Content uploaded by Vincent Raphael Nyirenda
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Vincent Raphael Nyirenda on Jan 19, 2016
Content may be subject to copyright.
Vol. 7(5), pp. 280-289, May, 2015
DOI:10.5897/IJBC2014.0784
Article Number: 738027653221
ISSN 2141-243X
Copyright © 2015
Author(s) retain the copyright of this article
http://www.academicjournals.org/IJBC
International Journal of Biodiversity
and Conservation
Review
Property rights regimes, resource utilisation and
biodiversity conservation in Eastern and Southern
Africa
Vincent R. Nyirenda
Department of Zoology and Aquatic Sciences, School of Natural Resources, Copperbelt University, Kitwe, Zambia.
Received 28 January, 2015; Accepted 16 April, 2015
Natural resources degradation threatens persistence of biological resources in many parts of Eastern
and Southern African regions. In these regions, property rights regimes intractably influence resource
utilisation and biodiversity conservation. Hitherto, the underlying causes of varied performances of
property rights regimes are rarely collated. Consequently, resource policies are often flawed, resulting
in pervasive systems failure and biodiversity losses. In this study, this particular information gap is
interrogated by systematically reviewing various property rights regimes, their influence on resource
utilisation and biodiversity conservation from wealthy of available literature. The results unravelled that
the performance of various property rights regimes are influenced by levels of social capital,
encompassing stakeholders’ participation, trust, commitment and social networking at the base
regardless of whether the property rights areby full hegemony or sanctioned by higher authorities.This
findingcloselyapproximatestheconceptofenvironmentalsubsidiarityinnaturalresourcemanagement.Furth
er, it is concluded that bottom-up self-institutional regulation and top-down state controlplay
complimentary if not invasive role to each other. These approaches stimulate sustainable resource
utilisation and biodiversity conservation, where legal actors are given full resource property rights to
access, own, utilise and exclude intruders to avoid the ‘tragedy of the commons’.
Keywords:Collaborative governance, environmental subsidiarity, sustainable development, natural resource
management.
INTRODUCTION
Resource property rights are a suite of entitlements or
bundle of rights to the bearers, especially over scarce
resources (Demsetz, 1998; Klein and Robinson, 2011).
Entitlements could relate to the income or utility that can
be derived from resources which are sanctioned, or at
least condoned, by society and protected by a higher
authority (De Alessi, 1983; Bromley, 1992). The bearers
may include the state, private actors and local
communities. Appropriate rights are therefore imperative
especially as human populations are ever growing in the
resource dominated areas (Wittemyer et al., 2008), with
increasing demands and claims over resources (Giller et
al., 2008). Property rights are also theoretical constructs
in economics for determining how are source is used and
E-mail: vrnyirenda@hotmail.com; vincent.nyirenda@cbu.ac.zm. Tel: +260 977 352035.
Author(s) agree that this article remain permanently open access under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0
International License
owned by individuals, associations or government
Leeetal., 1996; Ostrom, 2008). As an economic good,
Guerin (2003) has described the attributes of property
rights as entitlements to use the goods, earn income from
the goods, transfer the goods to others and enforce.
Therein are a boundary rules that determine who has the
rights to access, control, use and ownership (Denison
and Klingler-Vidra, 2012). Thus, these rules define the
distribution of the property rights. Over-utilisation and loss
of biological resources arise from incompletely defined
and enforced property rights (Libecap, 2009) and are
dismal (Barbier, 1991; Sinclairetal., 2006; Lindseyetal.,
2014). According to Millennium Ecosystem Assessment
(2005), anthropogenic activities are among the major
causes of biodiversity losses, especially in human-
dominated ecosystems such as African savannas.
The property rights can be held under either of four
different regimes: open access, public, common and
private property regimes (Swanson and Barbier,
1992).Sources of the property rights of access,
withdrawal, management, exclusion and transfer are
varied. The property rights may be conveyed as de jure
or de facto rights. De jure right are given lawful
recognition by formal and legal instrumentalities.
According to Schlager and Ostrom (1992), de facto rights
are less secure than de jure rights. De facto rights
originate from cooperative resource users who define,
monitor and enforce certain rights but may not be
recognised by the state. Thus, property rights institutions
range from formal arrangements, including constitutional
provisions, statutes and judicial rulings, to informal
conventions and customs regarding the allocations and
uses of property (Andelson, 1991). These property
regimes regulate the actual functioning of the tenure in
local settings and at multi-level scales (Berkes, 2006).
However, most natural resources are not exclusively
private or public, but are governed by a mixture of private
and public institutions, which often contradict (Bromley,
1992).
Further, the actors in the administration of property rights
would vary from authorised users, claimants, proprietors
to owners (Schlager and Ostrom, 1992), and potentially
forming institutions of sustainability (Hagedon,
2008;Bromquist,2009).The formation of regimes depends
on the transaction costs defining, monitoring and
enforcing property rights conferred by the parent
institutions (Denison and Klingler-Vidra, 2012).Therefore,
the distribution of the property rights would be skewed to
actors‟ affordability. For instance, needs of poor people
and small scale users are more likely to be met within
common property regimes rather than private property
regimes (Rohde et al., 2006; Lawry et al., 2014).
Protection of given property rights are provided by the
force of etiquette, social custom and formal legally
enacted laws supported by the state, developed under
rules of first possession (Lueck, 1998).
Property rights can either enforce or negate „tragedy of
Nyirenda 281
the commons‟ postulated by Hardin (1968). Ostrom
(2008) defines the commons as lands which rural
communities possess and use collectively in accordance
with community-derived norms. Further, commons maybe
defined by the fact of their communal ownership, that
they are acknowledged as being the shared property of a
definable group of persons, undivided shares whether or
not recognised in statutory law but governed by
communal norms (Wily, 2011). Tragedy of the commons
theory suggests that it occurs when individuals, acting
independently and rationally according to each one‟s self-
interest, behave contrary to the whole group‟s long-term
best interests by depleting some common resources
(Hardin, 1968).Typically, tragedy of the commons arises
when it is difficult and costly to exclude potential users
from common-pool resources that yield finite flows of
benefits as a result of which those resources will be
exhausted by rational, utility-maximising individuals rather
than conserved for the benefit of all (Rankin et el., 2007).
Tragedy of the commons refers to a particular type of
uncontrollable communal property management system
where individuals try to gain as much as possible in the
short term without taking longer term needs of the
community into perspective (Fabricius et al., 2001).
Consequently, tragedy of the commons has occurred for
instance in fisheries areas with about 80% of stock being
fished at beyond their maximum sustained yield (FAO,
2009), wildlife overharvested to levels well below their
carrying capacities (Lindsey et al., 2014) and forests
degraded at extremely high rates (Alajarvi, 1996;
Abdallah and Monela, 2007;ILUA, 2010; Henry et al.,
2011; Chidumayo, 2012). On the contrary, appropriate
property rights increase the incentives of households and
individuals to invest, and provide them with better access
to resources, their productivity and use (Deininger, 2003).
Hitherto, the impacts of property rights regimes in
natural resources have either been underplayed or
misconstrued by policy and decision makers, despite the
long debates on issues relating to the subject. This
review, therefore, evaluates property rights regimes in the
context of their impacts, drivers and suggested solutions
to numerous challenges in their implementation. The
typology and effectiveness of the particular property
rights regimes are discussed from multiple perspectives,
giving examples from across the Eastern and Southern
regions.
TYPES OF PROPERTY RIGHTS, FUNCTIONAL
CONDITIONALITIES AND THEIR EXAMPLES FROM
EASTERN AND SOUTHERN AFRICAN REGION
Open access regime
Open access property is a metaphor of the tragedy of the
commons (Blewett,1995).Typically, open access property
regime entails that the property is not owned by resource
users, and no one can exclude anyone else from using it
282 Int. J. Biodivers. Conserv.
(Denison and Klingler-Vidra, 2012). Therefore, it lacks
resource governance and individuals exploit there
sources as hastily as possible, thereby rapidly degrading
the resource (Repetto, 1988; Libby, 1994). When
effective enforcement is infeasible, users „„who would
willingly reduce their own appropriation if others did are
unwillingly to make a sacrifice for the benefit of a large
number of free riders…‟‟ (Ostrom, 1999). This scenario
creates crisis to the resource management system and
gives rise to system‟s collapse (Folke et al., 2010). If,
however, the government or the subsidiary authorities
start to control the use of resources on that property then
it ceases to be an open access property and is converted
to state property (Guerin, 2003).
There are several examples of open access regimes
that have occurred in Eastern and Southern Africa.
Examples of open access resources in Eastern and
Southern Africa include fisheries, forests and other non-
renewable energy sources such as coal (Leal, 1998). For
instance, Lake Kariba of Zambia and Zimbabwe was
overfished because it did not have imposed rules like the
“fish ban” (Submanian, 1996). In South Africa, the
communal small farm areas of Leliefontein of
Namaqualand experienced persistently higher stocking
rates of livestock which led to a depletion of palatable
perennials and loss of vegetative cover due to open
access regimes (Todd et al., 1999). In Zambia, bush
meat poaching can be considered as „prima facie‟
evidence of market failure in sustainable resource
utilisation as individuals receive benefits yet share the
damage to the commons (Lindsey et al., 2014).Another
example is overgrazing by mass introduced livestock on
the Kafue flats in Zambia, depleting wildlife forage (Haller
and Chabwela, 2009).
Public property regimes
Public property regime allows for cooperative ownership,
where access of the resources is controlled by the
authorities like the government (Guerin, 2003). Examples
are state owned and managed national parks in many of
states or expansive state farms for internationally
marketed tobacco, tea and sugar (Adams et al., 1999). In
some cases, the public property rights are enjoyed by
responsible states at the expense of impoverished rural
communities who receive limited benefit streams (Knox,
1996).Management effectiveness of state owned and
managed protected areas is strongly linked to community
involvement and benefit streams (Coad et al., 2010;
Leverington et al., 2010). In the recent decades, several
synergetic novel initiatives that include contractual parks
and trans frontier conservation areas have been
experimented upon to marshal multi-level support to
property regime functions under collective property,
owned by a group of individuals, whose access and use
are biodiversity conservation and appear to be promising
(Quan,2000;Child,2009a;GrossmanandHolden, 2009).
Common property regimes
Common property regimes are controlled by the joint
owners (Ostrom, 2008). Due to difficult in excluding or
limiting users, common-pool resources are prone to
degradation (Ostrom, 1999).Therefore, tragedy of the
commons occurs when unconstrained consumption of
common-pool resources takes place (Dodds, 2005). The
common property regimes differ from open access
regimes in so far as there would be well defined
ownership, access, use, controls through legitimate
resource management institutions. However, the use
rights of individuals can be delimited and regulated so
that over exploitation of the resource does not result. For
instance, grazing schemes in Zimbabwe‟s communal
lands demonstrated that when access to grazing was
unrestricted, exploitation of communal grazing land by
privately held livestock inevitably resulted in „tragedy of
the commons‟ (Barnes, 1978).Unconstrained use of
common-pool resources by local communities and
commercial users is a major conservation concern and
continues to be a major cause of decline of biodiversity
despite the key role the traditional leadership plays in
enforcing management rules and local resource regimes
(Wilson et al., 2006; Marks, 2009).
In Eastern and Southern Africa, several examples of
natural common-pool resources abound and include
fishing grounds, forests, populations of animal and plant
species, wetlands and grazing lands for livestock, wood
supply, medicines and farm land (Adams, 2004).Some
southern African societies developed relatively effective
indigenous institutions for the management of entire
landscapes and their component ecosystems, when this
was in their economic interest but these have not been
resilient to emerging changes (Magole et al., 2010).
Colonial legacy, later inherited by post-colonial govern-
ments, buttressed governance systems that ignored
indigenous knowledge and commons practice (Haller and
Chabwela, 2009; Magole, 2009; Mhlanga, 2009). In some
cases, indigenous management regimes were replaced
by sectorial or fragmented systems that focused on
technical, anti-political rationales (Bϋscher, 2010).
In the case of wildlife resources, since many native
communities were evicted by colonial governments from
their ancestral lands when protected areas were
proclaimed, local communities generally developed
antipathical view of wildlife (Mwima, 2001; Child, 2004;
Mbaiwa, 2007). Traditionally, conservation has focused
on the establishment of protected areas under central
government control and eviction of people residing in
these areas but it has negative impacts on local
livelihoods and sometimes results into increased
poaching pressure (BrockingtonandIgoe, 2006; Makagon
et al., 2014). To address such antipathy, government
agencies and non-government organizations (NGOs)
joined forces in the 1980s and 1990s to develop
community-based wildlife programmes aimed at providing
benefits to affected communities (Murphree, 1993).
However, common property rights which were based on
traditional leadership were evinced and proclaimed by the
state as flawed systems which caused natural resource
degradation, legitimising state intervention in
management of the commons (Leach and Mearns, 1996).
Thereafter, local communities retained legacies as
hunters and gatherers (Child, 2004; Marks, 2009).
Exacerbated by extreme poverty and low literacy levels of
resource harvesting, in many cases biodiversity
conservation efforts involving local communities have
been deemed unsuccessful in favour of „fortress
conservation‟ that seeks to exclude local people from
resources in order to ensure their conservation (Bϋscher
and Dressler, 2007). The intervention was a zeal for
reform entailing mainly privatisation and nationalisation of
communal resources (Magole, 2003).
However, one of the deterministic strategies the
Eastern and Southern regions spearheaded was the
return of rights from the state to local communities
through the community based natural resource
management (CBNRM) programmes (e.g. ADMADE in
Zambia; CAMPFIRE in Zimbabwe, LIFE in Namibia and
TRANSFORM in South Africa) and various partnerships
(Hulme and Murphree, 2001; Fabricius and Koch, 2004;
Dressler et al., 2010). CBNRM was poised to address the
biodiversity conservation challenges through trans-
formative collective action and devolution of resource
user rights (Child, 2004). Unlike in open-access property
regimes, common property owners have greater ability to
manage conflicts through shared benefits and
enforcement (Klein and Robinson, 2011). However,
widespread central control of common-pool resources by
the state occurs due to perceived inertia among the local
actors (Rankin et el., 2007). One of the key challenges in
managing common-pool resources is society
complexities due to heterogeneity in actors‟ values and
norms about commonly owned property resource
management and inadequate supportive legislation. In
order to minimise the challenges in managing common
resources, membership rules have been applied to
exclude non-members from common resources (Lawry et
al., 2014). Subsequently, CBNRM models have either
been unsuccessful or successful. For instance, CBNRM
in Namibia has encouraged the recovery of wildlife and
generated significant incomes (NACSO, 2008) while in
Mozambique and Zambia both wildlife and associated
incomes have dwindled over time (Lindsey et al., in
press). The differences in the outcomes of common
property rights in Namibian verses Mozambican and
Zambian scenarios were due to unclear and weak
proprietary rights to the resource users coupled with
weak relational social capital among the resource actors
like communities and wildlife agencies.
In Malawi, CBNRM focuses on natural resources within
protected areas and allows the consumptive use of
resources by communities adjacent to national parks and
wildlife reserves but wildlife remains the property of the
Nyirenda 283
state (Arntzen et al., 2003).Mesterton-Gibbons and
Milner-Gulland (1998) posited that Zimbabwean local
communities used cooperative game theory to determine
the conditions under which community self-monitoring
would ensure conservation occurs. These researchers in
Zimbabwe concluded that „„no self-monitoring agreement
can be sustainable without a payment to each individual
that exceeds the opportunity cost of monitoring even if no
one is poaching‟‟.
In Botswana, like in other states in the region,
assumption was made that once local communities fully
participate in natural resource management and derive
benefits, they can develop a sense of ownership and will
use their natural resources sustainably (Mbaiwa, 2007).
In all the above stated illustrations, the focus was bottom-
up programmes implementation. Users were usually local
residents that traditionally relied upon the common-pool
resource for subsistence and self-regulated consumption
by imposing their own enforcement of restrictions, or
partnering with local authorities to do so (Gibson and
Marks, 1995; Ostrom, 1999). Simultaneously, they
depended on the top-down regulations by the state for
their legitimacy (Child, 2004).
Caughley and Sinclair (1994) and Mphale et al. (1999)
gave an account of a pilot range management project in
Lesotho, where the Government of Lesotho and the
United States Agency for International Development
(USAID) established a successful grazing association at
Sehlabathebe in the Drakensburg Mountains, and gave it
management control over a badly degraded watershed. A
popularly elected executive committee was responsible
for administering a grazing management plan which
provided for the seasonal rotation of livestock among
winter grazing areas near villages and summer grazing
areas in the surrounding mountains.
Livestock found grazing in violation of the plan were
subject to impoundment by range riders. Local sanctions
and rules helped to control „free riders‟, who could
otherwise degrade the rangeland further. Other similar
examples are found in such countries as Botswana,
South Africa and Zimbabwe in Southern Africa (Scoones
and Cousins, 1991; Rohde et al., 2006). Despite these
innovative collective actions, several other areas
remained exposed to „free riders‟ of the commons,
effectively giving rise to open access resource regimes
(Dore, 2001), including where local institutions existed
(Lindsey et al., 2014).Therefore, strong investments in
capacity development of local institutions and
governance structures are required (Fabricius and
Collins, 2007).
Private property regimes
Private property regime is both excludable and rival,
while rights to access, use, exclusion and management,
appropriate stream of economic rents from use of and
284 Int. J. Biodivers. Conserv.
investments in the resource, and the rights to sell or
otherwise transfer the resource to others are controlled
by a private owner or a group of legal owners (Repetto,
1988; Guerin, 2003). To a considerable degree, Eastern
and Southern Africa have legalised and privatised the
use of wildlife, encouraging hunting, tourism and the sale
of meat, hides and horns for wildlife that remains res
nullius (without formal owner) or state-owned (Hill, 1994;
Lindsey et al., 2009). If certain conditions are met,
governments have delegated to the owners of private
land the full rights to control the use of wildlife on their
land (Jones and Murphree, 2004). With incentive to reap
the benefits, investment in the resource base will
optimise the benefits received, and will ensure the
resource is not depleted over time (Andelson, 1991).
For example, due to incentives to invest by the private
owners, management of wildlife was enhanced in
Zimbabwe, raising the average return on investment from
1.8 to 10.5%as compared to non-private wildlife entities
(Moyo,2000). In the Southern Africa, private rights
conferred on land owners such as game ranchers
resulted in drastically increased wildlife revenues,
expanded wildlife populations and enhanced habitats
(Child, 2009b). Establishment of de facto private rights to
wildlife reversed declining Namibian wildlife populations,
and resulted in an 80% increase in wildlife on freehold
land and a major boost to the national economy (Jones,
1999). In South Africa, game ranching developed rapidly
and contributed significantly, ecologically and to local and
national economies (Van der Waal and Dekker, 2000;
Child, 2009b). In Zambia, game ranching industry has
alsogrownrapidlysince1980s, contributing to biodiversity
conservation, job creation and economies (Lindsey et al.,
2013). However, implications of the contemporary global
pressure created by „land rush‟ (Cotula and Polack, 2012)
regarding resource property rights regimes needs to be
further studied.
Further, in Savé Valley Conservancy in Zimbabwe
private actors partnered with the local communities to
enhance benefits to local economies through improved
conservancy financing and management (Lindsey et al.,
2009). Partnership was born out of realisation that wildlife
could not be effectively conserved in protected areas or
on private land without the support of neighbouring
communities (Kreuter and Simmons, 1994).Again,
another example comes from contractual parks as one
innovative conservation mechanism which has been
popular in South Africa since the 1980s (Reid and Turner,
2004; Grossman and Holden, 2009). This kind of
contractual parks are established on land owned
privately, either by individuals or community groups,
which are then managed by the national conservation
authorities and effectively become part of the national
protected areas estate. Management of contractual parks
is carried out in accordance with a joint management
agreement devised by a board comprising
representatives of both the landowners and the conserva-
tion authorities.
Therefore, building relational social capital in such
arrangements is inevitable in fostering partnership.
RESOURCE PROPERTY RIGHTS VS. BIODIVERSITY
CONSERVATION
Resource property rights, resource use and biodiversity
conservation are intractably linked. Accelerated over-
harvesting of forest products and degradation of forests
occurred after national governments declared themselves
to be the owners of forested land (Ascher, 1995). Similar
problems of overexploitation have occurred with inshore
fisheries when national agencies presumed that they had
exclusive jurisdiction over all coastal waters (Finlayson
and McCay, 1998). The states usurp the rights from
users based on pessimism about the possibility of users
voluntarily cooperating to prevent overuse, leading to
widespread central control of common-pool resources
(Hardin, 1968). Consequently, the tragedy of the
commons arises when it is difficult and costly to exclude
potential users from common-pool resources that yield
finite flows of benefits. As a result, the resources will be
exhausted by rational, utility-maximising individuals rather
than conserved for the benefit of all (Guerin, 2003). Thus,
the problem of over exploitation is a result of the
resources being under public rather than private
ownership (WentworthandRatté,2002).Where
government manages public resource property, the
neighbouring local communities should be involved in
beneficial partnerships with the state to ensure resource
protection(Child, 2009a).Such engagement with local
communities may follow the principle of environmental
subsidiarity, where local communities will have the right
to make choice of rational decisions over resource use
and management (Ribot et al., 2010).
RESOURCE PROPERTY RIGHTS VERSUS
COLLABORATIVE GOVERNANCE
Collaborative governance of natural resources is a multi-
actor based social processing a collective action
(Imperial, 2005). Such collective action can greatly
caution decimation of natural resources in transient
resource property rights governance especially where
state governance structures become inadequate to
counteract resource depletion (Gibson and Marks, 1995).
CBNRM was founded based on the common property
theory which was applied to discourage open resource
access though promotion of resource ownership, control
and use by local communities (Rihoy and Steiner, 1995)
and emphasised participatory approaches (Twyman,
2000). It was realised by practitioners and scholars that
local communities can only conserve and use these
natural resources in a sustainable manner when they
Nyirenda 285
Table 1. Key conditions determining the likelihood for success of a particular property regime in Eastern and Southern Africa.
Type of property
regime
Key conditions for success or failure
Selected references
Open access
regime
Absence of controls leads to systems failure. Implementation of effective
internal and external controls by way of local rules, norms and practice as well
as sound policies and effective management result in sustainably managed
resources.
Submanian, 1996; Todd et
al., 1999; Guerin, 2003; Folke
et al., 2010; Lindsey et al.,
2014.
Public property
regime
Though exclusionary policies may appear enticing for policy makers and
resource managers, community involvement has shown to be promising. Local
integration in resource management and beneficiation enhances sustainable
resource management. Through local involvement, transactional costs for
resource management are lowered, thereby increasing success rates for
biodiversity conservation.
Child, 2009b; Grossman and
Holden, 2009.
Common property
regime
Like in other regimes such as public and private property regimes, relational
social capital plays a critical role in improving positive outcomes of resource
management. In addition, clear proprietary rights and associated benefits to
the resource users are crucial.
Wilson et al., 2006; Marks,
2009; Magole et al., 2010;
Lawry et al., 2014.
Private property
regime
Increased incentives, including ownership and use rights of the resources
within a given jurisdiction and sound relational social capital environment
stimulate sustainable utilisation and biodiversity conservation.
Moyo, 2000; Grossman and
Holden, 2009; Child, 2009b;
Lindsey et al., 2013.
derive benefits from them (Swatuk, 2005). In order to
address these biodiversity conservation challenges,
various models of institutional arrangements have been
piloted in Eastern and Southern region (Lund and Treue,
2008; Child, 2009a) and their effectiveness are mostly yet
to be assessed.
RESOURCE PROPERTY RIGHTS
VERSUSSUSTAINABILITY
Sustainability of the property rights depends on
legitimisation of the rights by local and state authorities
(Mbote, 2005). Property rights play an important role in
the sustainable use of resources as they create wealth to
local communities and land owners, and enhance
protection of resources and convey rights (Lyons, 1998;
Anderson et al., 2013). The stronger the institutions and
the rights, the less danger there is likely to the
persistence of the common-pool resources (Schlager and
Ostrom, 1992). Property rights ought to empower actors
evenly within the existing institutional arrangements
responsible for resource management (Brockington et al.,
2008). Strong institutional functionalities, including use of
formal and informal rules to give incentives to the actors,
are essential for sustainable natural resource manage-
ment (Hagedorn, 2008; Bromquist, 2009).Securing of
property rights in resource management serves to
provide for incentives for sustainable natural resource
management and rural development (Demsetz, 1998).
Convincing participants to have beneficial behaviour to
the rest of the group requires that individuals trust that
the desired outcome is attainable and that free-riders will
not benefit (Rankin et el., 2007). If gains can provide the
economic incentive to landowners to manage natural
resources on a sustained-yield basis, species will be
saved (Hobley, 1996). However, there are several threats
to sustainability that need to be dealt with. For instance,
oppressive state control and rent seeking behaviour can
put the resource base at risk (Benjaminsen et al., 2013).
Further, essential research on attributes of property rights
would contribute to sustainability of biological resources
(Diekert, 2012; Nkhata et al., 2012). As the tragedy of the
commons is increasingly part of the conventional wisdom
in environmental studies, economics and ecology
(McEvoy, 1988; Leach and Mearns 1996), results and
lessons from the tragedy of commons could proof
relevant in the formulation of strategies and policies for
sustainable natural resource management.
KEY REASONS FOR FAILURE OF VIABLE
RESOURCE PROPERTY RIGHTS
There are several reasons for failure of what would be
otherwise viable resource property rights. Key conditions
for success or failure of a particular property regime in
Eastern and Southern Africa are given in Table 1. The
following are reasons considered to influence impacts of
property regimes on resource utilisation and biodiversity
conservation, and these can be dynamic and site
specific. According to Lawrence (2000), failure to provide
necessary conditions for a property rights regime to
propel resource conservation through ownership rights
results in degradation of the resource base. For instance,
individual land ownership having more secured formal
286 Int. J. Biodivers. Conserv.
property rights to land have resulted in more investment
and improved productivity per unit area (Feder and
Feeny, 1991). In different instance, fishermen who have
clearly defined private rights are able to increase
efficiency in the use of space and technology (Schlager,
1994) and generate a positive incentive for conservation
(Bodal, 2003). A property rights system which includes
the right to alienation is often considered the most
efficient as it can be defined as equivalent to private
property (Ostrom, 2003).Failures to implement alienation
rules and participatory collective action have often led to
degradation of the natural resources (Haller and Merten,
2008; Chabwela and Haller, 2010).
Previously, failure by governments to provide adequate
preliquisite developmental facilities to local communities
coerced local communities to become dependent on
revenue remittances by the states from resource
utilisation. Although CBNRM initially focussed on
conservation approach, the rural development became
more prominent over any other objective (Arntzenet al.,
2007).This mismatch in the implementation of set
objectives occurred even when certain local communities
received exclusive rights and responsibilities over natural
resource management from the state (Arntzen et al.,
2003). Thus, failure to directly link conservation and
development to cement promotion of environmental
conservation and rural economic development through
local community participation in natural resource
management and other derivatives such as tourism
development facilitated increased resource degradation
(Leach et al., 1999; Twyman, 2000; Mbaiwa, 2004).
The property rights are often simplified and frail to
articulate representation of a complex social-ecological
system. For example, common-pool resources theory
tends to concentrate on simple systems and common
resource generates a predictable, finite supply of one
type of resource unit (for example wildlife or tons of fish)
in each time period (Ostrom, 2008). Further, resource
users are assumed to be short-term, profit-maximising
actors who have complete information and are
homogeneous in terms of their assets, skills, cultural
views and discount rates on harvesting.
The other limiting factor to improved resource property
regimes is that transaction costs for establishing,
implementation and monitoring can be prohibitive. For
instance, Tanzania continues with one of the highest
rates of deforestation in Africa despite having forest laws
supporting participatory forest management, and local
communities entering into agreements with the Forest
Department to manage local forestland and forest
resources (Abdallah and Monela, 2007). According to
Abdallah and Monela (2007), local communities can also
designate village land as protected forestland and can
develop plans for sustainable use and conservation. To
date, however, the country‟s participatory forest
management experience has not significantly reduced
the rate of deforestation and land degradation:
programmes are expensive and time-consuming to
establish; local forest departments often lack sufficient
human and financial resources; and the benefits to
communities have not been sufficient to offset their loss
of unrestricted use of the forest resources. Similar
scenarios have been experienced in Zambia‟s forests
following Joint Forest Management pilot projects (ILUA,
2010).
CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS
Sustainable natural resource management demands
deterministic and collective action to halt momentous loss
of biodiversity from overutilization. In Eastern and
Southern Africa, much of biodiversity conservation
challenges can be attributed to flaws in the
implementation of resource property rights and even the
absence of the property rights altogether as in the case of
prevalent open access regimes. Tragedy of the commons
occurs and is expressed in different forms of waning
natural resources at multiple temporal and geographical
scales. Institutions of governance, which will enable
definitive local rules, hegemony and self-governing of
actors would play a key role in progressive
implementation of property rights beyond existing
enabling legal provisions.
The role of local communities and other actors in
resource dominant areas is important to safeguarding
integrity of biological diversity. Integrative approaches are
required to stimulate active participation of local resource
actors. In order to maximise benefits and appropriately
internalise costs of establishing and implementing
appropriate property regimes among the actors, capacity
building through information generation and sharing in
addition to skills building is essential. Such strategies
curtail the challenges of dearth of information, lapses in
the taking advantages of economies of scale,
internalisation of transaction costs and misinterpretation
of legal and policy provisions among the actors. Land
tenure should always, thus, be made supportive and
clear to the actors. Therefore, functional social networks
such as partnerships between governments and other
actors are likely to improve collaborative governance of
natural resources delivery of the property rights via joint
ventures and other initiatives. Vices such as rent seeking
and undue political power relations among different
actors can be prevented by functional social networks
and collective action.
Conflict of interests
The author declared no conflict of interest.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The author is grateful to two anonymous reviewers who
criticized the initial draft. The Copper belt University also
gave access to various historical and contemporary
literature resources on this subject of property rights
regimes.
REFERENCES
Abdallah JM, Monela GG (2007). Overview of miombo woodlands in
Tanzania. Working papers of the Finnish Forest Research Institute
50:9-23. http://www.metla.fi/julkaisut/workingpapers/2007/mwp050-
02.pdf (accessed 7July 2014).
Adams WM (2004). Against extinction: the story of conservation.
London: Earthscan.
Adams M, Sibanda S, Turner S (1999). Land tenure reform and rural
livelihoods in Southern Africa. London: Overseas Development
Institute.
Alajarvi P (1996). Forest management planning and inventory. Lusaka:
ZFAP, MENR.
Andelson RV (ed.) (1991). Commons without tragedy: the social
ecology of land tenure and democracy.London: Centre for Incentive
Taxation.
Anderson J, Colby M, McGahuey M, Mehta S (2013). Nature, wealth
and power: leveraging natural and social capital for resilient
development. Washington, DC: USAID.
Arntzen JW, Molokomme DL, Terry EM, Moleele N, Tshosa O,
Mazambani D (2003). Final report of the review of community-based
natural resource review in Botswana: Report no. 1. Gaborone: Centre
for Applied Research for the National CBNRM Forum.
Arntzen J, Setlhogile T, Barnes J (2007). Rural livelihoods, poverty
reduction, and food security in Southern Africa: Is CBNRM the
answer? Washington, DC: International Resources Group.
Ascher W (1995). Communities and sustainable forestry in developing
countries. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press.
Barbier EB(1991).Environmental degradation in the third world. In:
Pearce DW, Markandya E, Barbier EB (eds.). Blueprint 2: Greening
world economy. London: Earthscan.
Barnes DL (1978). Problems and prospects of increased pastoral
production in the tribal trust lands. Zambesia 6(1):49-59.
Benjaminsen TA, Goldman MJ, Minwary MY, Maganga FP (2013).
Wildlife management in Tanzania: state control, rent seeking and
community resistance. Dev Change 44(5):1-23.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/dech.12055
Berkes F(2006). From community-based resource management to
complex systems. Ecol Soc 11(1):45. [online] URL:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol11/iss1/art45/ (accessed on 19
August 2014).
BlewettRA (1995). Property rights as a cause of tragedy of the
commons: institutional change and the pastoral Maasai of Kenya.
Eastern Econ. J. 21:447-490.
Bodal BO(2003). Incorporating ecosystem considerations into fisheries
management large-scale industry perspectives. In: Sinclair M,
Valdimarsson G(eds.), Responsible fisheries in the marine, pp. 41-
46. Wallingford: CABI.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1079/9780851996332.0041
Brockington D, Igoe J (2006).Eviction for conservation: a global
overview. Conserv. Soc. 4(3):424-470.
Brockington D, Duffy R, Igoe J(2008). Nature unbound: conservation,
capitalism and the future of protected areas. London: Earthscan.
Bromley DW (1992). Property rights as authority systems: the role of
rules in the resource management. In: Nemetz P (ed.), Emerging
Issues in forest policy, pp. 867-877. Vancouver: University of British
Columbia Press.
Bromquist W (2009). Multi-level governance and natural resource
management: in the challenges of complexity, diversity and
uncertainty. In: Beckmann V, Padmananbhan M (eds.), Institutions of
sustainability, pp. 109-126. Dordrecht: Springer Science and
Business Media BV. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4020-9690-7_6
Bϋscher B (2010). Anti-politics as political strategy: neoliberalism and
transfrontier conservation in Southern Africa. Dev. Change 41(1):29-
Nyirenda 287
51.
BϋscherB, Dressler W (2007). Linking neoprotectionism and
environmental governance: on the rapidly increasing tensions
between actors in the environment-development nexus. Conserv.
Soc. 5:586-611.
Caughley G, Sinclair ARE (1994). Wildlife ecology and management.
Oxford:Blackwell.
Chabwela HN and Haller T (2010). Governance issues, potentials and
failures of participatory collective action in Kafue Flats, Zambia. Int. J.
Commons 4(2):621-642.
Chidumayo EN (2012). Development of reference emission levels for
Zambia. Lusaka: FAO.
ChildB (2004). Growth of modern nature conservation in Southern
Africa. In Child B. (ed.). Parks in transition: biodiversity, rural
development and the bottom line, pp. 5-27. London: Earthscan.
Child B (2009a). Recent innovations in conservation. In Suich H, Child
B and Spenceley A (eds.), Evolution and innovation in wildlife
conservation: parks and game ranches to transfrontier conservation
areas, pp. 277-288. London: Earthscan.
Child B (2009b). Private conservation in Southern Africa: practice and
emerging principles. In Suich H, Child B and Spenceley A (eds.),
Evolution and innovation in wildlife conservation: parks and game
ranches to transfrontier conservation areas, pp. 103-111. London:
Earthscan.
Coad L, Abernethy K, Balmford A, Manica A, Airey L, Milner-Gulland EJ
(2010)
Distribution and use of income from bushmeat in a rural village, Central
Gabon.Conserv. Biol. 24:1510-1518.
Cotula L, Polack E (2012). The global land rush: what the evidence
reveals about scale and geography. London: IIED.
De Alessi L(1983). Property rights and transaction costs: a new
perspective in economic theory. Soc. Sci. J. 20:59-69.
Deininger K(2003). Land polices for growth and poverty reduction. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Demsetz H(1998). Property rights. In: Newman, P. (ed.), The new
palgrave dictionary of economics and the law, New York: Stockton
Press. 3: 144-155.
Denison M, Klingler-Vidra R(2012). Annotated Bibliography: property
rights. London: Economic and Private Sector PEAKS.
Diekert FK (2012). Growth overfishing: the race to fish extends to the
dimension of size. Environ Resource Econ 52:549-572.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-012-9542-x
Dodds WK(2005). The commons, game theory, and aspects of human
nature that may allow conservation of global resource. Environ. Value
14:411–425.http://dx.doi.org/10.3197/096327105774462683
Dore D (2001). Transforming traditional institutions for sustainable
natural resource management: history, narratives and evidence from
Zimbabwe's communal areas. African Studies Quarterly Volume 5,
Issue 3. Florida: University of Florida, Center for African Studies.
Dressler W, Bϋscher B, Schoon M, Brockington D, Hayes T, Kull C,
McCarthy J, Streshta K (2010). From hope to crisis and back?: a
critical history of the global CBNRM narrative. Environ. Conserv.
37:5-15. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892910000044
Fabricius C, Collins S (2007). Community-based natural resource
management: governing the commons. Water Policy 9(2):83-97.
Fabricius C, Koch E, Mangome H (2001). Community wildlife
management in Southern Africa: challenging the assumption of Eden.
London: IIED.
Fabricius C, Koch E (2004). Rights, resources and rural development:
community-based natural resource management in Southern Africa.
London: Earthscan.
FAO (2009). The state of world fisheries and aquaculture, 2008. Rome:
FAO.
Feder G,Feeny D(1991). Land tenure and property rights: theory and
implications for development policy. World Bank Econ. Rev.5:135-
153. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/wber/5.1.135.
Finlayson AC, McCay BJ (1998). Crossing the threshold of ecosystem
resilience: the commercial extinction of Northern cod. In: Berkes F,
Folke C, Colding J (eds.), Linking social and ecological systems:
management practices and social mechanisms for building resilience,
pp. 311-338. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Folke C, Carpenter SR, Walker B, Scheffer M, Chapin T, Rockström J
288 Int. J. Biodivers. Conserv.
(2010). Resilience thinking: integrating resilience, adaptability and
transformability. Ecol Soc 15(4): 20. [online] URL:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol15/iss4/art20/ (accessed on 14
May 2014).
Gibson CC, Marks SA(1995). Transforming rural hunters into
conservationists: an assessment of community-based wildlife
management programs in Africa. World Dev. 23 (6):941-957.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(95)00025-8
Giller KE, Leeuwis C, Andersson JA, Andriesse W, Brouwer A, Frost P,
Hebinck P, Heitkönig I, van IttersumMK, Koning N, Ruben R,
Slingerland M, Udo H,Veldkamp T, van de Vijver C, van Wijk MT,
Windmeijer P(2008). Competing claims on natural resources: what
role for science?. Ecol Soc 13(2): 34. [online] URL:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol13/iss2/art34/(accessedon5Jun
e2014).
Grossman D, Holden P (2009). Towards transformation: contractual
National Parks in South Africa. In: Suich H, Child B, Spenceley A
(eds.), Evolution and innovation in wildlife conservation: parks and
game ranches to transfrontier conservation areas, pp. 357-372.
London: Earthscan.
Guerin K (2003). Property rights and environmental policy, a New
Zealand perspective. Wellington. New
Zealand.http://www.treasury.govt.nz/publications/research-
policy/wp/2003/03-02/twp03-02.pdf (accessed on 20 May 2014).
Hagedon K (2008). Particular requirements for institutional analysis in
nature-related sectors. Eur Rev Agric Econ 35(3):357-384.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/erae/jbn019
Haller T, Chabwela HN (2009). Managing common pool resources in
the Kafue flats, Zambia: from common property to open access and
privatisation. Dev. Southern Africa 26:555-567.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03768350903181340
Haller T, Merten S (2008). "We are Zambians – don't tell us how to fish!"
Institutional change, power relations and conflicts in the Kafue flats
fisheries in Zambia. Hum Ecol 36(5):699-715.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10745-008-9191-4
Hardin G(1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1243-1248.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.162.3859.1243
Henry M, Maniatis D, Gitz V, Huberman D, Valentini R (2011).
Implementation of REDD+ in sub-Saharan Africa: state of knowledge,
challenges and opportunities. Environ. Dev.Econ. 16:381-404.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1355770X11000155
Hill K (1994). Politicians, farmers and ecologists: commercial wildlife
ranching and the politics of land in Zimbabwe. J.Asian Afr. Stud.
29:3-4. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/002190969402900305
Hobley M (1996). Participatory forestry: the process of change in India
and Nepal. Rural development forestry study guide.Rural
development forestry network. London: Overseas Development
Institute.
Hulme D, Murphree M (eds.)(2001). African wildlife and livelihoods: the
promise and performance of community conservation. Oxford: James
Currey.
ILUA (2010). Integrated land use assessment, 2005-2008. Lusaka:
ILUA, MENR.
Imperial MT (2005). Using collaboration as a governance strategy:
lessons from six watershed management programs. Admin. Soc.
37(3):281-320. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0095399705276111
Jones BTB (1999). Lights, revenues and resources: the problems and
potential of conservancies as community wildlife institutions in
Namibia. Evaluating Eden Project. London: IIED.
Jones BTB, Murphree MW (2004). Community-based natural resource
management as a conservation mechanism: lessons and directions.
In Child B (ed.), Parks in transition: biodiversity, rural development
and the bottom line, pp. 63-104. London: Earthscan.
Klein DB, Robinson J (2011). Property: a bundle of rights? Prologue to
the symposium.Econ.J. Watch8(3):193-204.
Knox A (1996). Malawi Country Profile.In:Bruce JW (ed.),Country
profiles of land tenure, Southern Africa,pp. 13-18. Madison:
University of Wiscconsin.
Kreuter UP, SimmonsRT (1994). Economics, politics and controversy
over African elephant conservation. In:Freeman MR, Kreuter UP
(eds.), Elephants and whales: Resources for whom?, pp 39-57. New
York: Gordon and Breach.
Lawrence R(2000). Property, rights and fairness. Cambridge:
Cambridge Research for the Environment.
Lawry S, Samii C, Hall R, Leopold A, Hornby D, Mtero F (2014). The
impact of land property rights interventions on investment and
agricultural productivity in developing countries: a systematic review.
Cambridge, MA: Ash Centre for Democratic Governance and
Innovation.
Leach M, Mearns R, Scoones I(1999). Environmental entitlements:
dynamics and institutions in community-based natural resources
management. World Dev. 27(2):225-247.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X(98)00141-7
Leach M, Mearns R (eds.) (1996). The lie of the land: challenging
received wisdom on the African environment. Oxford: James Currey.
Leal DR (1998).Community-run fisheries: avoiding the
tragedy of the commons.Popul. Environ. 19:225-246.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1024691919628
Lee JA,Libecap GD, Schneider R (1996). The determinants and impact
of property rights: land titles on the Brazilian frontier. J.Law Econ.
Organ 12(1):25-61.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a023360
Leverington F, Costa KL, Courrau J, Pavese H, Nolte C, Marr M, Coad
L, Burgess N, Bomhard B, Hockings M (2010). Management
effectiveness evaluation in protected areas : a global study. Second
edition. Brisbane: University of Queensland.
Libby LW(1994). Conflict on the commons: natural resource
entitlements, the public interest, and agricultural economics. Am.J.
Agr. Econ. 6:997-1009. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/124338
Libecap GD (2009). The tragedy of the commons: property rights and
markets as solutions to resource and environmental problems.
Australian J. Agric. Res. Econ. 53:129-144.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8489.2007.00425.x
Lindsey PA, NyirendaVR,BarnesJI, BeckerMS, McRobb R, Tambling C,
Taylor A, Watson F, t'Sas-Rolfes M (2014). Underperformance of
African Protected Area Networks and the Case for New Conservation
Models: insights from Zambia. PLoS One 9(5):e94109.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0094109
Lindsey PA, Barnes J, Nyirenda V, Pumfrett B, Tambling CJ, Taylor
WA, t'Sas-Rolfes (2013). The Zambian wildlife ranching industry:
scale, associated benefits and limitations affecting its development.
PLoS One 8(12):e81761.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0081761
Lindsey PA, du Toit R, Pole A, Roma-ach S (2009). Savé Valley
Conservancy: a large-scale African experiment in cooperative wildlife
management. In: Suich H, Child B, Spenceley A (eds.), Evolution and
innovation in wildlife conservation: parks and game ranches to
transfrontier conservation areas, pp. 163-184. London: Earthscan.
Lindsey P, Taylor WA, Nyirenda V, Barnes J (In press). Bushmeat
poaching costs African countries hundreds of millions of dollars per
year. PLoS One.
Lueck DL(1998). First possession. In: Newman, P. (ed.), The new
palgrave dictionary of economics and the law, New York: Stockton
Press. 2: 132-144.
Lund JF, Treue T (2008).Are we getting there? Evidence of
decentralized forest management from the Tanzanian miombo
woodlands. World Dev 36:2780-2800.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.01.014
Lyons A(1998). A profile of the community based monitoring systems of
three Zambia rural development project. Lusaka USAID/ZAMBIA.
Magole IL (2009). Common pool resources management among the
San communities in Ngamiland, Botswana. Dev Southern Africa
26:597-610. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03768350903181381
Magole L (2003). A tragedy of the commoners: the evolution of
communal rangeland management in Kgalagadi, Botswana. PhD
Thesis, University of East Anglia.
Magole L, Turner S, Bϋscher B(2010). Towards an effective commons
governance system in Southern Africa? Int. J. Commons 4(2):602-
620.
Makagon JE, Jonas H, Roe D (2014). Upholding human rights in
conservation: who is responsible? London: IIED.
Marks SA (2009). Rural people and wildlife in Zambia's central Luangwa
Valley: precautionary advice from a long-term study. In: Baldus RD
(ed.), A practical summary of experiences after three decades of
community-based wildlife conservation in Africa: what are the lessons
learnt?, pp. 52-71. CIC Technical Series Publication No. 5. Budapest:
FAO and CIC.
Mbaiwa JE (2007). Local community attitudes towards wildlife
conservation and community based natural resources management
in Ngamiland District, Botswana. In: Schuster B, Thakadu OT(eds.),
Natural resources management and people, pp. 19-26. Gaborone:
IUCN CBNRM Support Programme.
Mbaiwa JE(2004). The success and sustainability of community-based
natural resource management in the Okavango delta, Botswana. S.
Afr.Geogr. J. 86 (1):44-53.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03736245.2004.9713807
Mbote KP(2005). Land tenure, land use and sustainability in Kenya:
towards innovative use of wildlife property rights in wildlife
management. Nairobi: International Environmental Law Research
Center.
McEvoy AF (1988). Toward an interactive theory of nature and culture:
ecology, production, and cognition in the California fishing industry.
The Ends of the Earth: perspective on modern environmental history.
Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.
Mesterton-Gibbons M, Milner-Gulland EJ(1998). On the strategic
stability of monitoring: implications for cooperative wildlife
management programmes in Africa. Proc R Soc Lond B 265:1237-
1244. http://dx.doi.org/10.1098/rspb.1998.0425
Mhlanga L (2009). Fragmentation of resource governance along the
shoreline of Lake Kariba, Zimbabwe. Dev. Southern Africa 26:585-
596. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03768350903181365
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005). Ecosystems and human
well-being: biodiversity synthesis.Washington D.C: World Resources
Institute.
Moyo S(2000). Land reform under structural adjustment in
Zimbabwe:land-use change in the Mashonaland Province. Uppsala:
Nordic Africa Institute.
Mphale M, Makoae M, Rwambali EG (1999).Stakeholder opinion
analysis in Mokhotlong District for Drakensberg Mountains
Conservation Programme. Maseru: German for National Environment
Secretariat.
Murphree MW (1993). Communities as resource management
institutions.Gatekeeper Series No. 36. London: IIED
Mwima HK (2001). A brief history of Kafue National Park, Zambia.
Koedoe 44(1):57-72. http://dx.doi.org/10.4102/koedoe.v44i1.186
NACSO (2008). Namibia's communal conservancies: a review of
progress and challenges in 2007. Windhoek: Namibian Association of
CBNRM Support Organizations.
Nkhata BA, Mosimane A, Downborough L, Breen C, Roux DJ (2012). A
topology of benefit sharing arrangements for governance of social-
ecological systems in developing countries. Ecol Soc 17(1): 17.
http://dx.doi.org/10.5751/ES-04662-170117
Ostrom E (2008). Tragedy of the commons: the new palgrave dictionary
of economics. In: Durlauf SN, Blume LE (eds.), The new palgrave
dictionary of economics. Second edition. Online. Palgrave Macmillan.
http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_T000193.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/9780230226203.1729
Ostrom E(2003). How types of goods and property rights jointly affect
collective action. J. Theoretical Polit. 15:239-270.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0951692803015003002
Ostrom E(1999). Coping with tragedies of the commons. Ann. Rev.
Polit. Sci. 2:493-535.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.polisci.2.1.493
Rankin DJ, Bargum K, Kokko H (2007). The tragedy of the commons in
evolutionary biology. Trends Ecol.Evol. 22(12):643-651.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tree.2007.07.009
Reid H, Turner S (2004). The Richtersveld and Makuleke contractual
parks in South Africa: win-win for communities and conservation? In:
Fabricius C, Koch E, Magome H, Turner S (eds.), Rights, resources
and development: community-based natural resource management in
Southern Africa, pp. 223-234. London: Earthscan.
Repetto R(1988). Economic policy reform for natural resource
conservation. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Ribot JC, Lund JF, Treue T (2010). Democratic decentralization in sub-
Saharan Africa: its contribution to forest management, livelihoods,
Nyirenda 289
and enfranchisement. Environ.Conserv. 37(1):35-44.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892910000329
Rohde RF, Moleele NM, Mphale M, Allsopp N, Chanda R, Hoffman MT,
Magole L, YoungE(2006). Dynamics of grazing policy and practice:
environmental and social impacts in three communal areas of
Southern Africa. J. Environ. Sci. Policy 9:302-316.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2005.11.009
Rihoy E, Steiner A (1995). The commons without tragedy?: strategies
for community-based natural resources management in Southern
Africa. In: Proceedings of the regional natural resources management
annual conference. Kasane: SADC Wildlife Technical Co-ordinating
Unit.
Schlager E(1994). Fishers' institutional responses to common-pool
resource dilemmas. In: Ostrom E, Gardner R, Walker J (eds.), Rules,
games, and common-pool resources, Ann. Arbor, Michigan:
University of Michigan Press. pp. 247-266.
Schlager E, Ostrom E(1992). Property-rights regimes and natural
resources: a conceptual analysis. Land Econ. 68 (3):249-262.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3146375
Scoones I, Cousins B (1991). Key resources for agriculture and grazing:
the struggle for control over dambo resources in Zimbabwe. In:
Scoones I (ed.), Wetlands in drylands: the agroecology of savanna
systems in Africa. London: IIED Drylands Programme.
Sinclair ARE, Fryxell JM, Caughley G(2006). Wildlife ecology,
conservation and management. Second edition. Malden, MA:
Blackwell Publishing.
SubmanianJ (1996). Zambia country profile.In: Bruce JW(ed.),Country
profiles of land tenure, Southern Africa, pp.65-68. Madison:
University of Wiscconsin, Land Tenure Centre.
Swanson TM, Barbier EB (1992). Economics for the wilds.Britain:
Guernsey Press Co. Ltd.
Swatuk LA (2005). From project to context: community-based natural
resources management in Botswana. Glob Environ. Polit. 5(3):95-
124. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/1526380054794925
Todd SW,Hoffman MT (1999). A fence-line contrast reveals effects of
heavy grazing on plant diversity and community composition in
Namaqualand, South Africa. Plant Ecol 142:169-178.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1009810008982
Quan J (2000): Land tenure, economic growth and property in sub-
Saharan Africa. In: Toulmin C, Quan J. (eds.), Evolving land rights,
policy and tenure in Africa, pp. 151-179. London: DFID, IIED and
NRI.
Twyman C(2000). Participatory conservation? Community-based
natural resource management in Botswana. Geogr. J. 166 (4):323-
335. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4959.2000.tb00034.x
Van der Waal C, Dekker B (2000). Game ranching in the Northern
province of South Africa. S. Afr. J. Wildl. Res. 30:151-156.
Wentworth DR,Ratté K (2002). Fish tales: classroom lessons about
economics and the environment. Montana: The Centre for Free
Market Environmentalism.
Wilson DC, Raakjaer-Nielsen J, Degnbol P (2006). Local ecological
knowledge and practical fisheries management in the tropics: a policy
brief. Mar Policy 30:794-801.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2006.02.004
Wily LA (2011). The tragedy of public lands: the fate of the commons
under global commercial pressure.Rome: International Land
Coalition.
Wittemyer G, ElsenP, BeanWT, Burton ACO, Brashares JS (2008) Accelerated
human population growth at protected area edges. Science 321:123-126.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1158900