Content uploaded by Riel Miller
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Riel Miller on Nov 30, 2015
Content may be subject to copyright.
The future of the global economy: towards a long boom?
Riel Miller
International Futures Programme
The world stands on the threshold of a tantalising opportunity – the possibility of a sustained long boom over the first decades of the next millennium. It
is an opportunity we should not miss.
Long booms are exceptional events. There have been relatively few in the history of human economic development. Two rapid growth periods of the
last 130 years - one in the latter decades of the 19th century and the other in the period after the Second World War - made major contributions to
lifting the long-run historical average to a higher level.
The anatomy of previous long booms reveals two basic characteristics. The first is that a boom's above-average pace of development tends to be part
of a longer, century-spanning flow. This is a distinct phenomenon not to be confused with shorter business cycles that fluctuate up and down around
the historical trend.
The second feature of a long boom is the coincidence of diverse forces which work together in a specific historical conjuncture. Most recently, this
occurred during the 1950s when the post-war reconstruction boom coalesced around the diffusion and development of innovative technologies,
advanced methods of mass-production as well as new economic and institutional frameworks. Such a constellation of forces helps to spark and
sustain the unusually fast rates of socio-economic change and productivity growth that characterise a long boom.
Harmony and dissonance
Not necessarily. Certainly, strong growth in investment, in the capabilities of the labour force and in trade are crucial for very long periods of sustained
economic development. But the dynamic element that drives change forward is the systemic chemistry that either catalyses the process or stifles it.
History has cast the role of system functionality or dysfunctionality into stark relief. The dire consequences of systems failure are evident, for instance,
in the demise of Soviet command planning or the post-1970s "debt crisis" which plunged many countries into even deeper poverty. On the other hand,
system functionality normally brings immense benefits. This can be seen in the convergence of income levels between North America, Europe and
Japan, and the impressive economic take-off of many Asian countries over the last two to three decades.
What are the ingredients of a functional system that allows it to militate against stagnation and maintain its capacity to change over time? The
answers can be grouped into three areas. First, there are the aspirations and imperatives that emerge when democracy and a competitive market
place are allowed to develop together. Second, there is the capacity to innovate and adapt that can flourish only when there is pluralism, transparency
and openness. And third, there is a whole range of cultural values, such as a respect for both civil liberties and social obligations, which underpin the
constant search for ways of balancing co-operation with competition, security with risk taking.
Of course, systems that are hierarchical, closed and intolerant are capable of short bursts of development, even over several years. This is particularly
so if the technological, organisational and social structures are imposed from above, for example, during wartime, or during a period of forced
industrialisation. But, as the record this century shows, these are not dynamic systems capable of sustaining long-run economic development.
The fact that some systems fail does not mean that all systems must be the same or that functionality can be assured by clinging to what worked in
the past. The ways of sustaining long-run economic dynamism change over time. The 19th century's rather narrowly defined democracies and trading
institutions offered tremendous scope in that era. The same can be said of the organisations of mass production, mass consumption and mass
government that have dominated the 20th century. However, these institutional and organisational forms are hardly adequate to the conditions and
tasks of the 21st century, when meeting a growing diversity of demand will mean encouraging an ever greater diversity of supply. That, in turn,
depends on more initiative, customisation and a further relaxing of centralised controls.
Sustaining the prevailing tide of long-run economic dynamism is a necessary, but not sufficient, condition for sparking a long boom. A confluence of
specific technological, economic and social factors will have to fall into place to push the global rate of per capita income growth into the 3% and
above range of a long boom. To reach this target over the next few decades, sufficient progress will have to be made in three critical areas: the
knowledge society; integration of global markets; and environmental sustainability.
Regarding the first set of forces, the transition to a knowledge economy and society, there is a close parallel to the powerful growth-inducing impact of
this century's development of mass production, mass consumption and mass government. In the 21st century, a shift to an economy dominated by the
production and consumption of intangibles, such as the trade in know-how and ideas, could spur the above-average growth rates of a long boom.
The more difficult question is whether or not this catalyst will be sufficiently strong both to drive change forward in as rapid and diffuse a manner as
possible and to overcome any constraints on the way. Just the prospect of laboratory breakthroughs and product innovations offers no assurance of
wide diffusion of new technologies nor the equally important reorganisation of the ways in which people work and live.
Momentum for change does appear to be building in several areas. With the explosive growth of the Internet and electronic commerce, attention is
now turning to building the frameworks needed to enable a deeper and faster transition. The global infrastructure for overcoming inadequate privacy
safeguards, payment systems and intellectual property laws is now being designed. Should this infrastructure fall into place, there is a good chance
that decentralised market competition and knowledge diffusion will accelerate the transition process.
However, improving the ease with which people and firms everywhere can enter markets -- both on the demand and supply sides -- is only part of the
solution. Constraints, such as limited access to easy-to-use, "appropriate" technology and out-dated methods for improving, assessing and attributing
value to human capital threaten to slow change or render it too shallow. The intangible economy's radically new organisational patterns of production,
consumption and human settlement will take hold only if people are helped to overcome their fear of both unfamiliar technology and the prospect of
OECD Observer: The future of the global economy: towards a lon... http://www.oecdobserver.org/news/printpage.php/aid/50/The_futu...
1 of 2 30/11/15 15:54
new, possibly disruptive economic and social changes.
The second set of developments that could power a long boom spring from the possibility of an accelerated and much fuller integration of global
markets. There is good reason to believe such integration would bring positive results. After all, the creation of national or regional spaces for the free
flow of goods, services, finance and technology have had telling effects on long-term growth. Extended world-wide, such integration offers huge scope
to improve both the efficient allocation of resources and the competition of ideas that are the key ingredient of knowledge societies. But numerous
constraints block the way, from having to use existing frameworks for resolving trade disputes, to having to reform or invent institutions that can
manage the volatility of global financial markets.
In addition, the rapid and much fuller integration of global markets required for a long boom is unlikely to be politically feasible without mechanisms for
compensating losers and introducing minimum standards regarding both human and workplace rights. Here the notion of social values plays a
decisive role. Negotiations to merge markets and establish much higher degrees of transparency swiftly confront issues like the value attached by
many to preserving national sovereignty or the willingness to tolerate other people's social norms.
The drive towards environmental sustainability is the third factor that could contribute to sparking a long boom over the first few decades of the next
century. The job of lightening tomorrow's ecological footprint of wealth creation compared to today's industrial societies could, if the policies are
designed appropriately, spur the rapid development of both the intangible, environmentally benign, side of the economy, and improve the
eco-efficiency of the more traditional forms of production and consumption.
Such policies could help to accelerate the diffusion of new technologies, like hydrogen fuel-cells that can generate electricity for both home use and
transportation needs. Perhaps even more importantly, they could help to paint tomorrow's long boom green by making good use of the opportunity
afforded by new technologies to reorganise economic and social life.
On the other hand, moving aggresively towards an environmentally more sustainable economy and society might turn out to be more of a constraint
than a catalyst. Using economic incentives to change consumption and investment behaviour may be highly effective, as experience during the oil
shocks demonstrated, but the adjustment costs are often prohibitively high. These costs could end up compounding the drag exerted by trying to use
global institutions that are still somewhat immature for the daunting tasks of the future. Those tasks could include negotiating the attribution of rights
and the redistribution of income as part of a new form of global ecological citizenship.
Provoking a long boom
The key factors needed to spark a long boom do indeed appear to be present today. However, its prospects depend first, on the condition of the
underlying systemic "motors", such as the competitive markets, social openness and political democracy that create the foundations for long-run
economic dynamism, and second, on the extent to which the balance between historically specific catalysts and constraints -- of the knowledge
society, global markets and environmental sustainability -- can provide the necessary fuel. Provoking a long boom will be contingent on inducing as
many of the available catalytic forces as possible and making them work together. In concrete terms that means coherent and integrated policies to
accelerate the emergence of the knowledge economy, globalisation and a new environmental sustainability. It also means making the best of the
possibilities open to humanity on the eve of the 21st century.
Unfortunately, opportunities are not always grasped. There is now a rare chance to realise a period of rapid, widely shared growth and to reverse the
trends towards deepening inequality and exclusion that have marked recent decades. These are two very good reasons for making the exceptional
economic and social policy efforts required for the long boom to become reality.
Bibliography
Schwartz, Peter and Leyden, Peter, "The Long Boom: A History of the Future, 1980 - 2020",
Wired Magazine
, July 1997.
21st Century Technologies: Promises and Perils of a Dynamic Future
, OECD, 1998.
The Future of the Global Economy: Towards a Long Boom?
, OECD, 1999.
©OECD Observer No 217/218, Summer 1999
OECD Observer: The future of the global economy: towards a lon... http://www.oecdobserver.org/news/printpage.php/aid/50/The_futu...
2 of 2 30/11/15 15:54