ArticlePDF Available

Egalitarianism in young children

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Human social interaction is strongly shaped by other-regarding preferences. These preferences are key for a unique aspect of human sociality – large scale cooperation with genetic strangers – but little is known about their developmental roots. We show here that young children’s other-regarding preferences assume a particular form – inequality aversion – that develops strongly between the ages of 3 and 8. At age 3-4, the overwhelming majority of children behave selfishly, while the vast majority at age 7-8 prefers resource allocations that remove advantageous or disadvantageous inequality. Moreover, inequality aversion is strongly shaped by parochialism, a preference for favouring the members of one’s own social group. These results indicate that human egalitarianism and parochialism have deep developmental roots, and the simultaneous emergence of altruistic sharing and parochialism during childhood is intriguing in view of recent evolutionary theories which predict that the same evolutionary process jointly drives both human altruism and parochialism.
Content may be subject to copyright.
ARTICLES
Egalitarianism in young children
Ernst Fehr
1,2
, Helen Bernhard
1
& Bettina Rockenbach
3
Human social interaction is strongly shaped by other-regarding preferences, that is, a concern for the welfare of others.
These preferences are important for a unique aspect of human sociality—large scale cooperation with genetic strangers—
but little is known about their developmental roots. Here we show that young children’s other-regarding preferences assume
a particular form, inequality aversion that develops strongly between the ages of 3 and 8. At age 3
4, the overwhelming
majority of children behave selfishly, whereas most children at age 7
8 prefer resource allocations that remove
advantageous or disadvantageous inequality. Moreover, inequality aversion is strongly shaped by parochialism, a preference
for favouring the members of one’s own social group. These results indicate that human egalitarianism and parochialism
have deep developmental roots, and the simultaneous emergence of altruistic sharing and parochialism during childhood is
intriguing in view of recent evolutionary theories which predict that the same evolutionary process jointly drives both human
altruism and parochialism.
Other-regarding preferences are decisive for the human ability to
achieve and maintain cooperation in large groups of genetic stran-
gers
1,2
. If an individual cares for the welfare of other group members,
he or she is more likely to refrain from free-riding in cooperative
projects. Similarly, if an individual dislikes the free-riding of others—
because it is associated with inequality
3–5
or because it represents a
norm violation
6
—the individual is more likely to punish free-
riders
7–9
. This punishment then constitutes an incentive for potential
free-riders to cooperate. Other-regarding preferences are also
important in public life and politics
10
and they powerfully amplify
reputational incentives in strategic interactions, thus contributing to
the cooperation-enhancing force of reputation opportunities
11–14
.
The developmental origins and proximate mechanisms behind
other-regarding preferences are not well understood, however, despite
recent progress
15–22
. Because we know little about when young chil-
dren start to take the welfare of others into account, we conducted
experiments with 229 young, genetically unrelated, Swiss children
(127 girls and 102 boys) between the ages of 3 and 8. An understanding
of the development of other-regarding preferences in children may
enable us to gain deeper insights into the proximate and ultimate
sources of species differences in preferences and cooperation. The
study of children’s preferences is also of particular interest in light
of recent experiments in non-human primates
23–27
, allowing a more
direct comparison between human and non-human primates.
Experiments with non-human primates have, for example, demon-
strated that chimpanzees show little willingness to provide food to a
familiar conspecific in situations where they could do so with no or
only a small cost
23,24,27
. In view of this result, it is interesting to study
whether (and if so, when) children are willing to provide valuable
resources to their partners. In this way, the large species differences
in cooperation between humans and non-human primates can be
more directly traced back to species differences in other-regarding
preferences.
Investigation of the development of moral judgment
28
and proso-
cial behaviour
29–35
is a rich tradition in psychology, but there is a
surprising lack of studies that isolate the development of other-
regarding preferences from the development of other forms of
prosocial behaviour. The experimental study of other-regarding pre-
ferences in humans involves the conduct of one-shot experiments
with anonymous interaction partners because the behaviour in non-
anonymous face-to-face interactions, or in repeated interactions
with the same partner, can easily be affected by selfish motives. A
subject could, for example, behave prosocially because of the expecta-
tion of future benefits from the partner that accrue as a result of
prosocial behaviour in the current interaction. Selfish motives could
therefore drive prosocial behaviours such as sharing a valuable
resource in non-anonymous face-to-face interactions or in repeated
interactions between the experimental subjects. Measuring other-
regarding preferences without such confounds thus requires the
conduct of anonymous one-shot experiments.
Testing for inequality aversion in children
For this reason, we conducted experiments with young children that
enabled us to measure other-regarding preferences such as inequality
aversion. In the context of our experiments, inequality aversion pre-
vails if subjects prefer allocations that reduce the inequality between
themselves and their partner, regardless of whether the inequality is
to their advantage or disadvantage
3
.
Each subject participated in the three treatments described below
and was paired with one other anonymous partner in each treatment.
Each treatment condition was explained in detail to the decision
maker so that we could be sure that the child had completely under-
stood the experiment and the consequences of the different choices
(see Methods and Supplementary Methods). In all treatments, the
decision maker allocated units of sweets (smarties, jellybabies or
fizzers) to himself and/or to the partner. In the ‘prosocial’ treatment,
which was inspired by recent experiments with chimpanzees
23,24
, the
subject could choose between the allocation (1,1)—that is, 1 for
himself, 1 for partner—and the allocation (1,0). This treatment mea-
sures some elementary form of prosociality, because by choosing
(1,1) the subject can at no cost to himself deliver a benefit to the
partner and, thus, avoid advantageous inequality. In principle, the
choice of (1,1) can be driven by the equality motive
3
or by a motive to
increase the partner’s payoff or both parties joint payoff
36
. Economic
self-interest is not involved in the prosocial game because the
decision maker receives one unit regardless of which choice he makes.
It is therefore also possible that a selfish individual who does not care
about the partner’s payoff will choose (1,1). In fact, because there is
1
University of Zurich, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, Blumlisalpstrasse 10, CH-8006 Zurich, Switzerland.
2
Collegium Helveticum, Schmelzbergstrasse 25, CH-8092
Zurich, Switzerland.
3
University of Erfurt, Nordha
¨use
r Straße 63, D-99089 Erfurt, Germany.
Vol 454
|
28 August 2008
|
doi:10.1038/nature07155
1079
©2008
Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
no reason for a selfish individual to make either choice, a population
of self-interested individuals would choose (1,1) in 50% of the cases.
For this reason, evidence for other-regarding behaviour in the pro-
social game requires that the population of children choose (1,1)
significantly above 50% frequency.
In the ‘envy’ treatment, the subject could choose between (1,1) and
(1,2). Here again, it is possible to deliver a benefit to the partner at no
cost, but the choice (1,2) leads to disadvantageous inequality for the
decision maker. Thus, if an individual just wants to increase the part-
ner’s or the joint payoff, he should choose (1,1) in the prosocial
treatment and (1,2) in the envy treatment. In contrast, if the equality
motive drives behaviour in these two conditions, the subject chooses
(1,1) in both treatments, thus avoiding the unequal allocations (1,0) in
the prosocial treatment and (1,2) in the envy treatment. However, as
in the prosocial treatment, a purely selfish individual has no reason to
make either choice in the envy treatment. For this reason, evidence for
the equality motive in the envy game again requires that the popu-
lation of children choose (1,1) significantly above 50% frequency.
In a third condition, the ‘sharing’ treatment, the subject could
choose between (1,1) and (2,0). This treatment measures a strong
form of inequality aversion because the provision of a benefit for the
partner is costly for the subject. Selfish children should therefore
never make the egalitarian choice in this treatment, indicating that
the choice of (1,1) unambiguously suggests an other-regarding pref-
erence. The sharing treatment also enables us to measure altruism as
defined by evolutionary biology because sharing implies a costly
transfer of a valued resource to another individual.
In addition to these treatments, we also implemented an ingroup
and an outgroup condition ‘across subjects’. In the ingroup con-
dition, the partner came from the same playschool, kindergarten or
school, whereas the partner came from another playschool, kinder-
garten or school in the outgroup condition. The rationale for the
outgroup condition is provided by evidence and theory indicating
that parochialism strongly shapes adult human altruism
37–39
, and that
the same evolutionary process might determine the development of
both human altruism and parochialism
40
.
From self-interest to inequality aversion
Among the 3–4-yr-old children, most behaved selfishly in the
ingroup condition of the sharing game because only 8.7% of the
children were willing to share (Fig. 1). The fact that the frequency
of (1,1) choices did not differ significantly from 50% in the prosocial
game and in the envy game further supports the low incidence of
other-regarding preferences at this age (binomial test; P 5 0.21 for
the prosocial game, P 5 0.68 for the envy game; n 5 23). The preval-
ence of selfish behaviour in the sharing game decreased slightly for
5–6-yr-old children, but 78% were still not willing to share at this age.
Also, as with the 3–4-yr-old children, the frequency of egalitarian
choices in the prosocial and the envy game for the 5–6-yr-olds was
not significantly different from 50% (binomial test; P 5 0.24 for the
prosocial game, P 5 0.41 for the envy game; n 5 36). A substantially
different picture emerged, however, for children at ages 7–8 (Fig. 1):
45% of them showed sharing behaviour, and we also found strong
evidence for other-regarding preferences in the other two games. Of
the 7–8-yr-olds, 78% preferred the egalitarian allocation in the pro-
social game, refuting the null hypothesis of random choices (bino-
mial test, P , 0.001, n 5 56). Similarly, an overwhelming majority
(80%) preferred the egalitarian alternative in the envy game at this
age (binomial test, P , 0.001, n 5 56).
Taken together, the behavioural patterns across all three games sug-
gest that children at age 3–4 show little willingness to share resources
but a non-negligible percentage of the children is willing to make
choices that benefit the recipient if it is not costly. After this age,
other-regarding preferences develop, which take the form of inequality
aversion instead of a simple preference for increasing the partner’s or
the joint payoff. If the motive to increase the partner’s or the joint
payoff were to drive the children’s other-regarding preferences, they
would have then chosen the alternative (1,2) in the envy game. In fact,
however, most of the children at age 7–8 preferred the egalitarian
allocation.
Therefore, if we pool the children’s choices across the various
games, we find that both strongly and weakly egalitarian choices
show a large increase with age (Fig. 2, Supplementary Fig. 3 and
Supplementary Table 1). Egalitarianism, which is characterized by
a (1,1) choice both in the prosocial and the envy game (red columns
in Fig. 2), increases from 21% at age 3–4 to 33% at age 5–6, whereas
60% prefer the egalitarian allocation in both games at age 7–8. The
percentage of egalitarian choices at age 7–8 significantly differs from
an independent random choice in each of both games (binomial test,
P , 0.0001, n 5 56). If the children had made independent, random
choices, only 25% of them would have chosen (1,1) in both the
prosocial and the envy game. If we pool the children’s choices in
all three games, the percentage of children who preferred the egal-
itarian allocation in all three games increases from 4% at age 3–4 to
30% at age 7–8 (Fig. 2). Thus, among those children who choose the
egalitarian allocation in the prosocial and the envy game at age 7–8,
roughly 50% share resources in the sharing game. The other 50%
choose the selfish allocation (2,0) in the sharing game.
It is notable that the share of subjects who maximize the partner’s
payoff by choosing both (1,1) in the prosocial game and (1,2) in the
envy game (blue columns in Fig. 2) decreases sharply from 43% at age
3–4 to 16% at age 7–8. Furthermore, the percentage of subjects who
maximize the partner’s payoff in all three games is only roughly 5%
and does not change much with age. The across-game perspective
also enables us to identify a third type of subject whom we call
‘spiteful’ because they minimize the partner’s payoff in all three
games. The share of spiteful subjects is 22% at age 3–4 and 5–6 and
decreases slightly to 14% at age 7–8, a percentage that is similar to the
relative share of spiteful subjects observed in adult subject pools
41,42
.
Parochial egalitarianism
Parochial tendencies affected children’s choices in all three treat-
ments, and these tendencies are pervasive in the sharing and prosocial
0
20
40
60
80
100
3–4
Age
Prosocial game: (1,1) versus (1,0)
Envy game: (1,1) versus (1,2)
Sharing game: (1,1) versus (2,0)
Percentage of egalitarian choices
5–6 7–8
Figure 1
|
The relative frequency of egalitarian choices across all ingroup
treatments.
In these treatments, the decision maker’s choice determines the
resources of an ingroup partner. The frequency of egalitarian choices
strongly increases with age across all three ingroup treatments, and most
children prefer equality at age 7–8 in the prosocial and the envy game.
However, if equality is costly for the children, they choose the egalitarian
allocation less frequently—as indicated by the behaviour in the sharing
game—and at age 3–4, self-interested choices dominate almost completely.
ARTICLES NATURE
|
Vol 454
|
28 August 2008
1080
©2008
Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
games (Fig. 3). The egalitarian choice is roughly 15%–20% more
likely in the prosocial game if the partner is an ingroup member
(Fig. 3a). This difference is highly significant (ingroup dummy in
probit regression, P 5 0.004, z 5 2.92, n 5 229) and a similar
ingroup–outgroup gap prevails across all ages. The largest difference
was found in the sharing game (Fig. 3b), where we observed a strong
increase in the frequency of egalitarian choices if the partner was from
the ingroup (age effect in probit regression, P 5 0.001, z 5 3.33,
n 5 115), whereas the children’s willingness to share even slightly
declined with age in the outgroup condition although this was not
significant (age effect in probit regression, P 5 0.123, z 521.54,
n 5 114). We did observe, however, a highly significant interaction
effect between age and outgroup condition (probit regression,
P , 0.001, z 5 3.50, n 5 229), indicating that the difference between
sharing in the ingroup and outgroup conditions strongly increases
with age. Thus, the children’s altruism and parochialism emerges
simultaneously between the ages of 3 and 8 and is associated with a
very strong ingroup bias at age 7–8 (probit regression, P , 0.001,
z 5 3.58, b 5 105), with very little willingness to share with an out-
group member (only 12% of the children shared in the outgroup
condition at this age).
The prevalence of egalitarian choices in the envy game developed
earlier in the outgroup condition, where the children at age 5–6
already overwhelmingly favour the (1,1) allocation (Fig. 3c). The
willingness to remove disadvantageous inequality towards ingroup
members becomes so prevalent at age 7–8 that an ingroup–outgroup
gap no longer exists. However, averaging across gender hides an
important gender effect in the envy game: boys show much stronger
parochial tendencies than girls do because boys seem to be much less
averse against disadvantageous inequality if the partner is an ingroup
member (Fig. 4a; outgroup dummy in probit regression controlling
for age, P 5 0.001, z 5 3.23, n 5 102). In contrast, girls do not differ-
entiate in their choices between ingroup and outgroup partners
(Fig. 4b; outgroup dummy in probit regression controlling for age,
P 5 0.663, z 520.44, n 5 127), but, like boys, they also show an
increasing trend towards egalitarian choices in the envy game as they
become older.
Birth order and sibling effects
We find a strong ‘only child’ and ‘youngest child’ effect in the sharing
game. Children without siblings showed much more costly sharing
behaviour than children with siblings. On average, children without
siblings were 28% more likely to share than children with siblings—a
highly significant difference (probit regression, P 5 0.006, z 5 2.75,
n 5 197) that also exists if we control for income effects (see
Supplementary Data). With increasing age, however, the difference
between children with and without siblings decreases slightly, as
indicated by an interaction effect between ‘child without siblings’
and ‘age’ in a probit regression (P 5 0.022, z 522.29, n 5 197).
Among the children with siblings, we found that—regardless of
age—the youngest children in a family were 17% less willing to share
than children with younger siblings (probit regression controlling for
age, P 5 0.007, z 5 2.71, n 5 172). Thus, it seems that the mere exist-
ence of siblings or birth order may have an important role in deter-
mining altruistic behaviours. Further analyses and interpretation of
the effects of birth order and other demographic and psychological
characteristics can be found in the Supplementary Information.
0
20
40
60
80
100
Prosocial game:
(1,1) versus (1,0)
a
0
20
40
60
80
100
Sharing game:
(1,1) versus (2,0)
b
0
20
40
60
80
100
Envy game:
(1,1) versus (1,2)
c
Percentage of egalitarian choices
Percentage of egalitarian choices
Percentage of egalitarian choices
3–4
Age
Age Age
5–6 7–8
3–4 5–6 7–8 3–4 5–6 7–8
Figure 3
|
Egalitarian choices across ingroup and outgroup conditions.
Grey dashed lines denote when the partner was an ingroup member; black
solid lines represent when the partner was an outgroup member (
ac). a,In
the prosocial game, the children remove inequality that favours themselves
more often if the partner is an ingroup member.
b, Egalitarian choices
slightly decrease over time in the sharing game (with very little sharing at age
7–8) if the partner is an outgroup member, whereas sharing with ingroup
members strongly increases with age, providing strong evidence for
parochial altruism in children.
c, In the envy game, children develop a
preference for equality much earlier if the partner is an outgroup member
but eventually the aversion against disadvantageous inequality with regard
to ingroup members becomes so strong that ingroup–outgroup differences
are small.
4%
14%
30%
17%
19%
30%
4%
6%
5%
39%
22%
11%
22%
22%
14%
0
20
40
60
80
100
Strongly egalitarian Weakly egalitarian
Strongly generous Weakly generous
Spiteful
3–4
Age
5–6 7–8
Percentage of relative frequency
Figure 2
|
Behavioural types in the ingroup condition. The figure classifies
subjects according to their behaviour in all three games, that is, in the
prosocial game ((1,1) versus (1,0)), the sharing game ((1,1) versus (2,0)), and
the envy game ((1,1) versus (1,2)). Strongly egalitarian subjects choose the
egalitarian allocation in all three games. Weakly egalitarian subjects choose
the egalitarian allocation only in the prosocial and the envy games, but not in
the sharing game, where egalitarian behaviour is costly. Strongly generous
subjects choose the allocation that maximizes the partner’s payoff in all three
games. Weakly generous subjects maximize the partner’s payoff only in the
prosocial and the envy games, but not in the sharing game, where generous
behaviour is costly. Spiteful subjects choose the allocation that minimizes
the partner’s payoff in all three games. The percentage of egalitarian subjects
increases steeply with age, whereas the share of generous subjects declines.
Moreover, most subjects who are willing to share at age 7–8 belong to the
egalitarian and not to the generous type of subjects.
NATURE
|
Vol 454
|
28 August 2008 ARTICLES
1081
©2008
Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
Discussion
The development of inequality aversion relatively early in childhood
is particularly interesting in the light of ethnographic evidence that
suggests that there is a strong role of egalitarian ‘instincts’ in human
evolutionary history. There is considerable ethnographic evidence
that egalitarian concerns have shaped many human small-scale soci-
eties
43,44
. For example, sharing of large hunted game across families
seems to have been the rule rather than the exception in small-scale
societies, and egalitarian sentiments also play a part in contemporary
large-scale societies
4,5
. The important role of egalitarian sentiments in
human evolutionary history raises the possibility that there may have
been cultural or even genetic transmission that favours egalitarian
behaviours. In fact, recent evidence from behavioural genetics sug-
gests that egalitarian behaviour in the ultimatum game has a genetic
component
45
.
The simultaneous development of altruistic behaviour and paro-
chialism and the gender differences in parochialism are also interest-
ing in view of evolutionary theories that predict that the same
evolutionary process
40
jointly determines human altruism and paro-
chialism, meaning that these traits co-evolve in such a way that either
both or neither of them evolves. According to the theory, the driving
force behind this evolutionary process is frequent intergroup
conflict. Because mainly males were involved in intergroup fights, it
seems possible that evolution favoured a gender bias in parochialism.
In fact, a payoff advantage relative to the outgroup may have been
particularly advantageous for males because it strengthened the
ingroup’s position in intergroup conflicts. Males bore the main cost
of intergroup conflict in terms of injuries and deaths and often gained
more than females in the case of victory because of the increase in the
pool of potential mating partners
46
. Thus, evolution may have
favoured a greater sensitivity in males for payoff advantages relative
to outgroup members. In view of this prediction, we find it notable
that boys showed a much stronger ingroup bias than girls in the envy
game.
These potential evolutionary roots of human egalitarianism and
parochialism do not preclude culture and socialization from playing
an important part in other-regarding preferences; they may even be a
main factor in their evolution
2,47
. As the children move from an
informal playgroup to kindergarten and then on to formal schools,
they may learn that equality is a rule that the authorities (for example,
the teachers) endorse. Thus, the children probably acquire some of
the normative rules of the society which surrounds them during the
age period on which we focused
30
. In this context, it is interesting that
the motive to increase the partner’s payoff declined strongly between
ages 3 and 8, whereas egalitarian behaviour strongly increased in this
age period (Fig. 2), providing a hint about the content of the norm-
ative rule they acquired. The children may also become more sens-
itive with regard to the opinions of others about themselves, a
cognition which requires the ability to understand that one’s actions
affect what other people believe about oneself. Recent evidence indi-
cates that adult humans care even about what anonymous others may
think about them
48,49
. Theory-of-mind and perspective-taking abil-
ities are certainly conducive to such social cognitions. Therefore, if
older children care about what anonymous others think about them,
they may be more prone to behave in a normatively appropriate way
because—owing to their age—they are more likely to have theory-of-
mind and perspective-taking abilities
30,50
.
Our results also indicate that important inter-species differences
occur in other-regarding preferences when compared to the patterns
observed in chimpanzees
23,24,27
and marmosets
26
. In the prosocial
game, adult chimpanzees, who could allocate food in a face-to-face
interaction to a familiar recipient, did not show a significant pref-
erence for the (1,1) choice
23,24,27
, whereas most of the children
develop a preference for the egalitarian choice in this game even
though their partner is anonymous. Furthermore, as the sharing
game indicates, many children at age 7–8 are also willing to share
with an anonymous ingroup member. The facts in the envy game also
contrast sharply with experimental findings in both chimpanzees and
marmosets. The children developed a widespread aversion against
disadvantageous inequality, whereas chimpanzees have been shown
to be unwilling to take actions to remove inequality between them-
selves and a conspecific
24
, and marmosets even tend to take actions
that generate disadvantageous inequality for themselves if the action
provides food for the partner
26
. In view of the decisive role of other-
regarding preferences for a species ability to achieve large-scale coop-
eration, the observed inter-species differences are probably import-
ant in explaining why humans are so exceptionally cooperative.
METHODS SUMMARY
Each child played all three games against anonymous partners. To avoid satiation
effects, three different currencies (smarties, jellybabies and fizzers) were used in
randomized order in the three games. In each game, subjects had two mutually
exclusive choices that were represented with two cardboards; we drew two circles
with arrows on each (see Supplementary Fig. 1). One arrow pointed to the
decision maker, illustrating that the sweets in that circle goes to him or her,
whereas the other arrow pointed to a group photo which had been made earlier.
In the ingroup condition, the group photo showed the members of the child’s
playgroup, kindergarten or school, whereas it showed the members of a different
playgroup, kindergarten or school in the outgroup condition. The photos were
used to communicate the partner’s ingroup or outgroup status to the children in
the game. Depending on whether the ingroup or the outgroup condition applied,
the decision maker was told that the sweet(s) in the other circle (if there were any
0
20
40
60
80
100
a
0
20
40
60
80
100
b
Percentage of egalitarian choicesPercentage of egalitarian choices
A
g
e
3–4 5–6 7–8
Figure 4
|
Gender differences in parochial egalitarianism in the envy game
where the child could choose between (1,1) and (1,2). a
, b, The propensity
of boys (
a) and girls (b) for egalitarian choices in the ingroup (grey dashed
line) and outgroup (black solid line) condition. The difference between
ingroup and outgroup condition is large for boys but virtually absent
for girls.
ARTICLES NATURE
|
Vol 454
|
28 August 2008
1082
©2008
Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
in that circle) would be given to one of the children on the ingroup photo or
outgroup photo, respectively. If there was no sweet in the circle, it was made clear
to the child that the choice of the corresponding cardboard indicates that the
partner would receive nothing. We also controlled for the spatial assignment of
the different alternative. In the prosocial game, for example (shown in
Supplementary Fig. 1), the alternative (1,1) was randomly assigned to the left
or right side. Thus, preferences for left or right cannot explain any of our find-
ings. We also made it clear to the children that neither other children nor their
parents or teachers will be informed about their decisions (see Supplementary
Methods).
Full Methods and any associated references are available in the online version of
the paper at www.nature.com/nature.
Received 12 March; accepted 6 June 2008.
1. Bowles, S. Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions and Evolution 93
126 (Princeton
Univ. Press, 2004).
2. Boyd, R. T. & Richerson, P. The Origin and Evolution of Cultures (Oxford Univ. Press,
2005).
3. Fehr, E. & Schmidt, K. M. A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Q. J.
Econ. 114, 817
868 (1999).
4. Fowler, J. H., Johnson, T. & Smirnov, O. Human behaviour: Egalitarian motive and
altruistic punishment. Nature 433, E1 (2007).
5. Dawes, C. T. et al. Egalitarian motives in humans. Nature 446, 794
796 (2007).
6. Falk, A. & Fischbacher, U. A theory of reciprocity. Games Econ. Behav. 54, 293
315
(2006).
7. Fehr, E. & Ga
¨
chter, S. Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415, 137
140
(2002).
8. Gu¨rerk, O., Irlenbusch, B. & Rockenbach, B. The competitive advantage of
sanctioning institutions. Science 312, 108
111 (2006).
9. Hauert, C. et al. Via freedom to coercion: The emergence of costly punishment.
Science 316, 1905
1907 (2007).
10. Fong, C., Bowles, S. & Gintis, H. in Handbook on the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity,
and Altruism (eds Kolm, S.-C. & Ythier, J. M.) (Elsevier, 2006).
11. Milinski, M., Semmann, D. & Krambeck, H. J. Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy
of the commons’. Nature 415, 424
426 (2002).
12. Brown, M., Falk, A. & Fehr, E. Relational contracts and the nature of market
interactions. Econometrica 72, 747
780 (2004).
13. Nowak, M. A. & Sigmund, K. Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature 437,
1291
1298 (2005).
14. Rockenbach, B. & Milinski, M. The efficient interaction of indirect reciprocity and
costly punishment. Nature 444, 718
723 (2006).
15. Harbaugh, W. T. & Krause, K. Children’s altruism in public good and dictator
experiments. Econ. Inq. 38, 95
109 (2000).
16. de Quervain, D. J.-F. et al. The neural basis of altruistic punishment. Science 305,
1254
1258 (2004).
17. Sutter, M. Outcomes versus intentions: On the nature of fair behavior and its
development with age. J. Econ. Psychol. 28, 69
78 (2007).
18. Sutter, M. & Kocher, M. G. Trust and trustworthiness across different age groups.
Games Econ. Behav. 59, 364
382 (2007).
19. Benenson, J. F., Pascoe, J. & Radmore, N. Children’s altruistic behavior in the
dictator game. Evol. Hum. Behav. 28, 168
175 (2007).
20. Fliessbach, K. et al. Social comparison affects reward-related brain activity in the
human ventral striatum. Science 318, 1305
1308 (2007).
21. Cesarini, D. et al. Heritability of cooperative behavior in the trust game. Proc. Natl
Acad. Sci. USA 105, 3721
3726 (2008).
22. Ellingsen, T. & Johannesson, M. Anticipated verbal feedback induces altruistic
behavior. Evol. Hum. Behav. 29, 100
105 (2008).
23. Silk, J. B. et al. Chimpanzees are indifferent to the welfare of unrelated group
members. Nature 437, 1357
1359 (2005).
24. Jensen, K., Hare, B., Call, J. & Tomasello, M. What’s in it for me? Self-regard
precludes altruism and spite in chimpanzees. Proc. Biol. Sci. 273, 1013
1021 (2006).
25. Jensen, K., Call, J. & Tomasello, M. Chimpanzees are rational maximizers in an
ultimatum game. Science 318, 107
109 (2007).
26. Burkart, J. M., Fehr, E., Efferson, C. & van Schaik, C. P. Other-regarding preferences
in a non-human primate: Common marmosets provision food altruistically. Proc.
Natl Acad. Sci. USA 104, 19762
19766 (2007).
27. Vonk, J. et al. Chimpanzees do not take advantage of very low cost opportunities
to deliver food to unrelated group members. Anim. Behav. 75, 1757
1770 (2008).
28. Turiel, E. in Handbook of Child Psychology Vol. 3 (eds Damon, W. & Eisenberg, N.)
863
932 (Wiley and Sons, 1998).
29. Knight, G. P. & Kagan, S. Development of prosocial and competitive behaviors in
anglo-american and mexican-american children. Child Dev. 48, 1385
1394
(1977).
30. Eisenberg, N. & Mussen, P. H. The Roots of Prosocial Behavior in Children
(Cambridge Univ. Press, 1989).
31. Thompson, C., Barresi, J. & Moore, C. The development of future-oriented
prudence and altruism in preschoolers. Cogn. Dev. 12, 199
212 (1997).
32. Eisenberg, N. & Fabes, R. A. in Handbook of Child Psychology Vol. 3 (eds Damon, W.
& Eisenberg, N.) 701
778 (Wiley and Sons, 1998).
33. Murnigham, J. K. Ultimatum bargaining by children and adults. J. Econ. Psychol. 19,
415
445 (1998).
34. Warneken, F. & Tomasello, M. Altruistic helping in human infants and young
chimpanzees. Science 311, 1301
1303 (2006).
35. Warneken, F. et al. Spontaneous altruism by chimpanzees and young children.
PLoS Biol. 5, e184 (2007).
36. Charness, G. & Rabin, M. Understanding social preferences with simple tests.
Q. J. Econ. 117, 817
869 (2002).
37. Goette, L., Huffman, D. & Meier, S. The impact of group membership on
cooperation and norm enforcement: Evidence using random assignment to real
social groups. Am. Econ. Rev. 96, 212
216 (2006).
38. Bernhard, H., Fischbacher, U. & Fehr, E. Parochial altruism in humans. Nature 442,
912
915 (2006).
39. Shinada, M., Yamagishi, T. & Ohmura, Y. False friends are worse than bitter
enemies: ‘‘Altruistic’’ punishment of in-group members. Evol. Hum. Behav. 25,
379
393 (2004).
40. Choi, J. K. & Bowles, S. The coevolution of parochial altruism and war. Science 318,
636
640 (2007).
41. Van Lange, P. A. M. The pursuit of joint outcomes and equality in outcomes: An
integrative model of social value orientation. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 77, 337
349
(1999).
42. Falk, A., Fehr, E. & Fischbacher, U. Driving forces behind informal sanctions.
Econometrica 73, 2017
2030 (2005).
43. Boehm, C. Egalitarian behavior and reverse dominance hierachy. Curr. Anthropol.
34, 227
254 (1993).
44. Boehm, C. Impact of the human egalitarian syndrome on darwinian selection
mechanics. Am. Nat. 150, S100
S121 (1997).
45. Wallace, B., Cesarini, D., Lichtenstein, P. & Johannesson, M. Heritability of
ultimatum game responder behavior. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 104, 15631
15634
(2007).
46. Chagnon, N. A. Life histories, blood revenge, and warfare in a tribal population.
Science 239, 985
992 (1988).
47. Henrich, J. et al. ‘‘Economic man’’ in cross-cultural perspective: behavioral
experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behav. Brain Sci. 28, 795
855 (2005).
48. Dana, J., Cain, D. M. & Dawes, R. M. What you don’t know won’t hurt me: Costly
(but quiet) exit in dictator games. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 100, 193
201
(2006).
49. Ellingsen, T. & Johannesson, M. Paying respect. J. Econ. Perspect. 21, 135
149
(2007).
50. Wellman, H. M., Cross, D. & Watson, J. Meta-analysis of theory-of-mind
development: The truth about false belief. Child Dev. 72, 655
684 (2001).
Supplementary Information is linked to the online version of the paper at
www.nature.com/nature.
Acknowledgements This paper is part of the Research Priority Program
‘Foundations of Human Social Behaviour—Altruism versus Egoism’ at the
University of Zurich and of the Swiss National Competence Center in research on
affective sciences, which is financed by the Swiss National Science Foundation. We
also thank N. Kessler for her research assistance during the conduct of the
experiments.
Author Information Reprints and permissions information is available at
www.nature.com/reprints. Correspondence and requests for materials should be
addressed to E.F. (efehr@iew.uzh.ch) or B.R. (bettina.rockenbach@uni-erfurt.de).
NATURE
|
Vol 454
|
28 August 2008 ARTICLES
1083
©2008
Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
METHODS
Subjects. We recruited young children (3–8-yr-old) from playschools, kinder-
gartens and first grades for our experiments. We received permission for the
experiments from the school president, the school board, the teachers and the
parents. Of the parents that we asked, 92% agreed so that a total of 229 children
participated in the study: 62 children from playschools, 75 from kindergartens
and 92 children from grade one. The children live in Rapperswil-Jona, a small
city in the canton of St Gallen, Switzerland. Two women aged between 20 and 25
conducted the experiment. The experimental instructions are reproduced in the
Supplementary Information.
Experimental procedures. Each child played the prosocial game, the envy game
and the sharing game against anonymous partners. The order of the games was
counterbalanced across subjects. The partners came either from the ingroup
(same playschool, kindergarten or school) or from an outgroup (a different
playschool, kindergarten or school).
Payoffs. We needed an experimental currency desirable for the younger and
older children in our sample. Therefore we decided to use various sweets. To
avoid satiation effects, a different currency was used in each of the three games
(smarties, jellybabies or fizzers), and these were randomized across games. Before
the experiment started, we asked each child whether he or she likes those sweets
(all of them did). At the end of all three treatments we asked each child whether
they liked all three sweets the same or whether they liked one more than the
other. If they indicated that they liked some of the sweets more than the others we
asked which they liked the most and least (see Supplementary Information). The
average ‘liking rates’ of the different currencies were identical. Moreover, we
asked the parents to rate on a 7-point scale how much their children value the
sweets and their answers showed that our currencies provide equally strong
incentives for the children across all ages.
The choice situation. To ensure that the children could easily understand the
choice problem, we used a set up that made the two available choices transparent.
The two mutually exclusive choices were represented with two cardboards; we
drew two circles with arrows on each (see Supplementary Fig. 1). One arrow
pointed to the decision maker, illustrating that the sweet in that circle goes to him
or her, whereas the other arrow pointed to a group photo which had been made
earlier. In the ingroup condition, the group photo showed the members of the
child’s playgroup, kindergarten or school, whereas it showed the members of a
different playgroup, kindergarten or school in the outgroup condition. The
photos were used to communicate the partner’s ingroup or outgroup status to
the children in the game. Depending on whether the ingroup or the outgroup
condition applied, the decision maker was told that the sweet(s) in the other
circle (if there were any in that circle) would be given to one of the children on the
ingroup photo or outgroup photo, respectively. If there was no sweet in the
circle, it was made clear to the child that the choice of the corresponding card-
board implies that the partner would receive nothing. The advantage of this
design is that the same procedure can be used for the ingroup and the outgroup
condition, and that the children can grasp the partner’s ingroup or outgroup
status very easily. In fact, many children across all ages immediately expressed
their knowledge of the children on the photo, that is, they spontaneously indi-
cated that they knew or did not know the children in the photo. On the basis of
this spontaneous insight, it was then easy to explain that the partner will be a
member of the child’s group or the member of another group.
We also controlled for the spatial assignment of the different alternatives. In
the prosocial game, for example, which is shown in Supplementary Fig. 1
(Supplementary Methods), the alternative (1,1) was randomly assigned to be
on the left or the right side. Thus, preferences for left or right cannot explain any
of our findings. We also made it clear to the children that neither other children
nor their parents/teachers would be informed about their decisions.
Before a child played a game we ensured that he or she fully understood the
game situation (that is, the available choices, the implications of different choices
for the allocation of currencies for ‘self’ and ‘partner’, the partner’s ingroup–
outgroup status, and so on). The subjects had to answer several questions for this
purpose (Supplementary Methods). Only three children had problems in
answering these questions, which shows that we successfully implemented the
three games even for the youngest participants in the sample. The three children
who could not answer correctly were excluded from the data analyses (229 is the
number of children who correctly answered the questions). Once the children
had answered the questions correctly, they were asked to make a decision in the
first game before the second game was presented and explained. Because we
ensured that the children understood the payoff implications of the two available
choices very well and because it was clear that the choices were mutually exclusive
(that is, only one cardboard could be chosen), the children did not make mis-
takes while choosing, for example, by indicating that they wanted to choose both
cardboards. Nor did any children reverse their opinion during the choice pro-
cess, that is, children who first chose one cardboard but later switched to the
other.
Questionnaire. After all children had participated in the experiment we sent the
parents a questionnaire in which we asked them about characteristics of their
child, such as whether he or she can easily imagine how other children feel
(‘empathy’), whether there are siblings, the birth order, who primarily cares
for the child during the day, the number of regular playmates, and so on. We
sent 198 questionnaires to the parents and 161 questionnaires were sent back.
The questionnaire is reprinted in the Supplementary Information.
doi:10.1038/nature07155
©2008
Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
... En lo que tiene que ver con la relación entre la distribución y las diferencias de género en niños, los estudios pueden ser clasificados en dos grandes grupos: los que postulan a la distribución como una actividad de primera persona, es decir, la que implican interés propio del niño y las que no, es decir, aquellas distribuciones en las que el niño participa como un juez imparcial, las de tercera persona. Es necesario especificar que se habla de actividades de primera persona frente a la de tercera persona y no de actividad costosa frente a actividad no costosa, porque una actividad en la que el niño es objeto de la distribución (primera persona) puede ser no costosa, como en los casos en que se examina la prosocialidad (Fehr et al, 2008(Fehr et al, y 2013House et al, 2012;2013ay 2013b. 1 Además de estas dos grandes distinciones, se hace necesario atender a aspectos metodológicos que influyen de manera decisiva en los resultados presentados. A manera de ejemplo, se podría enunciar si los personajes beneficiarios de la distribución están presentes o ausentes; si han realizados actividades colaborativas entre ellos o con el participante; si son conocidos (familiares o amigos) o extraños (pertenecientes o no al grupo), los materiales objetos de la distribución y, finalmente, tanto el tipo de juego económico a que se enfrenta el participante como la manera en la que se le presenta. ...
... En primer lugar, aquellos que no dan cuenta de diferencias de género (Thompson et al, 1997y Gruen et al, 2019. En segundo lugar, los que muestran, mediante el uso de determinados juegos económicos, que las niñas tienden a ser más igualitarias que los niños y un poco menos altruistas que ellos, aun cuando no logran encontrar diferencias significativas con relación al género (Fehr et al, 2008;Jennings, 2019;Harbaugh y Krause, 2000y Samek et al, 2020. Y, finalmente, aquellos que establecen, gracias a la aplicación de algún juego económico, diferencias significativas con relación al género tanto en la aversión a la desigualdad como en lo que tiene que ver con el altruismo (Fehr et al, 2013y Martinsson et al, 2011. ...
... Para sostener esta afirmación cita los trabajos de Fehr et al (2008de Fehr et al ( y 2013. La afirmación de la no correspondencia con la literatura debe ser matizada, pues los resultados de Fehr et al (2008de Fehr et al ( y 2013, aun cuando ofrecen resultados en una misma dirección, se diferencian en que en el estudio con niños de primera infancia y de principios de infancia media no hallan resultados significativos en la variable género, como se pudo notar hace un momento (Fehr et al, 2008); mientras que sí encuentran resultados en la magnitud de significancia para el final de la infancia media y para la adolescencia, como se verá en el siguiente sub apartado (Fehr et al, 2013). ...
Article
Full-text available
The article shows that experimental studies that aim to examine principles of distributive justice in children can be read from their relationship with the demographic variable gender. By making this critical reading from a thematic review, it is possible to observe that the studies, in general terms, show findings in three directions: no gender differences; non-significant differences; and significant differences. These results, however, are directly related both to participants’ age and methodological specificities of the experimentation. In order to account for these aspects, the text is divided into three parts: first-person studies, third-person work, and cultural comparisons.
Article
Humans cooperate with one another to a degree that is unmatched in any other species on the planet. However, there is enormous variability in cooperative thinking and behaviour within and between cultures. Here, we identify the features of the early social environment that we know to be predictors of positive elements of cooperation and create a roadmap for parents, educators and policymakers to guide them through the process of encouraging cooperation in development. We identify four basic psychosocial skills that support cooperation: (1) perspective taking; (2) expanding the concept of self to include others; (3) ensuring a secure attachment through shared positive emotions; and (4) internalising the norms of society (thereby decreasing reliance on externally motivated behaviour). We take a policy-oriented approach with a focus on the practical implications of the research presented throughout the article.
Preprint
Factors such as a person’s liking of the model or perceived similarity can influence imitation. However, to date, it is unclear whether perceived similarity influences one specific type of imitation, automatic imitation, in children. This study investigated whether school-aged children (N = 101, Mage = 92.57, SDage = 3.28 months) differ in their automatic imitation depending on whether they perceived the model as similar or dissimilar to themselves. Although the similarity manipulation seemed to work, we did not find support for an effect on children’s automatic imitation. We discuss our findings in light of previous research in this area and critically reflect upon the methodological challenges of this study.
Article
This survey article provides an overview of the recent experimental economic literature on fairness‐related behaviors in children and adolescents. We discuss different motives underlying fair behavior, summarize the development of fairness and inequality acceptance across different developmental stages, and we shed light on behavioral heterogeneity with respect to gender, SES, and cultural background. Moreover, we also discuss the role of preferences and social norms as determinants of fair behavior in children and adolescents. To learn about the origins of fair behavior, we address the influence of social environments, such as the family and we discuss the potential contribution of the genetic disposition.
Article
Full-text available
Human cooperation varies both across and within societies, and developmental studies can inform our understanding of the sources of both kinds of variation. One key candidate for explaining within-society variation in cooperative behaviour is gender, but we know little about whether gender differences in cooperation take root early in ontogeny or emerge similarly across diverse societies. Here, we explore two existing cross-cultural datasets of 4- to 15-year-old children's preferences for equality in experimental tasks measuring prosociality (14 societies) and fairness (seven societies), and we look for evidence of (i) widespread gender differences in the development of cooperation, and (ii) substantial societal variation in gender differences. This cross-cultural approach is crucial for revealing universal human gender differences in the development of cooperation, and it helps answer recent calls for greater cultural diversity in the study of human development. We find that gender has little impact on the development of prosociality and fairness within these datasets, and we do not find much evidence for substantial societal variation in gender differences. We discuss the implications of these findings for our knowledge about the nature and origin of gender differences in cooperation, and for future research attempting to study human development using diverse cultural samples. This article is part of the theme issue ‘Cooperation among women: evolutionary and cross-cultural perspectives’.
Article
Full-text available
A long history in economics going back to Adam Smith has argued that people give primacy to merit – rather than luck – in distributive choices. We provide a theoretical framework formalizing the merit primacy effect, and study it in a novel experiment where third-party spectators redistribute from high-earners to low-earners in situations where both merit and luck determine earnings. We identify a strong and consistent merit primacy effect in the spectator behaviour. The results shed new light on inequality acceptance in society, by showing how just a little bit of merit can make people significantly more inequality accepting.
Article
The relations between prosocial risk taking (taking a risk to benefit another person; PSRT) and interpersonal regret (regret that one's choices have caused a poor outcome for another person) were examined in 192 children aged 7–9. PSRT was measured by children's choices within a gambling task in which one choice guaranteed participants a good prize whereas the other involved risking this prize to help a peer also win a good prize. Interpersonal regret was assessed within the same task by examining children's change in emotion when they learned they would have won a better prize for a peer had they chosen differently. Performance on this task was also examined in relation to sympathy and resource sharing. Findings indicated that the operationalizations of PSRT and interpersonal regret were meaningful. Children who took a prosocial risk were more generous in a resource sharing task. In some circumstances, children who took a prosocial risk were also more likely to experience interpersonal regret than those who did not take a prosocial risk, indicating that experiencing interpersonal regret may be related to individual differences in prosociality. However, experiencing interpersonal regret did not have a direct effect on subsequent prosocial behavior, when measured by resource sharing. We consider findings in relation to a possible distinction between outcome and process regret and the generalizability of the behavioral consequences of regret.
Article
Full-text available
Humans have a deeply rooted sense of fairness, but its emotional foundation in early ontogeny remains poorly understood. Here, we asked if and when 4- to 10-year-old children show negative social emotions, such as shame or guilt, in response to advantageous unfairness expressed through a lowered body posture (measured using a Kinect depth sensor imaging camera). We found that older, but not younger children, showed more negative emotions, i.e. a reduced upper body posture, after unintentionally disadvantaging a peer on (4,1) trials than in response to fair (1,1) outcomes between themselves and others. Younger children, in contrast, expressed more negative emotions in response to the fair (1,1) split than in response to advantageous inequity. No systematic pattern of children's emotional responses was found in a non-social context, in which children divided resources between themselves and a non-social container. Supporting individual difference analyses showed that older children in the social context expressed negative emotions in response to advantageous inequity without directly acting on this negative emotional response by rejecting an advantageously unfair offer proposed by an experimenter at the end of the study. These findings shed new light on the emotional foundation of the human sense of fairness and suggest that children's negative emotional response to advantageous unfairness developmentally precedes their rejection of advantageously unfair resource distributions.
Article
Full-text available
Experimental research has studied the emergence of fairness criteria such as merit and equality at increasingly younger ages. How much does the recognition and practice of these principles depend on the influence of central aspects of Western educated and industrialized societies? In an attempt to answer these questions, this article provides evidence regarding the choices of children in the Kogi indigenous community of the Sierra Nevada de Santa Marta, a traditional society living in the mountains of Northern Colombia that practices swidden agriculture, cattle-raising, and enjoys a special cultural status granted by the Colombian Constitution. Two groups of 6–7 and 10–11 year olds (N = 104) were tested on a modified dictator game and several scenarios from a resource distribution task including different fairness criteria. Our results point to the lack of focality of the idea of merit among Kogi children at these ages when deciding on third-party allocation tasks, even when the design prevented equal distribution.
Article
We tested when U.S. children reject bribery, and whether their rejections vary by public versus private setting. Six‐ to 10‐year‐olds (224 children, 118 boys, 106 girls, majority‐White) participated across four experiments, in which participants indicated whether a contest judge should accept a contestant's financial gift. Children conveyed their preferences while in public or in private (in the presence or absence of an adult experimenter). Children's rejections of bribes were found to increase with age. Notably, younger children's acceptance rate was higher when the experimenter was present than in their absence; in contrast, older children showed comparable rejection rates across settings. Limitations in children's early reasoning about bribery, including the reputational and moral implications of accepting bribes in public, are discussed.
Article
Full-text available
In this novel introduction to modern microeconomic theory, Samuel Bowles returns to the classical economists' interest in the wealth and poverty of nations and people, the workings of the institutions of capitalist economies, and the coevolution of individual preferences and the structures of markets, firms, and other institutions. Using recent advances in evolutionary game theory, contract theory, behavioral experiments, and the modeling of dynamic processes, he develops a theory of how economic institutions shape individual behavior, and how institutions evolve due to individual actions, technological change, and chance events. Topics addressed include institutional innovation, social preferences, nonmarket social interactions, social capital, equilibrium unemployment, credit constraints, economic power, generalized increasing returns, disequilibrium outcomes, and path dependency. Each chapter is introduced by empirical puzzles or historical episodes illuminated by the modeling that follows, and the book closes with sets of problems to be solved by readers seeking to improve their mathematical modeling skills. Complementing standard mathematical analysis are agent-based computer simulations of complex evolving systems that are available online so that readers can experiment with the models. Bowles concludes with the time-honored challenge of "getting the rules right," providing an evaluation of markets, states, and communities as contrasting and yet sometimes synergistic structures of governance. Must reading for students and scholars not only in economics but across the behavioral sciences, this engagingly written and compelling exposition of the new microeconomics moves the field beyond the conventional models of prices and markets toward a more accurate and policy-relevant portrayal of human social behavior.
Article
Full-text available
The author provides a conceptual framework for understanding differences among prosocial, individualistic, and competitive orientations. Whereas traditional models conceptualize prosocial orientation in terms of enhancing joint outcomes, the author proposes an integrative model of social value orientation in which prosocial orientation is understood in terms of enhancing both joint outcomes and equality in outcomes. Consistent with this integrative model, prosocial orientation (vs. individualistic and competitive orientations) was associated with greater tendencies to enhance both joint outcomes and equality in outcomes; in addition, both goals were positively associated (Study 1). Consistent with interaction-relevant implications of this model, prosocial orientation was strongly related to reciprocity. Relative to individualists and competitors, prosocials were more likely to engage in the same level of cooperation as the interdependent other did (Study 2) and the same level of cooperation as they anticipated from the interdependent other (Study 3). (PsycINFO Database Record (c) 2012 APA, all rights reserved)
Article
What kinds of childbearing practices foster the development of helping, sharing, and other prosocial behaviours? What roles do biology and culture play in the development of prosocial behaviour? In this book, Nancy Eisenberg and Paul Mussen review and summarize scholarly research that has been devoted to the development of prosocial behaviour in children, and examine the variety of influences that contribute to children's prosocial development, including the media, parents, peers, biology, culture, personal characteristics, as well as situational determinants. The authors argue that prosocial behaviour can be learned and is modifiable, and they suggest ways that parents, teachers, and other can enhance prosocial development. In addition, the authors attempt to communicate the advances in the study of prosocial development that have taken place over the last decade. The book highlights some questions that have not yet been addressed adequately by researchers, and suggests areas for future work.
Article
A novel behavioral choice card designed to distinguish 4 social behaviors (altruism/group enhancement, equality, superiority, and rivalry/superiority) was administered to 5-6- and 7-9-year-old children from 3 populations: upper-middle-SES Anglo-American; lower-SES Anglo-American; and lower-SES Mexican-American. Comparison of the 2 lower SES groups revealed an ethnic difference in the development of social behaviors: with age, Mexican-American children tended to be somewhat more prosocial in contrast to Anglo-American children who were increasingly competitive. Comparison of the 2 Anglo-American groups indicated lower-SES children make more prosocial choices than upper-middle-SES children. Boys made significantly more rivalry/superiority and fewer equality choices than girls across both ages in all populations and conditions. Behavior was generally consistent across conditions which varied the presence and activity level of the peer. Further, superiority and equality appeared to be strong social motives, rivalry and altruism appeared to be intermediate in strength, and group enhancement was a very weak motive.
Article
Egalitarian society is ''explained'' chiefly in terms of ecological or social factors that are self-organizing. However, egalitarian behavior is found in a wide variety of social and ecological settings, and the indications are that such societies are deliberately shaped by their members. This paper looks to egalitarian behavior as an instance of domination of leaders by their own followers, who are guided by an ethos that disapproves of hierarchical behavior in general and of bossiness in leaders in particular. A substantial cross-cultural survey reveals the specific mechanisms by which the political rank and file creates a reverse dominance hierarchy, an anomalous social arrangement which has important implications for cross-phylogenetic comparisons and for the theory of state formation.
Book
Over the past 25 years, Boyd and Richerson have become well-known across a wide range of disciplines for their path-breaking work on evolution and culture. This work collects twenty of the influential but relatively inaccessible published articels that form the backbone of this research. It could not be more timely given the growing influence of evolutionary psychology. The papers – which were published in a diverse set of journals and which are not easily available – a conceptually linked and form a cohesive, unified evolutionary account of human culture. Their interdisciplinary research is based on two notions. First, that culture is crucial for understanding human behavior: unlike other organism, socially transmitted beliefs, attitudes and values heavily influence our behavior. Secondly, culture is part of biology: the capacity to acquire and transmit culture is a derived component of human psychology, and the contents of culture are deeply intertwined with our biology. Taking off from these two assumptions, Boyd and Richerson’s novel idea is that culture is a pool of information, stored in the brains of a population, that gets transmitted from one brain to another by social learning processes. Among their conclusions: culture can account for both our astounding ecological success as well as the maladaptations that characterize much of human behavior. Interest in Boyd and Richerson’s work spans anthropology, psychology, economics, philosophy, and political science, and has influenced work on animal behavior, economics and game theory, memes, and even archaeology.
Article
This study examined developmental and socioeconomic status (SES) differences in young children's altruistic behavior in the dictator game (DG). Children aged 4, 6, and 9 years old from six British primary schools played the DG with genetically unrelated individuals using stickers as resource. Results demonstrated that older children and children from higher SES environments behaved more altruistically, although the majority of children displayed altruistic behavior even at the youngest age level. Results buttress conclusions based on studies from diverse cultures and from brain imaging research by providing additional evidence for the fundamental nature of altruistic behavior, as well as for the probable influence of local socialization practices on development.
Article
Research on theory of mind increasingly encompasses apparently contradictory findings. In particular, in initial studies, older preschoolers consistently passed false-belief tasks — a so-called “definitive” test of mental-state understanding — whereas younger children systematically erred. More recent studies, however, have found evidence of false-belief understanding in 3-year-olds or have demonstrated conditions that improve children's performance. A meta-analysis was conducted (N= 178 separate studies) to address the empirical inconsistencies and theoretical controversies. When organized into a systematic set of factors that vary across studies, false-belief results cluster systematically with the exception of only a few outliers. A combined model that included age, country of origin, and four task factors (e.g., whether the task objects were transformed in order to deceive the protagonist or not) yielded a multiple R of .74 and an R2 of .55; thus, the model accounts for 55% of the variance in false-belief performance. Moreover, false-belief performance showed a consistent developmental pattern, even across various countries and various task manipulations: preschoolers went from below-chance performance to above-chance performance. The findings are inconsistent with early competence proposals that claim that developmental changes are due to tasks artifacts, and thus disappear in simpler, revised false-belief tasks; and are, instead, consistent with theoretical accounts that propose that understanding of belief, and, relatedly, understanding of mind, exhibit genuine conceptual change in the preschool years.
Article
People are reciprocal if they reward kind actions and punish unkind ones. In this paper we present a formal theory of reciprocity. It takes into account that people evaluate the kindness of an action not only by its consequences but also by its underlying intention. The theory is in line with the relevant stylized facts of a wide range of experimental games, such as the ultimatum game, the gift-exchange game, a reduced best-shot game, the dictator game, the prisoner's dilemma, and public goods games. Furthermore, it predicts that identical consequences trigger different reciprocal responses in different environments. Finally, the theory explains why outcomes tend to be fair in bilateral interactions whereas extremely unfair distributions may arise in competitive markets.