ArticlePDF Available

The relative performance of small cap firms and default risk across the business cycle: International evidence

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

The time-varying nature of the firm size effect has been the subject of growing interest, particularly in the aftermath of the recent financial crisis. Small-cap firms provide a significant nexus for entrepreneurship and innovation and hence might be viewed as less prone to governance problems than large firms. This could in part explain the superior performance of small-cap firms over long time horizons, although leverage, which may be exacerbated during downturns, may hinder their short-term performance. Moscarini and Postel-Vinay (2009) suggest that the small cap premium is linked to job creation: large employers destroy proportionally more jobs during and right after recessions, and create proportionally more jobs late in expansions, relative to small employers. This differential is shown to explain in part the superior performance of US small firms during recoveries (Moscarini and Postel-Vinay, 2010). Switzer (2010) shows that the US small cap premium is significantly related to default risk in the economy, which may impact on investments in R and D and innovation. This paper looks at the impact of the business cycle on the small cap premium internationally. The sample consists of small cap and large cap returns of G-7 countries and the MENA region. Default risk, which may be tied to innovative investments, is not priced in non-common law settings, where protection of shareholders and creditors in bankruptcy states is limited.
Content may be subject to copyright.
North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
North American Journal of
Economics and Finance
The behaviour of small cap vs. large cap stocks in recessions
and recoveries: Empirical evidence for the United States
and Canada
Lorne N. Switzer,1
Finance Department, John Molson School of Business, Concordia University,
1455 De Maisonneuve Blvd. W., Montreal, Quebec, Canada H3G 1M8
article info
Article history:
Received 29 June 2009
Received in revised form 12 October 2010
Accepted 13 October 2010
Available online 4 November 2010
Keywords:
Small-cap equities
Business cycles
Style based investing
Return performance
Market segmentation
abstract
This paper examines the relative performance of small-caps vs.
large caps surrounding periods of peaks and troughs of economic
activity, and reexamines the relationship between the small firm
anomaly and the business cycle. Small-cap firms outperform large
caps over the year subsequent to an economic trough. In the year
prior to the business cycle peak, however, small caps tend to lag.
US style based large caps perform better over peaks, but there
is no dominant category across size and book to market asset
classes over troughs. The US small cap premium is related to default
risk, although recessions per se do not on average impact on this
premium. Default risk and the inflation risk differential between
Canada and the US significantly impact on the Canada–US equity
premium. Abnormal positive performance observed for US small
caps in the recent (post 2001) period as well as for the long horizon
is attributable to the small cap growth cohort. Canadian small firm
stocks also exhibit significantly positive performance in the post
2001 period.
© 2010 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Tel.: +1 514 848 2424x2960; fax: +1 514 481 4561.
E-mail address: switz@jmsb.concordia.ca
1Van Berkom Endowed Chair of Small-Cap Equities and Associate Director, Institute for Governance of Private and Public
Organizations, John Molson School of Business, Concordia University. I would like to thank Christopher Schwarz and participants
at the 2010 Midwest Finance Association Meetings as well as Robert Bliss, Martin Bohl, Pierre Siklos, Hamid Beladi (the Editor),
and the anonymous referees for their very helpful comments and suggestions. Financial support from the SSHRC and the Autorité
des Marches Financiers is gratefully acknowledged.
1062-9408/$ – see front matter © 2010 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.najef.2010.10.002
L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346 333
1. Introduction
A standard presumption of the efficient markets paradigm in finance is that stock market returns
reflect anticipated cash flows of firms in the economy. One of the early challenges to the efficient
markets paradigm is the small firm (small cap) anomaly. The essence of this anomaly is that for long
term holding periods, small cap stocks outperform large cap stocks (e.g., Banz, 1981; Hawawini &
Keim, 1999; Reinganum, 1981; Siegel, 1998). Dimson and Marsh (1999) state that the striking out-
performance of small cap companies is “the premier stock market anomaly” that is inconsistent with
market efficiency. Bhardwaj and Brooks (1993),Horowitz, Loughran, and Savin (2000) and Schwert
(2003) challenge the small-firm anomaly, however. Based on returns that extend to the 1982–2002
period, Schwert concludes (2003, p. 943) the “small-firm anomaly has disappeared since the initial
publication of the papers that discovered it.” The issue of small stock outperformance remains a topic
of debate across countries. More recently, Switzer and Fan (2007) show that the high returns to small
caps may be country dependent, and demonstrate the benefits of adding Canadian small caps for
international investors in enhancing their risk-return performance.
Kim and Burnie (2002) suggest that the time-varying nature of the firm size effect may be
attributable to the business cycle. They study returns over the period 1976–1995, asserting that differ-
entially higher returns for small cap firms relative are observed during economic expansion phases.
Small firm underperformance is shown to occur in their sample over economic contractions. They
postulate that this may be due to the relatively lower productivity and high financial leverage during
downturns (Chan & Chen, 1991; Kim & Burnie, 2002).2Switzer and Tang (2009) note that small-cap
firms provide a significant nexus for entrepreneurship and innovation and hence might be viewed
as less prone to governance problems than large firms; this could in part explain the superior per-
formance of small-cap firms, although leverage, which may be exacerbated during downturns, may
hinder their performance.3
This paper provides new evidence on the small cap anomaly for the US and Canada extending the
sample to include the most recent recessionary period, which dates the trough of the worst post World
War II recession as occurring in June 2009.4In addition, new evidence is put forth to identify whether
the differential returns for small firms vs. large firms are due to the state of the business cycle per
se, as asserted by Kim and Burnie (2002) or due to uncertainty factors including default risk, interest
rate risk, and inflation risk that may be distinct from business cycle effects for small cap vs. large cap
firms. The paper also explores the performance of the Canada vs. US stock premium as a small-country
vs. large country variant of the small firm anomaly over the business cycle. Various determinants of
the Canada–US equity premium are also examined including the role of changing institutional factors,
such as the Canada–US Free Trade Accord (FTA)and the approval of the Multi-Jurisdictional Disclosure
System, which enhances the integration of the markets (see e.g., Doukas & Switzer, 2000).
The organization of the remainder of the paper is as follows. Section 2describes the data. Section 3
revisits the small cap premium in the U.S. and provides some new evidence for a small cap premium
for the Canadian market. As is shown therein, it is apparent that the announcement of the death
of the small firm anomaly seems premature based on the post 2000 period, in particular for small
cap value firms as well as for the experience of Canadian small firms. Section 4looks at business
2This argument has also appeared in the popular financial press. As reported by an analyst in the Financial Times (Handy Caps,
May 26, 2009, p. 12): “The final stages of a boom, though, are an inauspicious time to own small companies. As the economy
slows, they are often the first to feel the pinch: small businesses tend to be biased towards cyclical industries and mostly do not
have the luxury of international diversification. Also, as bull markets near their apex, inflows from naïve retail investors may
be concentrated in the largest, most liquid shares. True to form, small caps began to underperform the broader US market just
as the housing bubble peaked. From April 2006 to the end of 2008, they shed 32 per cent of their value compared with just 24
per cent for large stocks. Conversely, much of small stocks’ historical edge comes from outperforming early in any recovery...
3Switzer and Tang (2009) support the paradigm of entrepreneurial CEO’s whose ownership in such firms is optimally aligned
with performance. However, suboptimal deployment of debt is observed in their sample. In particular, excess leverage is
observed which significantly reduces firm value. This is consistent with the view that debt reduces the entrepreneurial capacity
of firms, by hindering the firm’s ability or willingness to compete aggressively, particularly against well-financed competitors.
4See the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) announcement on September 20, 2010:
http://www.nber.org/cycles/sept2010.html.
334 L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346
cycle effects on the U.S. and Canadian small cap premia. In this section explores various risk factors
apart from recessions per se as explanatory variables as determinants of the small firm premium.
In addition, event study results for differential responses of firms by market capitalization for NBER
announcements of recessions and recoveries are presented.
Section 5looks at the U.S. vs. Canadian stock premium as a large country vs. small country variant
of the small cap anomaly.
The paper concludes in Section 6.
2. Data description
The small cap portfolio returns for the U.S. are based on monthly returns on the Ibbotson/DFA
small stock portfolio, which is available from January 1926. The U.S. large cap portfolio from Morn-
ingstar/Ibbotson is the S&P 500. The U.S. market portfolio proxy is the CRSP value weighted portfolio
of NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ stocks, which is available since 1926. The Dow Jones Industrial Average
(from 1900 on) is also used as a reference for the US market. The US risk free rate is the 1 month T-bill
rate, from WRDS. For the series, the only continuous extant proxy for Canadian small firms is Nesbitt
Burns Small Cap Index, which is available since producing a benchmark series in January 1987. The
Canadian Index combines the S&P/TSX Index with the Switzer Canadian Century Index, as reported
in Dimson, Marsh, and Staunton (2002). The US risk factors are obtained from Morningstar EnCorr.
Default risk (bond default premium) is measured by the geometric difference between total returns
on long-term corporate bonds and long-term government bonds. Term structure risk (bond horizon
premium) is measured by the geometric difference between Government Long Bond and Treasury Bill
Returns. Inflation is based on the US consumer price index. The Canadian Consumer Price Index is
obtained from the Bank of Canada, while the US/Canadian dollar exchange rate is from the Wall Street
Journal.
The business cycle peaks and troughs are based on the National Bureau of Economic Research
(NBER) dates. While a recession is usually defined as the reduction of a country’s gross domestic
product (GDP) for at least two quarters, the NBER as well as policymakers in Canada follow a more
complex identification process that in various cases can conflict with the two quarter GDP rule.5The
NBER has declared twenty-two recessions since 1900, with an average duration of about 14 months.
The most marked of these is the Great Depression – from August 1929 to March 1933, a period of 43
months. Since the end of World War II, the latest 2007 recession, with a duration of eighteen months,
is the most severe.6The Canadian economy moves somewhat in tandem with the US market, and
several US recessions overlap closely with Canadian recessions. However, the most recent recessionary
episode in Canada was much milder and of shorter duration than in US.7Table 1 lists the recession
episodes of recession for both Canada and the US since World War II.
3. The small stock premium anomaly revisited
Is the small stock anomaly dead? Table 2 below shows that for the 84-year holding period beginning
in 1926, the small cap premium, as captured by the geometric difference between the Ibbotson small
5As noted by Cross (2009), in both 2001 and 2008, the NBER identified recessions without back-to-back declines in GDP, as did
Statistics Canada in 1975. See Cross (2009) and the references cited therein. The Bank of Canada is responsible for announcing
the official recession beginning and end date; this is done in coordination with various official parties including Statistics Canada
since 1981. As in the US, the officially announced recessions in Canada do not follow the two quarter GDP contraction rule, but
a combination of factors including employment, industrial growth and others. This paper focuses on ex post recession turning
points that are reported by NBER with considerable lag. Of course building a profitable investment strategy based on these
results can be enhanced by developing a predictive model for recession turning points. The few studies that have appeared in
this vein (e.g., Atta-Mensah & Tkacz (1998); Estrella & Mishkin, 1996, 1998; Leamer, 2008) have been largely inconclusive, and
hence the topic remains an important area for future research.
6The average duration of the other post WWII recessions is 10 months.
7Statistics Canada announced a similar end date to the Canadian recession (Summer 2009). In this “technical recession,” the
Canadian economy contracted over three quarters, which was much milder and of shorter duration than the US recession as
well as Canada’s previous two recessions: http://www.statcan.gc.ca/pub/11-010-x/2010004/part-partie3-eng.htm.
L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346 335
Table 1
Business cycle peaks and troughs (since World War II) as identified by NBER and the Bank of Canada/Statistics Canada.
Canada US Description
Peak Trough Peak Trough
September-47 March-48 February-45 October-45 Demobilization
February-49
June-51
July-49
December-51
November-48 October-49 Economy adjusting to
peace-time production
April-53 April-54 July-53 May-54 Post-Korean war
demobilization; inflation,
restrictive monetary policy
April-57 January-58 August-57 April-58 Monetary tightening,
world recession, high US
dollar
February-60 March-61 April-60 February-61 Restrictive monetary
policy, industrial
adjustments
March-70 June-70 December-69 November-70 Restrictive monetary policy
January-75 March-75 November-73 March-75 OPEC quadrupling oil
prices, Insolvency of the
Franklin National Bank
February-80 June-80 January-80 July-80 Doubling Oil Prices,
July-81 October-82 July-81 November-82 Iranian Revolution
April-90 Apr-92 July-90 March-91 Iraq invades Kuwait, Oil
prices soar
March-01 November-01 Dot-Com Bubble
December-08 June-2010 December-07 June-07 Credit crunch, real estate,
banking crash
Source: Statistics Canada and NBER.
cap portfolio return and the S&P 500 has amounted to over 2.03% per year. There is some variability
over the decades, it is most noticeable during the 1976–1982 period where it stood at 20.33% on an
annualized basis.
Panel B of Table 1 provides estimates of the Jensen (1968) alpha performance regression using
the excess of the Morningstar/Ibbotson U.S. Small Company Portfolio (RSt) over the US risk free rate,
proxied by the one month T-bill rate (RFt) as the dependent variable; the independent variables consist
of a constant and the excess of the CRSP value weighted portfolio of NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ stocks
benchmark market index (RMt) over the one month treasure bill as the risk free rate (RFt); εis the
random error term.
RStRFt=˛+ˇ(RMtRFt)+εt
The intercept of the regression measures the Jensen (1968) ˛, shows the difference between the
monthly return of the small cap portfolio and the Capital Asset Pricing Model. Consistent with Schwert,
there is some time variation in the estimate of ˛. Consistent with Schwert (2003), while economically
and statistically significant in the 1976–2002 period, over the following decade this effect disappears.
However, the small stock premium reappears again in the post 2000 period, and ˛is again significant
at the 5% level.
To probe further into these results, we look at whether the small firm effect is associated with time
varying investment style (Arshanapalli, Switzer, & Panju, 2007). Panels C and D show the Jensen (1968)
alpha regressions for the Fama/French small-cap value and small-cap growth portfolios respectively.
Positive and significant alphas are observed for the long period estimates (1927–2010), as well as
for the 1976–1982 and post 2000 periods significant alpha is observed for the small-cap value port-
folio. The small cap growth portfolio, however is only significant in the 1976–1982 period. Hence,
investment style does affect the abnormal returns to small-cap firms.
Table 3 below shows the analogous Canadian small stock premia, and performance tests against the
CRSP benchmark. Similar to the US small cap portfolio, the BMO Nesbitt Burns proxy for Canadian small
caps does not outperform its reference large cap market index over the period 1987–2000. However,
336 L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346
Table 2
The small cap premium in the US.
Panel A. Annualized holding period returns for US small firms vs. large firms, July 1926–August 2010; the Small Firm
Index is the Ibbotson Associates/DFA small stock. Portfolio. The Large Cap Index is the S&P 500.
Small Cap Index Large Cap Index Small stock premium
1926–1950 9.06% 7.71% 1.35%
1951–1975 10.62% 10.30% 0.32%
1976–1982 32.38% 12.05% 20.33%
1983–2000 12.53% 16.63% -4.1%
2001–2010 0.40% 8.14% 7.74%
1926–2010 11.81% 9.78% 2.03%
Panel B. Small firm Jensen (1968) alpha performance regressions.
Jensen (1968) alpha performance regression of the Morningstar/Ibbotson U.S. Small Company Portfolio (RSt) using the
CRSP value weighted portfolio of NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ stocks (RMt) as the benchmark market index, and the U.S.
one month treasure bill as the risk free rate (RFt); εis the random error term. The intercept of the regression measures
the Jensen (1968) alpha, shows the difference between the monthly return of the small cap portfolio and the Capital
Asset Pricing Model.
RStRFt=˛+ˇ(RMtRFt)+εt
Estimated coefficient
˛ˇR2
1926–1950 0.0025 1.5138*** 0.8059
t-Statistic 0.7669 34.8062
1951–1975 0.0001 1.1526*** 0.7186
t-Statistic 0.3312 27.5880
1976–1982 0.0123*** 1.2849*** 0.7368
t-Statistic 3.1201 15.1504
1983–2000 0.0017 1.0278*** 0.6381
t-Statistic 0.7181 19.4233
2001–2010 0.0056** 1.1442*** 0.7896
t-Statistic 2.0151 20.6858
1926–2010 0.0017 1.3420*** 0.7556
t-Statistic 1.2963 55.8224
***Indicates significance at .01 level.
**Indicates significance at .05 level.
Panel C. Small Cap Value Portfolio Jensen (1968) alpha performance regressions, July 1927–August 2010
Jensen (1968) alpha performance regression of the US Small Cap Value Portfolio (Fama/French/IbbotsonPortfolio) (RSt)
using the CRSP value weighted portfolio of NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ stocks (RMt) as the benchmark market index,
and the U.S. one month treasure bill as the risk free rate (RFt); εis the random error term. The intercept of the
regression measures the Jensen (1968) alpha, shows the difference between the monthly return of the small cap value
portfolio and the Capital Asset Pricing Model
RStRFt=˛+ˇ(RMtRFt)+εt
Estimated coefficient
˛ˇ R2
1926–1950 0.0034 1.5432*** 0.8188
t-Statistic 1.0305 35.5657
1951–1975 0.0024 1.1152*** 0.7294
t-Statistic 1.4783 28.3451
1976–1982 0.0119*** 1.0685*** 0.7292
t-Statistic 3.5990 14.8584
1983–2000 .001089 .8758*** 0.6891
t-Statistic 0.6162 21.7802
2001–2010 0.0181*** 1.14722*** 0.7351
t-Statistic 2.5100 17.7896
1927–2010 0.0032** 1.3471*** 0.7575
t-Statistic 2.4036 55.7752
***Indicates significance at .01 level.
**Indicates significance at .05 level.
L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346 337
Table 2 (Continued )
Panel D. Small Cap Growth Portfolio Jensen (1968) alpha performance regressions, July 1927–August 2010.
Jensen (1968) alpha performance regression of the US Small Cap Growth Portfolio (Fama/French/IbbotsonPortfolio)
(RSt) using the CRSP value weighted portfolio of NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ stocks (RMt) as the benchmark market
index, and the U.S. one month treasure bill as the risk free rate (RFt); εis the random error term. The intercept of the
regression measures the a, shows the difference between the monthly return of the small cap growth portfolio and
the Capital Asset Pricing Model.
RStRFt=˛+ˇ(RMtRFt)+εt
Estimated coefficient
˛ˇ R2
1927–1950 0.0021 1.2638*** 0.8406
t-Statistic .8360 38.4314
1951–1975 .0020 1.2707*** 0.7513
t-Statistic 1.1549 30.0058
1976–1982 0.0067** 1.3779*** 0.8601
t-Statistic 2.4291 23.2301
1983–2000 .0055** 1.3444*** 0.6996
t-Statistic 2.0681 22.3264
2001–2010 0.0012 1.2157*** 0.8294
t-Statistic .4829 23.5433
1927–2010 .00003 1.2773*** 0.8000
t-Statistic .3205 63.1163
***Indicates significance at .01 level.
**Indicates significance at .05 level.
Table 3
The small cap premium in Canada.
Panel A. Annualized holding period returns for Canadian small firms vs. Canadian large firms, January
1987–August 2010; the Small Firm Index is the BMO/Nesbitt Small Stock Index. The Large Cap Index is the
S&P/TSX Index.
Small Cap Index Large Cap Index Small stock premium
1987–1993 5.33% 5.02% .31%
1994–2000 10.87% 11.07% 0.32%
2001–2010 7.31% 3.19% 4.12%
1987–2010 6.07% 5.97% .10%
Panel B. Jensen (1968) alpha performance regression of the BMO/Nesbitt Small Company Index (RSt)
translated to U.S. dollars; the benchmark market index is the CRSP value weighted portfolio of NYSE, AMEX
and NASDAQ stocks (RMt), and the U.S. one month treasure bill is the risk free rate (RFt); εis the random error
term. The intercept of the regression measures the Jensen (1968) alpha, shows the difference between the
monthly return of the small cap portfolio and the Capital Asset Pricing Model
RStRFt=˛+ˇ(RMtRFt)+εt
Estimated coefficient
˛ˇ R2
1987–1993 .0033 .752*** .4360
t-Statistic .775 7.962
1994–2000 0.0120** .9361*** .4981
t-Statistic 2.586 9.201
2001–2010 0.0094** 1.3027*** .6448
t-Statistic 2.125 14.388
1987–2010 .0014 1.033*** .5273
t-Statistic .530 17.738
***Indicates significance at .01 level.
**Indicates significance at .05 level.
338 L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60
LARGEINDEX SMALLINDEX
0
2
4
6
8
10
26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50
LARGEINDEX SMALLINDEX
0
200
400
600
800
1000
1200
62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82
LARGEINDEX SMALLINDEX
0
4000
8000
12000
16000
86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10
LARGEINDEX SMALLINDEX
AB
CD
Fig. 1. US large cap vs. small cap stocks, January 1926 (=1)–January 2010; shaded areas indicate recessionary periods. Panel
A. January 1926–January 1952. Panel B. January 1952–June 1961. Panel C. July 1961–November 83. Panel D. December
1983–September 2010.
an economically and statistically significant small cap abnormal return is observed when the excess
return to the BMO/Nesbitt Burns portfolio (translated into US dollars) are regressed against the excess
return to the CRSP value weighted portfolio for the post 2001 period.
4. The small cap premium over business cycle peaks and troughs
4.1. Differential return performance
How do small-caps vs. large caps perform over business cycle peaks and troughs over a long histor-
ical perspective? Fig. 1 plots the US small cap vs. large cap indices across all fifteen NBER recessionary
episodes since 1926.
The one year market performance from the onset of these recessions is shown in Table 4.
As can be seen in Table 4, over seven of the fifteen recessionary periods since 1926, both large cap
and small cap stocks appreciated in value from the onset of the recession to the end of the recession
(1926, 1945, 1948, 1953,1957, 1960, 1980). However, most recessions show mixed performance at
best for both small caps and large caps. In the most recent recession, from the business cycle peak in
December 2007 to the trough in June 2009, the US large cap index (S&P 500) dropped 38.1%, while the
US small cap portfolio fell by 40.15%.
L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346 339
Table 4
The Performance Small Cap Stocks vs. Large Cap Stocks Portfolios and the small cap premium in the year commencing with the
onset of the recession. This table shows the one year holding period returns for the Ibbotson/DFA small cap portfolio and the
large cap portfolio (S&P 500) from the month corresponding to an NBER designated economic peak (signalling the onset of the
recession)..
Small Cap Index Large Cap Index S
October 1926 20.82% 34.64% 13.82%
August 1929 51.04% 23.48% 27.56%
May 1937 63.00% 37.30% 25.70%
February 1945 91.49% 43.91% 47.58%
November 1948 .23% 4.12% 3.89%
July 1953 11.07% 27.96% 16.89%
August 1957 8.12% 2.55% 5.57%
April 1960 25.81% 21.59% 4.22%
December 1969 28.31% 3.46% 24.85%
November 1973 27.05% 28.83% 1.78%
January 1980 39.88% 32.42% 7.46%
July 1981 15.17% 11.42% 3.75%
July 1990 2.11% 7.39% 9.50%
March 2001 14.05% 9.51% 23.57%
December 2007 40.15% 38.10% 2.05%
Table 5
The Performance Small Cap Stocks vs. Large Cap Stocks Portfolios and the small cap premium over recoveries. This table shows
the one year holding period returns for the Ibbotson/DFA small cap portfolio and the large cap portfolio (S&P 500) from the
month subsequent to an NBER designated economic trough (signalling the end of the recession).
Recession end month Small Cap Index one-year return Large Cap Index one-year return Small stock premium
November 1927 47.29% 39.46% 7.83%
March 1933 296.48% 98.77% 197.72%
June 1938 27.64% 30.71% 3.07%
October 1945 6.33% 3.73% 10.06%
October 1949 38.41% 34.67% 3.73%
May 1954 56.73% 40.84% 15.89%
April 1958 57.47% 36.44% 21.03%
February 1961 22.67% 14.83% 7.83%
November 1970 18.07% 16.88% 1.19%
March 1975 68.13% 27.20% 40.93%
July 1980 69.67% 20.47% 49.20%
November 1982 47.19% 27.91% 19.28%
March 1991 39.63% 15.97% 23.67%
November 2001 4.75% 15.11% 10.36%
June 2009 23.47% 14.43% 9.04%
Table 5 below shows the behaviour of large cap and small caps over the recovery period, defined as
the twelve month period subsequent to an economic trough.8Small-caps provide substantially higher
returns than large caps over this time frame. The differential return to small caps is positive for all of
these recoveries, except for the June 1938 trough, for which small caps had a one-year holding period
return of 27%.
While small-caps generate relatively high returns in the year subsequent to a trough, in the year
prior to the peak (i.e., the year preceding the onset of the recession), small-caps often lagged, as is
shown in Table 6. While the average small-cap premium was positive (1.77%) for all NBER recessions
from 1926 to 2007, in eight out of the fourteen cases for which the data are available, the annual
small-cap premium is negative over the year prior to the onset of the recession.
8The Ibbotson small cap premium is defined as the geometric difference between the small-cap total returns and the S&P
500 which proxies as the large cap portfolio.
340 L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346
Table 6
The Performance Small Cap Stocks vs. Large Cap Stocks Portfolios and the small cap premium in the year prior to the onset of
the recession. This table shows the one year holding period returns for the Ibbotson/DFA small cap portfolio and the large cap
portfolio (S&P 500) from the month prior to an NBER designated economic peak (signalling the onset of the recession).
Small Cap Index Large Cap Index Small stock premium
August 1929 15.28% 54.33% 39.05%
May 1937 46.26% 24.82% 21.45%
February 1945 51.44% 19.60% 31.84%
November 1948 9.74% 13.43% 3.70%
July 1953 4.31% 2.30% 2.01%
August 1957 3.31% 0.75% 2.56%
April 1960 0.60% 3.11% 2.50%
December 1969 19.02% 10.60% 8.42%
November 1973 10.77% 0.01% 10.78%
January 1980 43.46% 18.44% 25.02%
July 1981 69.67% 20.47% 49.20%
July 1990 1.17% 16.40% 17.57%
March 2001 22.09% 8.20% 13.89%
December 2007 3.64% 7.72% 11.36%
4.2. Business cycle turning points and other risk determinants of the small cap premium
How does the small-cap premium behave over the business cycle? Kim and Burnie (2002) assert
that the small firm effect is only observed during business cycle expansions, and not contractions.
However, they do not directly account for differential risk exposures that firms may face that have been
postulated to be significant factors affecting the returns to firms (e.g., Chen, Roll, & Ross (1986); Ferson
& Harvey, 1991) and that may work apart from the state of the business cycle per se in affecting the
return differential between large cap and small cap firms. This paper looks at three such risk exposures:
default risk (DEF), term structure risk (TERM), and inflation risk (INFLATION). Default risk or the bond
default premium, again measured by the long term corporate to government yield spreads (DEF).
A positive default risk premium is consistent with investors’ desire to hedge against unanticipated
increases in the aggregate risk premium induced by an increase in uncertainty in the economy (Ferson
& Harvey, 1991). In Fama and French (1995), the small firm premium is a proxy for a default risk state
variable. Vassalou and Xing (2004) show that default risk does affect the Fama and French (1995) size
and book to market factors. Beck and Demirguc-Kunt (2006) assert that small and medium size firms
are more exposed to default risk due to their lack of capital and liquidity compared to large firms.
Term structure risk is also included as a possible determinant of the small cap premium. A rising
term reflects an increase in riskiness of longer term assets, which may be require a separate premium
for small caps firms to the extent that they are more exposed to leverage risk than large cap firms.
Inflation risk has been attributed as a significant factor in adversely affecting stock returns, and in
the asset allocation (e.g., Bekaert, 2009; Boudoukh & Richardson, 1993; Fama, 1981; Katzur & Spierdijk,
2010). To the extent that small firms operate in more competitive environments, they may have less
pricing power than larger firms, and hence may be more exposed to inflation risk, and hence command
an inflation premium relative to larger firms.
Table 7 reports the results of regression tests for the period 1926–2010 of the model:
SMLt=˛0+˛1DEFt+˛2TERMt+˛3INFLATIONt+
15
i=1
ıiDUMit +εt(1)
where SML is the small cap premium, DEF is default risk (bond default premium), TERM is term
structure (bond horizon risk), INFLATION is the monthly inflation rate (consumer price index), RECiis a
dummy variable for the recession episode i,i= 1, 15, RECiis a dummy variable for the recession episode
i,i= 1, 15: REC1 1926–1927 Recession; REC2 1929–1933 Recession; REC3 1937–1938 Recession; REC4
1945 Recession; REC5 1948–1949 Recession; REC6 1953–1954 Recession; REC7 1957–1958 Recession;
REC8 1960–1961 Recession; REC9 1969–1970 Recession; REC10 1973–1975 Recession; REC11 1980
L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346 341
Table 7
Determinants of the US Small Cap Premium. This table reports the results of regression tests using monthly data for the period
January 1926–August 2010 of the model:.
(1)SMLt=˛0+˛1DEFt+˛2TERMt+˛3INFLATIONt+
15
i=1
ıiDUMit +εt
where SML is the Ibbotson/DFA small cap premium, DEF is default risk (bond default premium), TERM is term
structure (bond horizon risk), INFLATION is the US monthly inflation rate (consumer price index), RECiis a dummy
variable for the months corresponding to recession episode i,i= 1, 15: REC1 1926–1927 Recession; REC2 1929–1933
Recession; REC3 1937–1938 Recession; REC4 1945 Recession; REC5 1948–1949 Recession; REC6 1953–1954
Recession; REC7 1957–1958 Recession; REC8 1960–1961 Recession; REC9 1969–1970 Recession; REC10 1973–1975
Recession; REC11 1980 Recession; REC12 1981–1982 Recession; REC13 1990–1991 Recession; REC14 2001 Recession;
REC15 2007–2009 Recession; εtis a random error term. The recessions are defined according to NBER reference dates.
Independent variable Estimated coefficient t-Statistic p-Value
Constant 0.0004 0.1880 0.8509
FTA 0.0027 0.3934 0.6941
MJDS 0.0025 0.3375 0.7358
DEF 0.2216 1.8147 0.0699
TERM 0.0130 0.1916 0.8481
INFLDIFF 0.6364 2.5525 0.0108
REC1 0.0041 0.3348 0.7378
REC2 0.0062 0.8814 0.3783
REC3 0.0069 0.5667 0.5710
REC4 0.0041 0.2690 0.7880
REC5 0.0005 0.0402 0.9679
REC6 0.0195 1.4295 0.1532
REC7 0.0166 1.1019 0.2708
REC8 0.0042 0.3054 0.7601
REC9 0.0049 0.3716 0.7103
REC10 0.0044 0.3973 0.6912
REC11 0.0154 0.9052 0.3656
REC12 0.0162 1.4605 0.1445
REC13 0.0005 0.0284 0.9774
REC14 0.0052 0.3383 0.7352
REC15 0.0055 0.5151 0.6066
F-stat 2.1136 0.0043
Obs. 1008
Wald test for rec. dummies Value p-Value
F-statistic 1.0185 0.4318
Chi-squared 14.259 0.4306
Recession; REC12 1981–1982 Recession; REC13 1990–1991 Recession; REC14 2001 Recession; REC15
2007–2009 and εiis a random error term.
Based on regression tests, the small cap premium is significantly related to default risk in the econ-
omy, consistent with Vassalou and Xing (2004). While the term structure and inflation coefficients are
positive, they are not significant indicating that interest rate risk and inflation risk do not differentially
affect small cap vs. large cap firms. Do recessions per se affect the small firm return premium? The
regression results indicate that this is not the case. Note from Table 7 that the coefficients for the
recession variables are significant in only two cases: the recessions of 1937–1938, and 1969–1970
respectively. As reported in Table 7, the Wald test results that the recession coefficients are jointly
equal to zero cannot be rejected.
4.3. Effects of NBER announcements of business cycle peaks and troughs across firm size
Is the market efficient across alternative size portfolios for NBER peak and trough announce-
ments? To address this question, an event study is performed using the event date specified as the
NBER peak or trough announcement. Compustat Research Insight is used to form portfolios of com-
342 L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346
panies listed on different indices NASDAQ, AMEX, NYSE, and TSX (for Canada) by market value as
follows:
US stocks:
Micro-cap: less than $300 million
Small-cap: between $300 million and $2 billion
Middle-cap: between $2 billion and $10 billion
Large-cap: greater than $10 billion
Canadian stocks:
Micro-cap: less than $100 million
Small-cap9: between $100 million and $1.5 billion
Middle-cap: between $1.5 billion and $10 billion
Large-cap: greater than $10 billion
Utilities and financial sector companies are excluded from the analysis. Value-weighted portfolios
are formed using randomly selected 20 stocks in each category for US and 10 stock portfolios for
Canada. US company data are from CRSP, while the Canadian portfolio data are from the TSX. Daily
return data are obtained for a 180 day estimation window and a 60 day event window surrounding the
announcement date. The analyses are conducted for the July 1990 and March 2001 recessions using the
market model approach, with the CRSP value weighted index serving as the market portfolio. To the
extent that the markets are semi-strong efficient, the null hypothesis is that abnormal returns should
be zero for trough announcements. Since the announcements reveal public information that pertains
to an event that occurred in the past, they should not affect stock market performance. The alternative
hypothesis is that market participants do not have sufficient data to confirm an economic recovery,
and as such an NBER announcement regarding the arrival of a trough date will be interpreted as good
news. Similarly, with semi-strong efficiency, an announcement of a business cycle peak should not
be associated with abnormal returns. On the other hand, peak announcements, might be deemed as
unexpected bad news. Hence, such announcements could give rise to significantly negative abnormal
returns.
The results of the event studies can be summarized as follows.10 Trough announcements do elicit
significantly positive abnormal returns for small-cap, mid-cap and large cap US stocks over the event
day (direct effect) and in most cases over longer event windows across most size-based categories.
This is consistent with the view that an economic recovery is fraught with uncertainty, and the
NBER’s trough announcements provide welcome resolution of this uncertainty. On the other hand,
the announcement of a business cycle peaks is viewed as a significantly negative event.
How do Canadian stocks respond to these US announcements? On the whole, not to any signifi-
cant degree. For all size categories (micro cap, small cap, as well as mid and large cap stocks) across
announcements of US peaks and troughs, there is little evidence of abnormal returns around the NBER
announcement dates. This may reflect differential exposures to business cycle risk between coun-
tries, in part due to the differential industry composition of the markets, with Canadian markets more
heavily exposed to the resource sector relative to the US market.11
5. The US vs. Canadian stock premium as a large country vs. small country variant of the
small cap anomaly
Does the Canada–US equity premium behave in a similar manner to the US small-cap premium? One
might conjecture that there should be some similarities, given the significantly smaller capitalization of
the Canadian market relative to the American market. Indeed as of January 2010, the average listing on
the TMX Group has a market capitalization of a conventionally defined small cap firm, at $889 billion;
9The S&P/TSX Small-Cap Index size criteria are used for eligibility in this group.
10 Detailed tables are omitted in order to preserve space. They are available on request.
11 Cross (2009) states that “Recessions in the United States have been accompanied by a wide range of outcomes in Canada.”
For example, while the US economy contracted significantly during 1974–1975 and 1981–1982, Canada experienced a mild
and a severe recession respectively. In contrast, the mild downturns in the US in 1990–1991 and 2001 were accompanied in
Canada by a severe recession in the former case and no recession in the latter.
L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346 343
Table 8
Annual holding period returns for US and Canadian equity markets, January 1900–August 2010. This table shows annual holding
period returns for the US equity market, represented by the Dow Jones Industrial Average Adjusted Index and the Canadian
market index translated into US dollars which combines the S&P/TSX Index with the Switzer Canadian Century Index, as reported
in Dimson et al. (2002).
Canadian Index US Index Canadian–US Premium
1900–1925 3.11% 3.37% 0.26%
1926–1950 2.15% 1.62% 0.53%
1951–1975 4.38% 5.05% 0.67%
1976–2000 2.76% 5.39% 2.63%
2001–2010 6.83% .78% 7.61%
1900–2010 4.61% 4.65% .04%
Table 9
The performance of Canadian stocks vs. US stocks over twelve months commencing with the onset of the recession. This table
shows the one year holding period returns from the month corresponding to an NBER designated economic peak, signalling the
onset of a recession. The US Index is the Dow Jones Industrial Average Adjusted Index; The Canadian Index is translated into
US dollars, and combines the S&P/TSX Index with the Switzer Canadian Century Index, as reported in Dimson et al. (2002).
Canadian Index US Index Canada–US
September 1902 17.80% 30.76% 48.56%
May 1907 11.71% 6.84% 4.87%
January 1910 6.35% 7.59% 13.94%
January 1913 12.76% 1.10% 11.66%
August 1918 10.84% 17.75% 28.59%
January 1920 9.36% 26.95% 17.59%
May 1923 1.67% 7.82% 6.15%
October 1926 33.81% 20.54% 13.27%
August 1929 39.60% 36.79% 2.81%
May 1937 24.61% 38.33% 13.72%
February 1945 31.30% 18.51% 12.79%
November 1948 0.22% 11.89% 11.67%
July 1953 13.48% 26.34% 12.86%
August 1957 2.05% 5.01% 7.06%
April 1960 23.11% 12.80% 10.31%
December 1969 1.42% 4.82% 6.24%
November 1973 27.17% 24.76% 2.41%
January 1980 6.53% 8.15% 1.62%
July 1981 38.39% 15.09% 53.48%
July 1990 0.52% 4.11% 4.63%
March 2001 1.94% 5.32% 3.38%
December 2007 46.94% 33.84% 13.10%
in contrast, the average market capitalization of NYSE companies is over $4 billion. However, since
the comparison is cross-border, aside from default risk and term structure risk, the potential effects of
inflation differentials between countries is also examined. The long period returns for Canadian stocks
and US stocks are fairly similar. As is shown in Table 8, over the period January 1900 through August
2010, the differential return between Canada and the US amounts to only .04% per year.12
However, Canada and the US experience dissimilar responses to NBER business cycle turning points.
In many cases, the Canadian dollar depreciates in a significant manner relative to its US counterpart at
the onset of recessions. The impact of currency changes is material insofar as it affects the results. For
example, when exchange rate is fixed (or exchange risk is hedged completely), the Canadian market
performed worse than the US market over the one year period after the onset of US recessions in only
five of the fifteen NBER recessions since 1926. In Table 9 the results for an unhedged investor are
shown, with the returns translated into Canadian dollars, this number increases to eleven.
344 L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346
Table 10
The performance of Canadian stocks vs. US stocks over twelve months commencing with the end of the recession. This table
shows the one year holding period returns from the month corresponding to an NBER designated economic trough, signalling
the end of a recession. The US Index is the Dow Jones Industrial Average Adjusted Index; The Canadian Index combines the
S&P/TSX Index with the Switzer Canadian Century Index, as reported in Dimson et al. (2002).
Canadian Index US Index Canadian–US Index
December 1900 6.86% 8.79% 15.65%
August 1904 18.73% 47.76% 29.03%
June 1908 14.88% 27.12% 12.24%
January 1912 6.43% 4.40% 2.03%
December 1914 19.55% 81.66% 62.11%
March 1919 7.91% 15.71% 7.80%
July 1921 15.04% 41.95% 26.91%
July 1924 14.35% 31.00% 16.65%
November 1927 32.03% 48.01% 15.98%
March 1933 79.65% 81.06% 1.41%
June 1938 2.93% 2.42% 0.51%
October 1945 2.31% 9.35% 7.04%
October 1949 27.33% 18.71% 8.62%
May 1954 23.66% 29.73% 6.07%
April 1958 25.08% 36.83% 11.75%
February 1961 8.74% 6.94% 1.80%
November 1970 2.47% 4.69% 7.16%
March 1975 8.57% 30.11% 21.54%
July 1980 3.51% 1.82% 5.33%
November 1982 38.00% 22.78% 15.22%
March 1991 4.95% 11.04% 15.99%
November 2001 11.06% 9.70% 1.36%
June 2009 18.00% 15.71% 2.29%
Table 10 shows that both indices tend to deliver high returns in the one year period after the end
of US recessions, but there is some variation in the relative performance across recessions.
To what extent does the Canada–US equity premium depend on the US business cycle apart from
other, potentially independent risk factors?
To address this issue, the regression model (1) for the small-cap premium is augmented to include
changes in the regulatory environment that could enhance the integration of the markets, which
would narrow the Canada–US equity premium. Such institutional changes could enhance the inte-
gration of the markets, which would narrow the Canada–US equity premium.13 These include the
implementation of the Canada–US Free Trade Accord (FTA), which was ratified in October 1987.14
In addition, it overlaps with the introduction of the Multi-Jurisdictional Disclosure System (MJDS) in
July 1991, which relaxed the financial reporting requirements for Canadian companies listing in the
United States, the amendments to MJDS in July 1993, as well as changes in disclosure requirements
for Canadian companies listed on the domestic market mandated by Canadian securities regulators in
October 1993 (see Doukas & Switzer, 2000). The model estimated is:
CANPREMt=ˇ0+ˇ1FTAt+ˇ2MJDSt+ˇ3DEFt+ˇ4TERMt+ˇ5INFLDIFFt+
15
i=1
ıiDUMit +t
(2)
where CANPREM is the Canada–US equity premium (Canadian market return – Dow Jones Industrial
Average Return); FTA is a dummy variable =1 after the finalizing of the Canada–US Free Trade Accord
in October 1987 and 0 otherwise; MJDS is a dummy variable = 1 after the introduction of Multi Juris-
dictional Disclosure System (MJDS) in July 1991 and 0 otherwise; INFLDIFF is the difference between
12 Note <fn0055>however that more recently (from 2001 to 2010) Canadian markets have outperformed their US market by
774 basis points per year.
13 He and Kryzanowski (2007) assume that the US and Canadian equity markets are integrated.
14 Martínez-Zarzosoa, Nowak-Lehmann, & Horsewood (2009) show that NAFTA had beneficial trade creation effects.
L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346 345
Table 11
Determinants of the Canada–US equity premium.
This table reports the results of regression tests using monthly data for the period January 1926-August 2010 of the
model:
(2)CANPREMt=ˇ0+ˇ1FTAt+ˇ2MJDSt+ˇ3DEFt+ˇ4TERMt+ˇ5INFLDIFFt+
15
i=1
ıiDUMit +t
where CANPREM is the Canada–US equity premium (Canadian market return – Dow Jones Industrial Average Return);
FTA is a dummy variable =1 after the finalizing of the Canada–US Free Trade Accord in October 1987 and 0 otherwise;
MJDS is a dummy variable =1 after the introduction of Multi Jurisdictional Disclosure System (MJDS) in July 1991 and
0 otherwise; INFLDIFF is the difference between the Canadian and US monthly inflation rate (consumer price index),
RECiis a dummy variable for the recession episode i,i= 1, 15, REC1 1926–1927 Recession; REC2 1929–1933 Recession;
REC3 1937–1938 Recession; REC4 1945 Recession; REC5 1948–1949 Recession; REC6 1953–1954 Recession;REC7
1957–1958 Recession; REC8 1960–1961 Recession; REC9 1969–1970 Recession;REC10 1973–1975 Recession; REC11
1980 Recession; REC12 1981–1982 Recession; REC13 1990–1991 Recession; REC14 2001 Recession; REC15 2007
Recession; tis a random error term. The recessions are defined according to NBER reference dates.
Constant 0.0004 0.1880 0.8509
FTA 0.0027 0.3934 0.6941
MJDS 0.0025 0.3375 0.7358
DEF 0.2216 1.8147 0.0699
TERM 0.0130 0.1916 0.8481
INFLDIFF 0.6364 2.5525 0.0108
REC1 0.0041 0.3348 0.7378
REC2 0.0062 0.8814 0.3783
REC3 0.0069 0.5667 0.5710
REC4 0.0041 0.2690 0.7880
REC5 0.0005 0.0402 0.9679
REC6 0.0195 1.4295 0.1532
REC7 0.0166 1.1019 0.2708
REC8 0.0042 0.3054 0.7601
REC9 0.0049 0.3716 0.7103
REC10 0.0044 0.3973 0.6912
REC11 0.0154 0.9052 0.3656
REC12 0.0162 1.4605 0.1445
REC13 0.0005 0.0284 0.9774
REC14 0.0052 0.3383 0.7352
REC15 0.0055 0.5151 0.6066
Wald Test for Recession Dummies
Value df p-Value
F-statistic .5581 (15.988) 0.9071
Chi-squared 8.3719 150.9080
the Canadian and US monthly inflation rate (consumer price index), RECiis a dummy variable for the
recession episode i,i= 1, 15 as in the previous section.
Table 11 presents empirical estimates of Eq. (2). Similar to the US small cap premium regression,
a significant business default risk component is observed in the Canada–US equity premium, while
the Wald test rejects the joint significance of the recession dummy variables. However, a significant
inflation risk component is also observed: higher inflation in Canada relative to the US serves to reduce
the returns to Canadian equities relative to their US counterparts. This result is consistent with Fama
(1981),Boudoukh and Richardson (1993),Bekaert (2009), and Katzur and Spierdijk (2010). Neither
the FTA nor the MJDS are found to be significantly related to the Canada–US equity premium. This
suggests that the relaxation of barriers of goods and capital flows has not enhanced the integration of
the markets.
6. Conclusion
This paper takes a new look at the small cap premium in Canada and the US. In contrast to various
studies pronounce an end to the small cap performance anomaly, the study shows that since 2000,
346 L.N. Switzer / North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21 (2010) 332–346
economically and statistically significant abnormal performance is observed for small cap stocks in
the US and Canada. The US small cap anomaly in recent years is focused on small cap value stocks. In
previous decades where the small-cap anomaly is most pronounced, the anomaly is found for both
small cap value as well as small cap growth stocks.
Differential performance for size based asset portfolios is found to be associated with risk factors
that are distinct from business cycle turning points per se. The factors that drive differential perfor-
mance across asset size classes should be of interest for future research looking at the benefits from
time-varying asset allocation strategies (see e.g., Arshanapalli et al., 2007).
References
Arshanapalli, B. G., Switzer, L. N., & Panju, K. (2007). Equity-style timing: A multi-style rotation model for the Russell large-cap
and small-cap growth and value style indexes. Journal of Asset Management,8, 9–23.
Atta-Mensah, J. & Tkacz, G. (1998). Predicting Canadian Recessions Using Financial Variables: A Probit Approach, Working Paper
98-5, Bank of Canada.
Banz, R. W. (1981). The relationship between return and market value of common stocks. Journal of Financial Economics,9, 3–18.
Beck, T., & Demirguc-Kunt, A. (2006). Small and medium-size enterprises: Access to finance as a growth constraint. Journal of
Banking and Finance,30, 2931–2943.
Bekaert, G. (2009). Inflation risk and the inflation risk premium. Netspar NEA Paper 21.
Bhardwaj, R., & Brooks, L. (1993). Dual betas from bull and bear markets: Reversal of the size effect. Journal of Financial Research,
16, 269–283.
Boudoukh, J., & Richardson, M. (1993). Stock returns and inflation: A long-horizon perspective. American Economic Review,83,
1346–1355.
Chan, K., & Chen, N. (1991). An unconditional asset-pricing test and the role of firm size as an instrumental variable for risk.
Journal of Finance,43, 309–325.
Chen, N. F., Roll, R., & Ross, S. (1986). Economic forces and the stock market. Journal of Business,59, 383–403.
Cross, P. (2009). The impact of recessions in the United States on Canada. Canadian Economic Observer,22(3). Available at
http://www.statcan.gc.ca
Dimson, E., & Marsh, P. (1999). Murphy’s law and market anomalies. Journal of Portfolio Management,25(2), 53–69.
Dimson, E., Marsh, P., & Staunton, M. (2002). Triumph of the optimists: 101 years of global investment returns. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Doukas, J., & Switzer, L. N. (2000). Common stock returns and international interlisting: Conditional tests of the mild segmen-
tation hypothesis. Journal of Banking and Finance,24, 471–502.
Estrella, A., & Mishkin, F. S. (1996). The yield curve as a predictor of US recessions. Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Federal
Reserve Bank of New York,2(7).
Estrella, A., & Mishkin, F. S. (1998). Predicting US recessions: Financial variables as leading indicators. Review of Economics and
Statistics,80(1), 45–61.
Fama, E. F. (1981). Stock returns, real activity, inflation, and money. American Economic Review,4, 545–565.
Fama, E. F., & French, K. (1995). Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal of Finance,50, 131–155.
Ferson, W., & Harvey, C. (1991). Sources of predictability in portfolio returns. Financial Analysts Journal,47(3), 49–56.
Hawawini, G., & Keim, D. (1999). The cross-section of common stock returns: A synthesis of the evidence and explanations. In
D. Keim, & W. Ziemba (Eds.), Security market imperfections in world wide equity markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
He, Z., & Kryzanowski, L. (2007). Cost of equity for Canadian and US sectors. North American Journal of Economics and Finance,
18(2007), 215–229.
Horowitz, J. L., Loughran, T., & Savin, N. E. (2000). Three analyses of the firm size premium. Journal of Empirical Finance,7,
143–153.
Jensen, M. C. (1968). The performance of mutual funds in the period 1954–64. Journal of Finance,23, 389–416.
Katzur, T. & Spierdijk, L. (2010) Stock Returns and Inflation Risk: Implications for Portfolio Selection, Working Paper, University
of Groningen.
Kim, M. K., & Burnie, D. A. (2002). The firm size effect and the economic cycle. Journal of Financial Research,25(1), 111–124.
Leamer, E.E. (2008). What’s a recession, anyway? NBER Working Paper No. W14221.
Martínez-Zarzosoa, I., Nowak-Lehmann, D., Felicitas, & Horsewood, N. (2009). Are regional trading agreements beneficial? Static
and dynamic panel gravity models. North American Journal of Economics and Finance,20, 46–65.
Reinganum, M. R. (1981). Abnormal returns in small firm portfolios. Financial Analyst Journal,37, 52–56.
Schwert, G. W. (2003). Anomalies and Schwert, G. William 2003. Anomalies and market efficiency. In G. M. Constantinides, M.
Harris, & R. M. Stulz (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of finance (pp. 939–974). Elsevier.
Siegel, J. (1998). Stocks for the long run (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw Hill.
Switzer, L. N., & Fan, H. (2007). Spanning tests for replicable small-cap indexes as separate asset classes: Evidence from G-7
countries. Journal of Portfolio Management,33(4), 102–110.
Switzer, L. N., & Tang, M. (2009). The impact of corporate governance on the performance of US small-cap firms. International
Journal of Business,14(4), 343–357.
Vassalou, M., & Xing, Y. (2004). Default risk in equity returns. Journal of Finance,59, 831–868.
... In addition, research by Hendra et al. (2017), Wijaya et al. (2017), and Zheng et al. (2020) found a positive effects of firm size on portfolio excess returns. Switzer (2012) revealed that differences in portfolio performance based on assets could be associated with different risk factors in the business cycle. The factor driving the differences in performance is the difference in interest in examining the benefits of asset allocation strategies that vary in time. ...
Article
Full-text available
This study aims to examine common risk factors' effects in the Fama and French Five-Factor Model plus Momentum Factor on The Bisnis-27 Index Stocks component during the 2016-2020 period. This research's common risk factors include market risk premium, firm size, book-to-market equity ratio, profitability, investment, and momentum. A quantitative approach will be used in this study by using multiple linear regression. The regression in this study was generated by the common effects model method. This study reveals that a portfolio's excess return is simultaneously affected by common risk factors that are in place this study. The findings in this study show that market risk premium, book-to-market ratio, company size, and momentum positively affect portfolios' excess returns. The greater the market risk premium, the smaller the size of the company, the larger the book-to-market ratio, and the stock's past performance, as reflected by the momentum, has implications for the acquisition of a larger excess return on the portfolio. Meanwhile, there is no significant influence between profitability and investment factor on portfolios' excess returns.
... The hypothesis is motivated by the empirical regularity that small-cap firms outperform (underperform) large-cap firms during periods of economic expansion (contraction). Only a few studies have looked at this issue to date (e.g., Chan et al., 1985;Switzer, 2010Switzer, , 2013. Figure 1 provides a graphical illustration of this phenomenon for the US experience since 1926. Comparable data are available for Canada since 1970 and are projected on Figure 2. In both cases, a downward trend in the small-cap premium can be seen at the onset of recessionary periods, including the most recent short Canadian recession, which lasted from November 2008 to May 2009, and the US Great Recession from May 2007 to June 2009, denoted as the shaded areas within the graphs. ...
Article
While the average annual small-cap premia for the US and Canada are substantial over long horizons, there is considerable time variation of this premium within and across these countries. For the US, during expansions, the average annualized premium is a sizable 5.44%, while during recessions, there is a small-cap discount of 6.23%. The differentials are less pronounced in Canada. This paper investigates the hypothesis that the variation of the small-cap premium is related to macroeconomic and financial variables that can be captured by a nonlinear time series econometric model, i.e., the smooth transition autoregressive model (STAR model), with different factor sets across regimes between and countries. The regimes reflect expansionary vs. contractionary phases of the business cycle. For the Canadian small-cap premium, an augmented factor model that includes US factors dominates a purely domestic factor model, which is consistent with integrated markets.
... Whereas Pefindo25 Index is an index comprised of Small and Medium Enterprises (SME) listed companies with at least five trillion rupiah assets, it used to represent the "behavior" of small and medium cap stocks. Anomaly indications need to be seen in different stock capitalization as market, especially risk lover investors, usually prefers to trade on second line stocks because these stocks often offer higher returns than large-cap stocks, but of course with a greater risk (Switzer, 2012). The second line stocks are often reported in the media as an first alternative when the movements of LQ45 stocks are stagnant (Prasetyo, 2016). ...
Article
p>The aim of this study is to determine whether the “Day-of-The-Week Anomaly” (DOWA) exists on different stock capitalization in Indonesian stock market. A total of 58 stocks listed in both LQ45 index and Pefindo25 index used to represent large cap stocks and small and medium cap stocks respectively. The Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) method and ARCH/GARCH model were employed to capture the DOWA and the daily volatility behavior for the period between January 2010 and December 2015. The result reveals that DOWA exist for a significant proportion of individual stocks in both LQ45 and Pefindo25. Monday was found to have the lowest mean returns while Wednesday has the highest mean return. The differences between Monday’s return and return of the other days ranged from 0.15 to 0.41 percent. LQ45 stocks also found to have slightly higher Wednesday’s volatility than of Pefindo25 stocks. It indicates that the higher return of the LQ45 is naturally accompanied by a higher risk. JEL Classification: G02, G10, G17 Keywords: Day-of-The-Week Anomaly, Indonesia, LQ45, Pefindo25, Stock Market</p
... Selain indeks LQ 45 indeks lain yang digunakan adalah indeks PEFINDO 25, indeks PEFINDO 25 merupakan indeks yang beranggotakan emiten-emiten yang tergolong Small and medium enterprises (SME) dengan minimal aset lima triliun rupiah. Indikasi anomali perlu dilihat pada indeks berkapitalisasi berbeda karena pasar, terutama investor-investor risk lover, lebih memilih untuk melakukan trading pada saham-saham lapis kedua karena kelompok saham ini menawarkan return yang lebih tinggi dari pada saham-saham berkapitalisasi besar, namun dengan risiko yang lebih besar pula (Switzer, 2012). Tidak ada definisi pasti mengenai saham-saham lapis kedua, namun secara umum investor merujuk saham lapis kedua sebagai saham-saham pilihan kedua terbaik setelah saham-saham blue chips seperti LQ 45. ...
Article
Full-text available
Investasi saham merupakan salah satu jenis investasi yang terkenal. Investor menginginkan pengembalian yang positif dari investasi yang dilakukannya, pada kenyataannya memperoleh keuntungan dalam investasi sangat sulit. Salah satu cara untuk mengurangi kerugian adalah dengan menggunakan index, pergerakan indeks yang berfluktuatif merupakan pengaruh dari faktor-faktor makroekonomi seperti BI rate, IHK, Kurs tukar Rupiah-Dollar AS, harga minyak Brent, dan Harga emas. Indeks-indeks yang sering digunakan oleh inestor adalah indeks LQ 45 dan Pefindo 25. Indeks LQ 45 yang digunakan sebagai indikator pada penelitian ini untuk menggambarkan “perilaku” saham-saham kapitalisasi besar dan indeks Pefindo 25 digunakan untuk mereprensentasikan perusahaan kecil dan menengah. Penelitian ini ditujukan untuk melihat mengaruh faktor makroekonomi pada return kedua indeks. Metode yang digunakan dalam penelitian ini adalah model Ordinary Least Square (OLS). Hasil yang diperoleh dalam penelitian ini menunjukan bahwa faktor makroekonomi BI rate, nilai tukar, harga emas, harga minyak memiliki pengaruh positif terhadap indeks LQ 45 kecuali nilai tukar yang memiliki pegaruh negatif terhadap Indeks. Indeks Pefindo 25 dipengaruhi oleh BI rate, IHK, dan harga minyak. Hasil ini menunjukan bila investor berinvestasi pada indeks LQ 45 lebih baik memperhatikan BI rate, harga emas, harga minyak, dan nilai kurs tukar sebagai dasar pengambilan keputusab investasi yang dilakukannya. Pada indeks Pefindo 25 investor sebaiknya memperhatikan BI rate, IHK dan harga minyak sebagai dasar pengambilan keputusan investasi. Kata kunci: indeks, LQ 45, makroekonomi, Pefindo 25, IHK
... The large firms have more competitive advantage in the form of bigger market share, and opportunity to grab bulk purchases offers or project which require higher capital rates, opportunity to earn more profit than smaller one (Bayyurt 2007).On the other hand, smaller firms attract less attention from analysts and investors than larger one hence there remains less scope for mislead information as a result small firms earn higher stock return compared to big firms Banz (1981);(Collins 1990); Fama & French (1992); Berk (1997). However, small firm's stock performance is more risky than larger firms as investors expected higher return on their investment (Switzer 2012). Hall and Weises (1967)found in their study that the existence of significant positive relationship between firm size and profitability.In the same vein, study attempted by Fiegenbaum & Karnani (1991) The main purpose of this paper is to examine the existing literature on the relations between profitability and stock return into Indian firms quoted in National Stock Exchange (NSE). ...
Article
Full-text available
This study shows that the presence of valuable patents can be a key indicator of a company's survival rate. Smaller companies in particular had a higher chance of default than larger companies, but companies with high-quality patent portfolios had a much lower risk. Companies with a significant patent portfolio value of at least 8 million USD had a significantly lower risk of default - in particular the small ones. This could potentially lead to the creation of a low-risk fixed income product based on the monitoring of the value of a company's patent portfolio.
Article
This study provides new evidence on the interaction between firm size and IPO underpricing in the US and Canadian markets. We find a size effect on IPO underpricing in both Canada and the US, which is larger for Canadian firms. Canadian small firms show more underpricing than US small firms (19.32% vs. 13.87%). Large Canadian firms also exhibit more underpricing than their US counterparts over the sample period (12.83% vs. 10.09%). A size effect on performance is not apparent for holding periods beyond six months from the IPO in both countries, consistent with seasoning effects that reduce information asymmetries across firms over longer investment horizons.
Article
Full-text available
Given the crucial role played by banks in a developing country like Tunisia, it is important to maintain their stability. The purpose of this article is twofold. First, it studies the effect of banking governance on credit risk. Second, it tests the relationship between bank governance mechanisms and liquidity risk. In this article, we have combined literature regarding two areas of governance, first, ownership structure and board characteristics, and second, their impact on banking risks. To achieve this goal, we used a sample of 10 Tunisian banks observed during the period 1998-2015. The econometric approach used in this study is based on both the fixed and random effects models of panel data analysis. Our results show that credit risk and liquidity risk are directly related to bank governance mechanisms. These findings enable bank managers to better understand the factors influencing bank risk and serve as a basis for regulations to strengthen bank governance.
Article
Full-text available
The aim of this paper is twofold. Firstly, it investigates the effect of bank governance on bank risk measured by the standard deviation of the return on assets (SDROA). Secondly, it tests the relationship between bank governance mechanisms and bank insolvency proxied by the Zscore (ROA). To achieve this goal, we used a sample of 11 Tunisian banks observed during the period 2006-2015. These 11 banks are considered as the most dynamic banks in the Tunisian banking system. The econometric approach used in this study is based on panel data analysis especially fixed and random effect models. Empirical results indicate that the presence of Supervisory Committee and monitoring of risks (COR), the executive compensation (REMB) and the board size (BDSIZE) increases significantly Tunisian bank risk and insolvency. However, the presence of independent directors (INDD) and the proportion of institutional investors decrease bank risk and bank insolvency. With regard to the effect on macroeconomic condition, only inflation rate exerts a significant effect. However, this effect is negative when the dependent variable is SDROA and positive for Z-score. The effect of GDPG is not significant for both bank risk and bank stability.
Article
Full-text available
Traditional and step-down spanning tests are used to assess the behavior of replicable G7 and Asian country small cap indexes as separate asset classes of efficient portfolios for U.S. investors. Empirical tests on different index combinations show that the composition of a benchmark portfolio determines whether or not a small cap index could enlarge the original efficient frontier. The interaction among all assets in a portfolio is the key to the effectiveness and efficiency of a small cap index in efficient portfolios and constraints do not always reduce diversification benefits of the small-cap assets. Most small cap indexes of G 7 countries are separate asset classes to the portfolios consisting of the popular benchmark indexes in G 7 markets in our sample period.
Article
Full-text available
Researchers and practitioners have devoted considerable attention to devising market-timing strategies as potential value-enhancement tools. The success of such active or tactical asset allocation strategies is dependent on their ability to capture either inefficiencies, to the extent that they exist, or disequilibria associated with changes in the investor opportunity set. Much of the equity-style timing literature focuses on the shifting between pairs of risky assets or between one risky and one riskless asset class, using a binomial approach. This paper develops a multinomial timing model based on macroeconomic and fundamental public information using Frank Russell large-cap and small-cap style indexes. We model four different market segments simultaneously. Out-of-sample tests demonstrate that active multi-style rotation strategies can be devised that outperform the best performing buy-and-hold portfolio. The profitability of such strategies is robust to reasonable levels of transaction costs.
Article
"This article starts by discussing the concept of 'inflation hedging' and provides estimates of 'inflation betas' for standard bond and well-diversified equity indices for over 45 countries. We show that such standard securities are poor inflation hedges. Expanding the menu of assets to Treasury bills, foreign bonds, real estate and gold improves matters but inflation risk remains difficult to hedge. We then describe how state-of-the-art term structure research has tried to uncover estimates of the inflation risk premium, the compensation for bearing inflation risk. Most studies, including very recent ones that actually use inflation-linked bonds and information in surveys to gauge inflation expectations, find the inflation risk premium to be sizeable and to substantially vary through time. This implies that governments should normally lower their financing costs through the issuance of index-linked bonds, at least in an ex ante sense. Our findings thus indicate a potentially important role for inflation index linked bonds. We briefly discuss the pros and cons of such bonds, focusing the discussion mostly on the situation in the United States, which started to issue Treasury Inflation Protected Securities (TIPS) in 1997. We argue that it is hard to negate the benefits of such securities for all relevant parties, unless the market in which they trade is highly deficient, which was actually the case in its early years in the United States." Copyright (c) CEPR, CES, MSH, 2010.
Article
We study whether the behavior of stock prices, in relation to size and book-to-market-equity (BE/ME), reflects the behavior of earnings. Consistent with rational pricing, high BE/ME signals persistent poor earnings and low BE/ME signals strong earnings. Moreover, stock prices forecast the reversion of earnings growth observed after firms are ranked on size and BE/ME. Finally, there are market, size, and BE/ME factors in earnings like those in returns. The market and size factors in earnings help explain those in returns, but we find no link between BE/ME factors in earnings and returns.
Article
Investors have too often extrapolated from recent experience. In the 1950s, who but the most rampant optimist would have dreamt that over the next fifty years the real return on equities would be 9% per year? Yet this is what happened in the U.S. stock market. The optimists triumphed. However, as Don Marquis observed, an optimist is someone who never had much experience. The authors of this book extend our experience across regions and across time. They present a comprehensive and consistent analysis of investment returns for equities, bonds, bills, currencies and inflation, spanning sixteen countries, from the end of the nineteenth century to the beginning of the twenty-first. This is achieved in a clear and simple way, with over 130 color diagrams that make comparison easy. Crucially, the authors analyze total returns, including reinvested income. They show that some historical indexes overstate long-term performance because they are contaminated by survivorship bias and that long-term stock returns are in most countries seriously overestimated, due to a focus on periods that with hindsight are known to have been successful. The book also provides the first comprehensive evidence on the long-term equity risk premium--the reward for bearing the risk of common stocks. The authors reveal whether the United States and United Kingdom have had unusually high stock market returns compared to other countries. The book covers the U.S., the U.K., Japan, France, Germany, Canada, Italy, Spain, Switzerland, Australia, the Netherlands, Sweden, Belgium, Ireland, Denmark, and South Africa. Triumph of the Optimists is required reading for investment professionals, financial economists, and investors. It will be the definitive reference in the field and consulted for years to come. © 2002 Elroy Dimson, Paul Marsh, and Mike Staunton. All rights reserved.
Article
Despite the random walk hypothesis, which asserts that asset returns should be completely unpredictable, it is well known that returns are predictable to some extent. Does this predictability reflect inefficiencies such as market fads, or is it more systematic? A multi-beta asset pricing model using risk factors related to the stock market, unexpected inflation, consumer expenditures and interest rates indicates that most of the predictable variation in asset returns can be explained by shifts in the assets' risk exposures (betas) and by shifts in the market's compensations for holding these exposures (risk premiums). Little variation remains to be explained by market inefficiency. Both betas and risk premiums change predictably over time, although changes in risk premiums are far more important than changes in betas, at least at the portfolio level. The evidence suggests that investors rationally update their assessments of expected return. It also suggests that the relative contributions of different risk factors to predictable return will differ across assets.