ArticlePDF Available

Leveraging Psychological Insights to Encourage the Responsible Use of Consumer Debt

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

U.S. consumers currently hold 880billioninrevolvingdebt,withameanhouseholdcreditcardbalanceofapproximately880 billion in revolving debt, with a mean household credit card balance of approximately 6,000. Although economic factors play a role in this societal issue, it is clear that psychological forces also affect consumers' decisions to take on and maintain unmanageable debt balances. We examine three psychological barriers to the responsible use of credit and debt. We discuss the tendency for consumers to (a) make erroneous predictions about future spending habits, (b) rely too heavily on values presented on billing statements, and (c) categorize debt and saving into separate mental accounts. To overcome these obstacles, we urge policymakers to implement methods that facilitate better budgeting of future expenses, modify existing credit card statement disclosures, and allow consumers to easily apply government transfers (such as tax credits) to debt repayment. In doing so, we highlight minimal and inexpensive ways to remedy the debt problem.
Content may be subject to copyright.
For Review Only
Leveraging Psychological Insights to Encourage the
Responsible Use of Consumer Debt
Journal:
Perspectives on Psychological Science
Manuscript ID:
PPS-14-370.R3
Manuscript Type:
Special Issues Article
Date Submitted by the Author:
n/a
Complete List of Authors:
Hershfield, Hal; UCLA, Anderson School of Management
Sussman, Abigail; University of Chicago, Booth School of Business
O'Brien, Rourke; Harvard University,
Bryan, Christopher; UCSD, Psychology
Keywords:
Allied Field: Behavioral Economics, Application: Business, Thinking /
Reasoning / Judgment
User Defined Keywords:
Financial Decision-Making, Debt, Credit Card Use
Perspectives on Psychological Science
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 1
Running head: PSYCHOLOGICAL TOOLS AND DEBT ELIMINATION
Leveraging Psychological Insights to Encourage the Responsible Use of Consumer Debt
Hal E. Hershfield
University of California – Los Angeles
Abigail B. Sussman
University of Chicago
Rourke L. O’Brien
Harvard University
Christopher J. Bryan
University of California – San Diego
Author Note
Hal E. Hershfield, Anderson School of Management, University of California, Los
Angeles; Abigail B. Sussman, Booth School of Business, University of Chicago; Rourke L.
O’Brien, Harvard Center for Population & Development Studies, Harvard University;
Christopher J. Bryan, Department of Psychology, University of California, San Diego.
Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to Hal E. Hershfield, UCLA
Anderson School of Management, 110 Westwood Plaza, B419, Los Angeles, CA 90095. Email:
hal.hershfield@anderson.ucla.edu.
Page 1 of 12 Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 2
Abstract
US consumers currently hold $880 billion in revolving debt, with a mean household credit card
balance of approximately $6,000. Although economic factors play a role in this societal issue, it
is clear that psychological forces also affect consumers’ decisions to take on and maintain
unmanageable debt balances. We examine three psychological barriers to the responsible use of
credit and debt. We discuss the tendency for consumers to: 1) make erroneous predictions about
future spending habits, 2) rely too heavily on values presented on billing statements, and 3)
categorize debt and saving into separate mental accounts. To overcome these obstacles, we urge
policy-makers to implement methods that facilitate better budgeting of future expenses, modify
existing credit card statement disclosures, and allow consumers to easily apply government
transfers (such as tax credits) to debt repayment. In doing so, we highlight minimal and
inexpensive ways to remedy the debt problem.
Page 2 of 12Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 3
Leveraging Psychological Insights to Encourage the Responsible Use of Consumer Debt
US consumers currently hold $880 billion in revolving debt, with a mean credit card
balance of nearly $6,000 (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2014a,
2014b). The typically high interest rates on such debt can impede productive consumer spending
and investment, such as homeownership. Many intractable factors, both economic (e.g., high
interest rates and low wages; Zafar, Livingston, & VanDerKlaauw, 2014) and psychological in
nature (e.g., scarcity; Shah, Mullainathan, & Shafir, 2012) undoubtedly contribute to this
problem. However, a variety of psychological forces that are amenable to intervention also affect
consumers’ decisions to take on debt. Specifically, people make erroneous predictions about
future spending habits, rely too heavily on values presented on billing statements, and categorize
debt and saving into separate mental accounts. The presence of these context-based
psychological barriers suggests that policies designed to counter them may help ameliorate the
problem.
Although there are many types of debt, we focus on revolving debt (e.g., credit cards).
Given that the evidence for the success of financial education is mixed (e.g., Fernandes, Lynch,
& Netemeyer, 2014), we propose interventions that are psychological, rather than pedagogical in
nature. (See Table 1 for a summary of these interventions as well as the barriers they are meant
to overcome).
Incorporating the Future
People have difficulties thinking about the future: they view their distant selves as
strangers (Bryan & Hershfield, 2012) and fail to consider their changing tastes over time
(Loewenstein, O’Donoghue, & Rabin, 2003). It is perhaps unsurprising, then, that consumers
often act in ways that prioritize the present (e.g., overspend today), leaving negative
Page 3 of 12 Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 4
consequences for the future (e.g., large debt burdens). Recent research suggests some factors that
make it difficult to escape this debt cycle: people under-predict their future expenses (Peetz &
Buehler, 2009, 2012) and overspend on unusual items that are often considered in isolation
(Sussman & Alter, 2012). The latter is especially problematic given the large costs associated
with these exceptional purchases over time. The inverse is also true: people have the tendency to
overspend when they receive income that can be considered exceptional (e.g., a tax refund;
Arkes et al., 1994), neglecting to realize that such frivolous spending year after year can have a
significant negative effect on their overall wealth. Interventions that help people accurately
understand future expenses and income may thus minimize current spending and future debt.
Given that hundreds of billions of dollars flow from the government to households
annually, such transfers may be an ideal setting for policy-makers to implement interventions
that help people meet budgeting goals. These interventions should help consumers plan for the
future by 1) incorporating exceptional expenses into budgeting tools and 2) spreading spending
across time.
Our first policy recommendation is to match behaviorally informed budgeting tools with
the receipt of government transfers. First, government should follow the lead of major financial
institutions in using text messages to alert benefit recipients when the account balance associated
with a transfer is low or an unusually large transaction has been made. Second, cash transfers
such as Social Security could be paired with a free app that allows individuals to monitor their
spending. Most important, we suggest that any such budgeting tool (e.g., mint.com) should
include a budget category for expenses that are considered out of the ordinary. Doing so could
promote accurate budgeting for a class of expenses that may be difficult to predict in isolation,
and even lower spending on exceptional items (Sussman & Alter, 2012).
Page 4 of 12Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 5
A second intervention would target the largest lump sum payment most American
households receive each year: the tax refund. People are faster to spend windfall gains than
ordinary income (Arkes et al., 1994), and are more likely to treat a single large annual payment
as a windfall than several smaller repeated payments. Rather than delivering tax refunds in a
lump sum, we recommend breaking up payments into multiple streams; for example, as 12 pre-
paid credit cards
1
. Even if all 12 debt cards were delivered at the same time, dividing the
payment into 12 units could imply that the refund should not be spent at once, but rather, over
the course of a year (Soman & Cheema, 2011). Further, because consumers save more when a
tax refund is framed as a return to the status quo (i.e., “rebate”) rather than a sudden influx of
money (i.e., “bonus”) (Epley & Gneezy, 2007), the cards could be marketed as “rebate cards” in
an effort to encourage saving.
Improving Credit Card Statements
Recent legislation has tried to aid consumers by providing them with more information
on their credit card statements. Namely, the CARD Act of 2009 dictated that credit card
statements include payment warnings detailing not only how long it would take to pay off the
balance if only the minimum payment were made, but also the suggested payoff amount that
would result in the credit card balance being paid off over a period of 3 years. By one estimate,
the CARD Act saved consumers approximately $11.9 billion per year (Agarwal,
Chomsisengphet, Mahoney, & Stroebel, 2014).
However, this additional information has the potential to influence repayment in
unanticipated ways (e.g., through anchoring processes; Stewart, 2009). Indeed, aspects of the
CARD Act can potentially lead customers astray: people unduly gravitate toward paying the “3-
1
If tax refunds were directly deposited into consumers’ bank accounts, an alternative would be to implement an opt-
out system in which consumers receive their tax refund via monthly direct deposits, rather than a single installment.
Page 5 of 12 Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 6
year” amount compared to the minimum or the full balance (Agarwal et al., 2014), because they
view this 3-year amount as a strong suggestion for what they should pay (Hershfield & Roese,
2015). This legislation helped consumers who were previously paying less than the 3-year
amount, but caused a reduction in the fraction of account balances that were previously paid in
full (Wang & Keys, 2014). As a result, we recommend that policy-makers instruct credit card
companies to remove the 3-year payment warnings for consumers who regularly pay more than
the 3-year amount, and increase the warning amount (e.g., state a 2-year payment warning) for
those who regularly pay less.
Encouraging Debt Repayment
Prior research has demonstrated that people often create categories for money (i.e.,
mental accounts) and that this categorization constrains its use (e.g., reserving $1 in your right
pocket for certain purchases and $1 in your left pocket for others; Thaler, 1985, 1990). This
process can cause people to treat savings and debt as distinct financial categories rather than to
integrate them into overall wealth (Sussman & Shafir, 2012). In some cases, this categorization
can lead consumers to misguidedly take on high-interest rate debt, while simultaneously holding
money in low-interest bearing savings accounts (Gross & Souleles, 2002; Sussman & O’Brien,
2014). Existing government infrastructure focused on building savings often reinforces this
artificial separation. Policymakers could encourage wealth maximization by broadening the
scope to include debt repayment. We envision at least two ways to achieve this goal.
First, current tax policy actively subsidizes saving behavior (e.g., through a tax-deferred
saving platform). These policies communicate the problematic idea that when it comes to saving
money versus paying off debt, saving is always the right thing to do (i.e., an injunctive norm)
(e.g., Cialdini, 2003). But, many of the credits designed to promote saving could easily be
Page 6 of 12Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 7
expanded to provide similar tax benefits for paying down debt, and could specifically target high
interest consumer debt. Such policies might not only help make debt repayment as salient as
saving money for the future, but could also neutralize the existing norm.
Second, small tweaks to the tax filing process could enable consumers to remit a portion
of their tax refund to repay debt directly, just as U.S. consumers are now able to split their refund
among multiple savings vehicles. More broadly, the recent transition to electronic systems for
making government payments (e.g., direct deposit) provides an opportunity to implement
scalable behavioral interventions to reduce debt and improve financial well-being. Consumers
currently control where these funds are deposited (e.g., a bank account), but they do not have the
option of an automatic payment to a debt account. This structure encourages consumers to
preserve the mental segregation of asset and debt accounts and makes them less likely to direct
the money towards debt repayment once it has been received. We thus recommend that
consumers be given an option to deposit government funds directly towards credit card accounts.
Doing so could help consumers by opening the “channel factor”—making debt repayment easier
by eliminating the seemingly trivial but meaningful barriers that make behavior more difficult
(Lewin, 1951).
Summary of Policy Implications
People have a tendency to under-predict future expenses, rely too heavily on values
presented on billing statements, and fail to take into account overall wealth by categorizing debt
and saving into separate mental accounts. Drawing on insights from recent psychological
research, we make five key policy recommendations to overcome these obstacles: 1) pair
government transfers with budgeting tools that remind consumers when they are overspending
relative to their own guidelines and explicitly incorporate exceptional expenses, 2) split tax
Page 7 of 12 Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 8
refunds into separate payments, 3) revise suggested alternative payment warnings on credit card
statements, 4) provide tax credits for debt repayment, and 5) allow consumers to apply
government funds directly toward debt repayment. It is our hope that these suggestions will go a
long way toward encouraging the responsible use of consumer debt.
Page 8 of 12Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 9
References
Agarwal, S. and Chomsisengphet, S., Mahoney, N., & Stroebel, J. (2014). Regulating consumer
financial products: Evidence from credit cards. NBER Working Paper No. 19484
available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2330942
Arkes, H.R., Joyner, C.A., Pezzo, M.V., Nash, J.G., Siegel-Jacobs, K., & Stone, E. (1994). The
psychology of windfall gains. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,
59(3), 331-347. http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/obhd.1994.1063
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2014a). Household Debt and Credit Report.
Available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g19/hist/cc_hist_sa_levels.html.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2014b). Changes in U.S. Family Finances
from 2010 to 2013: Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances. Available at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/2014/articles/scf/scf.htm
Bryan, C.J. & Hershfield, H.E. (2012). You owe it to yourself: Boosting retirement saving with a
responsibility-based appeal. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 141(3), 429-
432. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/a0026173
Cialdini, R.B. (2003). Crafting normative messages to protect the environment. Current
Directions in Psychological Science, 12(4), 105-109. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1467-
8721.01242
Epley, N. & Gneezy, A. (2007). The framing of financial windfalls and implications for public
policy. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 36(1), 36-47.
doi:10.1016/j.socec.2005.12.012
Fernandes, D., Lynch, J.G., & Netemeyer, R.G. (2014). Financial literacy, financial education,
and downstream consequences. Management Science, 60(8), 1861-1883.
Page 9 of 12 Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 10
http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2013.1849
Gross, D.B. & Souleles, N.S. (2002). An empirical analysis of personal bankruptcy and
delinquency. The Review of Financial Studies, 15(1), 319-347.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/15.1.319
Hershfield, H.E. & Roese, N.J. (2015). Dual payoff warnings on credit card statements elicit
suboptimal decisions. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 25(1), 15-27.
doi:10.1016/j.jcps.2014.06.005
Lewin, K. (1951). Field theory in social science. New York: Harper.
Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Projection bias in predicting future
utility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1209-1248,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/003355303322552784
Peetz, J. & Buehler, R. (2009). Is there a budget fallacy? The role of savings goals in the
prediction of personal spending. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 35(12),
1579-1591. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0146167209345160
Peetz, J. & Buehler, R. (2012). When distance pays off: The role of construal level in spending
predictions. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 48(1), 395-398.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jesp.2011.07.016
Shah, A.K., Mullainathan, S., & Shafir, E. (2012). Some consequences of having too little.
Science, 338(6107), 682-685. http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1222426
Soman, D. & Cheema, A. (2011). Earmarking and partitioning: Increasing saving by low-income
households. Journal of Marketing Research, 48, S14-S22.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.48.SPL.S14
Stewart, N. (2009). The cost of anchoring on credit-card minimum repayments. Psychological
Page 10 of 12Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Eliminating Debt 11
Science, 20, 39-41. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9280.2008.02255.x
Sussman, A.B. & Alter, A.L. (2012). The exception is the rule: Underestimating and
overspending on exceptional purchases. Journal of Consumer Research, 39(4), 800-814.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/665833
Sussman, A.B. & O’Brien, R.L. (2014). Saving for a Purpose: The Financial Consequences of
Protecting Savings. Working paper available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2539861
Sussman, A.B. & Shafir, E. (2012). On assets and debt in the psychology of perceived wealth.
Psychological Science, 23(1), 101-108. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0956797611421484
Thaler, R.H. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4(3), 199-214.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1070.0330
Thaler, R.H. (1990). Anomalies: Saving, fungibility, and mental accounts. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 4(1), 193-205. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.4.1.193
Wang, J. & Keys, B.J. (2014). Perverse nudges: Minimum payments and debt paydown in
consumer credit cards. Penn Wharton Public Policy Initiative Issue Brief, 2(4), 1-6.
http://publicpolicy.wharton.upenn.edu/live/files/152-a
Zafar, B., Livingston, M., & VanDerKlaauw, W. (2014). Rising household debt: Increasing
demand or increasing supply? Liberty Street Economics (Federal Reserve Bank of New
York). Available at: http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2014/05/rising-
household-debt-increasing-demand-or-increasing-supply.html#.VI9VUVqslRG
Page 11 of 12 Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
For Review Only
Table 1. Psychological barriers undermining successful financial outcomes and suggestions for overcoming them
Problem Solution Example Policy Recommendation
Mispredicting future income and
spending
Highlight recurring nature of one-time events
for consumers
Match government transfers with
budgeting tools (e.g., Mint.com)
that explicitly incorporate
exceptional expenses
Split tax refunds into 12 separate
payments
Relying too heavily on suggested
payment amounts contained in credit
card statements
Modify anchors presented to credit card
customers
Remove 3-year payoff amount for
consumers who regularly pay
more than it
Increase 3-year payoff amount
(e.g., to a 2-year payoff amount)
for consumers who regularly pay
that amount or less
Separating saving and debt into
separate mental accounts, and
prioritizing saving over debt
repayment
Put debt repayment on an even playing field
with building savings
Provide tax credits for debt
repayment
Allow existing government
transfers to be applied to debt
repayment
Page 12 of 12Perspectives on Psychological Science
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
... The framing of payments seems to matter: Baker et al. (2007) found that more money was spent from likely recurring income (dividends) than from less recurring capital gain income. Hershfield et al. (2015) found that consumers placed savings and debt into different mental accounts, making them insensitive to the significant differences between the interest rates on these accounts. Shefrin and Thaler (1988) found that more of a lump sum bonus was saved than if the same amount increased regular income, even when the bonus is fully anticipated. ...
Article
Full-text available
Recently, Richard Thaler was awarded a Nobel Prize for his work in developing Behavioral Economics. While much of economics assumes that people act rationally, Areily (2008), expanding on Thaler’s body of work, proves that we are not only often irrational, but we are predictably irrational. When an interviewer asked Thaler how he would spend the roughly $1.1 million in prize money, he responded, “This is quite a funny question.” Thaler added, “I will try to spend it as irrationally as possible.” We know that affective tags for money exist but what specifically are those affective tags? More specifically still, is one of those tags for sources of income “fun,” and if so, does that affect whether the money will be spent on fun? Classical economics would assume that satisfaction comes from the consumption of goods and services, that money is a medium of exchange, and that the source of that medium of exchange does not enter into the choice of the goods or services consumed. Thaler’s (1999) works show that people create mental accounts, indicating that the source of the money may not be as completely irrelevant as classical economics predicted. This is important because where irrational behavior is suboptimal behavior, if we can anticipate it, we can construct environments to support better choices. We find that fun sources of income are significantly more likely to be spent on fun expenditures. However, as the amount of the windfall increases, the amount spent on fun levels off, indicating that this affect may be bounded. We were unable to find statistically significant support that more “adult” sources of income are more likely to be spent on more adult uses, but money from adult sources was significantly more likely to be invested. This is important because understanding more about affective tags and how they affect decisions to use money, we become better predictors of irrational behavior.
Article
Full-text available
With the increasing adoption of EMV (Europay, MasterCard, and Visa) payment systems, the state of global payments landscape has changed considerably. Despite their widespread success, EMV payment systems still face a number of technical challenges which need to be resolved, in order to sustain progress and innovation. These include issues of interoperability, security vulnerabilities, integration of purchase systems and mobile contactless payments. In this paper we study the technical barriers facing EMV payment systems, and explain how these barriers affect merchants, financial institutions and consumers. It also surveys the solutions and emerging technologies being created to beat these challenges and release the future of payment systems. This article explores current trends, problems and solutions to give a thorough view of how EMV payment systems are evolving and what the future holds for the global payment ecosystem.
Article
Full-text available
The EMV (Europay, MasterCard, and Visa) payment systems have completely changed the global financial landscape, providing a level of security and reducing fraud risk in card present transactions. As the digital payments ecosystem grows, however, EMV systems are confronted with a number of fundamental technical hurdles, including interoperability problems and security weaknesses, as well as the absorption of new forms of payment, including mobile wallets and contactless technologies. This paper discusses the solutions, which are being created to overcome the challenges facing achieving interoperability, fraud prevention, mobile payment integration and security protocols. In this paper, we present an overview of how the payments industry is responding to the rising demands for more secure, efficient, and user-friendly solutions to the transaction systems in the evolving digital economy, by analyzing current technical hurdles in the EMV payment systems, and the innovations that will shape the future.
Article
Full-text available
With the world shifting in the direction of EMV (Europay, MasterCard, and Visa) payment platforms, we're in the middle of a new age for secure and reliable financial payments. First popularized to remedy credit card fraud, the EMV technology has undoubtedly been a big improvement in payment security. Nevertheless, the transition to EMV payments has been anything but smooth. This paper present the major technical continuities met during implementing and optimizing EMV payment system such as interoperability, security vulnerabilities, system integration, and adopting the latest technologies such as mobile and contactless payments. The paper also examines the solutions that are being developed for mitigating these challenges in order to ensure that EMV payment systems remain responsive to the burgeoning needs of a worldwide digital economy. This article takes a deep-dive into the current state of EMV payments, and the technical challenges yet to be overcome to realise its full potential at these pivotal moments of EMV payments landscape.
Article
Full-text available
Rapidly growing need for reliable and efficient payments, allowing for secure transactions, especially to avoid fraud which is growing by the day and the call for digital or mobile payments that are taking the market place by storm, is what has evolved payment systems. However, Europay, Mastercard, and Visa (EMV) chip technology has become the de facto standard for securing card present transactions around the world. Yet, as payment systems progress, so do the kind of challenges EMV technology needs to tame. In this paper, we discuss the current core challenges facing EMV payment systems, including a noticeable shift towards card not present fraud and interoperability problems resulting from the use of cards across different regions and different devices, in addition to the complexity involved in integrating new technologies, such as mobile wallets and contactless payments. Additionally, it examines the new solutions and upcoming moves that are being carried out to overcome these drawbacks, making sure EMV sticks around as a security solution for digital payments and also included in improving the customer experience. However, this paper examines how technological innovations can help overcome the barriers to achieving a better performance in EMV payment systems, and future demands.
Article
Full-text available
EMV (Europay, MasterCard, and Visa) payment systems have been the biggest contributor in the worldwide shift to more secure payment systems, reducing the incidence of card present fraud. However, as the payments landscape evolves, EMV systems are faced with a number of technical challenges that will work to restrain its effectiveness. These involve interoperability problems and security issues and the integration of upcoming payment technologies including mobile wallets and contactless payments. In this paper we discuss the origin of EMV payment systems and outline the major technical challenges that they are facing. In particular, it details how work is being done on offering solutions to interoperability, security, infrastructure shortage and integration of newer payment methods. This paper analyzes the current state of EMV systems and the innovations along this direction that guided the future of the payment industry, specifically, how is the payment industry responding to these technical challenges and moving toward a more secure, efficient, and universally accessible payments ecosystem.
Article
Full-text available
EMV (Europay, MasterCard and Visa) technology has played a tremendous role in global shift towards limiting use of unsafe and inefficient payment systems. This is why we've seen the rise in EMV payment systems which are based on chip cards, and require a harder approach to fraud; in other words, payment systems that rely on the use of smart chip cards have completely changed the security landscape by reducing card present fraud. The market demand for EMV systems has kept pace with rising digital transactions along with changing payment technologies, incorporating newer methods such as the use of contactless payments, mobile wallets, advanced authentication protocols, etc. In this paper, we study the critical importance of EMV payment systems and how they achieve secure and efficient transactions. The report analyzes the primary core technical underpinnings of EMV systems, looks at the ongoing challenges they will need to address and discusses the ongoing innovation that will affect the future of EMV technology. It analyzes how EMV remains an evolving technology that aims to meet the increasing demand for enhanced security, easier user experience and wider system interoperability in an increasingly digital economy.
Article
Full-text available
Europay, MasterCard, and Visa (EMV), or chip, payment systems have changed how transactions are processed everywhere by boosting security through a chip. Yet, to maintain its relevance, EMV has some technical barriers to overcome and these technical barriers stem as digital payment systems evolve. While future EMV payment systems will face challenges ranging from interoperability and system integration to mobile wallets and contactless payments, overcoming these challenges will be the future of EMV payment systems. The aim of this work is to examine the key technical challenges pertaining to the EMV systems today as well as explore the new innovations in securing EMV payments in the future. This paper details how the payments industry is addressing important technical issues including fraud prevention, interoperability, mobile integration, and infrastructure upgrades, in order to continue the success of EMV payment systems in an ever more digital world by focusing on advancements in that arena.
Preprint
Full-text available
Objective The level of indebtedness of individuals has increased significantly in recent decades. The objective of this study was to analyze the scientific literature that evaluates the interrelationships between behavioral biases and personal indebtedness, with a view to investigating the intellectual structure of publications on the influence of behavioral biases on the level of personal indebtedness. Methodology Bibliometric analysis of scientific publications carried out until October 2023 in the "Web of Science" and "Scopus" databases and which analyze determinants of personal indebtedness from the perspective of behavioral sciences was used. Results The results reveal works with global and local relevance, how indebtedness has been discussed from a behavioral perspective and the main cognitive biases associated with it, research clusters that can serve as a reference for researchers, trends and research gaps in this field of knowledge, and that combining constructs from the field of behavioral sciences with other areas of knowledge, especially education/knowledge and psychology/behavior, tends to expand the literature related to personal indebtedness. Originality Based on the content analysis of the articles, an innovative scheme illustrating the possible definitions of indebtedness from an economic and psychological perspective is presented, which is an important contribution to the literature.
Article
We provide evidence of the existence of debt aversion and its negative implications for financial decisions. In a new experimental design where subjects are assigned debt randomly, we quantify the opportunity cost of subjects’ debt-biased decisions. One-third of our participants neglect high returns and focus instead on debt repayments. In addition, borrowing to invest is 50 percent less likely when it leads to indebtedness. On average, participants perceive 1lessindebtasequivalentto1 less in debt as equivalent to 1.03 in savings. Hence, a debt-averse agent will undertake a 10 percent guaranteed investment only if the cost of borrowing does not exceed 6.80 percent. (JEL C91, D91, G51)
Article
Full-text available
Policy makers have embraced financial education as a necessary antidote to the increasing complexity of consumers' financial decisions over the last generation. We conduct a meta-analysis of the relationship of financial literacy and of financial education to financial behaviors in 168 papers covering 201 prior studies. We find that interventions to improve financial literacy explain only 0.1% of the variance in financial behaviors studied, with weaker effects in low-income samples. Like other education, financial education decays over time; even large interventions with many hours of instruction have negligible effects on behavior 20 months or more from the time of intervention. Correlational studies that measure financial literacy find stronger associations with financial behaviors. We conduct three empirical studies, and we find that the partial effects of financial literacy diminish dramatically when one controls for psychological traits that have been omitted in prior research or when one uses an instrument for financial literacy to control for omitted variables. Financial education as studied to date has serious limitations that have been masked by the apparently larger effects in correlational studies. We envisage a reduced role for financial education that is not elaborated or acted upon soon afterward. We suggest a real but narrower role for “just-in-time” financial education tied to specific behaviors it intends to help. We conclude with a discussion of the characteristics of behaviors that might affect the policy maker's mix of financial education, choice architecture, and regulation as tools to help consumer financial behavior. This paper was accepted by Uri Gneezy, behavioral economics.
Article
Full-text available
Purchases fall along a continuum from ordinary (common or frequent) to exceptional (unusual or infrequent), with many of the largest expenses (e.g., electronics, celebrations) being the most exceptional. Across seven studies, we show that, while people are fairly adept at budgeting and predicting how much they will spend on ordinary items, they both underestimate their spending on exceptional purchases overall and overspend on each individual purchase. Based on the principles of mental accounting and choice bracketing, we show that this discrepancy arises in part because consumers categorize exceptional expenses too narrowly, construing each as a unique occurrence and consequently overspending across a series of discretely exceptional expenses. We conclude by proposing an intervention that diminishes this tendency by helping consumers consider their spending on exceptional items as part of a larger set of purchases.
Article
We analyze the effectiveness of consumer financial regulation by considering the 2009 Credit Card Accountability Responsibility and Disclosure (CARD) Act. We use a panel data set covering 160 million credit card accounts and a difference-in-differences research design that compares changes in outcomes over time for consumer credit cards, which were subject to the regulations, to changes for small business credit cards, which the law did not cover. We estimate that regulatory limits on credit card fees reduced overall borrowing costs by an annualized 1.6% of average daily balances, with a decline of more than 5.3% for consumers with FICO scores below 660. We find no evidence of an offsetting increase in interest charges or a reduction in the volume of credit. Taken together, we estimate that the CARD Act saved consumers $11.9 billion a year. We also analyze a nudge that disclosed the interest savings from paying off balances in 36 months rather than making minimum payments. We detect a small increase in the share of accounts making the 36-month payment value but no evidence of a change in overall payments. JEL Codes: D0, D14, G0, G02, G21, G28, L0, L13, L15.
Article
U.S. Federal regulation from 2009 requires credit card companies to convey information regarding payoff scenarios, i.e., details such as total amount paid and time to pay off when only a minimum payment is made (over time). Across seven studies, the present research shows that consumers who were given a dual payoff scenario (i.e., how much is paid in total based on the minimum payment and also based on a 3-year payoff window) on credit card statements recommended lower payments than those given a single payoff scenario (when the 3-year payment amount was less than what they would have paid otherwise), and were less likely to pay off the balance in full. The effect is driven by a tendency of consumers to infer that the 3-year payment amount is the most appropriate. The dual-scenario effect is minimized by an intervention that draws attention away from the 3-year payment amount. Theoretical and public policy implications are considered.
Article
Self predictions are often optimistically biased, even for recurrent events. People could generate more realistic predictions by using information about past experiences, however they tend to disregard this cognitive approach. Drawing on Construal Level Theory, we propose that increases in construal level facilitate the use of information from past experience, and thereby increase prediction accuracy. This proposal was tested in two studies examining predictions of personal spending. Consistent with the hypotheses, individuals induced to construe the prediction target at a higher level of abstraction generated more accurate predictions (Study 1) and the effect of increased construal level on prediction was attributable to a greater reliance on past experience (Studies 1 and 2). The findings indicate that high-level construal can sometimes benefit prediction accuracy.
Article
It is widely recognized that communications that activate social norms can be effective in producing societally beneficial conduct. Not so well recognized are the circumstances under which normative information can backfire to produce the opposite of what a communicator intends. There is an understandable, but misguided, tendency to try to mobilize action against a problem by depicting it as regrettably frequent. Information campaigns emphasize that alcohol and drug use is intolerably high, that adolescent suicide rates are alarming, and—most relevant to this article—that rampant polluters are spoiling the environment. Although these claims may be both true and well intentioned, the campaigns' creators have missed something critically important: Within the statement “Many people are doing this undesirable thing” lurks the powerful and undercutting normative message “Many people are doing this.” Only by aligning descriptive norms (what people typically do) with injunctive norms (what people typically approve or disapprove) can one optimize the power of normative appeals. Communicators who fail to recognize the distinction between these two types of norms imperil their persuasive efforts.
Article
Poor Choices Two categories of reasons for why poor people make economically unsound choices, such as obtaining a payday loan at an extraordinarily high rate of interest, reflect, first, the environment: Poor people are more likely to be living in poor neighborhoods with higher rates of crime and lower rates of social services. Second, they reflect the individual: People are poor in part because of their own psychological dispositions toward impatience and impulsiveness. For both cases, obtaining causal evidence in controlled experiments has been challenging. Shah et al. (p. 682 ; see the Perpective by Zwane ) propose a third category of reasons whereby being poor exerts a bias on cognitive processes and provide evidence for it in laboratory experiments performed in scenarios of scarcity.