ChapterPDF Available

The Multidimensional Adequacy and Efficiency of European Pension Systems: the Ranking and Relationships

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

The paper discusses the issue of the adequacy and efficiency of European pension systems. The author perceives the adequacy and efficiency as multidimensional categories expressing the " goodness " of contemporary pension systems. Adequacy refers to the social aspect of pensions whereas efficiency reflects its economic conditions, however broadly understood, including not only financial sustainability, but also the impact pensions have on the labour market. The main goal of the study is to evaluate the multidimensional adequacy and efficiency of European pension systems and to find possible relationships between these two categories of a pension system. The method employed in the study is mainly based on the multidimensional statistical analysis and correlation analysis. The data used in the analysis comes from Eurostat and covers 30 countries in the years 2007 – 2011. The study allows to identify the change in the relationship between synthetic adequacy and synthetic efficiency in a given period from negative to positive one. The paper supports the view that in the long run efficiency is a necessary condition for income adequacy.
Content may be subject to copyright.
128
The Multidimensional Adequacy and Efficiency of European Pension
Systems: the Ranking and Relationships
Filip Chybalski
Lodz University of Technology
Department of Management
Piotrkowska 266
Lodz, 90-924
Poland
e-mail: filip.chybalski@p.lodz.pl
Abstract
The paper discusses the issue of the adequacy and efficiency of European pension systems. The author
perceives the adequacy and efficiency as multidimensional categories expressing the “goodness” of
contemporary pension systems. Adequacy refers to the social aspect of pensions whereas efficiency
reflects its economic conditions, however broadly understood, including not only financial
sustainability, but also the impact pensions have on the labour market. The main goal of the study is to
evaluate the multidimensional adequacy and efficiency of European pension systems and to find possible
relationships between these two categories of a pension system. The method employed in the study is
mainly based on the multidimensional statistical analysis and correlation analysis. The data used in the
analysis comes from Eurostat and covers 30 countries in the years 2007 2011. The study allows to
identify the change in the relationship between synthetic adequacy and synthetic efficiency in a given
period from negative to positive one. The paper supports the view that in the long run efficiency is a
necessary condition for income adequacy.
Keywords: pension, adequacy, efficiency, synthetic indicators
JEL codes: J26, J11, J14, J18, J21
1. Introduction
Due to deteriorating demographics, pension systems have been constantly evolving all over the
world for few decades. The best model has been sought by many countries, however, the reforms or
retreats from reforms, like in CEE countries in 2008-2013, suggest that the optimal solutions in pension
security have not been found so far. Comparative analyses across many countries may serve for looking
for better pension system models, since they are usually based on empirical solutions in this field instead
of theoretical models simulated for a given country. Therefore, the main goal of the study is to evaluate
the multidimensional adequacy and efficiency of European pension systems and to find possible
relationships between these two categories. The paper includes the comparison of 30 European pension
systems and the proposition of a ranking based on two main criteria: income adequacy and efficiency of
pensions. However, these two categories are treated as multidimensional ones and their dimensions are
defined. The Author also tries to find any relationships between adequacy and efficiency. The study
enables two important questions to be answered.
Question 1: is it possible to identify any models of pension systems which in the period of 2007-
2011 seem to work better than others?
Question 2: are there any relationships between the adequacy and efficiency of pension systems?
To solve the stated problem, first the concept of a pension system as well as pension adequacy
and efficiency are defined. Then the dimensions of these two categories and indicators serving for their
measurement are proposed. Subsequently, simple adequacy and efficiency indicators are aggregated into
synthetic indicators and on this basis the ranking of pension systems is presented. The last stage of the
study includes the correlation analysis of the relationships between adequacy and efficiency. The
interpretation of the results is presented in the conclusion section.
129
2. Pension Adequacy and Efficiency: the Concepts and Idea of Measurement
A pension system is defined in literature from two different perspectives: micro- and
macroeconomic one. From the microeconomic perspective, a pension system is a tool of consumption
smoothing in the life cycle (Barr and Diamond 2006; Blake 2006; Góra, 2008). From the
macroeconomic perspective a pension system is a tool for dividing the current GDP between the working
generation and the generation of pensioners (Góra, 2008). Therefore, future GDP is crucial in a pension
system, since the consumption of future pensioners will be determined by future production, generated
mainly by the generation of their children (Barr and Diamond, 2006). These micro- and macroeconomic
perspectives of studying a pension system allow perceiving them as an input-output model in which
adequacy and efficiency are directly connected. Namely, a pension system is a system in which some
inputs (mainly pension expenditure, but also administrative costs) are transferred into outputs (pension
adequacy) by exogenous demographic conditions (expressed by e.g. old-dependency ratio), however
some important side-effects also occur and they concern a labour market first of all. Adequacy refers to
the main output or effect of a pension system, whereas efficiency expresses the r between this effect and
inputs; however it also includes the main side effects.
Pension adequacy is usually regarded in the literature as a one-dimensional category of a pension
system. In such an approach, the most common measure of this adequacy is the replacement rate, defined
however in many different ways. Biggs and Springstead (2008) analyze pension adequacy with the use
of four types of replacement rates, each based on a different measure of income in the pre-retirement
period. They prove that replacement rates can vary significantly depending on the construction of the
indicator. Holzmann and Guven (2009) study the replacement rates understood as “a useful yardstick
for measuring the adequacy of pension benefits, because they express benefits relative to pre-retirement
earnings, thereby indicating the degree to which income is replaced when workers retire” and suggest
two main variants of the replacement rates: gross and net, and include benefit indexation in their
analyses. Cole and Liebenberg (2008) associate pensioner income level with the level of pensioner
consumption using two indicators: the income replacement rate and the consumption replacement rate.
This approach refers directly to the fact that a pension system should allow to smooth consumption in
the life cycle, and income only enables this through its appropriate allocation in time (see e.g. Barr and
Diamond, 2006). A comparative analysis of pension adequacy based on cross-sectional data for 12
selected countries was conducted by Borella and Fornero (2009). They employ so called comprehensive
replacement rates (CORE) constructed as the relation between living standards after retirement and
living standards during the working years. However, Borella and Fornero (2009) focus only on one
dimension of pension adequacy as comprehensive replacement rates apply solely to the optimal level of
consumption smoothing.
On the converse side, the multidimensional approach to the analysis of adequacy may be
employed and seems to be more appropriate. This results for instance from the Open Method of
Coordination, where indicators refer to two dimensions: poverty alleviation and consumption
smoothing. Since a pension system in a microscale, according to the life cycle hypothesis, is perceived
as a tool of consumption smoothing in an agent’s lifecycle, the level of consumption smoothing should
ensure the maximization of agent’s utility. However, the consumption during the retirement period
should be over the poverty line (Barr and Diamond, 2006; Blake, 2006). Therefore, in this paper pension
adequacy is perceived as a category consisting on two main dimensions: poverty alleviation and
consumption smoothing, and one dimension which is actually the derivate from the two first: differences
in adequacy between the genders (see Chybalski and Marcinkiewicz, 2015).
To assess adequacy thus understood, the following measures referring to the first and second
dimension are employed. To evaluate the poverty alleviation, the at-risk-of-poverty rate (ARP) and sever
material deprivation ratio (SMD) are applied. ARP is defined as the percentage of pensioners’
population with income lower than 60% of the median equivalised income in a given country. The
equivalised income is a measure of household income that takes account of the differences in the
household size and composition (European Commission, 2012). ARP measures relative poverty and it
is based on the threshold measured as a percentage of median income, which means that the greater the
incomes of a population are, the higher the threshold is. Since relative poverty is sensitive to income
equality, severe material deprivation ratio is used as a supplementary measure. SMD is defined as the
share of population living in households unable to afford at least 4 out of the following 9 items: i) to pay
130
rent or utility bills, ii) heating to keep the home sufficiently warm, iii) face unexpected expenses, iv) eat
meat, fish or a protein equivalent every other day, v) a week holiday away from home, or which could
not afford (even if they wanted to) vi) a car, vii) a washing machine, viii) a colour TV, or ix) a telephone
(Eurostat, 2012; Maitre et al., 2013). The severe material deprivation ratio is resistant to the income
equality which is an important advantage of this measure in the comparison to ARP.
The other two variables refer to consumption smoothing. The first one is the aggregated
replacement ratio (ARR) and the other one is the relative median income ratio for people aged 65 and
over (MRI). The ARR indicator is defined as median individual pension of 6574-year-olds relative to
median individual earnings of 5059-year-olds. This measure is based on gross incomes and does not
include other social benefits. Chybalski and Marcinkiewicz (2015) show the main disadvantages of this
measure and undermine its representative character as the measure of pension adequacy indicating the
relative median income ratio as a supplementary measure. The MRI indicator is based on net incomes,
as opposed to the ARR, since it takes median disposable household income for people aged 65 and over
and for people aged under 65 into account. Therefore, this measure seems to be more reliable when
evaluating incomes of pensioners in the comparison to the incomes of working population.
To measure the third dimension of pension adequacy referring to the differences in poverty and
consumption smoothing between males and females, differences (males-females) for all the indicators
mentioned above are calculated.
The other multidimensional category of a pension system is efficiency. Due to deteriorating
demographics, this category has gained importance and the evaluation of pension systems disregarding
the efficiency and accounting only for adequacy would be faulty. To define and measure pension
efficiency, following methodology is employed (Chybalski, 2015). Pension system efficiency is
perceived as an overall category and refers to both a pension system as well as the economy (mainly the
labour market). In this approach, a pension system is perceived as a tool for transferring inputs into
outputs by a given demographic conditions, as it was mentioned before. Therefore, the efficiency of a
pension system refers to the relation between its adequacy (the main output of functioning of a pension
system, including poverty alleviation and consumption smoothing), and its cost in the sense of inputs
(pension expenditure, administrative costs) as well as in the sense of side effects on the economy,
perceived mainly as the impact a pension system has on the labour market.
To measure pension system efficiency, thus defined, from the static perspective, four sets of indicators
referring to different dimensions of this efficiency are employed. Dimension 1 - GDP-distribution
efficiency - includes one indicator (Chybalski 2014; Marcinkiewicz and Chybalski 2014):
 
 (1)
where GDP-D_e denotes the GDP-distribution efficiency indicator. This indicator refers directly to the
macroeconomic definition of a pension system according to which a pension system is perceived as a
tool for dividing current GDP between generation of workers and generation of pensioners (see Barr
and Diamond, 2006; Góra, 2008). I also discount conditions in which this distribution is realized since
the old-age dependency ratio affects the GDP distribution. GDP-D_e measures the resistance of this
distribution to the demographics since it is the ratio between pension expenditure as the percentage of
GDP, and old-age dependency ratio. The lower the value of this indicator is, the greater the resistance
of pension system to demographic changes is (i.e. to the aging of population).
Dimension 2 - Adequacy efficiency - measures the efficiency at which the pension adequacy is
ensured. Following indicators are employed to measure this dimension:
 
 (2)
 
 (3)
 
 (4)
 
 (5)
where ARP_e and SMD_e denote the efficiency of relative and absolute poverty alleviation, MRI65+_e
and ARR_e denote the efficiency of consumption smoothing measured respectively by the aggregated
131
replacement ratio and relative median income ratio. The first two indicators destimulate the efficiency
of a pension system (the-lower-the-better), and the other two stimulate it (the-greater-the-better).
Dimension 3 - Labour market efficiency - measures the most important side effect of a pension
system which is its impact on the labour market. This set includes three indicators:
  
 (6)
  
 (7)
 
 (8)
where EMP55-64_e denotes efficiency in terms of labour market I, EMP65-74_e denotes efficiency in
terms of labour market II and ARA_e denotes efficiency in terms of labour market III (due to data
structure, ARA_e is calculated for males and females separately). All the indicators classified to this set
refer to two age-groups: directly before retirement, and directly after retirement. They stimulate the
efficiency and measure how the GDP distribution affects the labour market.
Dimension 4 - Cost efficiency, includes one indicator which is AC_e administrative cost of
pension systems expressed as a percentage of GDP:
 
 (9)
where AC_e denotes the administrative cost of a pension system expressed as a percentage of pension
benefits. Obviously, this indicator affects the efficiency of a pension system negatively (the-greater-the
worse). To summarize this section, according to the presented concepts of adequacy and efficiency, and
the methods of their measurement, adequacy refers mainly to the microscale and characterizes the
capacity of a pension system to ensure the elderly appropriate income and, therefore, living standard
over the poverty line (relative or absolute) at least. The efficiency refers to macroscale and is developed
on the concept of a pension system perceived as a tool for dividing current GDP between generations.
As a result, efficiency takes also into account the relationship between pensions and the labour market,
similarly to relations between generation of pensioners and generation of workers.
3. Data and Research Strategy
The data used in the analysis comes from Eurostat database and OECD database (only average
age of retirement ARA) and cover the period of 2007-2011. The main limitation of the analyzed period
results from the data gap in average rate of retirement for the year 2012. The analysis embraces 30
European countries: Belgium (BE), Bulgaria (BG), Czech Rep. (CZ), Denmark (DK), Germany (DE),
Estonia (EE), Ireland (IE), Greece (GR), Spain (ES), France (FR), Italy (IT), Cyprus (CY), Latvia (LV),
Lithuania (LT), Luxembourg (LU), Hungary (HU), Malta (MT), Netherlands (NL), Austria (AT),
Poland (PL), Portugal (PT), Romania (RO), Slovenia (SI), Slovakia (SK), Finland (FI), Sweden (SE),
Great Britain (GB), Island (IS), Norway (NO) and Switzerland (CH).
The research strategy consists of the following stages. First, all the simple indicators are
standardized and transferred into stimulant variables (the-greater-the-better) and the group indicators for
each dimension of adequacy and efficiency are calculated as a linear combination (simple mean) of all
the indicators used to measure a given dimension of adequacy or efficiency. Second, synthetic indicators
of adequacy and efficiency are calculated as a linear combination (also simple mean) of group indicators,
obviously for adequacy and efficiency separately. For each year, all the simple indicators are used to
calculate group indicators, and as a consequence, to calculate synthetic indicators (see Chybalski, 2012).
This results from the fact that the only criterion for variables selection in the multidimensional analysis
is of substantial nature. Any correlation analysis is not used to eliminate possible similar variables since
it could result in different sets of indicators used to calculate group and synthetic indicators for different
years. The last stage of the study includes the interdependence analysis of different dimensions of
adequacy and efficiency to find possible relationships between them.
132
4. Ranking and Relationships
Table 1 presents the synthetic indicators of adequacy (SA) and efficiency (SE), and Table 2 the
adequacy ranking positions and efficiency ranking positions of the countries studied.
Table 1: Synthetic Adequacy (SA) Indicators and Synthetic Efficiency (SE) Indicators
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
SA
SE
SE
SA
SE
SA
SE
SA
SE
BE
0.71
0.45
0.45
0.69
0.45
0.67
0.45
0.60
0.44
BG
0.39
0.56
0.57
0.21
0.52
0.18
0.50
0.17
0.50
CZ
0.75
0.5
0.51
0.70
0.51
0.71
0.49
0.65
0.49
DK
0.67
0.26
0.26
0.65
0.24
0.61
0.27
0.59
0.27
DE
0.77
0.42
0.43
0.78
0.44
0.74
0.46
0.72
0.48
EE
0.41
0.81
0.78
0.39
0.74
0.49
0.69
0.50
0.83
IE
0.68
0.57
0.57
0.71
0.57
0.73
0.50
0.67
0.51
GR
0.55
0.52
0.49
0.64
0.56
0.53
0.48
0.54
0.39
ES
0.72
0.6
0.64
0.70
0.65
0.63
0.61
0.68
0.61
FR
0.85
0.24
0.23
0.89
0.19
0.84
0.20
0.82
0.23
IT
0.66
0.44
0.44
0.69
0.44
0.66
0.44
0.63
0.42
CY
0.34
0.54
0.58
0.47
0.59
0.44
0.50
0.44
0.47
LV
0.30
0.68
0.65
0.23
0.57
0.44
0.52
0.53
0.60
LT
0.37
0.60
0.58
0.46
0.54
0.69
0.61
0.60
0.66
LU
0.93
0.83
0.86
0.92
0.86
0.92
0.86
0.94
0.87
HU
0.81
0.55
0.58
0.82
0.62
0.79
0.57
0.74
0.62
MT
0.66
0.53
0.53
0.68
0.55
0.63
0.53
0.6
0.58
NL
0.77
0.30
0.33
0.78
0.31
0.76
0.32
0.74
0.32
AT
0.85
0.40
0.39
0.73
0.40
0.65
0.40
0.64
0.41
PL
0.76
0.47
0.48
0.67
0.49
0.59
0.47
0.58
0.47
PT
0.69
0.46
0.46
0.64
0.48
0.63
0.47
0.66
0.46
RO
0.47
0.59
0.64
0.59
0.61
0.61
0.6
0.62
0.61
SI
0.60
0.62
0.66
0.59
0.67
0.51
0.62
0.48
0.62
SK
0.69
0.45
0.52
0.70
0.53
0.74
0.53
0.67
0.56
FI
0.68
0.49
0.49
0.64
0.46
0.63
0.46
0.56
0.46
SE
0.81
0.53
0.53
0.71
0.53
0.64
0.54
0.59
0.55
GB
0.69
0.44
0.43
0.70
0.42
0.66
0.42
0.61
0.42
IS
0.68
0.79
0.86
0.68
0.87
0.71
0.9
0.71
0.84
NO
0.65
0.72
0.78
0.68
0.77
0.60
0.73
0.63
0.74
CH
0.67
0.29
0.30
0.59
0.31
0.57
0.30
0.53
0.29
Source: own calculations on the basis of Eurostat and OECD data
We can see that the best pension system in terms of both studied categories in the whole analyzed
period is that of Luxembourg. The SA indicator values for this country are not lower than 0.9 which
means that this pension system is almost equal to a hypothetical system being the best in terms of all the
adequacy dimensions (for such a theoretical pension systems SA would equal 1). In terms of efficiency,
this pension system is a bit more distant from a theoretical one being the best in terms of all the efficiency
dimensions, however, in each year SE exceeds 0.8. The second best pension system in terms of adequacy
is that of France, however, in terms of efficiency it is definitely the worst. The Luxembourgian pension
system suggests that adequacy goes hand in hand with efficiency while the example of France indicates
133
something quite the opposite. The other adequate pension systems are those of the Netherlands,
Hungary, Denmark and Austria. The other CEE countries like the Czech Rep. or Slovakia are
characterized also by relatively adequate pensions. However, Bulgaria and Lithuania are placed on the
opposite end with the lowest pension adequacy. Estonia, Slovenia, Latvia or Romania have also very
low pension adequacy.
Table 2: The Ranking of Pension Systems Based on Synthetic Adequacy (SA) and Synthetic
Efficiency (SE) Indicators (the Position of a Given Country in a Given Year)
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
SA
SE
SE
SA
SE
SA
SE
SA
SE
LU
1
1
1
1
2
1
2
1
1
FR
2
30
30
2
30
2
30
2
30
NL
7
27
27
5
28
4
27
3
27
HU
5
12
11
3
7
3
9
4
6
DE
6
25
24
4
24
6
22
5
17
AT
3
26
26
6
26
14
26
12
25
IE
15
10
13
7
11
7
14
8
14
CZ
9
17
17
11
18
9
17
11
16
IS
16
3
2
16
1
8
1
6
2
ES
10
7
8
9
6
17
6
7
9
SK
12
22
16
10
15
5
12
9
12
SE
4
14
15
8
16
15
10
21
13
GB
13
24
25
12
25
12
25
16
24
BE
11
21
22
13
22
11
23
17
22
IT
21
23
23
14
23
13
24
13
23
PT
14
20
21
20
20
16
19
10
21
NO
22
4
4
17
3
22
3
14
4
PL
8
19
20
18
19
23
20
22
19
DK
18
29
29
19
29
21
29
20
29
MT
20
15
14
15
13
18
11
18
11
FI
17
18
18
22
21
19
21
23
20
RO
25
9
7
25
8
20
8
15
8
GR
24
16
19
21
12
25
18
24
26
CH
19
28
28
24
27
24
28
25
28
LT
28
8
9
27
14
10
7
19
5
SI
23
6
5
23
5
26
5
28
7
EE
26
2
3
28
4
27
4
27
3
CY
29
13
10
26
9
29
16
29
18
LV
30
5
6
29
10
28
13
26
10
BG
27
11
12
30
17
30
15
30
15
Source: own calculations on the basis of Eurostat and OECD data
As far as efficiency is concerned, the group of the best pension systems belong (next to
Luxembourg) also Iceland, Estonia, Norway or Slovenia. The lowest efficiency, next to France, is
exhibited by such countries as Denmark, Switzerland, Netherlands or Austria. Since the goal of the study
is to indicate the best and the worst pension systems in terms of adequacy and efficiency and, then to
search for possible relationships between these categories, the selected pension systems are not
characterized. The answer to the question why given countries have better and others have worse pension
134
systems is also very important and this is a subject for further possible research based on the results
presented here. However, since the Danish pension system is assessed as one of the best when using the
Melbourne Mercer Global Pension Index (Australian Centre for Financial Studies, 2012), some
explanation is needed. Denmark has a relatively low level of consumption smoothing measured by ARR
and MRI indicators. In the studied period ARR for Denmark oscillates between 0.39-0.44 while the
mean value for the whole studied group equals 0.47-0.53 it is 0.70-0.76 and 0.79-0.89 respectively. This
results in low adequacy efficiency, especially due to relatively high pension expenditure as proportion
of GDP. In Denmark it was about 9.2%-11.2% while the mean for all the countries equals 6.5%-8.1%.
This expenditure is relatively high when accounting for old-age dependency ratio. Therefore, Denmark
has one of the worst proportions between pension expenditure and old-age dependency ratio (I
dimension of pension system efficiency GDP distribution). Besides, Global Pension Index does not
account for the labour market indicators for age groups directly before or after retirement age, as opposed
to the approach presented in this paper.
Figure 1 presents the scatter plots for SA and SE indicators for each of analyzed years. This
suggests that there is no significant relationship between synthetic adequacy and synthetic efficiency.
However, the figure reveals to some extent surprising regularity, namely, that the regression line changes
from negative to positive one. This suggests that the relationship between synthetic adequacy and
synthetic efficiency has changed over the studied period of time. However, as was mentioned previously,
this relationship is very weak, if it exists at all, therefore any conclusions about the changes in this
relationship must be very cautious.
Figure 1 also confirms that Luxembourg has the best pension system. Additionally, Iceland,
Norway, and Estonia seem to be at a different efficiency level in comparison to the rest of countries.
Bulgaria is at the lowest level in the sense of adequacy and the graph shows that this distance to other
countries is really significant and seems to grow. The fact that there are not identified strong
relationships between synthetic adequacy and synthetic efficiency does not imply that there are no such
relationships between given dimensions of these categories.
The correlation analysis for different pairs of group indicators (after their stimulation) suggests
that:
Poverty alleviation SA(I) is positively correlated with consumption smoothing SA(II) - the
lower the poverty rates, the higher the consumption level among pensioners (see Figure 2). This
results from the fact that three of four adequacy indicators are directly affected by incomes and
one indicator (SMD) referring to the absolute poverty is also affected by incomes, however in
an indirect manner;
Labour market efficiency SE(III) is positively correlated with the GDP-distribution efficiency
SE(I) (see Figure 3) and adequacy efficiency SE(II) (see Figure 4). Additionally, the relationship
between adequacy efficiency SE(II) and labour market efficiency SE(III) has become more and
more positive. This all may suggest that contemporary economies need an effective interactions
between a pension system and labour market to ensure adequate and relatively cheap benefits
(as the adequacy efficiency is the ratio between adequacy and pension expenditure);
The relationship between poverty alleviation SA(I) and labour market efficiency SE(III),
although weak, has evolved from negative to positive in the studied period (see Figure 5). This
confirms the conclusion drawn in the point above that an adequate pension system (also in the
sense of poverty alleviation) needs an efficiency referring to the labour market since the
interactions between a pension system and labour market are perceived as the main side-effect
of pensions.
The identified relationships suggest that the impact a pension system has on the labour market,
and vice versa, since this relation has obvious feedback resulting in the income from taxes or
contributions to a public pension fund, seems to be stronger and transforming into a positive one in the
studied period (see Figure 4 and 5). This efficiency is also positively correlated with the efficiency of
GDP-distribution (see Figure 3). This all suggests that in the period of deteriorating demographics the
impact of a pension system on the labour market has been crucial for financial sustainability and
therefore, on pension system adequacy, especially in terms of poverty alleviation. As Figure 5 shows,
the negative relation between labour market efficiency and poverty alleviation has transformed from a
135
negative to positive one, while, which is worth noting, in the case of labour market efficiency and
consumption smoothing has remained very weak (lack of correlation). This may suggest that today, the
first dimension of adequacy (poverty alleviation) is more sensitive to the efficiency of a pension system
in terms of its main side effect which is the impact on labour market, then the second dimension of
adequacy (consumption smoothing). Going forward, since the relationship between a pension system
and the labour market can be perceived as a function of the retirement age, the increasing of this age
seems to be obvious means to keep pension systems financially sustainable, regardless whether any
other reforms have been taken and what their direction is (to funded or unfunded model, to defined
benefit or defined contribution).
5. Conclusion
The theoretical background for studies on the relationship between pension system adequacy
and efficiency is still very weak since these two categories have been relatively recently regarded as
multidimensional ones. The study allowed two questions asked in the introduction to be answered. The
proposed measurement procedure based on synthetic indicators calculated as linear combinations of
given simple indicators of adequacy and efficiency, allows the evaluation of different pension systems
on the basis of comparable data. However, this method has some limitations. The first is regarding the
equal wages of each simple indicator, and then of each dimension of adequacy or efficiency when
calculating synthetic indicators (SA and SE). The other limitation concerns the relativeness of the
evaluation. This enables the comparison of different pension systems at a given moment of time,
however the comparison based on time series (between different moments of time) could be faulty since
the increase in a given synthetic indicator does not necessarily mean that a given pension system has
improved, and vice versa. This may result from changes in the values of indicators describing other
pension systems to which a given system is compared. However, the proposed approach to the
evaluation of adequacy and efficiency seems to be working and enables indicating a better and worse
pension system.
One of the most important results of the study is identification of transforming relationship
between synthetic adequacy and synthetic efficiency from a negative to positive one. It seems to confirm
that in the long prospect a main condition for income adequacy is efficiency. When demographics have
been deteriorating, only an efficient pension system can ensure adequate benefits in the long run. The
above mentioned change from a negative to a positive relationship between these two multidimensional
categories allows to suspect that the time in which many countries benefit from a demographic dividend
has gone and governments have to face the problem of optimization the adequacy by a given
demographic constraints instead of its maximization. Another interesting and strong relationship exists
between the first and the third dimension of efficiency. Pension system with a better GDP-distribution
between generations (with lower pension expenditure in relation to old-age dependency ratio) has
weaker negative side effects on labour market the lower the pension expenditure in comparison to the
old-dependency ratio is, the higher the employment rate in population aged close to retirement age is.
This all allows to draw a cautious conclusion that contemporary pension systems require better
stimulation of people to stay longer on labour market and keep them economically active throughout the
motivation to increase their pension benefits. Therefore, many countries have decided the change a
benefit formula from defined benefit (DB) to defined contribution one (DC). This has impact not only
on the microeconomic level (households) but also affects the macroeconomics of a pension system
throughout the change in the structure of GDP distribution between generations.
A preliminary study of the relationships between synthetic adequacy and synthetic efficiency as
well as between their dimensions described in this paper opens the prospect for further studies in this
area. These could concern seeking solutions (model and parameters) in selected pension systems making
them better than others, as well as more in depth analyses of the relationships between different
dimensions of adequacy and efficiency. However, these analyses could be based not on aggregated but
on simple indicators, referring to poverty, consumption smoothing, pension expenditure, old-
dependency ratio, administrative cost, and labour market indicators. The coincidence or causal
relationships between the labour market and the pension system seems to be the most interesting and
important when searching for the best models and parameters (including retirement age) of a pension
system.
136
Acknowledgement
This paper constitutes part of the project funded by the National Science Centre under grant
number DEC-2013/09/B/HS4/01516.
References
AUSTRALIAN CENTRE FOR FINANCIAL STUDIES (2012). Melbourne: Mercer Global Pension
Index.
BARR, N., DIAMOND, P. (2006). The economics of pensions. Oxford Review of Economics Policy,
vol. 22, no. 1, pp. 1539.
BIGGS, A.G., SPRINGSTEAD, G.R. (2008). Alternate measures of replacement rates for social
security benefits and retirement income. Social Security Bulletin, vol. 68, no. 2, pp. 119.
BLAKE, D. (2006). Pension Economics. West Sussex: John Wiley and Sons.
BORELLA, M., FORNERO, E. (2009). Adequacy of pension systems in Europe: An analysis based on
comprehensive replacement rates. ENEPRI Research Report No. 68. Brussels: Centre for European
Policy Studies.
CHYBALSKI, F. (2012). Measuring the multidimensional adequacy of pension systems in European
countries. Pensions Institute Discussion Paper PI-1204. London: Cass Business School.
CHYBALSKI, F. (2014). Financial Stability of Pension Systems: A Cross Country Analysis. In
Proceedings of the 14th International Conference on Finance and Banking. Karvina: Silesian University,
pp. 150158.
CHYBALSKI, F. (2015). The Multidimensional Efficiency of Pension System: Definition and
Measurement in Cross-Country Studies. Social Indicators Research (accepted paper, doi:
10.1007/s11205-015-1017-3).
CHYBALSKI, F., MARCINKIEWICZ, E. (2015). The Replacement Rate: An imperfect Indicator of
Pension Adequacy in Cross-Country Studies, Social Indicators Research (accepted paper, doi:
10.1007/s11205-015-0892-y).
COLE, C.R., LIEBENBERG, A.P. (2008). An Examination of Retirement Income Adequacy Measures
and Factors Affecting Retirement Preparedness. Working paper. New York: Social Science Research
Network.
EUROPEAN COMMISSION (2012). Pension Adequacy in the European Union 2010-2050. Brussels:
European Commission.
EUROSTAT (2012). Measuring material deprivation in the EU. Eurostat Methodologies and Working
papers. Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union.
GÓRA, M. (2008). Retirement decisions, benefits and the neutrality of pension systems, ENEPRI
Research Report No. 51. Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies.
HOLZMANN, R., GUVEN, U. (2009). Adequacy of retirement income after pension reforms in
Central, Eastern, and Sothern Europe: Eight country studies. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
MAITRE, B., NOLAN, B., WHELAN, T. (2013). Critical Evaluation of the EU 2020 Poverty and
Social Exclusion Target: The Analysis of EU-SILC 2009, Geary WP2013/09. Dublin: UCD Geary
Institute for Public Policy.
MARCINKIEWICZ E., CHYBALSKI F. (2014). How to measure and compare pension expenditure in
cross-country analyses? International Journal of Business and Management, vol. 2, no. 4, pp. 4359.
137
Appendix
Figure 1: Scatter Plots for Synthetic Adequacy (SA) and Synthetic Efficiency (SE)
Source: own calculations on the basis of Eurostat and OECD data
Figure 2: Scatter Plots for Poverty Alleviation SA(I) and Consumption Smoothing SA(II)
Source: own calculations on the basis of Eurostat and OECD data
138
Figure 3: Scatter Plots for GDP-distribution Efficiency SE(I) and Labour Market Efficiency SE(III)
Source: own calculations on the basis of Eurostat and OECD data
Figure 4: Scatter Plots for Adequacy Efficiency SE(II) and Labour Market Efficiency SE(III)
Source: own calculations on the basis of Eurostat and OECD data
139
Figure 5: Scatter Plots for Poverty Alleviation SA(I) and Labour Market Efficiency SE(III)
Source: own calculations on the basis of Eurostat and OECD data
... The works of Degtyar L.S. [6], Pudovkin A.V. [7], Fedotov A.I. [8] are devoted to the study of the world experience of pension provision and its possible application in Russia. Among the foreign researchers can be identified the work of Chybalski F. [9], Borella M., Fornero E. [10]. ...
Article
Full-text available
The article assesses the effectiveness of the pay-as-you-go pension system and the funded pension system as components of the current mixed model of pension provision in Russia. The prospects of their further application in Russia are presented.
Article
Przedmiotem artykułu jest renta po zmarłym żywicielu w kontekście zabezpieczenia emerytalnego. Oznacza to, że zakres podmiotowy beneficjentów renty rodzinnej zostanie ograniczony do osób w wieku równym co najmniej minimalnemu wiekowi emerytalnemu, będących jedynymi beneficjentami tego świadczenia. Rencie wdowiej przypisywane są dwa cele: (1) ochrona przed ubóstwem osób, które pozostawały na utrzymaniu zmarłego, (2) utrzymanie dotychczasowego poziomu życia osób, wobec których zmarły miał obowiązek alimentacyjny. Wydaje się, analogicznie do celów zabezpieczenia emerytalnego, że pierwszy z nich można by zaliczyć do poziomu makro, a drugi do poziomu mikro. Oba te dążenia konstytuują adekwatność świadczeń zabezpieczenia finansowego (tu bazowego) w odniesieniu do osób starszych. Zadaniem artykułu jest odpowiedź na pytanie, w jakim stopniu renta rodzinna będzie przyczyniać się do realizacji celu adekwatności w przekroju płci w odniesieniu do emerytek i emerytów pobierających świadczenie z nowego systemu emerytalnego. W artykule wykorzystano dwa źródła danych empirycznych: zastane, publikowane lub udostępnione przez Zakład Ubezpieczeń Społecznych, oraz wyniki samodzielnie przeprowadzonej mikrosymulacji (20 tys. przypadków) w stosunku do świadczeń osób, których emerytura pochodzić będzie wyłącznie z tzw. nowego systemu emerytalnego. Podstawowy wniosek dotyczy tego, że dla osób pobierających świadczenie z bazowego systemu emerytalnego w pierwszym roku po przejściu na emeryturę renta rodzinna w bardzo ograniczonym stopniu wpływa na adekwatność świadczeń. Zdecydowanie ważniejszym instrumentem, także dla kobiet, jest emerytura minimalna.
Book
Full-text available
All countries in the former transition economies of Central, Eastern, and Southern Europe have undertaken public pension reforms of varying depth and orientation, often with the support of the World Bank. Although the reformed public pension schemes provide broad benefit adequacy, in most cases additional measures are needed to achieve fiscal sustainability in an aging society. Adequacy of Retirement Income after Pension Reforms in Central, Eastern, and Southern Europe: Eight Country Studies assesses the benefit adequacy of the reformed pension systems for eight countries—Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Croatia, Hungary, Poland, Romania, the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia—to identify policy gaps and options. The authors identify the motivations for reform against the backdrop of the trend toward multi-pillar arrangements, document key provisions, and compare them in the context of the World Bank’s five-pillar paradigm for pension reform. They then evaluate the sustainability and adequacy of reformed pension systems and provide recommendations to address gaps and take advantage of opportunities for further reforms. The case studies and summary suggest the following broad policy conclusions: • Fiscal sustainability has improved in most study countries, but few are fully prepared for the inevitability of population aging. • The linkage between contributions and benefits has been strengthened, and pension system designs are better suited to market conditions. • Levels of income replacement are generally adequate for all but some categories of workers (including those with intermittent formal sector employment or low lifetime wages), and addressing their needs requires initiatives that go beyond pension policy. • Further reforms should focus on extending labor force participation by the elderly to avoid benefit cuts that could undermine adequacy and very high contribution rates that could discourage formal sector employment. • More decisive financial market reforms are needed for funded provisions to deliver on the expectations of participants and keep funded pensions safe
Article
Full-text available
The existing literature on the efficiency of pension system, usually addresses the problem between the choice of different theoretical models, or concerns one or few empirical pension systems. In this paper quite different approach to the measurement of pension system efficiency is proposed. It is dedicated mainly to the cross-country studies of empirical pension systems, however it may be also employed to the analysis of a given pension system on the basis of time series. I identify four dimensions of pension system efficiency, referring to: GDP-distribution, adequacy of pension, influence on the labour market and administrative costs. Consequently, I propose four sets of static and one set of dynamic efficiency indicators. In the empirical part of the paper, I use Spearman’s rank correlation coefficient and cluster analysis to verify the proposed method on statistical data covering 28 European countries in years 2007–2011. I prove that the method works and enables some comparisons as well as clustering of analyzed pension systems. The study delivers also some interesting empirical findings. The main goal of pension systems seems to become poverty alleviation, since the efficiency of ensuring protection against poverty, as well as the efficiency of reducing poverty, is very resistant to the efficiency of GDPdistribution. The opposite situation characterizes the efficiency of consumption smoothing—this is generally sensitive to the efficiency of GDP-distribution, and its dynamics are sensitive to the dynamics of GDP-distribution efficiency. The results of the study indicate the Norwegian and the Icelandic pension systems to be the most efficient in the analyzed group.
Article
Full-text available
In our paper, we discuss pension expenditure as one of the main indicators of pension system sustainability. However, given the large demographic diversity between the European countries, public spending on pensions is hard to compare. We proposed two alternative indicators visualising the level of pension expenditure. The first is the quotient of pension expenditure and GDP and old-age dependency ratio. The second replaces the old-age dependency ratio with the proportion of population aged 65 and over. Such standardisation of the commonly used pension expenditure to GDP indicator makes it possible to provide for the demographic effect and this way it facilitates a comparison of pension expenditures between countries with very different population structures.
Article
Full-text available
Discussions of retirement planning and Social Security policy often focus on replacement rates, which represent retirement income or Social Security benefits relative to preretirement earnings. Replacement rates are a rule of thumb designed to simplify the process of smoothing consumption over individuals' lifetimes. Despite their widespread use, however, there is no common means of measuring replacement rates. Various measures of preretirement earnings mean that the denominators used in replacement rate calculations are often inconsistent and can lead to confusion. Whether a given replacement rate represents an adequate retirement income depends on whether the denominator in the replacement rate calculation is an appropriate measure of preretirement earnings. This article illustrates replacement rates using four measures of preretirement earnings: final earnings; the constant income payable from the present value (PV) of lifetime earnings (PV payment); the wage-indexed average of all earnings prior to claiming Social Security benefits; and the inflation-adjusted average of all earnings prior to claiming Social Security benefits (consumer price index (CPI) average). The article then measures replacement rates against a sample of the Social Security beneficiary population using the Social Security Administration's Modeling Income in the Near Term (MINT) microsimulation model. Replacement rates are shown based on Social Security benefits alone, to indicate the adequacy of the current benefit structure, as well as on total retirement income including defined benefit pensions and financial assets, to indicate total preparedness for retirement. The results show that replacement rates can vary considerably based on the definition of preretirement earnings used and whether replacement rates are measured on an individual or a shared basis. For current new retirees, replacement rates based on all sources of retirement income seem strong by most measures and are projected to remain so as these individuals age. For new retirees in 2040, replacement rates are projected to be lower, though still adequate on average based on most common benchmarks.
Article
Full-text available
This book applies economic theory to the welfare state. Its core message is that the welfare state exists not only to relieve poverty and redistribute income and wealth (the ‘Robin Hood’ function) but also as a series of institutions that provide insurance and consumption smoothing (the ‘piggy‐bank’ function). The book develops three central arguments about the role of the state in industrial countries and also in post‐communist and middle‐income developing countries. First, the welfare state has an insufficiently understood piggy‐bank function that is additional to and separate from poverty relief. Even if all poverty and social exclusion could be eliminated, so that the entire population were middle class, there would still be a need for institutions to offer insurance (for example, unemployment insurance, long‐term care insurance, medical insurance) and consumption smoothing over the life cycle (for example, pensions and education finance in the form of student loans). Private institutions – though often effective in other areas – face pervasive problems of imperfect information, risk, and uncertainty, and attempts to address those problems inescapably involve state intervention. Second, and consequentially, the welfare state is here to stay, since twenty‐first‐century developments do nothing to undermine those reasons – if anything, they do the reverse. To argue that the welfare state is robust does not, however, mean that it is static. A third set of arguments concerns the ways it can and will adapt to economic and social change.
Article
The aim of this paper is to develop indicators to highlight the ability of different national pension systems to enable individuals to maintain their living standards at retirement. Authors Margherita Borella and Elsa Fornero of the University of Turin and CeRP, perform the analysis using data and projections on different European countries and propose the use of a ‘COmprehensive Replacement’ (CORE) rate. Their aim is to compute, for a set of countries representative of the different European welfare and pension systems, both an actual (data-based) version of CORE, based on ECHP data, and to project its evolution into the future.The paper is organised as follows. Section 1 provides a theoretical framework as well as a review of the literature on the topic. Section 2 contains the computation of replacement rates based on ECHP data. In Section 3 CeRPSAM projections are used to compute COREs over time. Section 4 concludes.
Article
This article uses a consistent methodology to estimate several retirement income adequacy measures for households that participate in two national surveys. In addition, we examine the impact of a variety of factors on retirement preparedness. We find that Survey of Consumer Finances households have higher income replacement rates, but lower consumption replacement rates, than Health and Retirement Survey households. We also find that replacement rate estimates are sensitive to the treatment of home equity and assumed retirement age. Finally, the impact of household characteristics on the likelihood of being better prepared for retirement differs depending on the survey data and retirement income adequacy measure used.
Melbourne: Mercer Global Pension Index
  • Australian Centre For Financial
  • Studies
AUSTRALIAN CENTRE FOR FINANCIAL STUDIES (2012). Melbourne: Mercer Global Pension Index.
Measuring the multidimensional adequacy of pension systems in European countries. Pensions Institute Discussion Paper PI-1204 Financial Stability of Pension Systems: A Cross Country Analysis
CHYBALSKI, F. (2012). Measuring the multidimensional adequacy of pension systems in European countries. Pensions Institute Discussion Paper PI-1204. London: Cass Business School. CHYBALSKI, F. (2014). Financial Stability of Pension Systems: A Cross Country Analysis. In Proceedings of the 14 th International Conference on Finance and Banking. Karvina: Silesian University, pp. 150–158.