ChapterPDF Available

Abstract

Much of social life involves interactions between individuals or corporate actors in dyads, groups, organizations or networks that can be viewed as social exchanges. This chapter presents an overview of the main theories of social exchange focusing on the key contributors in sociology, including George Homans, Peter Blau, Richard M. Emerson and those whose work subsequently built on their original formulations. The theories that have been developed in recent decades have focused on the social structures created by repeated exchanges and the ways in which these structures both constrain and enable actors to exercise power and influence. Other related social processes addressed within the exchange tradition include interpersonal commitment, trust, fairness, procedural and distributive justice, coalition formation and collective action. Recent work also focuses on emotions and their role in social exchange. The methodological challenges of studying social exchange in the laboratory and in the world outside the lab are addressed as well as links between exchange theory and topics under study by economic sociologists and network scholars more broadly, including Internet-mediated exchanges and their growing significance.
61
J. DeLamater and A. Ward (eds.), Handbook of Social Psychology, Handbooks of Sociology and Social Research,
DOI 10.1007/978-94-007-6772-0_3, © Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2013
Introduction
We engage in many exchanges on a daily basis with a wide range of actors most often embedded in
the groups, networks, organizations and institutions we inhabit. Thus it is not surprising that exchange
theory has remained one of the major theoretical perspectives on social interaction and social structure
since the early writings of George Homans ( 1961 ), Peter Blau ( 1964 ) and Richard Emerson ( 1962 ,
1972a , 1972b ). In this chapter we review the foundational work of these three key contributors and the
subsequent research their work has inspired. The roots of this theoretical orientation can be found in
earlier philosophical and psychological work deriving from utilitarianism on the one hand and behav-
iorism on the other, the vestiges of which remain evident in the versions of exchange theory current
today. We focus on the nature of the contributions of exchange theory to the analysis of social psycho-
logical and sociological phenomena of importance in understanding micro-level processes of exchange
and the social structures they constitute.
First, we provide an overview of the major theories of social exchange. Then we draw out some of
the relevant distinctions between the different theoretical formulations. After this exercise we discuss the
main topics of research that have been studied by many of the key contributors to the exchange tradi-
tion within the fi eld of sociology. One major hallmark of recent research on social exchange in the
eld of sociology is its attention to the links between social exchange theory and theories of social
status, infl uence, social networks, fairness, coalition formation, solidarity, trust, affect, emotion and
collective action. We address these topics in our review of recent important contributions to exchange
theory. We conclude with a brief statement concerning methodological issues in the study of social
exchange and directions for future research. In particular we focus on the linkages between exchange
theory in sociology and work in related fi elds of inquiry such as economic sociology, social networks
and online exchange. There are many important topics of research yet to be studied fully within the
exchange tradition, which provide an exciting research agenda for the future.
Chapter 3
Social Exchange Theory
Karen S. Cook , Coye Cheshire , Eric R. W. Rice , and Sandra Nakagawa
K. S. Cook () S. Nakagawa
Department of Sociology , Stanford University , Stanford , CA , USA
e-mail: kcook@stanford.edu
C. Cheshire
School of Information , University of California , Berkeley , CA , USA
E. R. W. Rice
School of Social Work , University of Southern California , Los Angeles , CA , USA
62
Social Behavior as Exchange
For Homans ( 1961 ), one of the fi rst sociological theorists to focus on interpersonal exchanges, the
dominant emphasis was the individual behavior of actors in interaction with one another. His primary
aim was to explain fundamental processes of social behavior (infl uence, conformity, status, leader-
ship, and justice) from the ground up. Homans believed that there was nothing that emerges in social
groups that cannot be explained by propositions about individuals as individuals, together with the
given condition that they happen to be interacting. In his effort to embrace this form of reductionism
his formulation is very clearly different from the subsequent work of Peter Blau ( 1964 ) who built into
his theory of social exchange and social structure an analysis of the “emergent” properties of social
systems, which could not be reduced to individual action alone.
Homans ( 1961 , p. 13) defi ned social exchange as the exchange of activity, tangible or intangible, and
more or less rewarding or costly, between at least two parties. Cost was viewed primarily in terms of
alternative activities or opportunities foregone by the actors involved. Reinforcement principles derived
from the kind of behaviorism popular in the early 1960s (e.g. the work of B. F. Skinner) were used by
Homans to explain the persistence of exchange relations. Behavior is a function of payoffs, whether the
payoffs are provided by the nonhuman environment or by other humans. Emerson (
1972a ) subsequently
developed a more formal psychological basis for exchange based on these general reinforcement
principles. Linda Molm’s ( 1979 , 1980 , 1985 ) later work also built on this foundation of behaviorism.
Homans explained social behavior and the forms of social organization produced by social inter-
action by showing how A’s behavior reinforced B’s behavior (in a two party relation between actors
A and B), and how B’s behavior in contingent fashion reinforced A’s behavior in return. This was the
explicit basis for continued social interaction explained at the “sub- institutional” level. The existing
historical and structural conditions were taken as given. Value in this formulation is determined by the
actor’s history of reinforcement and thus was also taken as a given at the initiation of an exchange
relation. Homans’ primary focus was the social behavior that emerged as a result of the social process
of mutual reinforcement over time. Relations could also terminate on the basis of the failure of
reinforcement or as a result of too much asymmetry in the relevant rewards and costs.
Dyadic exchange, the main emphasis of his work, formed the basis for much of his theoretical
consideration of other important sociological concepts such as distributive justice, balance, status,
leadership, authority, and solidarity. Homans’ work was criticized for two main reasons: it was too
reductionist (i.e., it took the principles of psychology as the basis for sociological phenomena) and in
analyzing the sub-institutional level of social behavior it underplayed the signifi cance of the institu-
tional forces as well as the social processes and structures that emerge out of social interaction, a
major focus of the work of Blau and Emerson. In this respect, it is somewhat ironic that one of
Homans’ lasting contributions to social psychology has been his early treatment of distributive justice
in social exchange relations. The irony derives from the fact that Homans was explicitly much less
interested in norms since he was preoccupied with the “sub institutional” level of analysis in his study
of elementary social behavior. His effort to focus on elementary behavior is derived from his opposi-
tion to the systems oriented and normative views of Parsons that held sway during the time that he
wrote his treatise on social behavior. In his autobiography, Homans (
1984 ) refers to Parsons’ main
work on the social system as the “yellow peril.” We discuss Homans’ conception of distributive justice
in greater detail in the section on commitment and fairness in exchange relations.
Homans’ key propositions framed the study of social behavior in terms of rewards and punish-
ments. Behavior that is rewarded in general continues (up to the limit of diminishing marginal utility).
His fi rst proposition, the success proposition, states that behavior that generates positive consequences
is likely to be repeated. The second proposition, the stimulus proposition, states that behavior that has
been rewarded on such occasions in the past will be performed in similar situations. The value
proposition, the third proposition, specifi es that the more valuable the result of an action to an actor,
the more likely that action is to be performed.
K.S. Cook et al.
63
The fourth proposition, the deprivation- satiation proposition, qualifi es the stimulus proposition
introducing the general ideal of diminishing marginal utility: the more often a person has recently
received a particular reward for an action, the less valuable is an additional unit of that reward.
Finally, the fi fth proposition specifi es when individuals will react emotionally to different reward
situations. People will become angry when they do not receive what they anticipate. Homans ( 1974 )
later argues that they can become angry when they do not receive a fair rate of return, introducing the
normative concept of distributive justice into his analysis of dyadic exchange.
Blau, writing at about the same time, framed his micro-exchange theory in terms of rewards and
costs as well, but took a decidedly more economic and utilitarian view of behavior rather than building
on the reinforcement principles derived from experimental behavioral analysis. A key distinction
between these two broad perspectives, as Heath ( 1976 ) points out, is whether the actor is forward-
looking or backward-looking in his determination of what to do next. Utilitarianism generally looks
forward. Actors are viewed as acting in terms of anticipated rewards that benefi t them and they tend
to choose the alternative course of action that maximizes benefi t (and minimizes costs, but see Molm,
Takahashi, & Peterson, 2000 ). Reinforcement theories look backwards with actors valuing what has
been rewarding to them in the past. The micro-level exchange theory in Blau’s work is embryonic and
under developed though it is one of the fi rst attempts to apply utilitarianism derived from economics
to social behavior.
Blau viewed social exchange as a process of central signifi cance in social life and as underlying the
relations between groups as well as between individuals. He focused primarily on the reciprocal
exchange of extrinsic benefi ts and the forms of association and emergent social structures that this
kind of social interaction created. According to Blau ( 1964 , p. 91): “Social exchange … refers to
voluntary actions of individuals that are motivated by the returns they are expected to bring and typi-
cally do in fact bring from others.” In contrasting social and economic exchange he emphasizes the
fact that it is more likely in social exchange for the nature of the obligations involved to remain
unspecifi ed, at least initially. Social exchange, he argues, “involves the principle that one person does
another a favor, and while there is a general expectation of some future return, its exact nature is
defi nitely not stipulated in advance” (Blau, 1986 , p. 93).
The rst third of Blau’s book on exchange and power specifi es the nature of the social processes
that result in associations between individuals (e.g., attraction). Two conditions are defi ned as
important in the assessment of whether or not the behavior involved leads to exchange. The behav-
ior “must be oriented toward ends that can only be achieved through interaction with other persons,
and it must seek to adapt means to further achievement of these ends” (Blau, 1986 , p. 5). Social
exchange processes give rise to differentiation in social status and power based on the dependence
of some actors on others for the provision of valued goods and services. This conception of power
was based on the approach taken by Emerson ( 1962 ) in his treatment of power-dependence
relations.
Much of the remaining focus of Blau’s classic book is on the structure of social exchange and
emergent social processes at the group and organizational level. His explicit attempt to build a theory
of social structure on the basis of a micro- level theory of exchange was also infl uential in Emerson’s
work, though they used different theoretical strategies.
Emerson’s important contributions to exchange theory are an interesting mix of the work of Homans
and Blau. The behavioral underpinnings of his micro-level theory are based on reinforcement princi-
ples of the type that animated Homans’ work in the 1960s. In Part I of his theory, Emerson takes the
experimental analysis of behavior of Skinner and others as the basis for his formal theory of exchange
behavior (see Emerson,
1972a ). In Part II, he builds on the analysis of dyadic exchange to develop a
framework for the analysis of exchange network structures (see Emerson,
1972b ). This work is
reviewed in our discussion of exchange and power, since power was the dominant emphasis of the early
work on exchange structures. It was the main focus of the work of Blau and Emerson and until the
1990s it was the central topic of much of the empirical work on social exchange networks.
3 Social Exchange Theory
64
The Structure of Social Exchange
One of the distinguishing features of Blau’s ( 1964 ) infl uential book on social exchange is the primary
emphasis on the structure of associations larger than the dyad. Blau’s explicit aim was to develop a
theoretical formulation that could provide the basis for a theory of macro-social structures as well. His
attempt to build links between a micro-sociological theory of behavior and a macro-sociological
theory of social structure was in many respects prophetic of the theoretical efforts in the 1980s and
1990s that emerged to examine more closely the “micro-macro link” (Alexander, Munch, Smelser, &
Giesen, 1990 ; Huber, 1991 ), a project that remains unfi nished.
In addition to the effort to build a macro- sociological theory of structure on the basis of a micro-
sociological theory of behavior, Blau identifi ed generic social processes and mechanisms he viewed
as operative at various levels of social organization. These included collective action, legitimacy,
opposition, confl ict, and cooperation. This work set the stage for a number of subsequent develop-
ments in exchange theory on collective action, coalition formation, justice and status, among others
(see below), but Blau was not given full credit for this broader infl uence, until several decades later.
Montgomery ( 1996 ), for example, reformulated Blau’s ( 1964 ) model of social exchange to refl ect
the dynamic nature of interaction and the potential for opportunistic behavior. He demonstrated how
social exchange could be formalized as a repeated game, and how game-theoretic models might be
used to predict the stability of certain exchange network structures. Whereas Blau’s ( 1964 ) theory
could not explain the strong, reciprocal relationships in the work group advice network (Blau, 1955 ),
Montgomery’s model ( 1996 ) provided a plausible explanation. Montgomery’s model, however, only
addressed the stability of the exchange network noted by Blau ( 1955 ) and did not address the
emergence and possible transformation of this structure in real time. The primary emphasis in the
work of Blau on exchange structures such as advice networks was on its causal link to the distribution
of power and network infl uence.
Exchange Relations, Networks and Power
Starting with the early theoretical work of Blau ( 1964 , 1986 ) and Emerson ( 1962 , 1972a , 1972b )
research focused on the connection between social structure and the use of power. Despite his impor-
tant contributions to social exchange theory, Homans did not focus much attention on power (Cook &
Gerbasi,
2006 ). Blau ( 1964 ) believed that inequality and power distributions were emergent proper-
ties of ongoing relations of social exchange. Inequalities, he argued, could result from exchange
because some actors control more highly valued resources than do others. As a result, they incur
social debts that are most easily discharged through the subordination of their social debtors. Blau
( 1964 ) argued that such relations of subjugation and domination took on a self perpetuating character
and formed the micro-foundations of power inequality.
For Emerson, the relationship between power and social structure was the central theoretical
problem in social exchange theory. From his earliest work in social exchange, Emerson ( 1962 ) defi ned
power in relational terms as a function of the dependence of one actor on another. In a particular dyad
of exchange partners (A and B), the power of actor A over another actor B is a function of the
dependence of B on A for valued resources and behaviors. Dependence and power are, thus, a function
of the value one actor places on resources controlled by another and the relative availability of alter-
native sources of supply for those resources. This relational conception of power has two central
features that helped generate the large body of social exchange research that exists today. First, power
is treated explicitly as relational, not simply the property of a given actor. Second, power is potential
power and is derived from the resource connections (often now referred to as a form of “social
capital”) among actors that may or may not be used.
K.S. Cook et al.
65
It was Emerson’s move to conceptualize power as a function of social relations that opened the
door for the subsequent development of micro-theories connecting social networks to power. Like
Blau ( 1964 , 1986 ), Emerson viewed the fundamental task of social exchange theory to be the building
of a framework in which the primary dependent variables were social structure and structural changes.
He went on to expand his treatment of power and dependence as a function of social relations to an
extensive theory of social exchange relations and networks (Emerson, 1972a , 1972b ). He argued that
potential power was the direct effect of structural arrangements among actors who controlled valued
resources (1972b). In his work with Cook (Cook & Emerson, 1978 ), Emerson brought social exchange
theory into its contemporary empirical and theoretical domain. They argued and experimentally dem-
onstrated that power was a function of relative dependence. Moreover, dependence was a feature of
networks of interconnected exchange partners whose relative social power was the result of the shape
of the social network and the positions they occupied (Cook & Emerson). While Cook and Emerson
( 1978 ) concerned themselves with other exchange outcomes, particularly commitment formation, it
was the connection between the use of power and the structure of social networks that became the
central focus of a new generation of social exchange theorists.
The most consistent fi nding among scholars working on social exchange is that relative position in
a network of exchange relations produces differences in the relative use of power, manifest in the
unequal distribution of rewards across positions in a social network (Cook & Emerson, 1978 ;
Markovsky, Willer, & Patton, 1988 ; Skvoretz & Willer, 1993 ). While several competing micro-theo-
ries connecting network structure and power-use now exist, all these competing perspectives converge
on one point: “Power differentials between actors are related to differences in actor’s positions in the
network of exchange relations” (Skvoretz & Willer, p. 803). The theories, however, view different
causal mechanisms as being at work in converting differentials in network position into differentials
of power. The Graph-theoretic Power Index approach uses elementary theory and focuses on the role
of exclusion in networks (Markovsky, Skvoretz, Willer, Lovaglia, & Erger, 1993 ; Markovsky et al.,
1988 ; Skvoretz & Willer). Core theory borrows concepts and solutions from game theory and
focuses on viable coalitions among partners (Bienenstock & Bonacich, 1992 , 1993 , 1997 ). Equi-
dependence theory is based on power-dependence reasoning and centers on equilibrium points in
which dependence between parties to the exchange reaches a balance (Cook &Yamagishi, 1992 ).
Finally, expected value theory is based on a probabilistic logic and looks at the expected value of
exchanges weighted by their likelihood of occurrence (Friedkin, 1992 , 1993 ).
Bienenstock and Bonacich ( 1992 , 1993 , 1997 ) make arguments about how structural arrangements
affect the frequency of exchange. They introduce the concept of the core, as developed by game theo-
rists, into the context of social exchange. They argue that intuitively the core as a solution implies that
“no group of players will accept an outcome if, by forming a coalition, they can do better” (Bienenstock
& Bonacich, 1992 ). Not only do different network structures produce different power distributions,
but also different coalitions emerge as “solutions” to exchange. What this argument implies is that the
structural arrangement of actors in relative position to one another can be an impetus for some sub-
sets of actors to exchange more frequently than others. This increased frequency of exchange may in
turn reinforce the coalitions that form. Bienenstock and Bonacich (
1993 ) are aware of this implication
and test it explicitly, fi nding that the core typically made effective predictions about the frequency of
exchanges as well as relative power differences. Often these coalitions form in response to the exis-
tence of power differences among the actors in the network as Emerson ( 1972b ) noted. Coalitions
can serve to mitigate such power differences such as when employees combine efforts in order to
respond collectively to an employer’s requests for increased time commitments.
Cook and Yamagishi ( 1992 ) also proposed that structural arrangements would affect patterns of
exchange among actors in a social network. They argued that exchanges proceed toward an equilib-
rium point where partners depend equally on each other for valued resources. This equi-dependence
principle has implications for partner selection. They argue that three different types of relations can
emerge from a network of potential exchange relations (which they refer to as an opportunity
3 Social Exchange Theory
66
structure). Exchange relations are those relations in which exchanges routinely occur. Non-relations
are potential partnerships within the network which are never used, and which if removed from the
network do not affect the predicted distribution of power. Finally, latent relations are potential
relations, which also remain unused but which if removed affect the subsequent predicted distribution
of power across positions in the network.
Friedkin ( 1992 , 1993 ) likewise argues that some relations are the focus of more frequent interaction
than are others, depending on the structure of alternative relations present in the exchange network. He
views networks as a space for potential relations and calculates the probabilities that particular
exchanges will occur. Payoffs are a function of the expected value of a particular exchange weighted by
the probability of the occurrence of that exchange. For Friedkin, the fact that some relations are used
more than others is central to his explanation of how power becomes differentially distributed across
positions in a social network. Central to his theory of actor behavior in exchange networks are predic-
tions about how often some exchange relations occur and, moreover, how some relations are more likely
to occur within a given structure than are others.
As was the case for Expected Value Theory the Graph-Theoretic Power Index (GPI) is explicitly
concerned with predicting resource acquisition by actors in positions in networks of exchange. In so
doing, GPI relies explicitly on the probability of particular partnerships being formed (see Markovsky
et al., 1993 , pp. 200–204 for a detailed explanation). Beyond using the probability of an exchange
occurrence in the GPI, Markovsky and his collaborators focus on the idea that some types of structures
tend to have more of an impetus toward exclusion than do others. Some network structures can be
characterized as weak-power networks and others as strong-power networks. The essential difference
between these two types of networks is that strong-power networks include positions that can exclude
particular partners without affecting their own relative power or benefi t levels. On the other hand, a
weak power network is typically more densely connected, which acts to prevent the emergence of
large inequalities in exchange outcomes.
An example of a strong power network can be seen in a workplace where a manager can compel
increased compliance from workers because they are highly dependent on the manager for valued
outcomes that only she can offer. In a weak power network there are typically more alternatives from
which each actor can obtain resources of value. For example, in a group of friends if one of the friends
becomes rude or unfriendly each person typically has alternative social partners he or she can turn to
for support, thus there is less opportunity for exploitation to occur. One implication of this distinction
is that strong-power networks will tend to have lower levels of commitment between the parties to the
exchange than will weak-power networks, because strong- power structures allow the arbitrary
exclusion of some partners (Markovsky et al., 1993 ), facilitating power use.
Molm ( 1990 , 1997a ; Molm, Peterson, & Takahashi, 1999) formulated a different conceptualization
of the connection between social structure and the use of power. Molm started with Emerson’s two
central propositions: power is relational and power is a function of dependence. But Molm’s program
of research took a distinctly different direction from the other positional theories of social exchange.
First, Molm focused on exchanges that are not negotiated, but are reciprocal acts of contingent giving
(Molm,
1990 , 1994 , 1997a , 1997b ). In reciprocal exchange , actors do not bargain over the division of
a fi nite pool of resources (or a fi xed range of positive returns), rather exchange is a process of “gift-
giving” or the simple act of the provision of a valued resource or service and exchange relationships
develop over time through repeated acts of reciprocal giving. The failure of reciprocity results in
infrequent exchange. Second, power is not solely tied to the legitimate use of reward power. Power
may take the form of coercion or punishment (Molm , 1990 , 1994 , 1997a , 1997b ). Whereas the other
theories view the use of power as wielding structural infl uence through the threat and/or practice of
exclusion from exchange (especially when there is a power-imbalance in the network), Molm consid-
ers how actors may impose punitive sanctions or negative outcomes on one another. The threat or
practice of exclusion is most effective in networks in which there is a large power difference between
the actors as noted above. And, actors who are most dependent (least powerful) are most likely to be
excluded from exchange in certain networks (e.g., networks in which there is a monopoly structure).
K.S. Cook et al.
67
Molm’s extensive research on non-negotiated or reciprocal exchange has produced important
contributions to the understanding of the connections between social structure and the use of power (for
a thorough review of this body of research see Molm, 1997a , 1997b ). First, Molm’s work demonstrates
that not all types of power use are primarily structurally motivated (Molm, 1990 , 1994 ). While exclusion
can produce the unconscious use of reward power in negotiated exchange contexts (Molm, 1990 ), pun-
ishment power is used more sparingly. Second, power-use can have strategic motivations. Punishment
power may not be used frequently but when it is, it is usually employed purposively to infl uence the
future actions of one’s exchange partners (Molm, 1990 , 1994 ). Third, her work provides an analysis of
the alternative sources of power. Power-use in the form of punishment is distinct from power use in the
form of the differential distribution of rewards. Finally, her line of research shows how coercive power
is connected to and limited by the structures of dependence. Dependence on rewards is the primary force
in exchange relations, motivating both the use of punishment and reward power (Molm, 1990 ).
Exchange, Power and Status
In recent work, Thye and others have made explicit linkages between theories of exchange and status.
Although Homans and Blau included consideration of status processes centrally in their original
formulations of exchange, the empirical research on exchange since the 1980s shifted attention to
power processes primarily independent of status dynamics. After two decades of concentrated work
on the role of network structure as a determinate of power in exchange networks it thus appears that
status processes have been given short shrift. In addition, some of the most developed theoretical
formulations on status dynamics in social relations during this same time period have given much less
attention to power than originally implicated in earlier work. For example, the earliest formulations
of expectations states theory in sociology (e.g., Berger, Cohen, & Zelditch, 1972 ) presented status as
a clear determinant of the observable power and prestige order within a group. Status in this sense is
viewed as a cause of differences in power and infl uence in society. In contrast, the exchange formula-
tion of power dynamics focused more attention on the structural and locational causes of power
differences. The location of an actor in a network was viewed as the key determinant of an actor’s
power and infl uence (in the form of control over needed resources such as knowledge, information or
goods and services at her disposal), and less attention was paid to the links between structurally
determined power and pre-existing status distinctions.
The interesting feature of the work by Thye ( 2000 ) and Lovaglia ( 1994 , 1995 ), among others, is
that they attempted to produce a conception of composite power – power that is determined by both
location in a structure of exchange relations and power that is derived from the status of the actors in
a hierarchy of status relations. Specifi cally, power in this framework is conceived as a structural
potential that enables some actors to earn favorable resource distributions at the expense of others.
The status of the actors in the exchange is viewed as having infl uence on the perceived value of the
resources to be exchanged. Resources (e.g., goods and services) associated with high status actors are
perceived to be of higher status value than those of low status actors and this valuation is symmetric.
That is, both low and high status actors have the same view (i.e., view high status actors’ resources as
more valuable). Thye’s (
2000 ) ndings indicate that there is a preference for interaction with high
status actors in exchange networks of equal power. Even in unequal power networks status confers an
advantage on high status actors. High status actors were more actively sought after as exchange part-
ners and received more favorable exchange rates in both equal and unequal (weak) power networks.
Thye, Willer, and Markovsky (
2006 ) demonstrated that high status actors not only earned more than
low status actors in the same position, but high status actors also exerted more infl uence over others
and were perceived as higher in competence.
This research began the interesting task of determining the separate effects of status and power
differentials. What are the mitigating effects of positional power or status when the two are not
3 Social Exchange Theory
68
consonant? How does low status affect the relative power of an actor with high positional power or
vice versa? The fi ndings Thye ( 2000 ) reports suggest that there is a combinatorial effect of status and
positional power in exchange networks in which weak power differences exist. The relatively high
status actors in lower power positions exercised more power and were preferred as exchange partners
more often than in networks in which there was no status distinction among the actors in the network,
only positional differences. The effort to link attributional and positional determinants of power is an
important direction for continued research in exchange network theory. It might draw on signifi -
cant developments in network methods (Faust & Wasserman, 1992 ) that allow the analysis of posi-
tional and attributional factors as predictors of network level events and processes. Thye (p. 426)
concluded that, “further research is needed to determine exactly how levels of power and status
differentially affect the tendency to seek partners for exchange.” Only relatively recently have others
began to explore this topic (e.g., Harkness, 2011 ).
Exchange, Fairness, and Commitment
Normative constraints on the exercise of power in exchange relations often include assessments of
fairness, feelings of obligation and interpersonal commitments. Following a discussion of fairness and
its role in social exchange, we discuss research on the emergence of interpersonal commitments in
exchange relations and networks.
Fairness
Both Homans ( 1961 ) and Blau ( 1964 ) included a conception of fair exchange in their theoretical formula-
tions. For Homans distributive justice exists when rewards align with investments, except where partici-
pation in the exchange involves costs beyond those investments. Taking costs into account, Homans
suggests that distributive justice obtains when the profi ts (rewards minus costs) of two actors engaged in
an exchange relation are equal. Blau addressed fairness norms as determinants of the “proper” exchange
rates. Norms of fair exchange develop over time, Blau argues, to regulate social exchange and to eliminate
continuous negotiation and confl ict over fair returns. The conception of fairness and distributive justice in
dyadic exchange was expanded in Homans’ work to include indirect exchange involving three or more
parties. The notion of indirect exchange and the evaluations of exchange relations by third parties were
important in the development of Blau’s more macro level theory of exchange and legitimacy.
Cook and Emerson (
1978 ) demonstrated in their work on exchange networks that equity concerns
could limit the potentially exploitative use of power by power-advantaged actors (i.e., those with a
positional advantage in a network of exchange relations). Once actors in the networks they studied
were informed of consequential inequalities in the distribution of profi t in the network subsequent
exchange refl ected a reduction in the demands made by the powerful actors in their exchanges and an
increase in the demands of the less powerful actors. The power differences alone did not operate to
justify the inequalities that emerged. Cook and Hegtvedt ( 1986 ) show that power disadvantaged actors
view inequality in the distribution of profi ts resulting from exchange as more unfair than do those who
have advantageous power positions in the network and who benefi t from these positions in terms of
higher rates of return.
Molm ( 1988 ) also studied the role of fairness concerns in the exercise of power in relatively small
exchange networks, typically four-person networks. In her research, the type of power the actor has
(reward power or coercive power) infl uences the perceived fairness of their partners’ power-use strate-
gies. Molm, Quist, and Wiseley ( 1994 ), for example, fi nd that those who are the recipients of coercion
K.S. Cook et al.
69
feel that the use of power by their exchange partner is fairer when the power user was power advantaged
than when she was power-disadvantaged. Thus, fairness judgments are affected not only by the power
of the power-wielder, but also by the level of power of the recipient of the power use.
Molm ( 1988 ) reports that fairness judgments also vary by the type of power being used, reward
power versus coercive power. Coercive power is used much less frequently in power-imbalanced rela-
tions and is likely to evoke strong fairness judgments when exercised. In fact the norm against the use
of coercive power appears to be quite strong in exchange settings. Molm argues that this is because of
the fear that the use of coercive power to bring a partner’s exchange behavior into line with expecta-
tions may have negative consequences, perhaps even leading to termination of the relationship. This
nding explains why coercive power is used much less frequently. When it is used, however, Molm’s
work suggests that it can be a fairly effective mechanism for aligning the interests of the parties to the
exchange relation. In this research tradition fairness judgments were based on individuals’ own
conceptions of justice and they extended beyond the evaluation of the exchange outcomes to include
the strategies actors used to exercise the power they had in the relationship.
The early exchange formulation of distributive justice produced by Homans was subsequently
criticized by a number of authors (e.g., Berger, Zelditch, Anderson, & Cohen, 1972 ; Jasso, 1980 ) for
focusing only on local comparisons (to one’s exchange partner or those similarly situated in an
exchange network) rather than referential comparisons (to groups or classes of actors). This criticism
led to the development of several alternative justice formulations, the most signifi cant of which was
developed by G. Jasso ( 1980 , 1986 , 1998 ).
For Jasso, justice is an evaluation of what one receives in exchange or in an allocation more gener-
ally in comparison with a standard or expectation regarding one’s “just share.” The formulation is
represented as: JE = In (actual share/just share). The logarithm is taken of the ratio of the actual share
to the just share to represent the empirical fact that individuals react more strongly to under-reward
(i.e., receiving less than one expects based on the just share) than to over- reward (i.e., receiving more
than one anticipated based on the just share). What is expected can be based on either a local compari-
son, an aggregate set of comparisons, comparison with a group, or with an abstract standard or princi-
ple (e.g., equal shares for all). Jasso argues that things like crime rates and collective action in the form
of strikes or revolutions are often consequences of perceived injustices among individuals and mem-
bers of various social groups. Her theory allows for the prediction of differential rates of response to
types of injustice based on the aggregate levels of perceived injustice in the relevant social group or
society and extends well beyond relations of exchange.
Various empirical tests (see Jasso, 2001 ) of some of these predictions provide some support for
Jasso’s theory of distributive justice. In a later section we address the role of emotions in exchange
relations. The introduction of fairness conceptions into exchange theory by the early theorists placed
emphasis on the emotional side of exchange. That actors could view their exchange as unfair or
unjust and react negatively with anger was one of the reasons Homans included fairness as a relevant
concept in his formulation of dyadic exchange. Actors who receive what they anticipate, he argues,
feel their exchange was just. Actors react with either the positive emotion of guilt (when receiving
more than they expect), or the negative emotion, anger (when receiving less than they expect). Jasso
makes a similar argument concerning the emotions that attend receiving or not receiving the “just
share” from an exchange or a simple allocation process.
Commitment
Like many other research topics within exchange theory, the earliest work on commitment formation
between exchange partners was largely focused on examining how levels of commitment were
affected by structural arrangements between the actors involved (Cook & Emerson, 1978 ;
3 Social Exchange Theory
70
Cook, Emerson, Gillmore, & Yamagishi, 1983 ; Markovsky et al., 1988 ). In exchange theory, commitment
refers to the extent to which an actor engages in repeated exchanges with the same partner over time.
Examples include relations between friends, collaborators, marital partners, and colleagues, among
others. Connections to other social psychological concepts such as social uncertainty (Cook & Emerson,
1984 ; Kollock, 1994 ; Yamagishi, Cook, & Watabe, 1998 ) or affect (Lawler & Yoon, 1998 ; Lawler,
Yoon & Thye 2000 ; Molm et al., 2000 ) were later developments and refi nements. Even in some of the
earliest experimental work on social exchange (Cook & Emerson, 1978 ; Stolte & Emerson, 1977 ),
researchers were interested in actor’s commitments to particular relations within an opportunity struc-
ture of alternative relations. Cook and Emerson, for example, originally described commitment
within the context of social exchange as “an interpersonal attachment leading persons to exchange
repeatedly with the same partners.” For them, commitment was defi ned in pure behavioral terms, as
the frequency to exchange with a given partner relative to all available exchange opportunities. They
found that power-use and commitment were inversely related.
Commitments, moreover, have been shown to be a function of the distribution of power
throughout an exchange network (Lawler & Yoon, 1998 ; Markovsky et al., 1988 ). Markovsky and
his collaborators argue that some network structures (which they refer to as strong-power networks)
allow exclusion in any given round without reducing the rates of exchange for the non- excluded
members. Commitments in such network structures are rare. Take, for example, three actors
connected in a line, A to B to C. Actor B is pulled equally toward and away from each A and C.
Alternatively some network structures promote commitments. The classic, “kite-shaped” network
of four persons (one actor with three alternatives, two with two alternatives-one other and the
central actor-and a third actor connected only to the central actor) promotes commitment between
the central actor and the actor with only one alternative, and a second committed relation between
the remaining two actors (Skvoretz & Willer, 1993 ). The potential for commitment thus varies with
network structure.
While commitment has been shown to be a function of power-use (Cook & Emerson, 1978 ) as well
as the distribution of power in a network (Markovsky et al., 1988 ), much of the research within social
exchange theory has linked commitment to social uncertainty. The conceptualization of uncertainty,
however, has undergone some modifi cation over time. Initially, Cook and Emerson ( 1984 , p. 13)
argued “uncertainty refers to the subjective probability of concluding a satisfactory transaction with
any partner”. They found that greater uncertainty led to higher levels of commitment with particular
exchange partners within an opportunity structure. Actors formed these commitments, they argued,
because it increased the frequency of completed exchanges, thereby increasing an actor’s overall
level of benefi t. While this conceptualization of uncertainty was also used by Markovsky and his
collaborators (Markovsky et al., 1988 , 1993 ) in their work on exclusion, other social exchange
theorists opted for a different operationalization of social uncertainty.
Uncertainty in subsequent research has been conceived as the probability of suffering from acts of
opportunism imposed by one’s exchange partners (Kollock,
1994 ; Rice, 2002 ; Yamagishi et al., 1998 ).
For example, when selling a used product in an online marketplace a buyer may be worried about the
quality of the item while a seller may face uncertainty about receiving payment. In this line of research,
uncertainty has also been shown to promote commitment formation (Kollock, 1994 ; Rice, 2002 ;
Yamagishi et al., 1998 ). Commitments in these studies are examined in environments that allow actors
to cheat one another in their exchanges, thus commitments to specifi c relations become a viable solu-
tion to the problem of uncertainty. If an actor or subset of actors within a given opportunity structure
prove themselves to be trustworthy, continued exchanges with that exchange partner provides a safe
haven from other potentially opportunistic partners. Such commitments, however, have the drawback
of incurring sizable opportunity costs in the form of exchange opportunities foregone in favor of the
relative safety provide by ongoing commitments.
In Kollock’s ( 1994 ) initial study connecting opportunistic uncertainty and interpersonal commit-
ment, actors exchanged in two different environments. In one environment (low uncertainty) the true
K.S. Cook et al.
71
value of the goods being exchanged was known, while in the other (high uncertainty) environment the
true value of goods was withheld until the end of the negotiations. He found that actors had a greater
tendency to form commitments in the higher uncertainty environment. Moreover, actors were willing
to forgo more profi table exchanges with untested partners in favor of continuing to transact with
known partners who had demonstrated their trustworthiness in previous transactions (i.e., they did not
misrepresent the value of their goods).
Yamagishi et al. ( 1998 ) further explored the connections between uncertainty and commitment, devi-
ating from Kollock’s experimental design but coming to similar conclusions. In their experiment, actors
were faced with the decision of remaining with a given partner or entering a pool of unknown potential
partners. They employed several modifi cations of this basic design, but in each instance the expected
value of exchange outside the existing relation was higher than the returns from the current relation.
They found that actors were willing to incur sizeable opportunity costs to reduce the risks associated
with opportunism. Moreover, they found that uncertainty in either the form of an uncertain probability
of loss or of an unknown amount of loss promoted commitments between exchange partners.
Rice ( 2002 ) attempted to bridge this early work on uncertainty as the probability of fi nding an
exchange partner with the work on uncertainty as environments that allow opportunism. In both the
Kollock ( 1994 ) and Yamagishi et al. ( 1998 ) studies, exchange occurs among actors in environments,
which allow for potential opportunism, but where actors are guaranteed of fi nding an exchange part-
ner on every round. In Rice’s design, actors exchanged in two different environments: one that allowed
actors to renege on their negotiated exchange rates (high uncertainty) and one where negotiations
were binding (low uncertainty). Exchange, however, also occurred in two different network struc-
tures: a complete network where all actors could always fi nd a partner, and a T-shaped network, where
two actors were excluded from exchange every round. He found that uncertainty promoted commit-
ment in the complete network, but not in the T-shaped (strong-power) network. Commitments, he
argued, are viable solutions to uncertainty in networks that do not force exclusion. In networks that
do force exclusion, the structural pull away from commitment is suffi ciently intense as to undermine
the propensity to form commitments. Whereas the earlier work of Kollock and Yamagishi and his
collaborators suggested that actors would incur sizeable opportunity costs to avoid potentially oppor-
tunistic partners, Rice’s work suggested that such tendencies could be muted by particularly determin-
istic network structures.
Rice ( 2002 ), moreover, expanded the work on social uncertainty in exchange by exploring how
commitment relates to other exchange outcomes, such as the distribution of resources across relations
and within networks as a whole. He argued that commitments reduced the use of power in imbalanced
networks, resulting in a more egalitarian distribution of resources across different positions in a net-
work. In networks where power between actors is unequal, power-advantaged actors have relatively
better opportunities for exchange than their power-disadvantaged partners. These superior alternatives
are the basis of the power-advantaged actor’s power. If, as uncertainty increases, power-advantaged
actors form commitments with power-disadvantaged actors, they erode the very base of their power.
Forming commitments entails ignoring potential opportunities. Alternative relations are the basis of
structural power and as these relations atrophy, the use of power and the unequal distribution of
resources will be reduced.
Results on exchange under social uncertainty indicate a strong tendency for actors to incur large
opportunity costs by forming commitments to achieve the relative safety or certainty of ongoing
exchange with proven trustworthy partners (Kollock,
1994 ; Rice, 2002 ; Yamagishi et al., 1998 ). In
addition to these opportunity costs Rice argued that commitments may also have unintended nega-
tive consequences at the macro level of exchange. Actors tend to invest less heavily in their exchange
relations under higher levels of uncertainty. Moreover, acts of defection in exchange while producing
individual gain, result in a collective loss, an outcome common in prisoner’s dilemma games. Both
processes reduce the overall collective gains to exchange in the network as a whole. So while there
is a socially positive aspect to uncertainty, in so far as commitments increase feelings of solidarity
3 Social Exchange Theory
72
(e.g., Lawler & Yoon, 1998 ) and resources are exchanged more equally across relations (Rice), there
is the attendant drawback of reduced aggregate levels of exchange productivity and effi ciency.
Emotion and Exchange
Work on the role of emotion in social exchange over the past two decades represents a distinct move
away from the traditional focus on the structural determinants of exchange outcomes, although it
returns to some of the topics included in the work of the early exchange theorists, including the
emotions associated with fairness in exchange relations. Much of the actual empirical work on
exchange investigates specifi cally how the social structure affects the outcomes of exchange such as
power-use and commitment. The bulk of this research has shown that actors who are simply pursuing
their own interests can unknowingly generate inequities in the distribution of resources and pattern
exchange relations such that certain relations within an opportunity structure are favored over others.
This results from the power differences among actors derived from their positions in a network of
exchange and is a pure structural effect. Subsequent research began to explore the emotional conse-
quences of such patterns of exchange and the role that emotions play in the actual structuring of the
network of exchange relations.
Edward Lawler and his collaborators (Lawler , 2001 ; Lawler & Yoon, 1993 , 1996 ; Lawler et al.
2000 ), for example, examined various aspects of emotion and exchange in their work on affect and
relational cohesion. More recently Lawler and his colleagues have developed applications of the Affect
Theory of Social Exchange to what they call “micro social orders” (Lawler et al., 2008 ). Molm and her
collaborators (Molm et al., 1999 , 2000 ) also began to explore the role of emotions in exchange but they
focused more on affect as an outcome of exchange rather than as a mediating factor. A related line of
research by Molm and her colleagues (Molm, Collett, & Schaefer, 2007 ) aims to systematically exam-
ine how the structure of reciprocity affects the development of trust and solidarity in social exchange.
While these two bodies of research each represent a move away from the predominantly structural
concerns refl ected in earlier empirical work on exchange (e.g., Bienenstock & Bonacich, 1997 ; Cook
et al., 1983 ; Markovsky et al., 1988 ), the move to include affect more centrally in social exchange
theory has deep connections to the classical exchange formulations. Blau ( 1964 ), for instance, was
particularly concerned with the emergent properties of exchange relations. He argued that ongoing
relationships of social exchange develop intrinsic value to the exchange partners over time, a central
tenet of Relational Cohesion Theory (Lawler & Yoon, 1996 , 1998 ; Lawler et al., 2000 ). Moreover,
Emerson ( 1972b ) theorized explicitly about cohesion, liking and commitment as emergent outcomes
of successful exchange relations, all outcomes examined by Molm and her colleagues (Molm et al.,
1999 , 2000 ). We discuss each line of research in turn, focusing on the key theoretical contributions to
exchange theory. Then we briefl y describe a recent attempt by Kuwabara ( 2011 ) to reconcile fi ndings
from both lines of research.
Relational Cohesion, Solidarity, and Micro Social Order
Relational Cohesion Theory is based on the premise that emotion is a proximal mechanism in the
exchange process, mediating the effects of structural arrangements on behavioral outcomes. The basic
model which Lawler and Yoon (
1993 , 1996 , 1998 ) originally proposed argued for a simple causal
chain. First, structural power positively affects the frequency of exchanges between actors, which in
turn results in the development of positive everyday emotions (e.g., liking, satisfaction). These emo-
tions then lead to relational cohesion, which positively affects behavioral outcomes such as
K.S. Cook et al.
73
commitment to the relation. It is important to note their focus on the relation as the unit of theoretical
and empirical analysis. Lawler and Yoon ( 1993 , 1996 , 1998 ) repeatedly stress that central to this
process is the idea that actors come to see an ongoing exchange relationship itself as an object toward
which they develop emotional responses. Because of this focus, task interdependence is a key factor
in the development of social cohesion. They are careful to point out that each effect in the chain is
dependent on the previous step. It is only relational cohesion that is expected to have a direct effect on
commitment behaviors. All other variables work through relational cohesion.
Their early work generated a great deal of empirical support for many aspects of the theory (Lawler
& Yoon, 1993 , 1996 , 1998 ). Exchange partners expressed positive emotions about their relation-
ships and these positive emotions increased commitment to these relations. Two unanticipated results,
however, have led to subsequent modifi cations of their theory. First, they found that perceptions of
uncertainty and the frequency of exchange have enduring independent effects on relational cohesion
and commitment (Lawler & Yoon, 1996 ) as Cook and Emerson and Yamagishi et al. argued. Second,
when social network structures were added to their empirical tests, the effects of relational cohesion
became more complex. In egalitarian relationships (i.e., equal power), they found that affect acted in
accordance with their theory. However, in power imbalanced dyads, relational cohesion had a positive
effect on commitment for powerful actors but a negative effect on commitment for less powerful
members of the dyad (Lawler & Yoon, 1998 ). This latter fi nding revealed that individual actors within
a given relationship seem to have different orientations to the relationship, violating the relational
focus of the theory (but see Leik & Leik, 1972 ).
These empirical outcomes led to subsequent modifi cations in the basic model proposed in the
original theoretical formulation (Lawler et al., 2000 ). Lawler and his colleagues acknowledged that
two parallel processes affect the development of relational cohesion, one emotional and the other
more cognitive. Actors are motivated to form commitments to reduce uncertainty (Cook & Emerson,
1984 ; Kollock, 1994 ). They argue that this cognitive process is one of boundary defi ning, in which
individuals who are interested in reducing the possibilities of a loss by increasing the predictability of
exchange outcomes come to see relations as distinct social entities. The emotional aspect of exchange
is a social bonding process in which the relation becomes an object of intrinsic or expressive value.
As was the case with their earlier formulation, this more refi ned model also fi nds empirical support,
with one important caveat. The independent effect of “predictability,” the proximate cognitive causal
mechanism, has no direct effect on cohesion, but perplexingly from the theory’s standpoint has a
strong independent effect on commitment.
In a related line of work Lawler, Thye, and Yoon ( 2008 ) focus on the development of micro social
order. Lawler and colleagues describe micro social order as being characterized by the following:
repeated interactions, emotional responses, perceptions of a group, and affective sentiments con-
cerning the exchange relationship. Importantly, micro social orders are conceptualized as being
emergent social units that do not yet take the form of a fully developed social group. And, as with
Relational Cohesion Theory, the development of micro social order depends on actors attributing
feelings to a social unit rather than to another specifi c partner or to the self.
In theorizing about the emergence of micro social order, the authors argue that forms of exchange
that are characterized by more task jointness and a greater sense of shared responsibility for outcomes
will lead to the creation of stronger micro social orders. Findings support this claim and Lawler et al.
(
2008 ) experimentally demonstrate that productive exchange (in which jointness of the task and
shared responsibility are highest) leads to the development of the strongest micro social order, while
generalized exchange leads to the weakest (and negotiated and reciprocal forms of exchange fall in
between). A micro social order evolves when actors involved in repeated interactions begin feeling
emotions and affective sentiments in addition to experiencing emergent perceptions of a “group”.
However, at this stage the idea of the group has not fully developed. They argue that an emergent
micro social order is a somewhat tenuous state, which is still characterized more by individualistic
than collective, group-oriented motivations.
3 Social Exchange Theory
74
A Theory of Reciprocity in Exchange Relations
Molm and her collaborators (Molm et al., 1999 , 2000 ), while having an equally strong interest in the
connections between affect and commitment in social exchange, have a markedly different conception
of the social psychological processes at play. For them, affect is not a proximal mechanism promoting
commitment to particular relationship. In their theory, emotion is an outcome of the exchange process
generated largely by commitments to exchange relations. The structural arrangements, not emotional
mechanisms are responsible for differences in commitment behaviors that exist across different
exchange structures. They argue that level of affect is determined by the form of exchange (i.e., recip-
rocal or negotiated) and by the degree of behavioral commitment induced by the nature of the avail-
able alternatives to exchange in a social network (Molm et al., 2000 ).
Central to Molm and her colleagues’ theory is the delineation of two distinct components of commit-
ment, one behavioral and the other affective. The behavioral aspect of commitment focuses on the pat-
terns of exchange found in networks of social exchange, in which actors choose to interact repeatedly
with one another rather than with their available alternatives. The affective component, however, is
concerned with the emotional bonds that develop from repeated experiences with successful exchanges
between the same partners. This dimension of commitment shares many similarities with Lawler et al.’s
(
2000 ) “social bonding” aspect of relational cohesion, but there is a critical distinction that must be made
between the conceptions of bonding included in each of these theories. In Relational Cohesion Theory,
“social bonding” centers around an exchange relation as a social object, whereas Molm and her col-
leagues discuss emotion directed toward a particular partner, not the relation or group.
Molm et al. ( 1999 ) argue that the social psychological mechanisms responsible for each of the
two kinds of commitment are different. Behavioral commitment is determined by the structure of
the exchange relations. Large power imbalances lead to low levels of interpersonal commitment
while power-balanced (or equal) relations promote commitment behaviors (Molm et al., 2000 ; see
also Cook & Emerson, 1978 ). Affective commitment, however, is a function of two infl uences: the
type of exchange and the level of behavioral commitment. In reciprocal exchanges, as opposed to
negotiated exchanges, there are great uncertainties surrounding the outcomes of exchange; partners
are not obligated to return gifts or engage in acts of reciprocity. This lack of certainty leads actors
to develop feelings of trust (based on credible signals of trustworthiness) and other positive affec-
tive orientations toward their partners as successful exchange relations emerge over time. Moreover,
as the level of behavioral commitment increases, so too does an actor’s level of positive affect
toward her partner.
There are two important distinctions to be made between these theories of emotion in social
exchange. First, Molm and her colleagues see affect as directed toward specifi c exchange partners
whereas Lawler and his collaborators stress the centrality of the exchange relation as the object of
affect. While each theorist is careful to distinguish their primary unit of analysis, it is not entirely clear
that such distinctions are crucial. Lawler and Yoon (
1998 ) have found that looking at actor-specifi c,
relational affect is empirically and theoretically fruitful, despite their careful use of relations and not
individuals as the main unit of analysis in their theory. Moreover, in practice actors may have great
diffi culty separating affect directed toward a relation from affect directed toward a partner. The second
difference may be more critical. Molm et al. ( 2000 ) see affect as an outcome, whereas Lawler et al.
(
2000 ) view affect as a proximal mechanism. When emotion is taken to be an outcome, structural
issues still dominate theorizing, as Molm and her colleagues are careful to point out. When emotion
becomes a causal mechanism, however, structural arrangements can then become outcomes. If emo-
tion dictates patterns of behavior to the extent that alternative relations atrophy and cease to become
viable exchange alternatives, the shape of the social networks of actors engaged in exchange can be
altered. While Lawler and his collaborators continue to fi nd enduring independent effects for factors
outside of relational cohesion, their theoretical orientation may provide crucial insights into the
dynamic linkages between structure and action.
K.S. Cook et al.
75
Molm et al. ( 2007 ; Molm, 2010 ) have recently examined how the structure of exchange affects the
development of solidarity. Proposing a general theory concerning the structure of reciprocity and soli-
darity in exchange, Molm and her collaborators focus on whether exchange is direct or indirect and
whether it occurs bilaterally or unilaterally. While their study is methodologically similar to Lawler
et al.’s ( 2008 ) work on the development of micro social order, their results differ. Molm fi nds that
generalized exchange produces the highest level of social solidarity (with reciprocal exchange pro-
ducing a lower relative level of solidarity and negotiated exchange leading to the lowest level). They
identify three key factors that explain this fi nding: the risk of non- reciprocity, the salience of confl ict,
and the expressive value of reciprocity. The authors propose that the risk of non-reciprocity is greater
in generalized exchange since benefi ts fl ow unilaterally (while in bilateral forms of exchange, typical
of negotiated exchange, the risk of non-reciprocity is virtually eliminated). Moreover, the expressive
value (or the symbolic meaning independent of instrumental benefi t) is greater in generalized exchange
since reciprocity is highly uncertain and indirect (e.g. A gives to B, B gives to C, C gives to A).
Finally, Molm argues that salience of confl ict is lowest in generalized exchange since giving is very
indirect and it is much harder to compare outcomes in a network of generalized exchange than in
negotiated or reciprocal forms of exchange.
Recent work by Kuwabara ( 2011 ) proposes that the nature of the exchange context is a crucial fac-
tor in distinguishing between Lawler and Molm’s fi ndings. By examining competitively and coopera-
tively framed exchange settings, Kuwabara demonstrates how differences in Lawler’s theory of
relational cohesion and Molm’s work on affective outcomes in exchange can be reconciled. He argues
that bilateral or transactional forms of exchange, like negotiation between two parties, will produce
solidarity when experienced by the actors primarily as a cooperative venture. However, when bilateral
exchange is perceived as competitive, actors’ feelings of solidarity will be inhibited in part because
the salience of confl icting interests will be higher, as Molm suggests. By experimentally manipulating
cooperative and competitive contexts in bilateral and unilateral exchanges, Kuwabara demonstrates
distributive negotiation (in which confl ict of interest is high) and one- way trust games (also highly
competitive) lead to lower levels of cohesion, while integrative negotiation (in which there is room for
compromise) and two-way trust games (highly cooperative) create higher levels of cohesion.
Kuwabara’s work suggests that the development of relational cohesion through task jointness
(Lawler’s theory) and the emergence of trust through risk-taking (Molm’s theory) are distinct pro-
cesses that together increase our understanding of the role of affect in exchange relations. Affect and
emotion may also play a role in collective action and the resolution of social dilemmas.
Collective Action and Social Exchange
Research on social exchange has many theoretical ties to the enormous body of research on social
dilemmas (for a thorough review of this research see, e.g., Yamagishi,
1995 ). The theoretical prob-
lems, however, faced by theorists of power and dependence generate a unique perspective on the
problems of collective action in exchange (e.g., Cook & Gillmore, 1984 ; Lawler et al., 2000 ; Leik,
1992 ). As with most collective action problems, actors in social exchange contexts face the competing
pressures of satisfying their own interests and participating in the provision of collective goods.
Moreover, while exchanges are often the outcome of explicit negotiations, many exchanges occur
within contexts in which there is no explicit bargaining and no guarantee that partners will fulfi ll their
obligations (Kollock, 1994 ; Molm, 1997a , 1997b ; Yamagishi et al., 1998 ). Such uncertainties charac-
terize a large number of exchanges outside of the laboratory (Heckathorn, 1985 ). Heckathorn has
argued that exchanges in the “real world” are thus the product of two factors: the explicit negotiation
over social goods and the individual decision to abide by the terms of trade. He claims that social
exchange thus entails not only the bargaining over social goods, but also the playing out of a prison-
er’s dilemma concerning the fulfi llment of social obligations.
3 Social Exchange Theory
76
The dynamics of power and dependence within networks of exchange partners create additional
problems of collective action that cannot be characterized as a prisoner’s dilemma. Power inequality
creates strains in exchange relations and provides an impetus for structural changes, creating prob-
lems of collective action unique to exchange contexts (Cook & Gillmore, 1984 ; Emerson, 1972b ;
Lawler & Yoon, 1998 ). Before turning to empirical work on such collective action problems within
exchange networks it is necessary to briefl y review Emerson’s ( 1972b ) ideas concerning power-bal-
ancing mechanisms, for this theory constitutes the intellectual basis for this work. Emerson argued
that reciprocity was a core feature of exchange relations over the long term and that ongoing exchange
relations could be characterized as relations in which a balance of power existed. Power imbalances,
he argued, were a somewhat temporary state of social relations, which generated strains in exchange
relations to be resolved. He claimed that four distinct “balancing” operations existed which would
stabilize unequal power relationships. Within the context of a given dyadic exchange relation, if the
dependence of an actor A for good y (controlled by actor B) is greater than B’s dependence on A for
good x (controlled by actor A), there are four possible outcomes: First, there can be a decrease in the
value of good y for actor A, called withdrawal . Second, there can be an increase in the value of x for
actor B, called status-giving . Third, there can be an increase in the availability of resource y to A often
as a result of an increase in the number of alternatives open to A, called network extension . Fourth,
there can be a reduction in the number of alternatives for resources of value open to B, called coalition
formation . Note that the fi rst two mechanisms concern changes in value whereas the second two focus
on structural change. With the exception of Emerson ( 1987 ) exchange theorists have focused their
energies on exploring the latter two outcomes.
The work on coalition formation (e.g., Cook & Gillmore, 1984 ) has empirically demonstrated that
power imbalances do promote the formation of coalitions. In a network in which there are power
imbalances, some actors can be characterized as power-advantaged while others are power-disadvan-
taged. In simple hierarchical network structures in which one power-advantaged actor exchanges with
a number of power- disadvantaged actors, a coalition of all power- disadvantaged actors against the
power-advantaged actor will balance power in the network (Cook & Gillmore). Those coalitions that
do not include all disadvantaged actors will not attain power-balance because the power- advantaged
actor still possesses alternatives to the coalition. Moreover, coalitions that include all power-disadvan-
taged actors tend to be stable over time, as Emerson ( 1972b ) would argue they should. Coalitions,
however, that do not include all disadvantaged actors tend to deteriorate over time. More recently
Borch and Willer ( 2006 ) analyze power and the formation of coalitions in exchange networks from a
game theoretic perspective. They similarly fi nd that coalitions among the less powerful are a counter-
vailing force, when they occur.
The tensions generated by power inequality can also result in network extension. Power- disad-
vantaged actors rather than banding together to form coalitions to balance power, may alterna-
tively seek out new relations, thus also reducing their dependence on a given actor for valued
resources. This solution to power balance has been less thoroughly explored by exchange research-
ers, but nevertheless warrants a brief discussion.
Leik ( 1992 ) proposed a theory of network extension and contraction based on the theoretical prin-
ciples of the GPI model developed in Network Exchange Theory (e.g., Markovsky et al., 1988 , 1993 ;
Willer & Anderson, 1981 ). He argues that so long as actors are assumed to be trying to maximize their
power vis-a-vis their partners, power-advantaged actors will attempt to reduce linkages between part-
ners in an effort to consolidate their power while power- disadvantaged actors will attempt to create
new linkages to increase their power. He goes on to explain that such a theory requires that actors have
a great deal of information and strategic savvy: “Without suffi cient information and the savvy to uti-
lize it, neither the weak nor the strong will be able to perceive the advantage of linkage changes”
(Leik, p. 316). Empirical work by Lawler and Yoon (
1998 ), however, suggests that emotional responses
to inequality may be suffi cient to motivate network extension.
While Lawler and Yoon are explicitly concerned with developing a theory of relational cohesion
based on affect directed toward exchange relations (see the discussion of this work above), their
K.S. Cook et al.
77
empirical work sheds light on issues of network extension. Toward the end of their experiment, actors
are freed from the constraints of their initial network of exchange relations and allowed to interact
with every other participant. Actors in relations that can be characterized as power balanced continued
to seek out one another in exchange. Power-advantaged actors likewise continued to solicit exchanges
from their disadvantaged partners, whereas the disadvantaged attempted to form new relations with
other participants who had not been previously exploitative (Lawler & Yoon, 1998 ). Thus, the nega-
tive affect directed toward a power- advantaged actor by a power-disadvantaged partner in concert
with the low levels of reward accrued by power-disadvantaged actors seems suffi cient to motivate
network extension.
Beyond the issues of power-balancing operations and the prisoner’s dilemma features of exchange
relations, a third type of collective action problem has arisen in recent research on generalized
exchange. Generalized exchange exists when individuals exchange valued resources indirectly and
without explicit agreement (Molm & Cook, 1995 ). In generalized exchange, the rewards that an
individual receives from others do not depend on the resources provided by that individual (Ekeh,
1974 ; Emerson, 1976 ; Yamagishi & Cook, 1993 ). Because giving and receiving valued goods and
services is indirect, generalized exchange relations inherently involve a minimum of three actors.
Moreover, there is no one-to-one correspondence between what two actors directly give to and
receive from one another.
There have been several empirical studies that attempt to explain how such complex exchange
systems may emerge (Bearman, 1997 ; Cheshire, 2005 ; Mark, 2003 ; Takahashi, 2000 ; Takahashi &
Yamagishi, 1996 , 1999 ; Ziegler, 1990 ). Generalized exchange is challenging to explain since indi-
viduals have an incentive not to give their valued resources to others. However, if everyone in the
network refuses to give they clearly do worse since no one gains. Thus, the typical structure of a
generalized exchange system entails the classic incentives of a social dilemma (see Yamagishi,
1995 ). Coordination problems are also likely, especially as the size of the network increases. Actors
exchange indirectly with more than two participants, so individuals must rely on the goodwill of a
third party over which they have no direct control. Without assurances of reciprocity or mutually
contingent exchanges, actors can “free-ride” on the contributions of others by collecting rewards
while refusing to reward others (see Yamagishi).
In his review and synthesis of various forms of direct and indirect social exchange, Peter Ekeh
( 1974 ) describes several different types of generalized exchange. One of the major types in his
classifi cation is group-focused generalized exchange. This type of generalized exchange involves
individuals who independently choose whether to contribute to a collective good or not. Yamagishi
and Cook ( 1993 ) refer to this type of system as “group-generalized” exchange because individuals
pool their resources centrally as a group, and receive indirect benefi ts from the collective good rather
than directly from other individuals (in contrast to the decentralized nature of network-generalized
exchange). Examples include communities that pool resources to create valued shared outcomes such
as a school or a town bridge (Yamagishi & Cook,
1993 ), some forms of digital fi le sharing in peer-to-
peer Internet systems (Cheshire, 2005 ), combining resources for business ventures (Ruef, 2003 ), and
online information sharing and redistribution (Cheshire & Antin, 2009 ).
Online environments provide a ripe opportunity for the sociological study of large-scale group-
generalized exchange. For example, digital information goods (Kollock, 1999a ) are often pooled as a
collective good from which individuals receive benefi ts. Drawing on Kollock’s ( 1999a ) initial insights,
Shah and Levine ( 2003 ) and Cheshire ( 2005 ) argue that many digital goods have near-pure jointness
of supply (i.e., they are non-rival goods) because many enjoy such goods and those who contribute
need not lose value. Since digital goods can typically be perfectly replicated, the contributor keeps a
copy when she makes a contribution (Cheshire,
2005 ; Cheshire & Cook, 2004 ; Kollock, 1999a , b ).
The second key type of generalized exchange is chain-generalized, in which each individual gives
goods or services directly to other individuals in chains or cyclic patterns of exchange. Yamagishi and
Cook ( 1993 ) refer to this form of exchange as network-generalized since individuals receive goods or
services from others in the same network. The non-economic exchange of necklaces and bracelets
3 Social Exchange Theory
78
among the Trobriand Islanders in Papua New Guinea (Malinowski, 1922 ) is a classic example of this
type of generalized exchange. Bearman’s ( 1997 ) observation of aboriginal tribes that exchange
women between families also constitutes a form of network- generalized exchange. Other common
examples include stranded motorists in small communities where individuals help one another when
necessary, but rarely (if ever) in a direct, reciprocal fashion (Yamagishi & Cook, 1993 ). Early anthro-
pological and sociological research in this tradition predicts that indirect, generalized exchange will
lead to high social solidarity in a given society, compared to more direct forms of negotiation and
bargaining. Recent experimental research by Molm and her colleagues supports this classic prediction
as noted above (Molm et al., 2007 ).
The production of collective action is a diffi cult problem in both network-generalized and group-
generalized exchange because the interests of individuals and those of the larger collective often
confl ict. One way to alleviate this problem is to share information about prior interactions with new
partners, thereby creating mutual benefi ts within the collective. Takahashi ( 2000 ) uses simulations
to show that when self-interested actors can pass along information about the behaviors of others,
network-generalized exchange does emerge. This occurs when individuals employ a fairness-based
selective-giving strategy (see also Mark, 2002 ). Takahashi assumes individuals in generalized exchange
want to give more often to those with higher ratios of giving or receiving. Although this explanation
works in situations in which reputations exist, it potentially fails when individuals are anonymous or
when identities can be easily changed, as is often the case in online interactions (Yamagishi et al.,
2009 ). Takahashi’s solution, like many solutions to the problem of the evolution of cooperation in
systems of repeated prisoners’ dilemmas, relies on the existence of network structures that provide
some sort of localized information and accountability (e.g., Axelrod, 1984 ; Macy & Skvoretz, 1998 ).
Norms regarding contributions can emerge and persist in these network structures through systems of
reputation, monitoring and sanctioning. However, the existence of reputation and sanctioning struc-
tures creates a “second-order” social dilemma since at least some minimal group of individuals must
rst create and subsequently maintain these systems.
One promising avenue of research on large systems of network-generalized exchange examines uni-
lateral online sharing of goods, services, and information. For example, on websites such as NetCycler.
com and Freecycle.org, individuals give unneeded goods to others who indicate that they have a need for
those same goods. In systems such as Freecycle.org, direct negotiation or payment is explicitly dis-
couraged to sustain the culture of a unilateral gift economy. Many of these systems have become popu-
lar, prompting researchers to examine how online generalized exchange systems can foster group
identity, solidarity and community among participants over time (Suhonen et al., 2010 ; Willer, Flynn, &
Zak, 2010). Without the relative security of direct negotiation and sanctions for failed agreements, these
online systems foster perceptions of uncertainty that can be diffi cult for potential exchange participants
to overcome (Suhonen et al., 2010 ). Furthermore, many of these systems involve hybrid online-offl ine
social exchanges where the matching of givers and receivers takes place online, but the actual exchanges
occur offl ine. The relative risks and sources of uncertainty may be minimal when the exchanges take
place in small, local communities (Suhonen et al.,
2010 ), but the risks may be much higher when indi-
viduals must meet in-person to complete an exchange. In some cases the risks are especially conspicu-
ous, as with Couchsurfi ng.com where individuals use an online system to link travelers to hosts who
provide space in their own homes for visitors (Lauterbach, Truong, Shah, & Adamic, 2009 ).
Methodology and Social Exchange
Ethnography, participant-observation, and inductive reasoning formed the base from which different
approaches and research methods to analyze social exchange would later emerge. The fi rst empirical
descriptions and examples of social exchange processes came from the work of anthropologists such
K.S. Cook et al.
79
as Malinowski ( 1922 ) and Mauss ( 1923 ). In his ethnographic examination of the Kula ring among the
Trobriand islanders of Papua New Guinea, Malinowski provided the fi rst in-depth documentation of
stable generalized exchange within a society. Mauss ( 1923 ) later combined Malinowski’s observations
with several other ethnographic examples into his book, The Gift , which was among the fi rst critical
analyses of the role of gifts and reciprocity in social life.
The next major theoretical development in the examination of social exchange came from the
convergence of the psychological approaches of Homans ( 1958 , 1961 ) and Thibaut and Kelley
( 1959 ). Although Homans’ perspective was based primarily on the psychology of instrumental behav-
ior and Thibaut and Kelley focused on the examination of dyads and small groups of dyads, both
research traditions built on the same anthropological fi eld research and case studies to develop poten-
tially testable theories of social exchange. Blau’s ( 1964 ) version of social exchange, though not based
on the exact same assumptions as either Homans or Thibaut and Kelley, also built on the earlier eth-
nographic and fi eld research. Despite a strong foundation of propositions, theoretical arguments and
clear predictions, Homans, Thibaut and Kelly, and Blau never conducted controlled studies of their
respective approaches to social exchange theory. Instead, much of the empirical evidence for social
exchange theory in the 1950s and 1960s was limited to case studies.
The more formalized version of social exchange theory developed by Emerson ( 1972a , 1972b )
combined with the unique adoption of networked computers helped to bring controlled experimen-
tal testing to the study of social exchange in dyads and networks (Cook & Emerson, 1978 ; Cook
et al., 1983 ; Cook & Yamagishi, 1992 ; Yamagishi, Gillmore, & Cook, 1988 ). The rst experimental
studies by Emerson, Cook and their colleagues were quickly followed by an upsurge in laboratory
experiments by other researchers on different aspects of social exchange, including further exami-
nations of power dynamics (Molm, 1985 , 1990 ; Willer, Markovsky, & Patton, 1989 ), coercion
(Lawler, Ford, & Blegen, 1988 ; Willer & Anderson, 1981 ), commitment (Lawler & Yoon, 1993 ),
and emotion (Lawler & Yoon, 1998 ). As a supplement to experimental studies as well as a tool to
elaborate certain aspects of theory, computer simulation and game-theoretical modeling also
became useful tools for investigating network dynamics, power and social exchange (Bienenstock
& Bonacich, 1992 , 1993 , 1997 ; Whitmeyer, 1997a , 1997b ). For example, game-theoretic modeling
allows researchers to use different parameters to calculate specific predictions about power
distributions among actors in a given network structure. In more recent years, experimental inves-
tigations of social exchange processes have expanded to include studies of trust (Cook et al., 2005 ;
Molm, 2003 ) and transitions between modes of social exchange (Cheshire, Gerbasi, & Cook, 2010 ;
Molm, Whitham, & Melamed, 2012 ).
The development of controlled laboratory experiments remains the dominant methodological
approach for testing predictions from social exchange theory and examining related issues of power,
status, equity, and trust, among others. The specifi c characteristics of the experimental studies men-
tioned above vary by researcher, independent variables, and focal outcomes. Yet, the central features
of these experiments are fundamentally the same. First, most experiments in this tradition are con-
ducted using networked computers and all interactions take place only through the computer inter-
face to assure that behavior is affected solely by experimental manipulations and not by individual
characteristics. The setting must meet the general scope conditions of the theory, while making it
possible to control key aspects of exchanges (structures and processes) to measure exchange out-
comes (Molm,
2007 ).
Second, subjects are randomly assigned to positions in a particular exchange structure, such as
dyads or larger network forms. Third, valued resources are distributed to each participant (e.g., vir-
tual coins, units with different names and associated values such as “X’s” and “Y’s”), and these
valued resources are worth money that is provided at the end of the given study. Although social
exchange in natural environments occurs with a variety of different resources including status,
approval or expert guidance, money allows researchers to quantify and control the value across dif-
ferent actors and over time (Molm,
2007 ). Finally, participants exchange their valued resources
3 Social Exchange Theory
80
for others’ valued resources either in one-time interactions, repeated interactions with the same
individuals, or in some other combination of experimenter-controlled pairings or interaction choices
for the participants. Exchanges take place either in networks (e.g., Cook & Emerson, 1978 ) or in
dyads (e.g., Bacharach & Lawler, 1981 ). The rules about the form of the exchange, who can exchange
with whom, for how long, whether individuals can choose their partners or not, the presence of
intake or exit surveys, and other aspects of the exchange interaction defi ne the different conditions in a
given study.
In some cases, simulated or programmed actors are used as exchange partners with other real
actors (though the human actors typically are not made aware of this fact until the end of the experi-
ment). Simulated actors are most often used when the particular research questions in a study require
controlled or manipulated behavior, in much the same way that human confederates are used in other
types of psychological and social psychological studies. Since most social exchange experiments are
already computer- based, simulated actors provide reliable, controlled behavior that can scale from
dyads to very large networks. In general, when social exchange research focuses on behavioral and/or
affective responses of individuals instead of relational or interaction patterns, computer-simulated
actors are an attractive option for controlling the behavior of certain actors in dyads or networks
(Molm, 2007 ).
Experimental studies in the social exchange tradition are exceptionally good at controlling very
specifi c elements of exchange by restricting most (and usually all) interaction to lean computer- based
communication rather than rich, face-to-face based communication. Social exchange researchers have
directly compared face-to-face social exchange with computer- mediated settings, showing that verbal
and non- verbal cues in face-to-face interaction sometimes affect key outcomes such as perceptions of
justice and the use of power (Skvoretz & Willer, 1991 ). To avoid experimental confounds due to subtle
communication, the computer-mediated method continues to offer a controlled way to empirically
examine social exchange processes. While this approach is critical for establishing high internal valid-
ity and clear experimental manipulations, one critique of the experimental research on social exchange
theory is that it is hard to generalize to other contexts (low external validity), and the nature of the
experimental interactions are less like the real-world situations from which the origins of the theory
emerged (ecological validity).
Researchers are beginning to expand their empirical tests of social exchange processes to include
many real-world interactions, including organizational studies, online fi eld experiments, and other
mixed-methods studies of individuals who are engaged in different types of social exchange. Several
empirical studies of social exchange examine organizational relationships, including research on bal-
ance among employer and employee exchanges (De Jong, Schalk, & De Cuyper, 2009 ) and guanxi
processes (personal networks of infl uence, favors, and mutual understanding) in Chinese organiza-
tional partnerships (Chen, Friedman, Yu, Fang, & Lu, 2009 ). In the case of online social exchange
research, investigators are making use of advances in data collection techniques while capitalizing on
the rise of Internet-based social interactions. For example, it was once considered impractical to study
large- scale social exchange and romantic matching before the match occurred in the way that Thibaut
and Kelley (
1959 ) and Blau ( 1964 ) discussed in their respective approaches to social exchange theory.
However, the popularity of online dating systems now allows researchers to conduct analyses of the
logs of messaging data to examine aspects of social exchange and partner matching among millions
of potential pairings over time (Taylor et al., 2011 ). Furthermore, the rise of online generalized
exchange systems such as NetCycler.com and Freecycle.org allow social exchange researchers to
employ mixed methodologies including interviews, participant- observation, survey research, log
analysis of behavioral data over time (Suhonen et al., 2010 ), and online fi eld experiments (Willer
et al.,
2012 ). In sum, earlier concerns about the ecological validity of social exchange research meth-
odology have largely given way to a realization that, “the real world has become the laboratory”
(Cheshire & Cook, 2004 , p. 18).
K.S. Cook et al.
81
Future Directions: Linkages to Economic Sociology
and the Study of Networks
While exchange theorists for the past few decades have been primarily experimentalists, there is
certainly room for exchange theory to make more meaningful ties to other sub-fi elds on the broader
canvas of sociological research. The best candidate for such a venture seems to be in the sub- eld of
economic sociology. Exchange theory and economic sociology focus on a similar set of core theoreti-
cal issues. Both fi elds balk at the notion that individual motives (or the mere aggregation of individual
motives) can properly explain transactions between social actors. Moreover, both sub-fi elds theorize
extensively about the role of networks of ongoing relations in exchange. We argue in this section that
a marriage of these two fi elds would greatly benefi t each. First, we discuss the reasons for the develop-
ment of each fi eld in isolation from the other. We then focus on the theoretical overlap in the work of
“embeddedness” and Relational Cohesion Theory and argue that each fi eld can benefi t from exposure
to the other. Finally, we provide two illustrations of this argument by looking through the lens of
exchange theory at several notable studies within economic sociology of the credit card market in
Russia and of emerging business relations that extend beyond family and friendship ties in this transi-
tional economy.
The separation of these two sub-fi elds is likely due to the confl ation of several issues. First, early
theorists of social exchange were careful to make the distinction between economic and social
exchange. This focus, however, has slowly receded as work in exchange theory has become increas-
ingly abstracted and the exchange of resources under study are now typically concrete and quantifi -
able objects. Second, exchange theory is frequently aligned with rational choice theory (Bienenstock
& Bonacich, 1992 ; Blau, 1964 ; Heckathorn, 1984 ) and economic sociologists often use rational
choice theory as a theoretical foil against which to argue their more “social” theories. But even when
exchange theory is founded in operant psychology (e.g., Emerson, 1972a ; Molm, 1994 ), connections
between the two sub-fi elds are rare. This separation can most readily be attributed to methodological
divides. Exchange theorists tend to generate a priori predictions that they test in laboratory experi-
ments, whereas economic sociologists favor ex post explanations and empirical fi eld research. Such
differences in style have caused these two fi elds to develop in relative isolation, until more recently.
Research on “embeddedness” shares a great deal of intellectual common ground with contempo-
rary work in social exchange. Exchanges are rarely purely economic; rather they often are “embed-
ded” in networks of ongoing social relations. This last claim is a central claim of economic sociology
and the focus of much of the theoretical and empirical research. Uzzi ( 1996 ), for example, has argued
that “embeddedness” has profound behavioral consequences affecting the shape of exchange relations
and the success of economic ventures. “A key behavioral consequence of embeddedness is that it
becomes separate from the narrow economic goals that originally constituted the exchange and gener-
ates outcomes that are independent of the narrow economic interest of the relationship” (Uzzi, p. 681).
The work by Lawler and Yoon ( 1996 , 1998 ) and Lawler et al. ( 2000 ) mirrors this set of theoretical
concerns. They argue that as exchange relations emerge actors develop feelings of relational cohesion
directed toward the ongoing exchange relation. These feelings of cohesion result in a wide variety of
behaviors that extend beyond the “economic” interests of the relationship, such as gift-giving, form-
ing new joint ventures across old ties, and remaining in a relationship despite the presence of new,
potentially more profi table partnerships. They expand on this set of arguments in their latest work
linking relational cohesion and commitment to micro-social order (Lawler et al.,
2008 ).
There is great mutual benefi t to be derived from increased attention to research done in each fi eld.
Exchange theorists can benefi t from the rich tapestry of “real” world (i.e., non laboratory) exchange
contexts studied by economic sociologists. While great theoretical advances have been made in
exchange theory within the context of experimental work, any sociological theory worth its salt must
also speak to empirical phenomenon outside of the laboratory. Moreover, new insights and new
3 Social Exchange Theory
82
theoretical directions are likely to be uncovered by a renewed focus on the kinds of exchanges that can
be studied outside of the experimental setting. Economic sociology would likewise benefi t from the
work of exchange theorists, particularly in so far as exchange theory provides easily derivable and
testable predictions for actor behavior in exchange networks. Moreover, exchange theorists have
conducted research on the effects of a number of interesting variables that are often overlooked by
economic sociologists, such as the use and distribution of power and cohesion within relationships.
To illustrate the potential value of such a marriage, we discuss how two studies within economic
sociology relate to work in exchange theory and explore the possibilities for new research generated by
such an examination. Guseva and Rona-Tas ( 2001 ) compared the credit card markets of post-Soviet
Russia and the United States. They were concerned with how credit lenders in each country manage
the uncertainties of lending credit. In the United States, they argue, credit lending is a highly rational-
ized process that converts the uncertainty of defaulting debtors to manageable risk. Lenders take
advantage of highly routinized systems of scoring potential debtors, through the use of credit histories
and other easily accessed personal information. This system allows creditors in the United States to
be open to any individuals who meet these impersonal criteria.
In Russia, creditors must reduce uncertainties through personal ties and commitments. Defaulting is
an enormous problem in Russia, aggravated by the fact that credit information such as that used by
American lenders has, until relatively recently, been unavailable. To overcome these uncertainties,
Russian banks seeking to establish credit card markets must use and stretch existing personal ties.
Loan offi cers make idiosyncratic decisions about potential debtors, based largely on connections to
the banks, or known customers of the bank. In this way defaulting debtors cannot easily disappear, as
they can be tracked through these ties.
Viewed through the lens of theorizing on the connections between uncertainty and commitments,
these different strategies seem quite reasonable. As discussed earlier, exchange theorists have repeat-
edly shown that as uncertainty increa ses, commitments to specifi c relations likewise increases (Cook &
Emerson, 1984 ; Kollock, 1994 ; Yamagishi et al., 1998 ). In the case of credit card markets, it is clear
that the United States presents an environment of relatively low uncertainty, compared to the high-
levels of uncertainty present in Russia. Exchange theory implies therefore that commitments will be
greater in Russia, which is exactly the case. Lending is facilitated by existing commitments to the
banks or the bank’s known customers. While such theoretical confl uence is interesting, it is in generat-
ing new insights that one can see the value of examining this situation through the lens of exchange
theory. Rice ( 2002 ) in his work on exchange under uncertainty argued that network structure inter-
venes in the process of commitment formation. This insight suggests that sociologists ought to ask
how different shaped networks of potential debtors and lenders in Russia affect the use of commit-
ments to procure credit? Rice also argued that uncertainty, while promoting commitment simultane-
ously reduces the overall level of exchange in networks; this is yet another outcome observed in the
Russian credit card market, but one largely ignored by Guseva and Rona-Tas (
2001 ). It is this aspect
of the problem that is addressed to some extent in another study by Radaev ( 2002 ) on the emergence
of reputation systems in Russia. Finally, Yamagishi and his collaborators (Yamagishi et al.) argued that
uncertainty can stem from either the probability of loss or the size of loss. Another question that
should be raised in this context is how the size of loss, not just the potential for loss relates to the
behaviors observed in the Russian versus the American credit card markets.
This examination, however, is not a one sided affair, benefi ting only economic sociology.
Exchange theorists also can learn from this example. Exchange theory tends to focus on commitments
as an outcome, not as a social mechanism. In the case of the Russian credit card market, existing
commitments provide a mechanism through which network structures are expanded and changed.
This raises the issue of how commitments may in turn create opportunities for network expansion and/
or reduction. Similarly, in the context of credit card markets, there are two distinct roles, creditors and
debtors. Exchange theory, with the exception of Kollock’s (
1994 ) work, does not focus on the explicit
context of buying and selling. Exchanges are studied among actors who divide, give or trade resources
K.S. Cook et al.
83
with other actors who are engaged in an identical task. Much of the world of economic transactions,
however, does not occur in such contexts, rather buying and selling are the primary modes of exchange.
Exchange theorists if they are to speak to economic sociologists and inform economic research must
develop a more explicit and rigorous theory of exchange across roles of this type.
In another study of emerging markets for non- state businesses in Russia, Radaev ( 2002 ) investi-
gated the mechanisms and institutional arrangements that help actors cope with the uncertainty and
opportunism common in such an uncertain environment. Two features of the situation are signifi cant.
Under uncertainty individuals turn to interpersonal ties involving trust and greater certainty to pro-
duce some security in the context of high levels of opportunism. This is the behavior that is docu-
mented also by Guseva and Rona-Tas ( 2001 ) discussed previously.
In documenting the uncertainty of business relations in Russia, respondents to the surveys Radaev
( 2002 ) conducted indicated how important honesty and trustworthiness were in business partners.
This result is driven by the fact that there are frequent infringements of business contracts creating
both risk and high levels of uncertainty. Half of the respondents admitted that contract infringements
were quite frequent in Russian business in general and a third of the respondents had had a high level
of personal experience with such infringements. This degree of opportunism creates barriers to the
formation of reciprocal trust relations. Widespread distrust exists of newcomers to the market but reli-
able partners are viewed as more trustworthy.
In this climate commitment is clearly the most predictable response to uncertainty as in the case of
Kollock’s ( 1994 ) rubber markets and the credit card market discussed by Guseva and Rona-Tas
( 2001 ). Another reason for the uncertainty is that the existing institutions lack credibility and legiti-
macy. The courts do not effectively manage dispute resolution and existing institutions do not secure
business contracts. To cope with this fact the business community creates closed business networks
with reputation systems that defi ne insiders and outsiders. This system is based on information
obtained from third parties, but more importantly on common face-to-face meetings between poten-
tial partners.
In a 1993 survey conducted by Radaev the emerging networks of entrepreneurs in Russia post-
transition primarily included personal acquaintance (42 %), friends and their relatives (23 %) and
relatives (17 %). This fact refl ects the reality discussed in the work of Guseva and Rona-Tas ( 2001 ) on
the credit card market in Russia. Only a small percentage (11 %) of the business contacts in 1993 were
new or relatively new acquaintances. Subsequently, however, they moved away from affect-based
commitment and trust to reputation-based trust since networks formed purely on the basis of acquain-
tance, kin ties or friendship often fall apart due to ineffi ciency. The relatively closed business net-
works that have emerged to replace the older “familial” and friendship ties provide better information
about the trustworthiness of the partners and their competence. Within exchange theory the formation
of commitment and trust networks (see also Cook & Hardin, 2001 ) in the face of uncertainty provide
theoretical support for the evidence provided by Radaev (
2003 ) and others on the emergence of busi-
ness networks in Russia. This development is also consistent with Rice’s ( 2002 ) argument that com-
mitments can have negative aggregate level consequences in terms of productivity and effi ciency in
exchange systems.
This extended example identifi es only some of the ways in which exchange theory can inform
economic sociology and vice versa. Topics that have returned to center stage on the agenda for
research in the exchange theory tradition such as trust, emotion, affect, fairness, strategic action, com-
mitment and reputational networks all have potential applications in the analysis of the emergence of
exchange networks in countries with transitional economies as well as in other types of economies as
evidenced by the work of many economic sociologists (e.g., Uzzi, Granovetter, etc.). Moving from
closed groups to more open networks of trade mirror some of the processes identifi ed by Emerson
(
1972b ) as important for study from an exchange perspective contrasting group-level exchange systems
(productive exchange in corporate groups) with network- level exchange. In addition, the return to the
study of the signifi cant differences between social processes (e.g., power, justice, and commitment)
3 Social Exchange Theory
84
involved in different types of exchange, negotiated, reciprocal, and generalized exchange (Molm,
1988 , 1990 , 1994 , 2010 ) has the potential to provide new insights into a variety of emergent forms of
exchange under different circumstances. For example, under conditions of uncertainty, negotiated,
binding exchange is likely to emerge before reciprocal (most often, non-binding) exchange because
reciprocal exchange involves a greater degree of uncertainty. Reciprocal exchange, as Molm and her
coauthors (Molm, 2010 ; Molm et al., 1999 , 2000 ) have documented, generally requires more trust
since the terms of exchange are not simultaneously negotiated and opportunism is possible. This
research has the potential to produce a theoretical basis for the empirical work on the development of
various global economic sectors as well as for the study of the Internet and its consequences not only
for the world of trade, but also for social and political change more broadly as interactions bridge
across previously existing exchange boundaries.
Exchange theory provides a general analytic approach to a wide array of social processes that are
central to sociological inquiry at various levels. In particular, it emphasizes the role of exchange pro-
cesses at the micro-level and how such processes often form the bedrock of social structure and social
change. It provides a conception of the social interactions that result in the exchange of resources and
services of value, which occur on a daily basis in all societies. Understanding these interactions, how
they emerge, change, and alter the groups and networks in which they are embedded is one of the
major contributions of this theoretical perspective, not only to social psychology, but also to sociology
more broadly. Future theoretical work should lead to new connections between this perspective and
other social psychological perspectives covered in this volume. We have provided not only an intro-
duction to the current status of this work, but also a window into the ways in which it continues to
produce important insights into the world around us as the social, political, and economic landscape
continues to change, often more rapidly than our theories do.
References
Alexander, J., Munch, R., Smelser, N., & Giesen, B. (1990). The micro-macro link . Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press.
Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation . New York: Basic Books.
Bacharach, S. B., & Lawler, E. J. (1981). Bargaining: Power, tactics and outcomes . San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass Inc.
Bearman, P. (1997). Generalized exchange. The American Journal of Sociology, 102 , 1383–1415.
Berger, J., Cohen, B., & Zelditch, M., Jr. (1972). Status characteristics and social interaction. American Sociological
Review, 37 , 241–255.
Berger, J., Zelditch, M., Jr., Anderson, B., & Cohen, B. (1972). Structural aspects of distributive justice: A status value
formation. In J. Berger, M. Zelditch Jr., & B. Anderson (Eds.), Sociological theories in progress . Boston: Houghton
Miffl in.
Bienenstock, E. J., & Bonacich, P. (1992). The core as a solution to exclusionary networks. Social Networks, 14 ,
231–243.
Bienenstock, E. J., & Bonacich, P. (1993). Game-theory models for exchange networks: Experimental results.
Sociological Perspectives, 36 , 117–135.
Bienenstock, E. J., & Bonacich, P. (1997). Network exchange as a cooperative game. Rationality and Society, 9 ,
937–965.
Blau, P. M. (1955). The dynamics of bureaucracy . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Blau, P. M. (1964). Exchange and power in social life . New York: Wiley.
Blau, P. M. (1986). Exchange and power in social life (2nd printing). New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books.
Borch, C., & Willer, D. (2006). Power, embedded games and coalition formation. Journal of Mathematical Sociology,
30 , 77–111.
Chen, Y., Friedman, R., Yu, E., Fang, W., & Lu, X. (2009). Supervisor-subordinate guanxi: Developing a three-
dimensional model and scale. Management and Organization Review, 5 (3), 375–399.
Cheshire, C. V. (2005). A sociological analysis of generalized information exchange . Stanford University.
Cheshire, C., & Antin, J. (2009). Order, coordination and uncertainty. In K. S. Cook (Ed.), eTrust: Forming relation-
ships in the online world (pp. 266–291). New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.
K.S. Cook et al.
85
Cheshire, C., & Cook, K. S. (2004). The emergence of trust networks under uncertainty–Implications for internet inter-
actions. Analyse & Kritik, 26 (1), 220–240.
Cheshire, C., Gerbasi, A., & Cook, K. S. (2010). Trust and transitions in modes of social exchange. Social Psychology
Quarterly, 73 , 176–195.
Cook, K. S., & Emerson, R. M. (1978). Power, equity and commitment in exchange networks. American Sociological
Review, 43 , 721–739.
Cook, K. S., & Emerson, R. M. (1984). Exchange networks and the analysis of complex organizations. Research in the
Sociology of Organizations, 3 , 1–30.
Cook, K. S., Emerson, R. M., Gillmore, M. R., & Yamagishi, T. (1983). The distribution of power in exchange networks:
Theory and experimental results. The American Journal of Sociology, 89 , 275–305.
Cook, K. S., & Gerbasi, A. (2006). Homans and Emerson on power: Out of the Skinner box. In A. Javier Trevino (Ed.),
George C. Homans: History, theory and method (pp. 157–176). New York: Paradigm Publishers.
Cook, K. S., & Gillmore, M. R. (1984). Power, dependence and coalitions. In E. J. Lawler (Ed.), Advances in group pro-
cesses (pp. 27–58). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Cook, K. S., & Hardin, R. (2001). Norms of cooperativeness and networks of trust. In M. Hechter & K.-D. Opp (Eds.), Social
norms (pp. 327–347). New York: Russell Sage.
Cook, K. S., & Hegtvedt, K. A. (1986). Justice and power: An exchange analysis. In H. W. Bierhoff, R. L. Cohen, &
J. Greenberg (Eds.), Justice in social relations (pp. 19–41). New York: Plenum.
Cook, K. S., & Yamagishi, T. (1992). Power in exchange networks: A power-dependence formulation. Social Networks,
14 , 245–265.
Cook, K. S., Yamagishi, T., Cheshire, C., Cooper, R., Matsuda, M., & Mashima, R. (2005). Trust building via risk taking:
A cross-societal experiment. Social Psychology Quarterly, 68 (2), 121–142.
De Jong, J., Schalk, R., & De Cuyper, N. (2009). Balanced versus unbalanced psychological contracts in temporary and
permanent employment: Associations with employee attitudes. Management and Organization Review, 5 (3),
329–351.
Ekeh, P. (1974). Social exchange theory: The two traditions . Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Emerson, R. (1962). Power-dependence relations. American Sociological Review, 27 , 31–41.
Emerson, R. (1972a). Exchange theory, Part I: A psychological basis for social exchange. In J. Berger, M. Zelditch Jr., &
B. Anderson (Eds.), Sociological theories in progress (pp. 38–57). Boston: Houghton Miffl in.
Emerson, R. (1972b). Exchange theory, Part II: Exchange relations and networks. In J. Berger, M. Zelditch Jr., &
B. Anderson (Eds.), Sociological theories in progress (pp. 58–87). Boston: Houghton Miffl in.
Emerson, R. M. (1976). Social exchange theory. Annual Review of Sociology, 2 , 335–362.
Emerson, R. (1987). Toward a theory of value in social exchange. In K. S. Cook (Ed.), Social exchange theory
(pp. 11–58). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Faust, K., & Wasserman, S. (1992). Centrality and prestige: A review and synthesis. Journal of Quantitative
Anthropology, 4 , 23–78.
Friedkin, N. E. (1992). An expected value model of social power: Predictions for selected exchange networks. Social
Networks, 14 , 213–229.
Friedkin, N. E. (1993). An expected value model of social exchange outcomes. In E. J. Lawler (Ed.), Advances in group
processes (pp. 163–193). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Guseva, A., & Rona-Tas, A. (2001). Uncertainty, risk, and trust: Russian and American credit card markets compared.
American Sociological Review, 66 , 623–646.
Harkness, S. (2011). Consequences of rewards: The creation, perpetuation and erosion of social inequality . Dissertation,
Stanford University.
Heath, A. F. (1976). Rational choice and social exchange: A critique of exchange theory . Cambridge, MA: Cambridge
University Press.
Heckathorn, D. D. (1984). A formal theory of social exchange: Process and outcome. Current Perspectives in Social
Theory, 5 , 145–180.
Heckathorn, D. D. (1985). Power and trust in social exchange. In E. J. Lawler (Ed.), Advances in group processes
(pp. 143–167). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Homans, G. C. (1958). Social behavior as exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 63 , 597–606.
Homans, G. C. (1961). Social behavior: Its elementary forms . New York: Harcourt, Brace & World.
Homans, G. C. (1974). Social behavior and its elementary forms . New York: Harcourt, Brace and World.
Homans, G. C. (1984). Coming to my senses: The autobiography of a sociologist . New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction
Books.
Huber, J. (1991). Macro-micro linkages in sociology . Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Jasso, G. (1980). A new theory of distributive justice. American Sociological Review, 45 , 3–32.
Jasso, G. (1986). A new representation of the just term in distributive justice theory: Its properties and operation in theo-
retical derivation and empirical estimation. Mathematical Sociology, 12 , 251–274.
3 Social Exchange Theory
86
Jasso, G. (1998). Studying justice: Cross-country data for empirical justice analysis. Social Justice Research, 11 ,
193–209.
Jasso, G. (2001). Rule nding about rule making: Comparison processes and the making of rules. In M. Hechler &
K.-D. Opp (Eds.), Social norms (pp. 348–393). New York: Russell Sage.
Kollock, P. (1994). The emergence of exchange structures: An experimental study of uncertainty, commitment, and
trust. The American Journal of Sociology, 100 , 313–345.
Kollock, P. (1999a). The economies of online cooperation: Gifts and public goods in cyberspace. In M. A. Smith & P.
Kollock (Eds.), Communities in cyberspace (pp. 220–239). London: Routledge Press.
Kollock, P. (1999b). The production of trust in online markets. In E. J. Lawler, M. Macy, S. Thyne, & H. A. Walker (Eds.),
Advances in group processes (pp. 99–123). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Kuwabara, K. (2011). Cohesion, cooperation, and the value of doing things together: How economic exchange creates
relational bonds. American Sociological Review, 76 , 560–580.
Lauterbach, D., Truong, H., Shah, T., & Adamic, L. (2009). Surfi ng a web of trust: Reputation and reciprocity on
couchsurfi ng.com. In Proceedings of the 2009 international conference on computational science and engineering
(pp. 346–353).
Lawler, E. J. (2001). An affect theory of social exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 107 (2), 321–352.
Lawler, E. J., Ford, R. S., & Blegen, M. A. (1988). Coercive capability in confl ict: A test of bilateral deterrence versus
confl ict spiral theory. Social Psychology Quarterly, 51 , 93–107.
Lawler, E. J., Thye, S. R., & Yoon, J. (2008). Social exchange and micro social order. American Sociological Review,
73 , 519–542.
Lawler, E. J., & Yoon, J. (1993). Power and the emergence of commitment behavior in negotiated exchange. American
Sociological Review, 58 , 465–481.
Lawler, E. J., & Yoon, J. (1996). Commitment in exchange relations: Test of a theory of relational cohesion. American
Sociological Review, 61 , 89–108.
Lawler, E. J., & Yoon, J. (1998). Network structure and emotion in exchange relations. American Sociological Review,
63 , 871–894.
Lawler, E. J., Yoon, J., & Thye, S. R. (2000). Emotion and group cohesion in productive exchange. The American
Journal of Sociology, 106 , 616–657.
Leik, R. K. (1992). New directions for network exchange theory: Strategic manipulation of network linkages. Social
Networks, 14 , 309–323.
Leik, R., & Leik, S. (1972). Interpersonal commitment as a balancing mechanism in social exchange . Conference pre-
sentation at Pacifi c Sociological Association, Scottsdale, Arizona.
Lovaglia, M. J. (1994). Relating power to status. Advances in Group Processes, 11 , 87–111.
Lovaglia, M. J. (1995). Power and status: Exchange, attribution, and expectation states. Small Group Research, 26 ,
400–426.
Macy, M. W., & Skvoretz, J. (1998). The evolution of trust and cooperation between strangers: A computational model.
American Sociological Review, 63 , 638–660.
Malinowski, B. (1922). Argonauts of the western pacifi c: An account of native enterprise and adventure in the
archipelagoes of Melansian New Guinea . London: Routledge.
Mark, N. P. (2002). Cultural transmission, disproportionate prior exposure, and the evolution of cooperation. American
Sociological Review, 67 , 323–344.
Mark, N. P. (2003). Culture and competition: Homophily and distancing explanations for cultural niches. American
Sociological Review, 68 , 319–345.
Markovsky, B., Skvoretz, J., Willer, D., Lovaglia, M. J., & Erger, J. (1993). The seeds of weak power: An extension of
network exchange theory. American Sociological Review, 58 , 197–209.
Markovsky, B., Willer, D., & Patton, T. (1988). Power relations in exchange networks. American Sociological
Review, 5 , 101–117.
Mauss, M. (1923). Essais sur le don. formes et raison de l’échange dans les sociétés archaïques. In Sociologie et
Anthrophologie . Paris: PUF.
Molm, L. D. (1979). The effects of reinforcement differences and disruptions of social exchange in an alternative task situa-
tion. Social Psychology Quarterly, 42 , 158–171.
Molm, L. D. (1980). The effects of structural variations in social reinforcement contingencies on exchange and cooperation.
Social Psychology Quarterly, 43 , 269–282.
Molm, L. D. (1985). Relative effects of individual dependencies: Further tests of the relation between power imbalance
and power use. Social Forces, 63 , 810–837.
Molm, L. (1988). The structure and use of power: A comparison of reward and punishment power. Social Psychology
Quarterly, 51 , 108–122.
Molm, L. (1990). Structure, action, and outcomes: The dynamics of power in social exchange. American Sociological
Review, 55 , 427–447.
K.S. Cook et al.
87
Molm, L. (1994). Is punishment effective? Coercive strategies in social exchange. Social Psychology Quarterly, 57 ,
75–94.
Molm, L. (1997a). Coercive power in social exchange . Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Molm, L. (1997b). Risk and power use: Constraints on the use of coercion in exchange. American Sociological Review,
62 , 113–133.
Molm, L. D. (2003). Power, trust, and fairness: Comparisons of negotiated and reciprocal exchange. Advances in Group
Processes, 20 , 31–65.
Molm, L. D. (2007). Experiments on exchange relations and exchange networks in sociology. In M. Webster & J. Sell
(Eds.), Laboratory experiments in the social sciences (pp. 379–406). Amsterdam: Elsevier/Academic Press.
Molm, L. (2010). The structure of reciprocity. Social Psychology Quarterly, 73 , 119–131.
Molm, L., Collett, J., & Schaefer, D. (2007). Building solidarity through generalized exchange: A theory of reciprocity.
The American Journal of Sociology, 113 , 205–242.
Molm, L., & Cook, K. S. (1995). Social exchange and exchange networks. In K. S. Cook, G. A. Fine, & J. S. House
(Eds.), Sociological perspectives on social psychology (pp. 209–235). Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
Molm, L., Peterson, G., & Takahashi, N. (1999). Power in negotiated and reciprocal exchange. American Sociological
Review, 64 , 876–890.
Molm, L., Quist, T. M., & Wiseley, P. A. (1994). Imbalanced structures, unfair strategies: Power and justice in social
exchange. American Sociological Review, 49 , 98–121.
Molm, L., Takahashi, N., & Peterson, G. (2000). Risk and trust in social exchange: An experimental test of a classical
proposition. The American Journal of Sociology, 105 , 1396–1427.
Molm, L., Whitham, M. M., & Melamed, D. (2012). Forms of exchange and integrative bonds: Effects of history and
embeddedness. American Sociological Review, 77 , 141–165.
Montgomery, J. (1996). The structure of social exchange networks: A game-theoretic reformulation of Blau’s model.
Sociological Methodology, 26 , 193–225.
Radaev, V. (2002). Entrepreneurial strategies and the structure of transaction costs in Russian business. Problems of
Economic Transition, 44 , 57–84.
Radaev, V. (2003). Coping with distrust and contract infringement in the emerging Russian markets. In R. Hardin (Ed.),
Distrust . New York: Russell Sage Corporation.
Rice, E. R. W. (2002). The effect of social uncertainty in networks of social exchange . Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation,
Stanford University.
Ruef, M. (2003). A sociological perspective on strategic organization. Strategic Organization, 1 (2), 241–251.
Shah, S. K., & Levine, S. S. (2003, August). Towards a theory of large-scale generalized exchange . Conference presen-
tation at American Sociological Association, Theoretical Issues in Economic Sociology Session. Atlanta, GA.
Skvoretz, J., & Willer, D. (1991). Power in exchange networks: Setting and structural variations. Social Psychology
Quarterly, 54 , 224–238.
Skvoretz, J., & Willer, D. (1993). Exclusion and power: A test of four theories or power in exchange networks. American
Sociological Review, 58 , 801–818.
Stolte, J. R., & Emerson, R. M. (1977). Structural inequality: Position and power in network structures. In
R. L. Hamblin & J. H. Kunkel (Eds.), Behavioral theory in sociology (pp. 117–138). New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction
Books.
Suhonen, E., Lampinen, A., Cheshire, C., & Antin, J. (2010, November). Everyday favors: A case study of a local
online gift exchange system. In Proceedings of the 16th ACM international conference on Supporting group work
(pp. 11–20).
Takahashi, N. (2000). The emergence of generalized exchange.
American Journal of Sociology, 105 , 1105–1134.
Takahashi, N., & Yamagishi, T. (1996). Social relational foundations of altruistic behavior. Japanese Journal of
Experimental Social Psychology, 36 , 1–11.
Takahashi, N., & Yamagishi, T. (1999). Voluntary formation of a generalized exchange system: An experimental study
of discriminating altruism. Japanese Journal of Psychology, 70 , 9–16.
Taylor, L. S., Fiore, A. T., Mendelsohn, G. A., & Cheshire, C. (2011). “Out of my league”: A real-world test of the
matching hypothesis. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 37 (7), 942–954.
Thibaut, J. W., & Kelley, H. H. (1959). The social psychology of groups . New York: Wiley.
Thye, S. R. (2000). A status value theory of power in exchange relations. American Sociological Review, 65 , 407–432.
Thye, S. R., Willer, D., & Markovsky, B. (2006). From status to power: New models at the intersection of two theories.
Social Forces, 84 , 1471–1495.
Uzzi, B. (1996). The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: The
network effect. American Sociological Review, 61 , 674–698.
Whitmeyer, J. M. (1997a). Applying general equilibrium analysis & game theory to exchange networks. Current
Research in Social Psychology, 2 (2).
Whitmeyer, J. M. (1997b). The power of the middleman—A theoretical analysis. Journal of Mathematical Sociology,
22 (1), 59–90.
3 Social Exchange Theory
88
Willer, D., & Anderson, B. (1981). Networks, exchange and coercion: The elementary theory and its applications .
New York: Elsevier.
Willer, D., Markovsky, B., & Patton, T. (1989). Power structures: Derivations and applications of elementary theory. In
J. Berger, M. Zelditch, & B. Anderson (Eds.), Sociological theories in progress: New formulations (pp. 313–353).
New York, NY: Sage Publications.
Willer, R., Flynn, F. J., & Zak, S. (2012). Structure, identity, and solidarity: A comparative fi eld study of generalized
and direct exchange. Administrative Science Quarterly, 57 (1), 119–155.
Yamagishi, T. (1995). Social dilemmas. In K. S. Cook, G. A. Fine, & J. S. House (Eds.), Sociological perspectives on
social psychology . Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
Yamagishi, T., & Cook, K. S. (1993). Generalized exchange and social dilemmas. Social Psychology Quarterly, 56 (4),
235–248.
Yamagishi, T., Cook, K. S., & Watabe, M. (1998). Uncertainty, trust and commitment formation in the United States and
Japan. The American Journal of Sociology, 104 , 165–194.
Yamagishi, T., Gillmore, M. R., & Cook, K. S. (1988). Network connections and the distribution of power in exchange
networks. American Journal of Sociology, 93 , 833–851.
Yamagishi, T., Horita, Y., Takagishi, H., Shinada, M., Tanida, S., & Cook, K. S. (2009). The private rejection of unfair
offers and emotional commitment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106 (28), 11520–11523.
Ziegler, R. (1990). The Kula: Social order, barter and ceremonial exchange. In M. Hechter, K.-D. Opp, & R. Wippler
(Eds.), Social institutions: Their emergence, maintenance and effects . New York: Aldine de Gruyter.
K.S. Cook et al.
... SET argues that the development of Trust is the only way a relationship between two individuals can evolve from an economic to a social exchange. Furthermore, SET emphasises the fact that an interpersonal relationship can only be sustained and managed over time when the necessary Commitment is made towards the relationship (Cook et al. 2013). However, attributes such as Trust and Commitment may have different definitions based on the context and norm of the interpersonal ITO relationship (Lane and Lum 2011). ...
... The level of commitment represents the willingness of a participant to place effort and devote resources in order to sustain and manage a working relationship over time (Olsson et al. 2008). However, determining the level of commitment required to sustain a working relationship has proved to be difficult because the potential benefits expected from a particular relationship are unclear unless there have been prior exchanges and engagements (Cook et al. 2013). Furthermore, unlike written agreements which clearly define the type and amount of resources required, commitment towards the relationship requires mutual consent rather than a contractual term (Goo et al. 2009). ...
Conference Paper
Full-text available
Despite the growth of Information Technology Outsourcing (ITO), high failure rates persist, often due to overlooked interpersonal dynamics between clients and vendors. While prior research emphasizes contractual and operational factors, the role of Psychological Contract (PsyCon) in shaping Relationship Quality (ReQ)-comprising trust and commitment-remains underexplored. This study aims to examine how specific PsyCon obligations (competency, relationship building, personal compatibility, and project ownership) influence ReQ in ITO partnerships. A qualitative case study of six dyadic client-vendor relationships was conducted, analyzing interview data from 12 participants selected based on long-term ITO engagement and recurring collaboration challenges. Findings reveal that PsyCon significantly affects ReQ, with high ReQ mitigating breach impacts. Theoretically, this study advances a framework linking PsyCon dimensions to ReQ in ITO, enriching relational governance literature. Practically, it offers managers actionable insights for fostering trust and commitment through interpersonal alignment, ultimately improving outsourcing success.
... Another study found a moderately positive relationship between SL and PS [42,51]. Tis relationship aligns with the social exchange theory, which posits that supportive leadership fosters trust, promotes mutual respect, and reduces interpersonal risk [52]. In a study by Sasaki et al., the analysis of the SL subscale revealed that empowerment had the strongest positive correlation with PS, followed by stewardship, authenticity, and standing back. ...
Article
Full-text available
Background: Servant leadership (SL), characterized by moral behavior and a focus on serving and empowering team members, is particularly relevant in a critical care setting, where a highly pressured environment requires a consistent and empowered team. Psychological safety (PS), a high perception level, and speaking without fear of penalty are highly recommended in critical care areas, including ICUs, CCUs, ERs, burn units, and any other departments that require intensive care for patients to maximize professionalism and improve patient outcomes. Aim: Tis study aimed to investigate the relationship between SL and PS as perceived by nurses in critical care areas of Jordanian hospitals. Method: A descriptive, cross-sectional, and correlational design was used. A convenience sample of 207 registered nurses working in inpatient departments and the Hemodialysis Unit across fve Jordanian hospitals participated in the study. Data were collected using the SL survey and the PS survey to measure the nurses' perceptions of SL and PS. Result: Critical care nurses reported a moderate perception of SL (M � 66.7 out of 108) and PS (M � 90.4 out of 133). A strong, signifcant, and positive correlation was found between leadership and PS (r � 0.74). Regression results indicated that SL was a signifcant predictor of PS (β � 0.82, p < 0.001). Conclusion: SL is a key factor in healthcare institutions that facilitate PS among critical care nurses.
... The study hinges on the social exchange theory propagated by the American Sociologist George Homans in his published article titled "Social Behaviour as Exchange" and grounded theory. The theory propagates balance between systems, entities, individuals and groups as they interact and build relationship in society to foster satisfaction and equal performance for the overall benefit of stakeholders (Cook et al., 2013). It is in view of this that the study adopts the social exchange theory taking into perspective the interactions that exist between the Ghana Football Association, football fans, players, and sponsors among others to ensure balance creation between the GFA and players to bring satisfaction to the football fans. ...
Article
Full-text available
The mediation effects of the perceived performance of the Ghana Black Stars at the Qatar FIFA World Cup were examined on the satisfaction of football fans in Ghana. A cross-sectional design with closed-ended questions on Google Forms was used to collect data through football fans' pages on WhatsApp and Facebook. Ghanaian adults aged 18 and above participated in the study with a sample of 618 gathered through a random sampling procedure. Estimators of Path models were compared with WLSMV outperforming others. The findings revealed that lack of coherence (p-value=0.002) among players reduces the performance of players, while the higher the perception of call-ups (p-value=0.035) the higher the perceived performance of Black Stars. Good perceived football governance (p-value<0.001) led to improvement in the perceived performance of the Black Stars. The higher performance of the Black Stars led to improved satisfaction among football fans (p-value<0.001). However, a poor technical team (p-value=0.015) for the Black Stars reduced the satisfaction of football fans. Lack of coherence among players (p-value=0.003) indirectly affects the satisfaction of football fans by compromising the perceived performance of Black Stars. Good governance (p-value=0.001) indirectly improves the satisfaction of football fans by improving the performance of Black Stars. The satisfaction of football fans in Ghana is linked to lack of coherence among players, perceived performance of Black Stars, call-ups and good governance.
... The sequences of developing relations arise some obligations (Carpanzano & Mitchell, 2005) among the teachers with each-others. The emergence of obligations is depended on the "give and take" (Cooper-Thomas & Morrison, 2018) as well as the "cost and benefits" (Cook et al., 2013) approach. Connecting to it, leadership inspire (gives) their followers as the forms of cost and they were inspired (take) in the organization. ...
Article
Full-text available
School leadership addresses the challenges and threats of the school regarding the change process by inspiring and motivating teachers. This function of leadership is represented by inspirational leadership, which is composed of five dimensions according to Bass and Bass, 2008. Connecting to it, the researcher aims to determine the factors of inspirational leadership among teachers in a school setting. For this purpose, this study employed a cross-sectional survey and collected data via a structured questionnaire from 502 sample teachers. The sample teachers were identified by employing a multi-stage cluster sampling. Then, the collected data were analyzed through Exploratory Factor Analysis (EFA), and in the end, the results were reasoned with social exchange theory. Then, through EFA, this study retained five dimensions of inspirational leadership as intellectual stimulation, envisioning, managing impression, molding follower’s expectations, and Managing meaning. These five dimensions of inspirational leadership are related to the social exchange between schools and teachers. In line with this, the school leadership generates innovative ideas, visualizes the ideal outlook of the school, presents self as a role model, creates a belief system, and develops a sense of ownership among teachers by inspiring them. In return for this, teachers were inspired and perform a high job in the school.
... These findings can also be interpreted through the lens of social exchange theory, which assumes that organizations are environments for transactions [14][15][16][17]. Accordingly, when employees experience positive gains within the organization, they are likely to engage in positive behaviors as part of the social exchange process [18]. Therefore, any employee who receives adequate organizational support is likely to exhibit positive behavior toward the organization [19]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Computer-mediated interaction on the Internet provides new opportunities to examine the links between reputation, risk, and the development of trust between individuals who engage in various types of exchange. In this article, we comment on the application of experimental sociological research to different types of computer-mediated social interactions, with particular attention to the emergence of what we call ‘trust networks’ (networks of those one views as trustworthy). Drawing on the existing categorization systems that have been used in experimental social psychology, we relate the various forms of computer-mediated exchange to selected findings from experimental research. We develop a simple typology based on the intersection of random versus fixed-partner social dilemma games, and repeated versus one-shot interaction situations. By crossing these two types of social dilemma games and two types of interaction situations, we show that many forms of Internet exchange can be categorized effectively into four mutually exclusive categories. The resulting classification system helps to integrate the existing research on t rust in experimental social psychology with the emerging field of computer-mediated exchange.