains for boys and girls in each
competition stage. At first glance, the figures show that treatment eects are generally non-negative
across quantiles in both stages, for both boys and girls. For girls, the eects are positive across
quantiles in both stages, and statistically significant in low and high quantiles. This is because very
low gains (large negatives) result from under-entry into the tournament by girls that would have done
well in the tournament, which is significantly lessened by the treatment. Positive treatment eects at
high gains are indicative of optimal entry into competition (from a payo-maximization perspective),
which is significantly more prevalent in the treatment group. Taken together, these results suggest
that the increase in competitiveness brought about by grit training does not harm girls (or boys) in
terms of payos at any point in the distribution. On the contrary, the intervention results in significant
eciency gains, suggesting that many able girls are staying away from competition in the baseline.
Further support for our evidence of eciency gains on the part of girls comes from our analysis
of heterogeneous treatment eects based on cognitive function, as measured by Raven’s progressive
matrices. Specifically, we re-estimate treatment eects on Stage 1 and Stage 2 choices for students
with below and above mean cognitive scores. Table 11 presents the results of this analysis for males
and females separately. Estimates presented in this table clearly show that the treatment eects on
competition choices are similar for low and high cognitive scores within females and within males. A
notable finding here is that the treatment seems to be very eective in inducing both groups of girls
to choose to compete, in both stages. This immediately brings to mind that treated girls with low
cognitive scores may fare worse than those in the control group in terms of expected gains. However,
Table 12 shows that this concern is unwarranted. While we observe that treated girls with high
16For calculating expected payos from competition, the empirical win and tie probabilities corresponding to the
child’s actual performance is used.
16
cognitive ability are significantly more likely to make payomaximizing choices in both stages (10
percentage points in Stage 1 and about 6 percentage points in Stage 2), there is no negative eect
on girls with lower cognitive ability in either stage: the average treatment eects are statistically
insignificant for this group (see columns 1 and 5). For boys with high cognitive ability, we estimate
a statistically significant treatment eect on payomaximizing choices in Stage 1 only (see columns
4 and 8). The estimated treatment eects for boys with low cognitive ability are similar to those we
obtain for girls with low cognitive ability, statistically zero.
5.7 Mechanisms of Impact
Which aspects of the treatment are likely to drive girls and boys into competition, and what is the
reason for the dierential impact that virtually eliminates the gender gaps observed in both stages
in the baseline? It may be that multiple factors are at work, and the relative weight of these may
be dierent for girls and boys. While we cannot possibly account for every factor that could play
a role, we can explore several major factors that might be relevant. One such factor that underlies
competition choice is beliefs. Recall that we elicit beliefs by asking children about their absolute
and relative expected performance, in both choice stages. More specifically, children are asked how
many questions they expect to answer correctly, and how many they expect their opponent to answer
correctly. We construct a relative self-confidence measure by taking (and normalizing) the dierence
between own expected performance minus the expectation about the opponent’s performance, which
can be a positive or a negative number. As a backdrop to what follows, we first note that in the
control group, controlling for actual performance, boys are more self-confident than girls in both the
first stage and the second stage (p-values are 0.03 and 0.08 respectively). This is consistent with the
literature on gender gaps in confidence in adults17. We then turn to analyzing the treatment eect on
relative self-confidence, among girls and boys.
Table 13 columns 1 and 4 show that children’s initial confidence levels are positively aected by the
treatment. However, as can be seen in columns 2 and 5, these eects seem to be coming mainly from
girls. Specifically, treated girls’ average confidence score is about 0.16 standard deviations higher than
that of untreated girls in the first stage, and this eect is statistically significant at the 5% level. The
eect size is about 0.13 standard deviations in the second stage, and again statistically significant at
the 5% level. While the estimated treatment eects are also positive for boys, they are not statistically
17see Croson and Gneezy (2009) for a review.
17
dierent from zero. The eect of the treatment on relative confidence in both stages can be seen in
Figure 3 as well. Here, we see that the gender gaps in confidence we observe in the control group do
not exist in the treatment group. Given that the piece-rate performance of girls is not dierent across
treatment status (p-value=0.70), this increase in relative beliefs is not driven by improvements in task
performance through treatment but is likely to indicate a true increase in self-confidence for similar
performance. This self-confidence improvement can explain why treated girls opt to compete more.
This finding is our first piece of evidence that the potential mechanism through which the treatment
mitigates the gender gap may be a boost in task-related confidence experienced by girls that received
the treatment18.
To explore the belief channel further and in particular to understand the widely dierential treat-
ment eects across gender in the second stage, we construct another outcome measure related to beliefs.
This measure is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the child expects a better performance
from herself in the second stage relative to her actual first stage performance. Recall that we inform
every child about their absolute performance after the first stage is completed and ask them to guess
their own performance (and their opponent’s performance) in the second stage before the second stage
starts. Table 14 presents the estimated treatment eects on this measure. Note first that about 51%
of the girls and and 54% of the boys believe that they can improve upon their first stage performance
in the control group. On this measure, we estimate an about 7 percentage point treatment eect for
girls, which is significant at the 1% level. For boys, we estimate a statistically zero treatment eect.
This analysis provides further evidence on the importance of the belief channel in explaining the treat-
ment eects on competitiveness. The treatment seems to induce more optimistic beliefs about future
performance on the part of girls for a given prior performance: treated girls are significantly more
likely to believe that they can improve upon their past performance than those in the control group.
This belief may lead them to opt into competition more in the second stage.
The previous analysis brings to mind that grit, which is expected to be positively influenced by the
treatment, may play a role, especially in the second stage. To explore this potential mechanism we
make use of our surveys, which are administered both at baseline and follow-up. First, we explore the
gender gap in the grit score at baseline and find that boys score 0.8 standard deviations higher than
girls on grit and the p-value of this estimate is 0.02. Against this finding, we estimate a statistically
insignificant gender gap for the treatment group. Figure 4 summarizes these results. Next, we estimate
18We do have more general confidence measures unrelated to our competition task, collected at baseline and follow-up.
We do not estimate a significant treatment eect on those measures.
18
the eect of the treatment on the grit score, controlling for the baseline grit score. Table 15 presents
the results. Here, we see that treated students report significantly higher grit than those in the control
group (the eect size is 0.31 standard deviations). While we estimate significant eects for both boys
and girls, the eect size for girls (0.37 standard deviations) is significantly larger than that of boys
(p-value of the dierence is 0.08). This is consistent with the finding that grit is one of the driving
forces of competitive behavior after feedback and with the result that treated girls are significantly
more likely to opt into competing than untreated girls after feedback.
While beliefs and improved grit/perseverance are strong candidates for potential mechanisms
through which the intervention may have aected competition choices, there are other possibilities.
One such possibility is that the treatment might have aected risk tolerance levels, inducing girls to
take more risk and choose to compete. While we do not have data on post-treatment risk tolerance for
sample 2, we have data to compare risk tolerance across the groups for sample 1. In unreported regres-
sions, we find that the grit treatment does not have a significant eect on risk tolerance (p=0.36). This
suggests that the impact of grit training on competitive behavior does not work through increasing
the tolerance for risk.
Overall, improved self-confidence and increased grit on the part of girls are likely to play a large
role in generating the dierential treatment eects we estimate. By boosting their confidence and per-
severance, treatment significantly reduces under-entry into the tournament and leads girls to compete
as much as boys do. A possible reason for this is the strong emphasis on ambitious goal setting, the
role of eort and the value of perseverance in the training material. A child who is exposed to this
optimistic view on performance and achievement may now believe that she can tackle a challenging
task, and she can always improve her performance with higher eort, which would lead to increased
selection into the tournament, regardless of the feedback received.
6 Concluding Remarks
Documenting, understanding the reasons for, and exploring policies to mitigate gender gaps in compet-
itiveness has been a very active area of research in economics in recent years. Considering competitive
behavior in a dynamic context where individuals choose an incentive scheme, receive performance
feedback and make a decision again, we document that grit is one of the driving forces of sustained
willingness to compete. We then explore whether competitive behavior can be influenced by an ed-
ucational intervention that aims to foster grit in the classroom environment, via a carefully designed
19
curriculum implemented by trained teachers. Using choices in a two-stage competition task as our
outcome variables, we evaluate the impact of this unique educational intervention.
We first show that the competition propensity of boys and girls are significantly dierent, even
in childhood. We then show that an educational intervention that aims to foster the non-cognitive
skill of grit can have a significant impact on both girls’ and boys’ competitiveness. This indicates
that competitiveness as an individual attitude is malleable in childhood through a targeted program
that promotes ambitious goal-setting and perseverance. The eect on competitiveness naturally has
implications for the gender gap as well. We estimate a statistically significant treatment eect on the
willingness to compete for both boys and girls in the first stage and this eect is bigger for girls, miti-
gating the first stage gender gap. Moreover, we find a significant treatment eect on competitiveness
after feedback, only for girls, entirely eliminating the second stage gender gap. Our data suggest that
improved self-confidence and enhanced grit on the part of girls is likely to be the main mechanism that
generates our results.
Coupled with the fact that the treatment is overall payo-improving for highly able girls, our results
indicate that fostering grit in the classroom environment can address one of the most debated gender
gaps in the literature without sacrificing eciency. In this sense, our paper provides a complement to
the interventions in the literature that close the gender gap by changing tournament rules and thereby
the material incentives for women. Incorporating the type of intervention proposed in this paper
into the classroom environment (or even the home environment) can be an easy and cost-eective
alternative from a policy perspective.
Finally, our data highlight the importance of studying competitiveness in a dynamic framework
where, as in real life, individuals receive performance feedback and decide whether or not to stick
with the chosen path. Performance feedback is ubiquitous in economic life and in education, and the
way it is interpreted may have profound impact on an individual’s subsequent decisions. Evaluations
of educational and other policies that aim to mitigate inecient gender gaps in competitiveness in
particular, and achievement in general, will be more comprehensive if their eects on dynamic choices
and their interactions with feedback are taken into account.
20
References
[1] Alan, S. and Ertac, S. (2014), “Good Things Come to Those Who (Are Taught How to) Wait:
Results from a Randomized Educational Intervention on Time Preference”, HCEO Working Paper.
[2] Alan, S., Boneva T. and Ertac S. (2016), “Ever Failed, Try Again, Succeed Better: Results from
a Randomized Educational Intervention on Grit”, HCEO Working Paper.
[3] Almas, I., Cappelen A., Salvanes, K., Sørensen, E. and Tungodden, B. (2014), “Willingness to
Compete: Family matters”, Management Science, forthcoming.
[4] Almlund, M., Duckworth, A.L., Heckman, J.J. and Kautz, T.D. (2011), “Personality Psychology
and Economics”, Handbook of the Economics of Education, pp. 1-181.
[5] Andersen, S., Ertac, S., Gneezy, U., List, J. A., & Maximiano, S. (2013), “Gender, competitive-
ness, and socialization at a young age: Evidence from a matrilineal and a patriarchal society”,
Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1438-1443.
[6] Andersen, S., Ertac, S., Gneezy, U., List, J. A., & Maximiano, S. (2014). “Gender, competitiveness,
and the response to performance feedback: Evidence from a matrilineal and a patriarchal society”,
Mimeo.
[7] Azmat, G. and Iriberri, N. (2010), “The Importance of Relative Performance Feedback Infor-
mation: Evidence from a Natural Experiment using High School Students”, Journal of Public
Economics, 94, pp. 435-452.
[8] Balafoutas, L., & Sutter, M. (2012), “Armative action policies promote women and do not harm
eciency in the laboratory”, Science, 335(6068), 579-582.
[9] Barankay, I. (2011), “Rankings and social tournaments: Evidence from a crowd-sourcing experi-
ment”, Wharton School of Business, University of Pennsylvania Working Paper.
[10] Blackwell, L., Trzesniewski, K.H. and Dweck, C.S. (2007), “Implicit Theories of Intelligence Pre-
dict Achievement Across an Adolescent Transition: A Longitudinal Study and an Intervention”,
Child Development, 78(1), pp. 246-263.
[11] Booth, A., & Nolen, P. (2012), “Choosing to compete: How dierent are girls and boys?”, Journal
of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81(2), 542-555.
21
[12] Borghans, L., Duckworth, A.L., Heckman, J.J. and ter Weel, B. (2008), “The Economics and
Psychology of Personality Traits”, Journal of Human Resources, 43(4), pp. 972-1059.
[13] Buser, T., Niederle, M. and Oosterbeek, H. (2014), “Gender, Competitiveness and Career
Choices”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 2014, 129 (3): 1409-1447.
[14] Cárdenas, J. C., Dreber, A., Von Essen, E., & Ranehill, E. (2012), “Gender dierences in com-
petitiveness and risk taking: Comparing children in Colombia and Sweden”, Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization, 83(1), 11-23.
[15] Croson, R., & Gneezy, U. (2009), “Gender dierences in preferences”, Journal of Economic liter-
ature, 448-474.
[16] Dreber, A., Von Essen, E. & Ranehill, E. (2014), "Gender and Competition in Adolescence: Tasks
Matter." Experimental Economics, 17(1): 154-172.
[17] Duckworth, A.L., Peterson, C., Matthews, M.D., and Kelly, D.R. (2007), “Grit: Perseverance and
Passion for Long-Term Goals”, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 92(6), pp. 1087-1101.
[18] Duckworth, A. L. and Quinn, P. D. (2009), “Development and validation of the Short Grit Scale
(Grit-S)”, Journal of Personality Assessment, 91, pp. 166-174.
[19] Dweck, C. Mindset: The New Psychology of Success. Random House Digital, Inc., 2006
[20] Eckel, C. C., and Füllbrunn, S. (2015), “Thar ‘She’ Blows? Gender, Competition and Bubbles
in Experimental Asset Markets” The American Economic Review, Volume 105, Number 2, pp.
906-920(15).
[21] Eriksson, T., Poulsen, A. and Villeval, M.C. (2009), “Feedback and Incentives: Experimental
Evidence”, Labour Economics, 16(6), pp. 679-688.
[22] Ertac, S., & Szentes, B. (2011), “The eect of information on gender dierences in competitiveness:
Experimental evidence”, TÜSAD-Koç University Economic Research Forum working paper series.
[23] Flory, J. A., Leibbrandt, A., & List, J. A. (2014), “Do Competitive Workplaces Deter Female
Workers? A Large-Scale Natural Field Experiment on Job-Entry Decisions”, The Review of
Economic Studies, rdu030.
22
[24] Eskreis-Winkler, L., Shulman, E.P., Beal, S. and Duckworth, A.L. (2014), “Survivor mission:
Why those who survive have a drive to thrive at work”, Journal of Positive Psychology, 9(3), pp.
209-218.
[25] Gneezy, U, Leonard, K.L. and List, J.A. (2009) “Gender Dierences in Competition: Evidence
from a Matrilineal and a Patriarchal Society”, Econometrica, 77(5), 1637-1664.
[26] Gill, D. and Prowse, V. (2014), “Gender dierences and dynamics in competition: The role of
luck”, Quantitative Economics 5 (2014), 351–376.
[27] Gneezy, U., Niederle, M. and Rustichini, A. (2003), “Performance in Competitive Environments:
Gender Dierences”, Quarterly Journal of Economics,118(3), 1049-1074.
[28] Gneezy, U. and Potters, J. (1997), “An experiment on risk taking and evaluation periods”, Quar-
terly Journal of Economics, 112(2), pp. 631-645.
[29] Heckman, J.J., Stixrud, J. and Urzua, S. (2006), “The Eects of Cognitive and Noncognitive
Abilities on Labor Market Outcomes and Social Behaviour”, Journal of Labor economics, 24, pp.
411-482.
[30] Heckman, J.J., Moon, S.H., Pinto, R., Savelyev, P.A. and Yavitz, A.Q. (2010), “The Rate of
Return to the High Scope Perry Preschool Program”, Journal of Public Economics, 94(1-2), pp.
114-128.
[31] Heckman, J.J., Pinto, R. and Savelyev, P.A. (2013), “Understanding the Mechanisms Through
Which an Influential Early Childhood Program Boosted Adult Outcomes”, American Economic
Review, 103(6), pp. 1-35.
[32] Heckman, J.J., Moon, S.H. and Pinto, R. (2014), “The Eects of Early Intervention on Abilities
and Social Outcomes: Evidence from the Carolina Abecedarian Study”, unpublished manuscript.
[33] Kautz, T., Heckman, J.J., Diris, R., ter Weel, B., Borghans, L. (2014), “Fostering and Measur-
ing Skills: Improving Cognitive and Non-cognitive Skills to Promote Lifetime Success”, NBER
Working Paper 20749.
[34] Khachatryan, K., Dreber, A., Von Essen, E., & Ranehill, E. (2015), “Gender and preferences
at a young age: Evidence from Armenia”. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 118,
318-332.
23
[35] Lee, S., Niederle, M., Kang, N. (2014), “Do Single-Sex Schools Make Girls More Competitive?”,
Economics Letters, 124(3), pp. 474–477.
[36] Maddie, S.R., Matthews, M.D., Kelly, D.R., Villarreal, B. and White, M. (2012), “The Role
of Hardiness and Grit in Predicting Performance and Retention of USMA Cadets”, Military
Psychology, 24, pp. 19-28.
[37] Niederle, M., Segal, C., & Vesterlund, L. (2013), “How costly is diversity? Armative action in
light of gender dierences in competitiveness”, Management Science, 59(1), 1-16.
[38] Niederle, M., & Vesterlund, L. (2007), “Do Women Shy Away from Competition? Do Men Com-
pete Too Much”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 2007, vol. 122(3), 1067-1101.
[39] Niederle, M., & Vesterlund, L. (2011), “Gender and competition”, Annual Review of Economics,
3(1), 601-630.
[40] Petrie, R., & Segal, C. (2014), “Gender dierences in competitiveness: The role of prizes”, Avail-
able at SSRN 2520052.
[41] Raven, J., Raven, J.C., & Court, J.H. (2004), “Manual for Raven’s Progressive Matrices and
Vocabulary Scales”, San Antonio, TX: Harcourt Assessment.
[42] Sutter, M., & Glätzle-Rützler, D. (2015), “Gender dierences in the willingness to compete emerge
early in life and persist”, Management Science, forthcoming.
[43] Sutter, M., Glätzle-Rützler, D., Balafoutas, L., & Czermak, S. (2015), “Canceling out early age
gender dierences in competition–an analysis of policy interventions”, Experimental Economics,
forthcoming.
[44] Wozniak, D., Harbaugh, W. T., & Mayr, U. (2014), “The menstrual cycle and performance
feedback alter gender dierences in competitive choices” Journal of Labor Economics, 32(1), 161-
198.
24
Tables
Table A: Evaluation Design
STUDY 1
STUDY 2
Patience
(6 schools)
Control
(8 schools)
Grit
(8 schools)
Control
(8 schools)
Baseline Data
March 2013
March 2013
May 2015
May 2015
Patience Treatment
Fall 2013
-
-
-
Grit Treatment
-
-
Fall 2015
-
Follow-up Data
May 2014
May 2014
Jan 2016
Jan 2016
25
Table 1: Randomization Balance
PANEL 1: Baseline Variables
Control Treatment
Male 0.52 -0.01
(0.02)
Age 9.51 -0.01
(0.03)
Raven Score (normalized) 0.03 -0.07
(0.13)
Math Grades (normalized) 0.02 -0.04
(0.12)
Risk Tolerance 2.28 0.12
(0.17)
Male Teacher 0.22 -0.04
(0.10)
Wealth (teacher reported) 2.72 0.14
(0.18)
Academic Success (teacher reported) 3.43 0.04
(0.08)
Grit Score (normalized) -.00 .00
(.10)
PANEL 2: Within Task Variables
Control Treatment
Correct Answers in Part 1 5.80 -0.30
(0.39)
Negative Feedback in Stage 1 0.42 0.04
(0.05)
Male Opponent 0.50 -0.01
(0.02)
Note: Each row reports coecients from a regression of the variable shown in the first column on
the treatment dummy. The first column reports the mean of the control, the second one reports the
dierence between the treatment and control. Panel 1 presents the balance for demographic variables
and baseline attitudes either reported by the child or the teacher. Panel 2 presents the balance for
i) the performance in the first period, ii) the proportion of negative feedback in Stage 1 and iii) the
proportion of male opponents. Standard errors, obtained via clustering at the school level, are reported
in parentheses.
26
Table 2: Gender Gap in Competition Choice (Control Sample)
Stage 1 Stage 2
(1) (2) (3) (4)
W/O Controls With Controls W/O Controls With Controls
Male 0.081*** 0.078*** 0.095*** 0.100***
(0.02) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Male opponent 0.026 0.005
(0.02) (0.02)
Risk tolerance 0.042*** 0.024**
(0.01) (0.01)
Raven Score 0.053*** 0.041***
(0.01) (0.01)
Male Teacher -0.038 -0.031
(0.04) (0.02)
Relative confidence S1 0.070***
(0.01)
Baseline Grit Score 0.028* 0.052***
(0.02) (0.01)
Relative confidence S2 0.133***
(0.01)
Observations 1380 1354 1377 1353
Standard errors clustered at the classroom level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates
are marginal eects from logistic regressions.
27
Table 3: Gender Dierence in Performance (Control Sample)
Piece-Rate Stage 1
(1) (2) (3) (4)
W/O Controls With Controls W/O Controls With Controls
Male -0.280 -0.215 -0.262 -0.209
(0.19) (0.18) (0.23) (0.21)
Male opponent -0.025 0.025
(0.18) (0.22)
Risk tolerance -0.090 -0.046
(0.06) (0.06)
Raven Score 1.304*** 1.397***
(0.11) (0.13)
Male Teacher -0.621 -0.474
(0.38) (0.42)
Observations 1379 1379 1382 1382
Standard errors clustered at the classroom level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported
estimates are OLS coecients.
Table 4: Feedback Type and Gender Gap in Competition Choice (Control Sample)
NonNegative Feedback Negative Feedback
(1) (2) (3) (4)
W/O Controls With Controls W/O Controls With Controls
Male 0.112*** 0.101*** 0.091** 0.090**
(0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)
Male opponent 0.005 0.010
(0.03) (0.03)
Risk tolerance 0.038*** 0.003
(0.01) (0.01)
Raven Score 0.087*** -0.026
(0.02) (0.02)
Male Teacher 0.038 -0.079
(0.04) (0.06)
Observations 786 786 574 574
Standard errors clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates are
marginal eects from logistic regressions.
28
Table 5: Gender Gap in Competition Choice (Treatment Sample)
Stage 1 Stage 2
(1) (2) (3) (4)
W/O Controls With Controls W/O Controls With Controls
Male 0.017 0.033 -0.048 -0.028
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)
Male opponent -0.039* -0.003
(0.02) (0.03)
Risk tolerance 0.044*** 0.028**
(0.01) (0.01)
Raven Score 0.023 0.053***
(0.01) (0.02)
Male Teacher 0.025 -0.016
(0.04) (0.03)
Relative confidence S1 0.097***
(0.02)
Baseline Grit Score 0.066*** 0.049***
(0.01) (0.02)
Relative confidence S2 0.122***
(0.02)
Observations 1212 1190 1215 1190
Standard errors clustered at the classroom level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates
are marginal eects from logistic regressions.
29
Table 6: Feedback Type and Gender Gap in Competition Choice (Treatment Sample)
NonNegative Feedback Negative Feedback
(1) (2) (3) (4)
W/O Controls With Controls W/O Controls With Controls
Male -0.013 -0.013 -0.043 -0.042
(0.04) (0.04) (0.05) (0.05)
Male opponent -0.003 -0.029
(0.03) (0.05)
Risk tolerance 0.031* 0.018
(0.02) (0.01)
Raven Score 0.059*** 0.022
(0.02) (0.02)
Male Teacher -0.013 -0.020
(0.05) (0.05)
Observations 646 646 566 566
Standard errors clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates are
marginal eects from logistic regressions.
Table 7: Treatment Eects on Competition Choice: Stage 1
(1) (2) (3)
All Females Males
Treatment 0.119*** 0.146*** 0.091***
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03)
Male opponent -0.003 -0.004 -0.002
(0.02) (0.02) (0.03)
Risk tolerance 0.041*** 0.044*** 0.037***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Raven Score 0.049*** 0.064*** 0.037**
(0.01) (0.01) (0.02)
Male Teacher -0.016 -0.016 -0.017
(0.03) (0.03) (0.04)
Control Mean 0.38 0.34 0.42
N 2592 1264 1328
Standard errors are clustered at the school level. * p<0.10
** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates are marginal
eects from logistic regressions.
30
Table 8: Treatment Eects on Competition Choice: Stage 2
(1) (2) (3)
All Females Males
Treatment 0.089*** 0.156*** 0.022
(0.03) (0.03) (0.04)
Risk tolerance 0.024*** 0.025** 0.023***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Male opponent 0.003 0.008 -0.001
(0.02) (0.02) (0.03)
Raven Score 0.074*** 0.072*** 0.075***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Male Teacher -0.040* -0.030 -0.050*
(0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Control Mean 0.45 0.40 0.49
N 2592 1263 1329
Standard errors are clustered at the school level. * p<0.10
** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates are marginal
eects from logistic regressions.
Table 9: Treatment Eects on PayoMaximizing Choice
Stage 1 Stage 2
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
All Females Males All Females Males
Treatment 0.041* 0.059** 0.024 0.029* 0.051** 0.008
(0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03)
Risk tolerance 0.027*** 0.022* 0.032*** 0.016** 0.012 0.019***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Male opponent 0.005 0.003 0.006 0.010 0.012 0.009
(0.02) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Raven Score 0.007 0.001 0.011 0.023*** 0.017 0.027**
(0.01) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Male Teacher 0.040 0.063 0.019 -0.004 0.039 -0.043
(0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Control Mean 0.52 0.48 0.55 0.59 0.56 0.62
N 2592 1264 1328 2592 1263 1329
Standard errors clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates
are marginal eects from logistic regressions.
31
Table 10: Treatment Eects on Expected PayoGains
Stage 1 Stage 2
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
All Females Males All Females Males
Treatment 1.893*** 2.812*** 0.994 0.941 1.718** 0.200
(0.58) (0.68) (0.73) (0.59) (0.74) (0.76)
Risk tolerance 0.765*** 0.825*** 0.706*** 0.286** 0.226 0.338**
(0.14) (0.20) (0.18) (0.13) (0.20) (0.14)
Male opponent 0.223 0.693 -0.210 -0.044 -0.155 0.066
(0.38) (0.61) (0.53) (0.31) (0.49) (0.55)
Raven Score 0.842*** 0.974*** 0.710** 1.513*** 1.376*** 1.594***
(0.19) (0.29) (0.29) (0.17) (0.25) (0.22)
Male Teacher 0.110 0.339 -0.135 -0.535 -0.020 -1.015*
(0.55) (0.74) (0.75) (0.47) (0.63) (0.54)
Control Mean -0.65 -1.74 0.37 1.69 0.81 2.50
N 2580 1259 1321 2584 1260 1324
Standard errors are clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates
are OLS coecients.
Table 11: Heterogeneous Treatment Eects on Competition Choice (High vs Low Cognitive Score)
Stage 1 Stage 2
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Fem_L Fem_H Male_L Male_H Fem_L Fem_H Male_L Male_H
Treatment 0.153*** 0.145*** 0.111*** 0.079* 0.172*** 0.146*** 0.006 0.031
(0.05) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04) (0.06) (0.03) (0.04) (0.05)
Male opponent -0.036 0.014 0.018 -0.016 -0.032 0.028 -0.071** 0.050
(0.04) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.05) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04)
Risk tolerance 0.033** 0.051*** 0.029* 0.044*** 0.017 0.031*** 0.015 0.028**
(0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.01) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Raven Score 0.035 0.097*** 0.028 0.052 0.036 0.170*** 0.038 0.073**
(0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.04) (0.03) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Male Teacher -0.051 0.008 -0.036 -0.002 -0.088 0.011 -0.062 -0.040
(0.06) (0.04) (0.06) (0.05) (0.07) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)
Control Mean 0.27 0.37 0.37 0.45 0.34 0.43 0.42 0.55
N 494 770 559 769 495 768 557 772
Standard errors are clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates are marginal eects
from logit regressions.
32
Table 12: Heterogeneous Treatment Eects on PayoMaximizing Choice (High vs Low Cognitive
Score)
Stage 1 Stage 2
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Fem_L Fem_H Male_L Male_H Fem_L Fem_H Male_L Male_H
Treatment -0.005 0.100** -0.023 0.062* 0.038 0.058** -0.017 0.028
(0.04) (0.04) (0.05) (0.03) (0.04) (0.03) (0.05) (0.04)
Male opponent -0.082** 0.055 -0.000 0.010 -0.023 0.037 0.004 0.011
(0.03) (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04) (0.05) (0.03)
Risk tolerance 0.013 0.028 0.015 0.046*** 0.008 0.011 0.008 0.028**
(0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Raven Score -0.071** 0.106*** -0.014 0.058* -0.073** 0.096*** 0.007 0.036
(0.03) (0.04) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.03)
Male Teacher 0.056 0.082 0.032 0.020 0.132** -0.002 -0.057 -0.027
(0.04) (0.05) (0.06) (0.04) (0.06) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04)
Control Mean 0.52 0.46 0.56 0.54 0.54 0.57 0.60 0.64
N 494 770 559 769 495 768 557 772
Standard errors are clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates are marginal eects
logit regressions.
Table 13: Treatment Eects on Confidence
Stage 1 Stage 2
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
All Females Males All Females Males
Treatment 0.142** 0.163** 0.126 0.092* 0.128** 0.061
(0.06) (0.07) (0.08) (0.05) (0.06) (0.06)
Risk tolerance -0.024* -0.034* -0.015 -0.001 -0.021 0.018
(0.01) (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.02) (0.02)
Male opponent 0.013 -0.014 0.037 0.017 0.049 -0.016
(0.05) (0.07) (0.05) (0.05) (0.06) (0.06)
Raven Score 0.004 -0.022 0.029 0.103*** 0.090*** 0.115***
(0.02) (0.02) (0.04) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Male Teacher -0.034 -0.140** 0.071 -0.129** -0.172** -0.088
(0.06) (0.07) (0.08) (0.05) (0.07) (0.06)
Observations 2555 1255 1300 2551 1251 1300
Standard errors clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported
estimates are coecients from OLS regressions. Dependent variable is the number of
questions the subject expects to solve minus the number of questions she expects the
opponent to solve, normalized.
33
Table 14: Treatment Eects on Belief to Improve upon First Stage Performance
(1) (2) (3)
All Females Males
Treatment 0.053** 0.073*** 0.032
(0.03) (0.03) (0.04)
Risk tolerance 0.006 0.022** -0.010
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Male opponent 0.000 -0.029 0.029
(0.02) (0.03) (0.02)
Raven Score -0.082*** -0.095*** -0.072***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.02)
Male Teacher -0.052** -0.032 -0.067*
(0.02) (0.02) (0.04)
Control Mean 0.52 0.51 0.54
N 2559 1255 1304
Standard errors clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05,
*** p<0.01. Reported estimates are marginal eects from logit
regressions. The dependent variable takes the value of 1 if the
subject believes that her performance in the second stage will
exceed her actual performance in the first stage, and zero otherwise.
Table 15: Treatment Eects on the Grit Score
(1) (2) (3)
All Females Males
Treatment 0.313*** 0.371*** 0.259***
(0.06) (0.06) (0.07)
Baseline Grit Score 0.312*** 0.308*** 0.314***
(0.03) (0.04) (0.03)
Risk tolerance -0.004 -0.018 0.008
(0.02) (0.02) (0.02)
Male opponent 0.026 0.053 -0.000
(0.04) (0.06) (0.05)
Raven Score 0.165*** 0.156*** 0.173***
(0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Male Teacher 0.022 -0.048 0.084
(0.07) (0.08) (0.07)
Observations 2216 1091 1125
Standard errors clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05,
*** p<0.01. Reported estimates are coecients from OLS regressions.
34
Figure 1: Gender Dierence in the Willingness to Compete: Stage 1 and Stage 2
The Figure presents the marginal eects (and confidence bands) on the “male” dummy obtained via
logistic regressions. Depicted coecient estimates are obtained by controlling for opponent’s gender,
risk attitude, Raven score and teacher’s gender. Confidence bands are obtained via clustered standard
errors (classroom level). C: Control, TR: Treatment.
35
Figure 2: Distribution of Treatment Eects on Expected PayoGains: Stage 1 and Stage 2
Figures plot the quantile treatment eects on expected payogains and 95% confidence bands. Upper
panels show Stage 1 results and lower panels show Stage 2 results for females and males separately.
The dashed lines indicate the estimated average treatment eects with the dotted lines showing the
confidence bands for the average treatment eect estimates.
36
Figure 3: Gender Dierence in Relative Confidence: Stage 1 and Stage 2
The Figure presents the OLS coecients on the “male” dummy. Depicted coecient estimates are
obtained by controlling for initial performance, opponent’s gender, risk attitude, Raven score and
teacher’s gender. Confidence bands are obtained via clustered standard errors (classroom level). C:
Control, TR: Treatment.
37
Figure 4: Gender Dierence in Grit Score
The Figure presents the OLS coecients on the “male” dummy. Depicted coecient estimates are
obtained by controlling for opponent’s gender, risk attitude, Raven score, teacher’s gender and baseline
grit score. Confidence bands are obtained via clustered standard errors (classroom level).
38
Appendix
A Screenshot from Education Materials and Sample Class Activities
The first picture is a screenshot from a video that depicts the brain when it is struggling with
difficult math problems. With sustained practice, the brain becomes bigger and stronger. The
first and the second posters (made by children) are about quitting and unfounded fear of
math, with the second one translating as: “I never quit”. The third activity relates to goal-
setting, where each student posts their monthly target and updates it during the month.
39
Questions Used for Constructing the Grit Score
4-point item scale: completely agree, agree, disagree, completely disagree
1. I don’t like it when people (my teacher, parents, friends) make comments and suggestions about
how to improve my performance in a class, game or task that I am not very good at.
2. When I receive a bad result on a test it is because the test was unfairly hard.
3. I like school work best which makes me think hard, even if I make a lot of mistakes.
4. When I receive a bad result on a test I work harder.
5. Setbacks discourage me.
6. If I think I will lose in a game, I do not want to continue playing.
7. If I set a goal and see that it’s harder than I thought I easily lose interest.
8. When I receive a bad result on a test I spend less time on this subject and focus on other
subjects that I’m actually good at.
9. I work hard in tasks.
10. I prefer easy homework where I can easily answer all questions correctly.
11. If I’m having diculty in a task, it is a waste of time to keep trying. I move on to things which
I am better at doing.
40
Instructions for the Competition Task
Today we are going to play a game with you. At the end of the game, you will get to choose gifts from
this gift bag [show gift bag]. You will be asked to make some decisions in the game. How many gifts
you earn will depend on your decisions, and your performance in a task. We will now explain the rules
for this. Please listen very carefully. You can raise your hand if you have questions about the rules.
But in all the decisions you make, you should think to yourself and not tell your decision out loud to
others, OK? There is no right or wrong decision in this game. Everyone is free to choose what he/she
wants.
The game will consist of three parts: Part 1, Part 2, and Part 3. Only one of these parts will count
to determine your rewards. At the very end of the game, we will have a draw. Here are pieces of paper
with 1, 2 and 3 written on it. [Show papers] We will put these in a bag and draw one. Whichever part
comes out, only your decisions and performance in that part will count for rewards. This means, the
gifts do not accumulate in every part. You get rewards only based on what happens in the randomly
drawn part. Let’s give an example. Suppose someone would earn 3 gifts from the 1st part, 5 from the
2nd and 4 from the 3rd. In the draw at the end, Part 2 came out. How many gifts does this person
actually get? 5. Not 12, because the gifts do not accumulate. Any questions? OK.
Now, the task in this game will be to add numbers. In each question, there are two 2-digit numbers
and 1 one-digit number to be added. For example, [written on the board] 75+80+4=?, 72+47+8=?.
You will be given many addition questions like this. Now, we will distribute workbooks. There are
many pages in this workbook. It is extremely important that you do not turn over a page before we
tell you to do so, or go back to a previous page. Everyone should be at the same page at any given
time. OK? We are also going to give you a separate sheet of paper with some questions on it. First,
just write your name on everything you get. Then put the single sheet of paper aside with written side
down. That is for later. Once you write your name, please wait and do not open any pages. Now, I
will explain the rules for the 1st part of the game. In this part, you will be given 2.5 minutes. During
this time, you will try to do as many addition questions as you can. There will be many such questions
on your sheet. If this part (Part 1) gets drawn at the end of the game, you will earn gifts as follows:
every question you solve correctly in this part will mean one gift of your choice from the gift bag. The
more questions you solve, the more gifts you get. If you do 1 right, you get 1 gift, if you do 4 you get
4, if you do 7, you get 7, so on and so forth. Is this clear? [If no questions] Are you ready? OK, on
the count of three, everyone will turn the page to start. 3, 2, 1, Start! [At the end of 2.5 minutes] OK,
41
everyone turn the page! You should now see the waiting page, Page 2. Stay there, OK?
Now, we played this same game, before you, in other classes in other schools. Those children were
also 4th graders like you are. We also timed them on the exact same task with 2.5 minutes, and we
recorded how many sums each student did correctly in all three parts of the game. Now, we will ask
you something about the task you just did. Remember, you will think to yourself and not say anything
out loud, OK? We randomly selected, from those other classes in other schools where we played the
game before, one boy and one girl. One is called Batuhan, another called Merve [note: Batuhan is a
common boys’ name, Merve a common girls’ name in Turkey]. Now, we will ask you to guess: which
of them do you think did more questions right in 2.5 minutes? Batuhan more, Merve more, or did
they do equally well? If you guess correctly, you will get an extra, smaller gift. OK? Now turn the
page. You’ll be on Page 3. Circle your guess there, and turn the page [children see a waiting page]
Now, remember we told you we did this game in other classes in other schools before. We will match
each one of you, randomly, with one student from that group. You will not know who that student
is. You will never see them, you will not get to meet them. For example, let’s say, one of you, got
matched with somebody from another class, called Hakan. We had given Hakan a number when we
visited that class. Say, student number 1024. You will not know that you got matched with Hakan.
The only thing you will know is whether your matched student is a boy or a girl. Let’s take another
one of you. Suppose you were matched with student number 1038. You will not know who this person
is. But you will know whether it’s a girl or a boy. OK? Keep this in mind for now.
Now, we will explain the rules of the 2nd part of the game. In this part, the task is the same.
You will again do addition questions. And again, you will have 2.5 minutes. However, in this part,
you will choose how you earn gifts. You have two options: One option is “per-question”. [Write on
board: Per-question] What does this mean? If you choose this, for every addition question you answer
correctly you earn one gift. That is, 2 questions right=2 gifts, 4 questions right=4 gifts, 7 questions
right=7 gifts, so on and so forth. [Write on board: Every correct answer=1 gift] The other option is
“Competition”. [Write on board: Competition] Remember that every one of you is going to be matched
with another student? If you choose competition, you will be competing with that matched student.
In this case, how many gifts you earn will depend on how many questions you do correctly and how
many the matched student did correctly. We have here, recorded, the number of correct questions
solved by each of the matched students in each part of the game. If you do more questions right than
your matched student in Part 2, that is, if you outperform that student, you get not 1, but 3 gifts for
42
each question you solve correctly. [Write on board: Better: Each correct answer=3 gifts] But if you
do less questions right than your matched student, that is if he/she does better than you, you get zero
gifts [Write on board] If you do an equal number of correct questions as your matched student, you
get 1 gift for each question you solve correctly. [Write on board: Tied: Each correct answer=1 gift] Is
this clear? Now, let’s give some examples. Suppose that I chose the per-question option. Suppose that
I had 5 questions correct. [Write performances on board] How many gifts do I get? 5x1=5. It does
not matter what my matched student had done. Suppose that I chose to compete. How many gifts
do I get? Suppose my matched student had 4 questions correct. I outperformed the matched student,
so I get 5x3=15 gifts. What if the matched student had 7 questions correct? The matched person
outperformed me, so I get 0 gifts. What if the matched student had 5 questions correct, like I did? It
is a tie, so I get 5x1= 5 gifts. [Give 2 more examples, make sure students fully understand] Now let’s
give another example. Suppose that I chose piece-rate and got 7 questions right. How many gifts do I
get? 7x1=7 gifts. It is 7 regardless of what my matched student’s performance. Now suppose that I
chose competition. Suppose my matched student had less than 7 questions right. How many gifts do I
get? My performance was better, so I get 7x3=21 gifts. Suppose that my matched student had more
questions right than me. What do I get? I get 0 gifts. Suppose that my matched student also had 7
questions right. What do I get? 7x1=7 gifts. Did everyone understand? Do you have any questions?
Now, on your workbooks, there will be an ID number corresponding to the student you were
matched with. And you will see if this person is a boy or a girl. Now everyone turn the page. Do
you see it?. Now please think carefully and silently. If Part 2 is chosen for payment, based on which
option would you like to get gifts? Please circle what you want, and turn the page. OK. Now, we will
ask you two questions. As you know, every one of you is matched with a student from another school
and class. Everyone, even if they did not choose to compete, has a matched student. Now, please
think. Every part of this game has 16 addition questions. How many questions do you think you will
get right in Part 2? And how many do you think your matched student got right? Think carefully
because every correct guess can get you an extra small gift. At the end of the game, we will pick
3 students among you randomly. We will look at their guesses. For each correct guess, we will give
them an extra small gift. Understood? Now please everyone turn the page and make your guesses. Is
everyone done? Now, you will start doing the questions in Part 2 and will have 2.5 minutes again. One
thing to note–you should not stop solving questions just because you’ve already reached your guess
and want to be consistent with it. Why? Because solving more questions brings you more gifts than
43
being consistent with your guess. So to get more gifts, you should try to do as many as you can in the
time you are given. OK. Is everyone ready? Turn the page, and start on the count of 3. [When time
is up] Everyone turn the page immediately. You’ll see Page 7 (a waiting page).
Now, we will come to each of your desks. We will calculate how many questions you did, and
compare it with your matched student’s performance. We will mark on your sheet how many you did
correctly. We will also mark whether you have done more, the matched student has done more, or you
both did the same number of correct questions. Everyone will get this information. You should be
extremely quiet here and not tell anyone the information you got. Now while you are waiting, please
take that separate sheet we distributed at the start. There are some questions for you there. Please
start filling that in. [Note: Students work on a short questionnaire to fill the time when they are waiting
for their performance to be calculated and feedback given. When marking, empty answer blanks were
crossed over with a pen so that the child cannot go back and change performance. Experimenters wrote
the number of correctly solved questions and used a code on the workbooks to make the performance
comparison, and circled the outcome of the comparison on the student’s feedback page.] So, did
everyone see how many they got right? Did everyone see whether they did more, less or equal number
of questions with their matched student? You know how many you got right. You know whether it
was more, less or equal. But notice, you do not know how many more or how many less you did than
the matched student.
Now, we will start the 3rd part of the game. In this part, you will again do addition problems in 2.5
minutes. Your matched student is the same student as in Part 2 for this part. Remember that those
matched students also did this same task for 3 periods. We also recorded how many each matched
student did correctly in the 3rd part. Now please think. Again, you have 2 options for how you earn
gifts. You can choose per question, or you can choose to compete with the matched student. If you
choose per-question, for every correct answer, you get 1 gift. If you choose to compete, you get 3 gifts
per correct answer you have, but only if you do more questions than your matched student did in Part
3. If you do less, you get zero gifts. If you do equal, you get 1 gift per correct answer. Now, everybody
turn the next page. There you will make your decision for Part 3. If Part 3 is drawn at the end of the
game for reward, you will get gifts according to what you choose here. Did everyone decide? OK, now
turn the page. You will again make guesses. How many questions do you think you will get right in
Part 3? How many questions do you think your matched student did in Part 3? Don’t forget, again,
every correct guess can get you an extra small gift if you are one of the 3 people chosen. Now make
44
your guesses and wait, do not turn the page. Everyone ready? OK, now on the count of 3, turn the
page, and start! [When time is up] Everyone stop and turn the page!
45
Table 16: Treatment Eects by Disaggregated Treatment Status
Stage 1 Stage 2
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
All Females Males All Females Males
Grit 0.169*** 0.181*** 0.157*** 0.150*** 0.218*** 0.082**
(0.02) (0.04) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04)
Grit+Patience 0.094*** 0.137*** 0.049* 0.019 0.089** -0.051
(0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04)
Patience 0.061 0.073 0.051 -0.046 -0.040 -0.058
(0.06) (0.07) (0.07) (0.04) (0.04) (0.09)
Male 0.045** 0.030
(0.02) (0.03)
Risk tolerance 0.042*** 0.045*** 0.039*** 0.027*** 0.028*** 0.026***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Male opponent -0.002 -0.004 0.001 0.005 0.010 0.002
(0.01) (0.02) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03)
Raven Score 0.051*** 0.064*** 0.040** 0.083*** 0.080*** 0.083***
(0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Male Teacher -0.024 -0.022 -0.029 -0.056** -0.047 -0.065**
(0.03) (0.03) (0.04) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Control Mean 0.36 0.32 0.40 0.45 0.40 0.49
N 2592 1264 1328 2592 1263 1329
Standard errors are clustered at the school level. * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Reported estimates
are marginal eects from logistic regressions.
46
... Тематична група «Конкурентоспроможність жінок на ринку праці» уможливлює виявлення потенціалу рис особистості, або некоґнітивних навичок як потужних предикторів конкурентоспроможності на ринку праці. В умовах війни жінки змушені порушувати стереотипні соціальні норми та демонструвати такі некоґнітивні навички, як мотивація, сміливість і наполегливість, які пов'язані з іншою особистісною рисою, а саме конкурентоспроможністю (Alan, 2019). Останнім часом з'явилася велика кількість емпіричних робіт, які наводять докази того, що схильність до конкуренції також пов'язана з успіхом на ринку праці та величиною заробітної плати (Lackner, 2021;Lüthi, 2023). ...
Article
Full-text available
The article aims to outline the trends of gender professional segregation occurring in Ukraine during the military conflict. Materials and Methods. The research was carried out with the use of qualitative methods. A content analysis was chosen for this study. The material consists of online textual publications, which include interviews with managers, specialists, and employees of the State Employment Center. It also includes interviews in which women residing on the territory of Ukraine share their experiences of employment and work during the war. Results and Discussion. In Ukraine today, two factors operate in parallel. On the one hand, there is an urgent need to fill vacancies in professions that have traditionally been dominated by men. On the other hand, the financial situation of women is on the decline. Women are forced to rethink their gender identity in the family and in society because of financial difficulties and their inability to guarantee a minimum of financial stability for themselves and their families. This leads them to be willing to accept jobs with working conditions that are particularly harmful and difficult. Employment opportunities for women are increasing due to differentiated demand, which contributes to the reduction of horizontal gender segregation. One factor that impedes this process is the demand for professions traditionally considered women’s domains, which do not require basic skills, and for which demand increased during the war. These professions are mainly related to manufacturing and working specialties. Given that educated and skilled women occupy blue-collar jobs, we can expect vertical segregation to intensify during wartime, when gender differences are manifested in positions and roles with differing status or potential for advancement. In the area of state gender policy, Ukraine has business development initiatives that reduce the gender gap in women’s access to assets and capital to invest in profitable entrepreneurial industries. However, these initiatives only involve a limited number of women and cannot be associated with radical gender changes in society. At the same time, the positive aspects of reducing horizontal gender segregation observed in Ukraine during wartime may be negated by the lack of or insufficient incentives for the development of preschool education. Thus, there are few effective levers to overcome gender segregation in Ukraine in the short and medium term. Achieving gender equality in the labor market is practically declaratory. Conclusions. In the context of the wartime crisis, gender segregation is a significant issue with negative consequences. A market specifically for women’s labor is emerging, and the social status of women’s work is declining compared to pre-war times. This situation may reinforce societal stereotypes that view men as more suitable for leadership positions, potentially decreasing women’s motivation and career aspirations.
... Тематична група «Конкурентоспроможність жінок на ринку праці» уможливлює виявлення потенціалу рис особистості, або некоґнітивних навичок як потужних предикторів конкурентоспроможності на ринку праці. В умовах війни жінки змушені порушувати стереотипні соціальні норми та демонструвати такі некоґнітивні навички, як мотивація, сміливість і наполегливість, які пов'язані з іншою особистісною рисою, а саме конкурентоспроможністю (Alan, 2019). Останнім часом з'явилася велика кількість емпіричних робіт, які наводять докази того, що схильність до конкуренції також пов'язана з успіхом на ринку праці та величиною заробітної плати (Lackner, 2021;Lüthi, 2023). ...
Article
The article aims to outline the trends of gender professional segregation occurring in Ukraine during the military conflict. Materials and Methods. The research was carried out with the use of qualitative methods. A content analysis was chosen for this study. The material consists of online textual publications, which include interviews with managers, specialists, and employees of the State Employment Center. It also includes interviews in which women residing on the territory of Ukraine share their experiences of employment and work during the war. Results and Discussion. In Ukraine today, two factors operate in parallel. On the one hand, there is an urgent need to fill vacancies in professions that have traditionally been dominated by men. On the other hand, the financial situation of women is on the decline. Women are forced to rethink their gender identity in the family and in society because of financial difficulties and their inability to guarantee a minimum of financial stability for themselves and their families. This leads them to be willing to accept jobs with working conditions that are particularly harmful and difficult. Employment opportunities for women are increasing due to differentiated demand, which contributes to the reduction of horizontal gender segregation. One factor that impedes this process is the demand for professions traditionally considered women’s domains, which do not require basic skills, and for which demand increased during the war. These professions are mainly related to manufacturing and working specialties. Given that educated and skilled women occupy blue-collar jobs, we can expect vertical segregation to intensify during wartime, when gender differences are manifested in positions and roles with differing status or potential for advancement. In the area of state gender policy, Ukraine has business development initiatives that reduce the gender gap in women’s access to assets and capital to invest in profitable entrepreneurial industries. However, these initiatives only involve a limited number of women and cannot be associated with radical gender changes in society. At the same time, the positive aspects of reducing horizontal gender segregation observed in Ukraine during wartime may be negated by the lack of or insufficient incentives for the development of preschool education. Thus, there are few effective levers to overcome gender segregation in Ukraine in the short and medium term. Achieving gender equality in the labor market is practically declaratory. Conclusions. In the context of the wartime crisis, gender segregation is a significant issue with negative consequences. A market specifically for women’s labor is emerging, and the social status of women’s work is declining compared to pre-war times. This situation may reinforce societal stereotypes that view men as more suitable for leadership positions, potentially decreasing women’s motivation and career aspirations.
Article
Full-text available
Creativity and grit are widely recognized as vital components for the success and prosperity of individuals, even more so for younger people who will have to deal with the complex challenges connected to the digital era. Yet, whether these skills can be learnt or are innate traits is still subject to debate, which is further complicated by the difficulty of defining and, in turn, assessing these concepts. In this study, we challenge the idea that creativity and grit cannot be learnt and show that creative pedagogy activities, such as those offered by FabLabs, are powerful tools to enhance these non-cognitive skills. We conduct a randomized controlled trial in which 710 students from five Italian high schools are randomly assigned to creative STEM courses. The courses are delivered by FabLabs, small-scale workshops that offer access to tools for digital fabrication and employ a hands-on pedagogical approach expected to impact students’ creativity and grit positively. Assignment to the courses is at the class level: only students in classes randomly selected to join the Fablab activities can participate, and they may decide whether to enrol or not on a voluntary basis. We address noncompliance by adopting an instrumental variable approach. We use two modalities to measure creativity: a self-assessment through the Short Scale of Creative Self and an assessment made by an independent expert using an index of creativity developed by the authors. While the effect on self-assessed creativity is not significant, results show that the external, independent assessment of students’ creativity can capture a significant effect of Fablabs’ courses. It also emerges that FabLab activities have a positive significant effect on students’ grit, measured through the Duckworth scale. The encouraging results obtained for a relatively small sample of students should prompt a replication of the experiment on a broader scale.
Article
In this paper, we show that competitive female role models reduce women’s perceived stereotype threat and increase their willingness to compete. Competitive male role models have the opposite effect: they reduce women’s willingness to compete, and the gender gap in tournament entry increases. Results are strongest for the best performing women who would benefit most from competing. Role models have no impact on low performing women, and on men.
Article
High-pay, high-status jobs are competitive and male-dominated and typically demand long work hours. The authors study the role of competition in producing the latter two outcomes using two field experiments. In the first, they find that paying tournament prizes for performance induces both men and women to work longer, but that men respond more than women to the high-prize tournament. In the second, men are more likely than women to choose tournament-based compensation over a wage rate for larger prizes. These results demonstrate that high-stakes workplace competition can fuel gender inequality both directly, because men are more likely to enter and win tournaments, and indirectly, by raising work hours, which hurts women who face greater time demands in household production.
Article
In the past several decades, the experimental method has lent deep insights into economics. One area that has contributed is the experimental study of children, where advances as varied as the evolution of human behaviors that shape markets and institutions to how early life influences shape later life outcomes, have been explored. We first develop a framework for economic preference measurement that provides a lens into how to interpret data from experiments with children. Next, we survey work that provides general empirical insights within our framework and provide a comprehensive summary of experimental methods used with children. Finally, we provide 10 tips for pulling off experiments with children, including factors such as taking into account child competencies, causal identification, and logistical issues related to recruitment and implementation. We envision the experimental study of children as a high-growth research area in the coming decades as social scientists begin to more fully appreciate that children are active participants in markets who (might) respond predictably to economic incentives. (JEL C90, D11, D83, D91, J13, J16, Z13)
Article
Full-text available
We show that grit, a non-cognitive skill that has been shown to be highly predictive of achievement, is malleable in the childhood period and can be fostered in the classroom environment. Our evidence comes from the evaluation of a randomized educational intervention implemented in two independent elementary school samples in Istanbul. Outcomes are measured via a novel incentivized real effort task and performance in standardized tests. We find that treated students are 1) more likely to choose to undertake a more challenging and more rewarding task against an easier but less rewarding alternative, less likely to give up after failure, 3) more likely to exert effort to accumulate task-specific ability, and consequently, 4) more likely to succeed and collect higher payoffs. The intervention also has a large positive impact on students' standardized test scores. Treated students score 0.28 standard deviations higher in a standardized math test, and 0.13 standard deviations higher in a standardized Turkish test at follow-up.
Article
There is a growing interest in behavioral incentive schemes exploiting people preference about how they rank compared to others as a non-monetary mechanism to shape effort. In this paper we present evidence from a crowd-sourcing experiment where employees were given feedback about how they rank in terms of performance compared to others doing the same task. The context is such that rank had no implication for current or future compensation. Compared to a control group with no rank feedback, employees who received feedback about their rank were less likely to return to work and also less productive on the job.
Article
We study the effect of providing relative performance feedback information on performance under piece-rate incentives. A natural experiment that took place in a high school offers an unusual opportunity to test this effect in a real-effort setting. For one year only, students received information that allowed them to know whether they were above (below) the class average as well as the distance from this average. We exploit a rich panel data set and find that the provision of this information led to an increase of 5% in students’ grades. Moreover, the effect was significant for the whole distribution. However, once the information was removed the effect disappeared. To rule out the concern that the effect may be driven by teachers within the school, we verify our results using national level exams (externally graded) for the same students, and the effect remains.
Article
This paper studies the role of family background in explaining differences in the willingness to compete in a cognitive task. By combining data from a lab experiment conducted with a fairly representative sample of adolescents in Norway and high-quality register data on family background, we show that family background is fundamental in two important ways. First, boys from low socioeconomic status families are less willing to compete than boys from better-off families, even when controlling for confidence, performance, risk preferences, time preferences, social preferences, and psychological traits. Second, family background is crucial for understanding the large gender difference in the willingness to compete. Girls are much less willing to compete than boys among children from better-off families, whereas we do not find any gender difference in willingness to compete among children from low socioeconomic status families. Our data suggest that the main explanation of the role of family background is that the father's socioeconomic status is strongly associated with boys' willingness to compete. We do not find any association between the willingness to compete for boys or girls and the mother's socioeconomic status or other family characteristic that may potentially shape competition preferences, including parental equality and sibling rivalry.
Article
Rank-order relative-performance evaluation, in which pay, promotion and symbolic awards depend on the rank of workers in the distribution of performance, is ubiquitous. Whenever firms use rank-order relative-performance evaluation, workers receive feedback about their rank. Using a real-effort experiment, we aim to discover whether workers respond to the specific rank that they achieve. In particular, we leverage random variation in the allocation of rank among subjects who exerted the same effort to obtain a causal estimate of the rank response function that describes how effort provision responds to the content of rank-order feedback. We find that the rank response function is U-shaped. Subjects exhibit 'first-place loving' and 'last-place loathing', that is subjects increase their effort the most after being ranked first or last. We discuss implications of our findings for the optimal design of firms' performance feedback policies, workplace organizational structures and incentives schemes.
Article
In Western societies, it is generally known that men have a greater taste for competition than women. However, the determinants of the decision to enter competitions are still not fully understood. The aim of this paper is twofold. We first evaluate how participants update their beliefs after receiving feedback informing them of whether their performance is below or above the median performance. Second, we are interested in how men and women react to this information in terms of competitive entry. Our first result is that participants, and women in particular, react more strongly to the feedback they receive than would a Bayesian agent. As far as entry into competition is concerned, below-median participants adjust their entry decision according to the competition they expect to face, while above-median participants do not. However, the behaviour behind these results is quite different for men and women: women mainly react to information on their own performance, while men seem to respond more to their beliefs over the competition they will face. Moreover, most of the effect of feedback and the information regarding the level of the competition on the decision to compete seems to operate via beliefs.
Article
This article establishes that a low-dimensional vector of cognitive and noncognitive skills explains a variety of labor market and behavioral outcomes. Our analysis addresses the problems of measurement error, imperfect proxies, and reverse causality that plague conventional studies. Noncognitive skills strongly influence schooling decisions and also affect wages, given schooling decisions. Schooling, employment, work experience, and choice of occupation are affected by latent noncognitive and cognitive skills. We show that the same low-dimensional vector of abilities that explains schooling choices, wages, employment, work experience, and choice of occupation explains a wide variety of risky behaviors.