ArticlePDF Available

Introductory Comment–The Green Paradox: A Supply-Side View of the Climate Problem

Authors:

Abstract

Why have policies aimed at reducing the demand for carbon not succeeded in slowing down global carbon extraction and CO2 emissions, and why have carbon prices failed to increase over the last three decades? This comment argues that this is because of the Green Paradox, that is, the anticipation of sales by resource owners who try to preempt the destruction of their markets by green policies. Reviewing some of the conditions under which strong and weak versions of the Green Paradox may emerge, it is argued that there is little hope that green replacement technologies will impose hard price constraints that would keep long-run extraction within a fixed carbon budget and that, therefore, even strong versions of the paradox cannot easily be avoided.
Introductory Comment
The Green Paradox: A Supply-Side
View of the Climate Problem
Hans-Werner Sinn*
The climate problem is one of mankind’s biggest challenges. Averting disaster requires nothing
less than worldwide collective policy action. However, policies that ignore the laws of eco-
nomics may prove futile, if not downright counterproductive. In particular, policies aimed at
reducing future demand for fossil fuels could backfire by inducing resource owners to bring
forward their extraction plans, thus accelerating global warming. I have called this behaviour
the Green Paradox.
Economists and policy makers alike long overlooked the possibility of a Green Paradox
because the behaviour of resource owners played no specific role in the economics of climate
change. Although it has long been recognized that the anthropogenic carbon accumulating in
the atmosphere is basically the same as the carbon taken from the ground and that, except for
sequestration,no technical devices exist that could change the proportions accumulating in the
sea, biomass, and atmosphere, this has rarely been incorporated into climate models or
addressed by policy makers in the past. Instead the focus was on the demand side of the
market.Itwasthoughtthattomitigatetheclimate problem, it would be effective and sufficient
to require better insulation of homes, to extract higher mileage from car engines, to subsidize
green energy through tariffs, to morally discredit fossil fuel consumption, to tax the use of fossil
fuels, or to subsidize the development of green technologies, because it was taken for granted
that supply would follow demand. Resource suppliers were perceived to be like car producers,
facing flat marginal cost curves and producing what is demanded at given prices. However,
unlike cars, fossil resources sold in the market are already there (i.e., in the earth’s crust) and
thus cannot be producedin the normal sense of the word. Extraction and exploration costs
are typically small relative to user costs. This means that we cannot assume that the supply
reactions of resource owners will be elastic.
Fortunately, the period of ignoring the obvious appears to be coming to an end. Although the
supply-side view of the climate problem is not yet widely recognized by the public, both the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change and the literature on the economics of climate
change are now giving at least as much weight to the supply side as to the demand side. The
focus is on the intertemporal dimension of supply decisions, merging the traditional theory of
*President, Ifo Institute - Leibniz Institute for Economic Research, and Professor of Economics and Public
Finance, University of Munich, Germany; e-mail: hws-f2015@ifo.de.
239
Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, volume 9, issue 2, Summer 2015, pp. 239–245
doi:10.1093/reep/rev011
ßThe Author 2015. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Association of Environmental and Resource
Economists. All rights reserved. For Permissions, please email: journals.permissions@oup.com
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/reep/article-abstract/9/2/239/1626800
by Universitaetsbibliothek Muenchen user
on 23 August 2018
exhaustible resources with the theory of climate change. Exhausting the stock of carbon re-
sources in the ground and accumulating waste carbon in the atmosphere are now viewed and
modelled as a single decision.
The Hotelling View
In the spirit of Hotelling (1931), the new models typically assume that resource owners opti-
mize the composition of their wealth portfolios, with wealth consisting of both the physical
resource in the ground and the financial wealth that can result from extracting and selling some
of the resource. Ideally, resource owners will choose portfolios that equate the rates of return on
both the physical and financial assets. However, resource owners are blind to the carbon
externality they cause.
Under the Hotelling rule, it is essential that resource owners be forward-looking (i.e., that
they base their behaviour on expectations of future prices). This means that policies aimed at
limiting or reducing the possibility of generating resource-derived revenues in the future will
induce resource owners to bring their sales forward to the present. This, in turn, will depress
current market prices and increase resource demand, thus accelerating global warming.
The Green Paradox, Fossil Fuel Prices, and Overextraction
In my view, the Green Paradox is not simply a theoretical possibility. I believe it explains why
fossil fuel prices have failed to rise since the 1980s, despite decreasing stocks of fossil fuels and
the vigorous growth of the world economy. The emergence of green policy movements around
the world, rising public awareness of the climate problem, and increased calls for demand-
reducing policy measures, ranging from taxes and demand constraints to subsidies on green
technologies, have alarmed resource owners. In fact, while most of us perceived these devel-
opments as a breakthrough in the battle against global warming, resource owners viewed them
as efforts that threatened to destroy their markets. Thus, in anticipation of the implementation
of these policies, they accelerated their extraction of fossil fuels, bringing about decades of low
energy prices. In fact, as of this writing (April 2015), oil prices, in real terms, are at about the
same levels as just before the May 1979 price jump that led to the second oil crisis.
Concerns about the increasing influence of environmental activists may also explain the
strange behaviour of the owners of German lignite fields. While Germany’s lignite
resources rank tenth in the world and account for less than 2 percent of the available
global stock, its 17 percent market share makes it the world’s leader in terms of current
extraction. What else but fear of threats from Germany’s Green Party—arguably the world’s
most powerful environmental party—to close lignite mines and prohibit extraction can explain
this behaviour?
Of course there are probably other reasons for overextraction, including rising political
tensions in the Middle East, which have increased the threat of expropriation. However, this
only heightens the risk of global warming. For resource owners, it does not matter whether
expropriation occurs through a coup d’e
´tat in a particular country, or through pressure from
environmentalists to reduce dependence on fossil fuels. In either case, resource owners will seek
to protect their interests by bringing at least some of their extraction forward.
240 H.-W. Sinn
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/reep/article-abstract/9/2/239/1626800
by Universitaetsbibliothek Muenchen user
on 23 August 2018
This symposium on the Green Paradox and Climate Policy contains three important review
articles written by experts in the field (Jensen et al. 2015; Long 2015; and van der Ploeg and
Withagen 2015). The articles primarily present the theoretical literature because there has been
very little empirical research on the Green Paradox to date. Using different models of fossil fuel
extraction, they examine the impacts of a variety of announced or implemented green policies,
focusing on the roles of stock-dependent extraction costs, spatially differentiated policies, and
backstop technologies, in order to identify when well-intentioned policies are likely to backfire
and result in a Green Paradox outcome. Overall, they find that the literature confirms the risk of
Green Paradox outcomes and strengthens the case for taking a supply-side view of the climate
problem.
While it is not possible to review the symposium articles in detail here, I would still like to
comment on some of the key issues they raise.
The Price Wedge
My work on the Green Paradox (Sinn 2008a, 2008b, 2008c) focuses on the price wedgethat
may be created by green policies. Consider a baseline scenario (with an intertemporal market
equilibrium and rational expectations) that is distorted by a green policy aimed at the demand
side of the market (e.g., subsidies for green backstop technologies, enforced technological
demand constraints, carbon taxes). This policy depresses producer prices during some periods
relative to what they would have been without the policy, resulting in a price wedge. More
specifically, I define the price wedge at a particular point in time as the difference between the
old, pre-policy price and the new producer price, which would arise if suppliers did not adjust
the fossil fuel extraction path to the new policy.
My analysis is based on the standard assumption made by traditional resource models
whereby rising prices will always stay above (and be bounded away from) rising stock-depend-
ent unit extraction costs due to increasing scarcity and on-going depletion. This assumption
implies that laissez-faire markets will exhaust the available stock as time goes to infinity.
Assuming marginal policy measures, I showed that producers will:
(1) Bring their extraction forward if the present value of the expected price wedge
(discounted using the rate of return on financial assets) increases over time; (2) not change
the extraction path if the present value of the expected price wedge remains constant over
time; and (3) postpone extraction if the present value of the expected price wedge decreases
over time.
1
The first of the three outcomes is a Green Paradox, in both its weak and strong forms. It is a
weak paradox because global warming accelerates at least for a while. It is a strong paradox
because it moves the economy further away from an intertemporal Pareto optimum, which
requires a slower speed of global warming than would occur in competitive markets.
2
1
This analysis draws on earlier work (Long and Sinn 1985) that examines the effects of exogenous price changes
on extraction, as well as analysis of nonconstant sales tax rates in a resource extraction model (Sinn 1982).
2
See Sinn (2007, 2008a) for a generalization of the Solow-Stiglitz efficiency rule (Solow 1974; Stiglitz 1974) to the
case of global warming due to the accumulation of carbon in the atmosphere.
The Green Paradox: A Supply-Side View of the Climate Problem 241
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/reep/article-abstract/9/2/239/1626800
by Universitaetsbibliothek Muenchen user
on 23 August 2018
Backstop Technologies
Two of the symposium articles (van der Ploeg and Withagen; Jensen, Mohlin, Pittel, and
Sterner) emphasize the impact of a backstop technology that produces a perfect energy sub-
stitute at a fixed unit cost, thus preventing the extraction of fossil fuels with extraction costs
above this unit cost. They also note that subsidies that reduce the unit cost of the backstop
would accelerate global warming for a while (weak Green Paradox) but would reduce the total
amount of carbon released into the atmosphere. For those who view reducing the carbon
budget as the primary goal of climate policy, this is a satisfactory outcome.
Unfortunately, I am less optimistic about the potential role of backstop technologies. First, it
is not clear to me why reducing the total long-term carbon budget should be considered more
beneficial to human welfare than postponing extraction. Focusing on the final carbon budget
would make sense in a hypothetical world with no time preferences and discounting. But
without discounting, a welfare analysis of resource extraction would be meaningless, even
in the absence of global warming, as the optimal rate of resource extraction would be zero.
I believe that even hard-core philosophers would agree that this problem excludes a
lexicographic ordering of social preferences for postponing versus avoiding climate damages
forever.
Second, I do not see anything in the real world that even comes close to being the perfect
backstop assumed in theoretical models. Wind and solar power, often considered the most
likely candidates, will be able to replace some fossil fuel, but certainly not all, because they are so
volatile. The economic cost of storage devices such as pump storage or methanization plants
that could smooth the supply of green electricity is extremely high.
3
For example, in 2013,
Germany would have needed 3,500 pump-storage plants, more than a hundred times the
number it had at the time, to smooth its energy from wind and solar power, although the
latter accounted for only 3 percent of final energy consumption. I fear that the only effective
smoothing strategy would be one that is based on the intermittent production of energy from
fossil fuel to cover periods when wind or solar is not available. But this smoothing strategy can
only work if the green energy supply is small enough to prevent production spikes from
exceeding aggregate demand, something that already occurs in Germany from time to time.
Thus, beyond a certain production level, wind and solar energy would switch from being
substitutes to complements of fossil fuels. This means that they cannot serve as the backstop
technology assumed in many Green Paradox models.
Thus, at best, subsidies for green energy would reduce the demand for fossil fuels at all points
in time but would not impose the hard ceiling on prices assumed in the models. The subsidies
would shift the (period-specific) resource demand curves downwards, creating the price wedge
discussed earlier. At worst, subsidies for wind and solar energy would increase the demand for
complementary fossil fuels if wind andsolar energy were already extensively used, thus reducing
thepricewedgeatthemargin.
Nuclear fission and nuclear fusion have the potential to serve as backstops that induce hard
price ceilings. However, the former has been discredited by the Fukushima accident and thus
does not appear to offer a politically feasible alternative. Nuclear fusion could potentially garner
3
See H.-W. Sinn, Schafft es Deutschland, den Zappelstrom zu ba
¨ndigen?, public lecture, Ifo Annual Meeting,
available at: http://mediathek.cesifo-group.de/iptv/player/macros/cesifo/mediathek?content¼3583749&idx¼
2&category¼2196209669.
242 H.-W. Sinn
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/reep/article-abstract/9/2/239/1626800
by Universitaetsbibliothek Muenchen user
on 23 August 2018
more political support. However, decades of promises of imminent breakthroughs have given
way to more pessimistic expectations. At best, the availability of a nuclear fusion backstop can
be anticipated with time-dependent probabilities, but such probabilistic expectations translate
into a mathematically expected price wedge that has implications similar to those discussed
earlier.
Scenarios that Avoid the Green Paradox
Of course, there are model assumptions that would eliminate the risk of a Green Paradox
outcome. For example, it is possible that mankind would, under laissez faire, not exhaust the
entire resource stock, because, with the passage of time, the marginal willingness to pay for
dwindling fossil resources rises more slowly than the unit extraction costs resulting from the
depletion of the better fields. In this case, any permanent demand-reducing measures of the
kind discussed earlier would eliminate some of the stock that could be profitably extracted and
hence put a limit on the earth’s maximum temperature (see Withagen and van der Ploeg 2015).
However, we cannot know today whether the underlying conditions for this optimistic scenario
will hold because this all depends on technologies and preferences in a far distant and uncertain
future.
Alternatively,wemightwanttodesignastrategy that ensures a gradual decline in the present
value of the price wedge over time, thus giving resource owners an incentive to extract later.
However, I doubt that it will ever be politically possible to fine-tune such a policy and to
commit to its implementation over the long term. In the real world, there are no commitment
devices that bind successive generations. New generations of policymakers will reoptimize, and
when the world does get warmer, they may face increasing political pressure to intensify their
green policies, thus increasing the price wedge more than originally envisaged. In any case,
resource owners are likely to anticipate such policy changes and react by bringing forward their
fossil fuel extraction.
Carbon Leakage
The efficacy of demand policies may deteriorate further if only some resource-consuming
countries implement green policies, since their demand restraint would be outweighed by
additional consumption in other countries. In this case, the Green Paradox would be reinforced
by carbon leakage, rendering any unilateral actions toward solving the climate problem futile.
To illustrate this point, let’s assume that the green policy consists of implementing a
cap-and-trade system in a subgroup of countries, with quantity constraints tightening over
time. Let’s also assume for a moment that resource owners do not react by changing their
extraction path. Under these conditions, at each point in time, the world market price for fossil
fuels will be lower than it would have been without the policy because the cap reduces world-
wide demand. Consumers in countries not participating in the emissions trading system would
enjoy the lower world market price, and their energy demand would increase, while consumers
in participating countries would be forced to pay a higher energy price and consume less
because they would also have to pay for the emissions certificates. Consider now the possibility
of an adjustment reaction affecting the extraction path and suppose that, without such an
The Green Paradox: A Supply-Side View of the Climate Problem 243
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/reep/article-abstract/9/2/239/1626800
by Universitaetsbibliothek Muenchen user
on 23 August 2018
adjustment, the tightening of the cap would be fast enough to cause the present value of
the world-market price wedge to increase over time. In this case, the price signal would
again induce resource owners to bring forward extraction to the present to minimize revenue
losses.
These green policies carried out by only a group of countries are inefficient for two reasons.
First, the energy no longer consumed by these countries will be consumed by non-participating
countries instead. Second, the nonparticipating countries will also consume the additional
quantities of energy that resource owners extract and sell because of the Green Paradox. In
an initial phase, this would lead to more than 100 percent leakage because nonparticipating
countries would consume more carbon than the countries introducing the cap-and-trade
system would cut.
4
Conclusions
My pessimistic conclusions about the efficacy of green demand-reducing policies have no
doubt disappointed many environmental activists. However, the climate problem is too
important to be left to ideologues. The purpose of green policies is not to provide the public
with a warm glow from charitable actions but rather to cool the earth.
I would argue that nothing short of binding global agreements on quantity constraints can
successfully reduce the speed of global warming. Measures that simply work through price
signals are not sufficiently reliable to do the job, as it is the changes in prices, rather than their
levels, that will determine success; and it is easy enough to get the price changes wrong through
reoptimization by successive generations of policy makers.
The first step toward imposing quantity constraints should be to extend the existing UN
emissions trading system (initially introduced through the Kyoto agreement) to the entire
world and to add national or supranational cap-and-trade systems similar to Europe’s. If the
United States, China, and India could be convinced to sign such a treaty, 71 percent of world-
wide CO
2
output would be covered. In a second step, we should attempt to convince most of
the rest of the world to participate. By definition, such a global system would be safe from
international leakage and would not fall victim to the Green Paradox. In my opinion, this
approach offers the only potential solution to the world’s climate problem, which, as Stern et al.
(2006) have remarked, is the world’s greatest market externality ever.
References
Hotelling, H. 1931. The economics of exhaustible
resources. Journal of Political Economy 39 (2):
137–75.
Jensen, S., K. Mohlin, K. Pittel, and T. Sterner.
2015. An introduction to the Green Paradox: The
unintended consequences of climate policies.
Review of Environmental Economics and Policy
9 (2): 246–65.
Long, N. V. 2015. The Green Paradox in open
economies: Lessons from static and dynamic
models. Review of Environmental Economics and
Policy 9(2):26684.
Long, N. V., and H.-W. Sinn. 1985. Surprise price
shifts, tax changes and the supply behaviour of re-
source extracting Firms. Australian Economic
Papers 24: 278–89.
4
For a discussion of this possibility, see Sinn (2008b, 2008c) and Long (2015).
244 H.-W. Sinn
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/reep/article-abstract/9/2/239/1626800
by Universitaetsbibliothek Muenchen user
on 23 August 2018
Sinn, H.-W. 1982. Absatzsteuern,
Olfo
¨rderung
und das Allmendeproblem. In H. Siebert. Hrsg.,
83–103. Reaktionen auf Energiepreisa
¨nderungen.
Frankfurt: Lang.
———. 2007. Pareto optimality in the extraction
of fossil fuels and the greenhouse effect: A note.
NBER Working Paper No. 13453, September 2007.
———. 2008a. Public policies against global
warming: A supply side approach. International
Tax and Public Finance 15 (4): 360–94.
———. 2008b. Das gru
¨ne Paradoxon. Pla
¨doyer fu
¨r
eine illusionsfreie Umweltpolitik, Berlin: Econ.
English translation: The green paradox: A supply
side approach to global warming. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press, 2012.
———. 2008c. Das gru
¨ne Paradoxon: Warum
man das Angebot bei der Klimapolitik nicht verges-
sen darf. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 9(spe-
cial issue): 109–42.
———. 2014. Schafft es Deutschland, den
Zappelstrom zu ba
¨ndigen? Public lecture, Ifo
Annual Meeting, 26 June 2014, http://mediathek.
cesifo-group.de/iptv/player/macros/cesifo/media
thek?content¼3583749&idx¼2&category¼
2196209669.
Solow, R. 1974. Intergenerational equity and ex-
haustible resources. Review of Economic Studies 41:
29–45.
Stiglitz, J. E. 1974. Growth with exhaustible natural
resources: Efficient and optimal growth paths.
Review of Economic Studies 41: 123–37.
Stern, N., S. Peters, V. Bakhshi, A. Bowen, C.
Cameron, S. Catovsky, D. Crane, S. Cruickshank,
S. Dietz, N. Edmonson, S.-L. Garbett, L. Hamid, G.
Hoffman,D.Ingram,B.Jones,N.Patmore,H.
Radcliffe, R. Sathiyarajah, M. Stock, C. Taylor, T.
Vernon, H. Wanjie, and D. Zenghelis. 2006. Stern
review: The economics of climate change.London:
HM Treasury.
van der Ploeg, F., and C. Withagen. 2015.
Global warming and the Green Paradox: A
review of adverse effects of climate policies.
Review of Environmental Economics and Policy
9 (2): 285–303.
The Green Paradox: A Supply-Side View of the Climate Problem 245
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/reep/article-abstract/9/2/239/1626800
by Universitaetsbibliothek Muenchen user
on 23 August 2018
... However, the impact of environmental regulation on pollution emissions is not as straightforward as one might imagine. Scholars, on the basis of different research contexts and analytical methods, have developed two mainstream perspectives: the "forced reduction effect" hypothesis, and Sinn's "green paradox" hypothesis (Sinn 2015). Supporters of the "forced reduction" hypothesis argue that the implementation goal of environmental regulation is to reduce pollutant emissions; thus, environmental regulation should have a direct positive effect on reducing these emissions. ...
Article
Full-text available
How to effectively reduce pollution emissions and achieve high-quality economic development (HQED) is an important challenge currently facing China. On the basis of China’s provincial panel data from 2008 to 2020, this paper constructs a panel vector autoregression (PVAR) model, to clarify the dynamic interactive relationships among environmental regulation, pollution emissions and HQED from an endogenous perspective. On this basis, the threshold model was used to test the threshold effect of environmental regulation and pollution emission intensity. The results indicate the following: (1) A bidirectional Granger causality relationship exists between environmental regulation and pollution emission, and between pollution emission and HQED, with environmental regulation being a one-way Granger cause of HQED. (2) Environmental regulation can significantly promote HQED in the long term. Pollution emission intensity and HQED have a mutual inhibitory effect, with the inhibitory effect of pollution emission intensity showing a lag, and a long-term “inverted M” pattern. Pollution emission intensity has a positive promoting effect on environmental regulation intensity in the long term, whereas the reverse relationship is inhibitory, following an inverted U-shaped trend. (3) Variance decomposition reveals that, in addition to the variables themselves, pollution emissions contribute the most to the intensity of environmental regulation. Environmental regulation contributes the most to the other two variables. (4) The threshold regression model indicates that when the intensity of environmental regulation crosses the threshold value of 0.8430, pollution emission intensity has a significant negative impact on HQED. When pollution emission intensity crosses the second threshold value of 0.4870, the intensity of environmental regulation begins to show a positive promoting effect. This article not only effectively supplements the EKC hypothesis from a theoretical level, but also clarifies the dynamic interactive relationship between environmental regulation, pollution emissions and HQED from a practical level, providing a reference for the government to improve environmental regulation policies and facilitate HQED in China.
... There is also an opinion ('green paradox' theory) that stricter environmental policies would only lead to an increase in fossil fuel extraction [58]. According to the same author, Sinn [59], fossil fuel suppliers are not taxed enough. Thus, the size of the tax should be optimal, not too high, to discourage innovation and promote pollution haven, and not too low, so that there is an incentive for the action. ...
Article
Full-text available
Environmental pollution endangers nature, human health, and, subsequently, the economy. The governments of European countries are trying to mitigate the effects of environmental degradation and climate change by employing various policy instruments, including taxes, subsidies, trading schemes, and others. However, the question is whether such actions are efficient. Several researchers previously studied the effects of stringent environmental policy on CO2 emissions for different regions of the world. Nevertheless, there is a lack of understanding of how regional specifics and economic factors can impact the effect of the stringency. We examined the impact of environmental policy stringency and environmental taxes on greenhouse gas emissions in a sample of eight European countries, covering Western Europe and Central Europe. Our results show that the stringency of environmental policies has a significant effect only in Western Europe. Interestingly, the most influential factor for both groups turned out to be the R&D expenditure.
... Another strand of the literature highlights that environmental regulation, particularly taxes, can be counterproductive and adversely affect the ecology. Partisans of the so-called "Green Paradox" indicated that environmental taxes result in a rise in fossil fuel energy and are therefore targeting the demand side of fossil fuel [38]. Because there is a time lag between environmental policy and its implementation, there will be fear on behalf of fossil fuel suppliers, which will accelerate their extraction activities, leading to higher energy demand and environmental degradation [24]. ...
Article
Full-text available
The latest decades have been marked by rapid climate change and global warming due to the release of greenhouse gas emissions into the atmosphere. Environmental taxes have emerged as a cost-effective way to tackle environmental degradation. However, the effectiveness of environmental taxes in reducing pollution remains a topic of ongoing debate. The purpose of this paper is to examine empirically the effects of various environmental tax categories (energy, pollution, resource and transport) on CO2 emissions in 34 OECD countries between 1995 and 2019. The dynamic panel threshold regression developed by Seo and Shin (2016) is implemented to assess whether the impact of environmental taxes on CO2 emissions depends on a given threshold level. The locally weighted scatterplot smoothing analysis provides evidence for a nonlinear association between environmental taxes and CO2 emissions. The analysis indicates the existence of one significant threshold and two regimes (lower and upper) for all environmental tax categories. The dynamic panel threshold regression reveals that the total environmental tax, energy tax and pollution tax reduce CO2 emissions in the upper regime, i.e., once a given threshold level is reached. The threshold levels are 3.002% of GDP for the total environmental tax, 1.991% for the energy tax and 0.377% for the pollution tax. Furthermore, implementing taxes on resource utilization may be effective but with limited environmental effects. Based on the research results, it is recommended that countries in the OECD implement specific environmental taxes to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.
... Others, however, are sceptical about the effectiveness of these policy instruments in mitigating environmental damage (Wolde-Rufael & Mulat-Weldemeskel, 2022). Others point out the existence of a "green paradox", fearing that such policies may lead to unintended and undesirable consequences that exacerbate environmental damage (Sinn, 2015). Those who note this contradiction consider that these inadequate ecological laws solely handle the supply side of externalities, i.e., primary energy consumption, without taking the supply side of energy production into account (Jensen et al., 2015). ...
Article
Full-text available
Carbon dioxide (CO2) is a significant source of Greenhouse Gas (GHG) emissions and plays a crucial role in climate change and global warming. This study aims to explain the effects of primary and renewable energy supplies and environmental taxation and to analyse how taxation can alter their direct effects on carbon intensity. The research was conducted using a generalized method of moments model that uses instrumental variables with two-stage (2SGMM) estimators to calculate the direct and moderating effects of environmental taxes on carbon intensity. This study confirms the EKC theorem, and results have shown that primary energy supply and environmental-related taxation positively contribute to carbon intensity. The second finding indicates that a major increase in the proportion of renewable energy will greatly slow the rate of carbon dioxide emissions. The study provides additional evidence concerning the moderating role of taxation in amplifying the impacts of primary and renewable energy supply. The empirical findings suggest that the taxation impact is more fiscal than an incentive. In addition to the current energy and economic crisis, considerable funding and fiscal policies are needed to achieve more sustainable development paths towards carbon neutrality and energy security.
Chapter
Full-text available
This chapter attempts to examine the role of foreign direct investment (FDI) in the economic growth and development of the Global South countries, particularly the GS-11. The GS-11 comprises the present BRICS countries, including Brazil, China, India, Russia, South Africa, and six recent additions: the UAE, Saudi Arabia, Iran, Ethiopia, Egypt, and Argentina. Following this expansion, the GS-11 economies will represent approximately half of the world’s population and constitute nearly one-third of the global GDP. The economies of the Global South face various challenges, notably with respect to issues of financial stability, multilateral trade, and economic development. In order to address these challenges, FDI could play a significant role. Such investments from abroad provide host nations with much-needed capital, managerial expertise, technology, and access to global markets. Moreover, they play a pivotal role in fostering export-oriented growth. It also enhances a nation’s capacity to manufacture exportable commodities and wide-ranging services through technology transfer and knowledge spillovers. Further, it provides the necessary linkages to global value chains, helping to expand market access. To exploit the FDI phenomenon, the policymakers of GS-11 economies need to find an equilibrium between attracting foreign investment and promoting sustainable economic development. Against this backdrop, this chapter uses descriptive tools to examine the multifaceted impact of inward FDI on the economic growth, trade dynamics, and overall development of GS-11 countries. The findings highlight the significance of FDI inflows for the long-term economic growth of developing nations in the Global South.
Article
Full-text available
This study investigates the impact of geopolitical risk (GPR) on consumption-based carbon (CCO2) emissions as well as the moderating role of environmental policy stringency (EPS) on the above relationship. Based on data collected from 27 countries from 1990 to 2020, the basic results from the sample of the study indicate that GPR accelerates CCO2 emissions. Quantile regression results reveal that the effect of GPR is more pronounced in countries with higher CCO2 emissions. Moreover, EPS weakens the escalating effect of GPR on CCO2 emissions. The robust test results validate the findings reported in the basic regression model. The heterogeneity test indicates that the impact of GPR on CCO2 emissions is greater in developing countries compared in developed countries. The study also proposes these policy implications based on the findings: (1) countries should ensure a stable political environment, establish a robust legal system and promote energy transition; and (2) the scope of environmental taxes should be expanded where different tax rates should be imposed in order to be useful in reducing CCO2 emissions.
Article
Full-text available
This study investigates the impact of macroprudential policies on ecological footprint (EF) in the top 11 largest countries. This study uses country-level panel data from these countries, covering the period from 1992 to 2020. Findings indicate that macroprudential policies alleviates ecological footprint in the sample. Macroprudential policies primarily reduce the ecological footprint before medium quantile (50%) while the environmental benefits of the policies end in the later quantiles. Moreover, environmental policy stringency (EPS) amplifies the positive influence of macroprudential policies on environmental sustainability. Estimate results stay the same with basic regression results in the post-global financial crisis (GFC) period while the impact is positive in the pre-GFC period. Finally, other robust tests validate the findings reported in basic regression model. This study suggests that governments should customize various types of macroprudential policies while also considering environmental concerns. The achievement of a sustainable environment can be facilitated by the combined effects of macroprudential policies and EPS.
Chapter
Knowledge ofSupply chaintheEnergycarrier physical characteristics of energy and the various types of activities within energy supply chainsSupply chain is necessary before being able to analyse the optimal regulation of energy markets. Therefore, this chapter introduces the various types of energy carriersEnergycarrier, distinguishing primary from secondary carriers and non-renewableEnergynon-renewable from renewable sources (Sect. 2.2). This chapter also discusses the concept of the energy balance, which describes the origins of supply and the destinations of use of energy within an economy. The chapter proceeds by describing the various layers in the supply chainsSupply chain, from explorationExploration of energy resourcesEnergyresource, production, conversionConversion, storage, transport until consumptionConsumption of energy (Sect. 2.3). This chapter concludes by discussing how these energy supply chains of activities can be organized (Sect. 2.4).
Article
Full-text available
How important is the Green Paradox? We address this question in three ways. First, we present a simple model explaining how announcing a future climate policy may increase carbon emissions today – the Green Paradox effect. This effect is a result of fossil fuel producers increasing their extraction today as a response to a reduction in future resource rents. Second, we examine the theoretical and empirical literature to assess whether green paradoxes are likely to occur, and if they are, whether they are big enough to be of concern for policy makers. We consider several factors that affect the existence of the green paradox, including long-term extraction costs, short-term extraction capacities, the mix of policy instruments, and potential spatial carbon leakage to countries that have no climate policy. We find that these and other factors can sometimes strengthen, but mostly weaken, the case for concern about the green paradox. Third, we identify the lessons the literature offers for policy makers. We argue that in designing climate policy, policy makers need to consider the supply side of the fossil fuel market.
Article
Full-text available
The countries that have ratified the Kyoto Protocol have pledged to limit global warming by reducing the demand for fossil fuels. But what about supply? If suppliers do not react, demand reductions by a subset of countries are ineffective. They simply depress the world price of carbon and induce the environmental sinners to consume what the Kyoto countries have economized on. Even worse, if suppliers feel threatened by a gradual greening of economic policies in the Kyoto countries that would damage their future prices; they will extract their stocks more rapidly, thus accelerating global warming. The paper discusses the remaining policy options against global warming from an intertemporal supply-side perspective.
Article
Full-text available
Despite its efforts and obligations under the Kyoto Protocol, the EU has not succeeded in even making a dent in the rapidly rising trend of worldwide carbon dioxide emissions. If anything, the trend has accelerated in recent years. In his Thünen Lecture given to the Verein für Socialpolitik in October 2007, the author criticizes the attempt to slow down global warming by means of unilaterally curtailing the demand for fossil fuels and develops an intertemporal supply side approach to the economics of global warming. He advances the hypothesis that the ineffectiveness of demand policies results from anticipation effects on the part of the owners of fossil fuel resources. In addition to the threat of potential ousting by domestic rivals, the threat of falling energy prices (against a modified Hotelling trend) due to greening public policies and increasing participation in worldwide emissions trading systems gives resource owners the incentive to speed up extraction. Feasible policy measures that do not encounter such problematic anticipation effects include the rapid creation of a complete worldwide monopsony for fossil fuels that can dictate quantities rather than having to rely on price signals. Moreover, source taxes on the financial returns of resource owners will provide additional conservation motives; technical measures including afforestation and sequestration may also be a way to reduce the speed of global warming. Copyright 2008 der Autor Journal compilation 2008, Verein für Socialpolitik und Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Article
This article examines how, in a world with incomplete coordination among countries, well-intentioned unilateral environmental policies may actually harm the global environment. This outcome is known as the “Green Paradox.” The incentives for free-riding and the challenge of achieving an effective international environmental agreement are reviewed. I examine the various channels that lead to carbon leakage in static models of open economies, and report some simulation results. This is complemented by a review of the potential for Green Paradox outcomes in dynamic open-economy models in which forward-looking firms exploit an exhaustible resource. I show that border tax adjustments can lead to Green Paradox outcomes. I also discuss priorities for future research on environmental policies in a trading world that lacks a central enforcement agency.
Article
This article examines the possible adverse effects of well-intended climate policies, an outcome known as the Green Paradox. A weak Green Paradox arises if the announcement of a future carbon tax or a sufficiently fast rising carbon tax encourages fossil fuel owners to extract reserves more aggressively, thus exacerbating global warming. We argue that such policies may also encourage more fossil fuel to be locked in the crust of the earth, which can offset the adverse effects of the weak Green Paradox. We show that a subsidy on clean renewables may have similar weak Green Paradox effects. Green welfare (the converse of environmental damages) declines (i.e., the strong Green Paradox) if the beneficial climate effects of locking up more fossil fuel do not outweigh the short-run weak Green Paradox effects. Neither the weak nor the strong Green Paradox occurs for the first-best Pigouvian carbon tax. We also discuss dirty backstops, spatial carbon leakage, and green innovation.
Article
Contemplation of the world’s disappearing supplies of minerals, forests, and other exhaustible assets has led to demands for regulation of their exploitation. The feeling that these products are now too cheap for the good of future generations, that they are being selfishly exploited at too rapid a rate, and that in consequence of their excessive cheapness they are being produced and consumed wastefully has given rise to the conservation movement. The method ordinarily proposed to stop the wholesale devastation of irreplaceable natural resources, or of natural resources replaceable only with difficulty and long delay, is to forbid production at certain times and in certain regions or to hamper production by insisting that obsolete and inefficient methods be continued. The prohibitions against oil and mineral development and cutting timber on certain government lands have this justification, as have also closed seasons for fish and game and statutes forbidding certain highly efficient means of catching fish. Taxation would be a more economic method than publicly ordained inefficiency in the case of purely commercial activities such as mining and fishing for profit, if not also for sport fishing. However, the opposition of those who are making the profits, with the apathy of everyone else, is usually sufficient to prevent the diversion into the public treasury of any considerable part of the proceeds of the exploitation of natural recources.
Article
It is shown that a surprise increase in the current price (due to, say, a change in the tariff rate) may cause a resource firm to increase or decrease its current rate of extraction, depending on its expectation of future changes in the price. The key parameters are the rate of price change in the absence of the surprise shock, the rate of interest, and the rate of change of the tax rates. Copyright 1985 by Blackwell Publishers Ltd/University of Adelaide and Flinders University of South Australia