ArticlePDF Available

A Matter of (Relational) Style: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity in Microfinance

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Social scientists have long considered what mechanisms underlie repeated exchange. Three mechanisms have garnered the majority of this attention: formal contracts, relational contracts, and relationally embedded social ties. Although each mechanism has its virtues, all three exhibit a common limitation: an inability to fully explain the continuation and stability of intertemporal exchange between individuals and organizations in the face of change. Drawing on extensive quantitative data on approximately 450,000 microfinance loans made by a microfinance institution in Mexico from 2004 to 2008 that include random assignment of loan officers, this research proposes the concept of ”relational styles” to help explain how repeated exchange is possible in the face of personnel change. We define relational styles as systematically reoccurring patterns of interaction employed by social actors within and across exchange relationships—in this paper, between microfinance clients and loan officers. We show that relational styles that are consistent facilitate a clear understanding of expectations and thus exchange. We also demonstrate that consistency in the relational styles followed by successive loan officers mitigates the negative impact of a broken loan officer–client tie. This paper thus proposes and empirically tests a social mechanism based on relational styles that often accompanies relational embeddedness, but which may also serve as a partial substitute for it.
Content may be subject to copyright.
This article was downloaded by: [128.122.183.209] On: 09 September 2015, At: 12:12
Publisher: Institute for Operations Research and the Management Sciences (INFORMS)
INFORMS is located in Maryland, USA
Management Science
Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://pubsonline.informs.org
A Matter of (Relational) Style: Loan Officer Consistency
and Exchange Continuity in Microfinance
Rodrigo Canales, Jason Greenberg
To cite this article:
Rodrigo Canales, Jason Greenberg (2015) A Matter of (Relational) Style: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity in
Microfinance. Management Science
Published online in Articles in Advance 03 Sep 2015
. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2167
Full terms and conditions of use: http://pubsonline.informs.org/page/terms-and-conditions
This article may be used only for the purposes of research, teaching, and/or private study. Commercial use
or systematic downloading (by robots or other automatic processes) is prohibited without explicit Publisher
approval, unless otherwise noted. For more information, contact permissions@informs.org.
The Publisher does not warrant or guarantee the article’s accuracy, completeness, merchantability, fitness
for a particular purpose, or non-infringement. Descriptions of, or references to, products or publications, or
inclusion of an advertisement in this article, neither constitutes nor implies a guarantee, endorsement, or
support of claims made of that product, publication, or service.
Copyright © 2015, INFORMS
Please scroll down for article—it is on subsequent pages
INFORMS is the largest professional society in the world for professionals in the fields of operations research, management
science, and analytics.
For more information on INFORMS, its publications, membership, or meetings visit http://www.informs.org
MANAGEMENT SCIENCE
Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23
ISSN 0025-1909 (print) ISSN 1526-5501 (online) http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2167
© 2015 INFORMS
A Matter of (Relational) Style: Loan Officer
Consistency and Exchange Continuity in Microfinance
Rodrigo Canales
Yale School of Management, New Haven, Connecticut 06520, rodrigo.canales@yale.edu
Jason Greenberg
Leonard N. Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, New York 10012, jgreenbe@stern.nyu.edu
Social scientists have long considered what mechanisms underlie repeated exchange. Three mechanisms have
garnered the majority of this attention: formal contracts, relational contracts, and relationally embedded
social ties. Although each mechanism has its virtues, all three exhibit a common limitation: an inability to fully
explain the continuation and stability of intertemporal exchange between individuals and organizations in the
face of change. Drawing on extensive quantitative data on approximately 450,000 microfinance loans made by
a microfinance institution in Mexico from 2004 to 2008 that include random assignment of loan officers, this
research proposes the concept of ”relational styles” to help explain how repeated exchange is possible in the face
of personnel change. We define relational styles as systematically reoccurring patterns of interaction employed
by social actors within and across exchange relationships—in this paper, between microfinance clients and loan
officers. We show that relational styles that are consistent facilitate a clear understanding of expectations and
thus exchange. We also demonstrate that consistency in the relational styles followed by successive loan officers
mitigates the negative impact of a broken loan officer–client tie. This paper thus proposes and empirically tests
a social mechanism based on relational styles that often accompanies relational embeddedness, but which may
also serve as a partial substitute for it.
Keywords: economic sociology; organizational sociology; relational sociology; sociology of development; social
networks
History : Received October 8, 2013; accepted January 13, 2015, by Jesper Sørensen, organizations. Published
online in Articles in Advance.
1. Introduction
Formal contracts are fundamental features of eco-
nomic and social life. Because they specify rights
and responsibilities ex ante, they facilitate exchange
between actors by reducing the risk of defection.
In complex settings, however, it is impossible to
anticipate the myriad contingencies that may arise,
rendering formal contracts incomplete, difficult to
craft, and costly to enforce (Macneil 1978,Williamson
1985). Relational contracts can minimize these lim-
itations through more flexible structures based on
the trust that develops between parties with an eco-
nomic interest in repeated exchange (the “shadow
of the future”). Ultimately, relational contracts derive
value from relationships between social actors. Tradi-
tionally, these relationships are theorized and docu-
mented between organizations or organizations and
specific employees or clients (e.g., Rousseau 1990,
McMillan and Woodruff 1999,Baker et al. 2002).
However, organizations cannot establish informal
relationships—only people can (Sorenson and Rogan
2014). Relational contracts are established between
people who set, interpret, enact, and enforce them.
With this as a starting point, sociologists refer to
“relational embeddedness” as the quality of dyadic
relationships that develop between actors over time
(e.g., Granovetter 1992,Heimer 1992,Gulati 1998,
Nahapiet and Ghoshal 1998,Moran 2005). Consistent
with relational contracting, substantial research has
demonstrated the value of relational embeddedness
for individuals and the organizations they represent
(e.g., Uzzi 1997,Uzzi and Lancaster 2003).
A corollary of conceptualizing relationships at the
dyadic level is that when relationships change or
dissolve, so should the value they create for indi-
viduals or the organizations they represent in an
exchange (Seabright et al. 1992,Beatty et al. 1996,
Baker et al. 1998,Broschak 2004,Biong and Ulvnes
2011,Broschak and Block 2014; see also Burt 2000,
2001). This is particularly important when only one
representative of an organization controls the client
relationship. Given the ubiquity of change, employee
turnover, and broken ties, it is unclear how organi-
zations can consistently retain the value of the inter-
personal relationships established by its members
to sustain repeated exchange (Sorenson and Rogan
1
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
2Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
2014). Yet many do to good effect. Our paper provides
one explanation for this puzzle.
We do so using microfinance as a strategic research
site. Microfinance provides small loans using sim-
ple contracts between microfinance institutions (MFIs)
and their borrowers (e.g., Giné et al. 2010). The
frequency of loan disbursements allows for the
observation of a large number of simple contractual
interactions between an organization, its representa-
tives, and its clients. Microfinance clients tend to be
destitute and geographically dispersed, so loan offi-
cers are often their only point of contact with the
MFI. Because client needs vary considerably across
individuals and settings, ex ante contracts are nec-
essarily incomplete, and borrower–loan officer rela-
tional considerations carry particular importance. In
essence, microfinance constitutes an extreme version
of small business finance where decentralized banks
have been shown to be more effective because their
branch managers have the discretion and incentives
to establish relational contracts with their clients
(Petersen and Rajan 1994,Berger et al. 2001). Given
that bank employees are routinely promoted, fired, or
rotated, the ensuing broken ties should produce dis-
ruptions that impact continuity of exchange. Notwith-
standing constant change, these decentralized banks
retain an organizational advantage through their rela-
tional contracts.
We determine a way they do so, using a novel,
proprietary data set that includes information on
approximately 450,000 microfinance loans made by
an urban-market-focused MFI in Mexico between
2004 and 2008. Theory generation, construct devel-
opment and validation, and model specification and
interpretation are aided by rich ethnographic data,
including 129 interviews, collected as part of a larger
research project (Canales 2011,2014). We gain empir-
ical traction from the natural variation in agents’
relational styles and the firm’s policy of randomly
assigning and rotating loan officers across branches
when joining the firm and in response to vacant posi-
tions created by frequent turnover. The data include
fine-grained information concerning the terms of the
loan, the borrower’s characteristics, and unique mea-
sures characterizing the consistency of each loan offi-
cer’s relational style, where some agents follow a
strictly contractual approach; others adhere to a holis-
tic, broad interpretation of contractual terms and
client conditions; and others mix elements of both
approaches. Our identification strategy exploits the
fact that regardless of why a tie is severed between
a client and the loan officer representing the MFI,
the subsequent loan officer is assigned at random to
serve the client on behalf of the MFI. This provides
random variation with respect to the (in)consistency
in the previous and subsequent loan officers’ rela-
tional styles—orthogonal to client and loan officer
characteristics or vacancy—that affords the analytical
leverage required to test our predictions concerning
(in)consistency in inter-loan officer relational styles.
We provide compelling evidence that although for-
mal contracts bind the borrower to the MFI, these
formal contracts are enhanced, as expected by rela-
tional contracts and relational embeddedness, by the
loan officer’s relationship with the borrower. At the
same time, we show that relational value is not
solely derived from the nature or strength of the
dyadic relationship as characterized by the litera-
ture on relational embeddedness. Rather, clients care
considerably about the relational styles employed by
their previous and succeeding loan officers. We the-
orize these relational styles as systematically reoccur-
ring modes of interaction and underlying schemata
and scripts enacted by social actors. Below we pro-
pose theory that specifies how both a loan officer’s
individual consistency and the consistency between
successive loan officers’ relational styles influence a
borrower’s adherence to contractual provisions con-
cerning timely repayment.
Our findings show that when loan officers leave the
MFI, which occurs quite frequently both in the firm
we study and the industry at large (Janik 2012), clients
are approximately 24% more likely to miss a payment,
and contingent on a first missed payment, 47% of
clients also miss a second. We show that these figures
can be reduced significantly and rapidly depending
on the consistency of the relational style employed by
the loan officer subsequently (randomly) assigned to
administer the loan.
These findings have considerable economic impli-
cations. MFIs must maintain capital reserves equal to
specific percentages of their outstanding portfolios at
risk. As clients miss more payments, capital reserve
requirements increase nonlinearly (e.g., from 4% of
the loan value if only one payment has been missed
(1–7 days in arrears) to 30% if three scheduled pay-
ments are missed (30–60 days in arrears)). For an MFI
with a $100 million portfolio (which the MFI we study
has), capital reserve requirements can vary by mil-
lions of dollars.1
The focus on relational styles adds depth to our
understanding of relational contracts (see, e.g., Baker
et al. 2002,Gibbons and Henderson 2011) on two
separate levels. First, it specifies that relational con-
tracts are established through individuals and that,
1Because MFIs leverage capital (8×for conservative ones), the
difference in capital reserve requirements implies the inability to
invest several million dollars. With yearly turnover of invested cap-
ital averaging 3×, and high interest rates charged to clients (mean =
800122, SD =60475), this implies foregone income of millions of
dollars.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 3
as a result, the dyadic relationship is a core con-
duit of relational value attributed to relational con-
tracts vis-à-vis formal contracts. At the same time, our
research shows that relational contracts and relational
embeddedness do not provide organizations with sus-
tainable value solely through personal ties between
employees and clients. Rather, the consistency in the
styles of interaction employed by social actors occu-
pying similar roles (loan officers in this case) provides
a stable and clear set of expectations and thus shapes
action. We demonstrate the value of this social mech-
anism net of the strength and quality of personal ties.
Prior work that focuses solely on the nature and qual-
ity of dyadic ties without observing relational styles
across different individuals may thus conflate dis-
tinct social processes—that pertaining to the quality of
a dyadic relationship (relational embeddedness) and
that relating to the particular style used by different
actors as well as the expectations that such styles and
their consistent application can foster.
In the following section, we provide additional
background on microfinance and its suitability as a
research setting. We then offer a summary of formal
contracts, relational contracts, and relational embed-
dedness to provide more detail about their virtues
and common limitation—the inability to fully explain
the continuity of exchange in the face of interper-
sonal change. In the theory section, we develop our
arguments and hypotheses specifying how, when, and
why consistency in relational styles of loan officers
should matter net of a contractual or dyadic relation-
ship with a client. We then discuss the quantitative
and qualitative data collected, as well as our analytic
strategy. This is followed by a presentation of findings
and a discussion that includes consideration of scope
conditions and avenues for future work.
1.1. Microfinance as a Setting to Research
(Relational) Contracts
Each year, microfinance provides approximately
$85 billion in loans to more than 150 million low-
income borrowers (Daley-Harris 2009,Reille and
Forster 2008). Broadly speaking, microfinance pro-
vides financial services, mostly in the form of
microcredit, to unbanked and often destitute pop-
ulations. Loans are typically small, uncollateralized,
provided for short terms (between four and six
months), and amortized through high-frequency pay-
ments (for a good introduction, see Morduch and
Armendáriz de Aghion 2005). Loans are of the sim-
plest form with terms, fixed rates, and a straight
amortization schedule specified in a simple legal
document.
From its origins in the 1970s, microfinance has
demonstrated that poorer households not only con-
stitute reasonable credit risk but also can put loans
to productive use, even using them to mitigate the
effects of poverty (Yunus 2003). One of the most
remarkable aspects of microfinance is that, contrary to
conventional contract and finance theory (e.g., Bester
1985,Stiglitz and Weiss 1986), destitute populations
with little collateral and no experience with formal
finance exhibit exemplary repayment rates (Morduch
1994,Morduch and Armendáriz de Aghion 2005). Ini-
tial explanations for this puzzle centered on the com-
mon methodology of providing loans to joint liability
groups where members have the incentive to screen,
monitor, and enforce repayment of joint liability loans
(e.g., Stiglitz 1990, Besley and Coate 1995). However,
recent research employing experimental designs has
demonstrated that other lending models, including
noncollateralized loans to individuals, can achieve
similarly impressive results (Giné and Karlan 2012).
This has shifted focus away from the joint liabil-
ity mechanism to more general contractual structures
common in microfinance (Giné et al. 2010).
Recent research shows that future access to cap-
ital is the central incentive for timely repayment,
which can be reinforced through different contractual
structures, including (a) lending progressively (i.e.,
loans increase in size with timely prior payment) to
place more value on future loans than on a potential
default, (b) favoring borrowers (e.g., women’s groups)
who generally follow more conservative investment
strategies, (c) making small yet frequent payments
(e.g., weekly), or (d) engaging in intense supervi-
sion of clients (Armendáriz de Aghion and Morduch
2000,2004;Anthony 2005;Field and Pande 2008;
Giné et al. 2010).
Considerably less attention has been devoted to the
organizations and the agents that create and enforce
MFI contracts (Jain and Moore 2003). This neglect
is surprising for several reasons. First, microfinance
clients are mostly poor and geographically dispersed,
which means that loan officers are often the sole point
of contact between a client and the MFI. Whereas
the central MFI determines lending policies, loan con-
tracts, and collection procedures, these are always
enacted and primarily enforced by loan officers oper-
ating from a network of small branches. It is loan
officers who find and evaluate clients, gather credit
information, perform a credit analysis, produce a
credit recommendation, and provide all the neces-
sary information for the disbursement of the loan.
They also supervise loan repayment, ensure collec-
tion in cases of missed payments, renew and increase
credit lines when a loan reaches maturity, and “sell”
other products such as life insurance to good clients.
As a result, even though clients have a contractual
agreement with the MFI, they establish and experi-
ence it through their relationship with loan officers.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
4Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
Second, client needs vary considerably across indi-
viduals and time, making ex ante contracts necessar-
ily incomplete. More broadly, microfinance constitutes
an extreme version of small business finance, which
has been shown to be especially sensitive to relational
contracts and the “soft” information that can only
travel through personal—rather than contractual—
ties (e.g., Petersen and Rajan 1994,Berger et al.
2001). It also shares important characteristics with
street-level bureaucracies, where agents must exercise
unusual levels of discretion in the enactment of rules
(Lipsky 1980,Canales 2011,Coslovsky 2011,Piore
2011). For these reasons, we can expect that borrower–
loan officer relational considerations will interact
with formal contractual structures to affect loan out-
comes. In addition, the high frequency of microcre-
dit results in a large number of contractual exchanges
between an MFI and its diverse client population
(Giné et al. 2010). Microfinance therefore presents
a rich setting to test and separate specific claims
and mechanisms concerning formal and relational
contracts.
1.2. Predictions Concerning Contracts,
Loan Officer Change, and Relational Styles
Contracts are foundational components of economic
and social life (Durkheim 1997, p. 155; Weber 1978,
Chap. VIII; Fudenberg and Tirole1990). Contracts spec-
ify rights and responsibilities between individuals—
or between individuals and institutions—in various
exchanges. From the most mundane of matters such
as consumer purchases to the most intimate such as
marriage, contracts reflect, shape, coordinate, and cir-
cumscribe expectations and action.
In a spot market with perfect information, contracts
would not be essential because there would be no
need to account for contingencies or facilitate coor-
dination (Hermalin et al. 2007). In the presence of
information asymmetries and the risk of contingen-
cies, however, contracts can stipulate the price, quan-
tity, and timing of repayment, as well as penalties and
remedial rights if the contract is breached, thus facil-
itating exchange.
Formal contracts have limitations. First, they are
incomplete, as the myriad contingencies that may
arise cannot be accounted for ex ante (Hart and Moore
1999). Second, they can be costly in time and money
to craft and enforce. Relational contracts solve some
of these limitations. They are less rigid than for-
mal contracts as they rely on the trust that devel-
ops between parties who have an interest in repeated
exchange (Macaulay 1963,Macneil 1978,McMillan
and Woodruff 1999,Baker et al. 2002).
Some have argued that formal contracts and the
trust required for relational contracts are substitutes
(Zucker 1986,Guseva and Rona-Tas 2001). Others
have argued that formal contracts stunt the devel-
opment of trust (Malhotra and Murnighan 2002).
Research also suggests that the two can be comple-
ments (e.g., Poppo and Zenger 2002) and are often
used to reinforce each other (Baker et al. 1994). A case
in point is the imagery of community bankers who
rely on relational lending practices that incorporate
“soft” and “hard” information in decision making, as
well as formal contracting mechanisms (e.g., Sharpe
1990,Berger and Udell 1995).
Relational contracts can be between organizations
or people and organizations. For example, IBM
once offered the promise of “lifetime employment”
(Baker et al. 1994) that was not formally stipu-
lated in employment contracts but was understood
by corporate actors and applicants who enacted
and enforced these contracts. More generally, orga-
nizational blueprints entail a host of implicit and
explicit agreements with employees concerning the
“employment deal,” such as how their efforts will
be coordinated, controlled, and compensated (Baron
et al. 2001). When blueprints are changed, employee
turnover often ensues as implicit agreements are
rescinded.
Change is ubiquitous in organizations as employ-
ees come and go, strategies and blueprints change,
and internal soft expectations of performance adjust to
align with the demands of changing market environ-
ments. When change alters or severs the ties that have
sustained a relational contract, it follows that the value
it creates can be compromised, often leading to the
loss of an exchange relationship (e.g., Seabright et al.
1992,Hannan et al. 1996,Baron et al. 2001,Broschak
2004,Biong and Ulvnes 2011).2This follows because
relational value is created by individuals who play
dual roles, both as individuals and as representatives
of their organizations. When a loan officer changes an
aspect of the relationship, for example, the borrower
determines whether to confer ownership of the rela-
tional value to the loan officer or the organization the
loan officer represents (Sorenson and Rogan 2014).
As noted above, microfinance loans are simple in
form: they have fixed terms, rates, and a straight-
forward amortization schedule summarized in a sim-
ple legal document. Timely payment should thus
not vary as a function of the loan officer because
the contract is signed between the borrower and the
MFI.3More broadly, credit methodologies typically
2The MFI (and industry) we study experiences high rates of
employee turnover (Janik 2012). Consequently, it seeks to limit the
depth of officers’ ties to clients because it fears that if they leave
they will take good clients with them. Random loan officer rota-
tions are employed to reduce this possibility. But, as a consequence,
MFIs suffer increased delinquencies, as we show here.
3Payment is made directly, electronically, to the MFI. Consequently,
there is no technical reason changing loan officers should have an
impact on timely payment.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 5
assess the credit worthiness of a borrower. Clients
can be classified as “good credit risks” because client
types are assumed to be stable. To keep track of
clients, facilitate loan officer work, and ease transi-
tions in cases of turnover, MFIs—including the ones
we study—have developed sophisticated software
platforms that standardize lending decisions, keep
track of loan activity, and enable loan officers to col-
lect and record rich information about each client and
document every visit or interaction. There is thus no
economic, informational, or legal reason why clients,
who were evaluated with the same credit methodol-
ogy, should differ in their repayment behavior when
interacting with loan officers with different relational
styles. Furthermore, given that lack of payment will
likely lead to the loss of the credit line, the significant
incentive for repayment provided by future access to
credit is in no way dependent on a loan officer’s rela-
tional style. Finally, loan officers are in a position of
power as a function of the client’s dependency on
them (Emerson 1962). Formal mechanisms and power
dynamics should thus strongly incent timely payment
irrespective of the relational styles employed by loan
officers.
Yet our ethnographic work revealed the negative
impact of change on borrowers. As noted above,
although borrowers know their loan is provided by
the MFI, they often perceive that their commitment
is to the loan officer they have worked with. Thus, a
change in the loan officer can be experienced by the
client as a change in the relationship with the organi-
zation, which reveals the presence of relational con-
siderations alongside their formal contract.
1.3. Individually Consistent Relational Styles
(Within Individual)
The ways in which social actors interact can be ab-
stracted and classified based on the roles each occu-
pies (Berger and Luckmann 1967, pp. 72–77). This
means that although there is heterogeneity in social
interaction, there is also much that can be assumed
based on homogeneity within roles. We argue that
similar dynamics operate with respect to relations.
Social cognitive psychologists have focused on spe-
cific layers of this process and refer to the oper-
ating mechanism as relational schemata (Baldwin
1992,Sanchez-Burks et al. 2000). Relational schemata
include an interactional model of “ego” and “alter.”
Each actor has expectations of self and other, and
both employ relational scripts that form a model of
a typical interaction (Smith 1984). Relational scripts
are often conceptualized as “if-then” statements that
structure behavior. Hence, each interaction, even
those with complete strangers, starts with a baseline
of understanding. We focus on the aggregation of
these schemata into systematically reoccurring rela-
tional styles used by actors across interactions.
In field observations of loan officers, we found that
certain loan officers interpret and enact policies flexi-
bly while others adhere strictly to them. These obser-
vations led to an inductively developed typology of
loan officer relational styles. Table 1presents their
underlying interpretive frames. One category of loan
officers tends to adhere strictly to the rules. They rely
heavily on standardized models to assess borrowers,
customer relationship management systems to define
client management tasks and track client information,
and handheld technological devices to help automate
decision making in line with organizational policies
and procedures. In turn, this underlying philosophy
informs and is enacted in their relationships with
clients. We refer to them as “letter of the law” (LL)
officers. Consider a typical LL officer’s description of
his job:
My job is to recruit the new loan groups, train them on
the methodology, do the credit analysis, and make sure
that the whole process runs smoothly. It basically con-
sists of applying the methodology strictly and making
sure that the groups adhere closely to the policies.
LL loan officers adhere strictly to rules not nec-
essarily because they believe there is no latitude in
their client relationships. Rather, they assume that
the rules are designed intelligently to maximize effi-
ciency. The interpersonal distance maintained by LL
officers is intended to maintain objectivity in rela-
tions with limited information, not necessarily out
of contempt for clients. Officers in the second rela-
tional category, “spirit of the law” (SL), interpret pro-
visions more expansively and flexibly; they also tend
to develop deeper relationships with their clients as
they learn about their lives, needs, and concerns holis-
tically. This is not necessarily out of altruism. SL offi-
cers believe developing multiplex relationships with
clients enables them to perform their jobs more effec-
tively (May and Winter 2000):
Policies are good, they are useful, but you also need
to give them a personal touch. 000 It is much better
to spend that time learning about the client, about
her relationships, and selling her on opportunities.000
That’s what helping my clients is about. (SL officer)
Finally, some loan officers exhibited relational styles
that are neither purely LL nor SL, but display a mix
of both. These loan officers were labeled as “mixed,”
as they blend elements of each style with every client,
rather than different styles with different clients.4
4We interviewed managers and loan officers after the typology was
developed. A few notes are worth making. First, they all believe
that loan officer styles are stable. This is because styles emerge from
an underlying philosophy about the nature of organizational rules
and the role of the MFI vis-à-vis its clients. Furthermore, clients
adapt and react to styles, generating self-reinforcing dynamics.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
6Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
Table 1 Interpretive Frames Associated with Different Relational Styles
Why and how loan
officers interact as
they do with clients Spirit of the Law (SL) Letter of the Law (LL)
View on the nature of
microfinance and
borrowers
—The best thing for the organization is to help its clients. The
organization should always adapt to meet client needs.
To the clients, we are 6MFI7. And to 6the MFI7, we are the
clients.000 We have to make sure that the company is doing
the right thing, that it is truly helping our clients, and that our
clients are being heard.”
—The best thing for the organization is to stick to the business
model that it knows and that works. The organization should
select clients who fit the model well.
At the end of the day, we are a business. We are not a welfare
organization, even if our work helps people.”
View on organizational
rules and related
client interaction
—Rules are tools, to be used as needed.
—Rules are made by people who have less information than is
available on the field.
Policies are good, they are useful, but you also need to give
them a personal touch. 000 Managers don’t see what I see.
The policies don’t see what I see.”
—Rules are instructions that specify what can and cannot be
done.
—Rules are made by people who have more information than is
available on the field.
I explained things to them carefully; I went over the contract
with them and they agreed. I told them of the responsibilities
and the implications and they agreed. I went through different
scenarios of good things and bad things that could happen
and what the contract specified for good behavior and for bad
behavior, and they agreed.”
Contracts,
information, and
clients
—Our rules and contracts are incomplete in unforeseen ways.
The more information I can have about my client—including
personal information—the better.
—The more information I can reveal to my client about me, how
we do things, and how the system works, the better.
When you visit a prospect’s store, you could just begin asking
questions following the policies.000 It is much better to spend
that time learning about the client, about her relationships,
and selling her on opportunities, such as the purchase of a
ham slicer and how productive the loan would be.”
—The only information that is relevant is that which is specified
and codified in our contracts and our systems. Collecting
other types of information is a waste of our time.
—Our clients need to understand how our contracts work and
what their formal commitments are.
There is a reason why we have these tools. The most efficient
thing to do is to just ask the questions that the system needs
in that order. You input information, the tool gives you an
answer, and you’re done.”
How loan officers
handle problems
in the client
relationship
—We work with the client to understand the situation and jointly
find a solution; the contract is a guideline.
Whenever my poorer clients tell me they cannot make a
payment because something bad happened to them, I have a
policy of always trusting them. So I sit down with them,
understand the problem and we come up with a solution,
even if that means fighting 6the MFI7to change the terms of
the loan or do a formal restructuring.000 Sure, some of my
clients end up not being morally solvent, but I can tell you
that of every 10 clients I have helped, 9 have made it and 8
have become long-term clients.”
—The client knows what the rules are; we enforce the contract
as specified.
I did not design these rules, and I did not force my clients to
sign these contracts 000what’s the surprise? I am only doing
what I told you 000keeping my side of the contract that you
and I signed.” “Once I make an exception for the first woman,
what do I do when her cousin calls me and wants the same?
000No, no, no. We have an agreement. I don’t come in and tell
you why I did not deposit your loan amount after we signed a
contract. So, if you don’t repay the company, my job is to
come in and make sure that you do.”
Notes.N=711: SL =235, LL =233, and 243 =mixed. “Mixed” loan agents blend various elements of SL and LL agents, vacillating between the two. The
em dash denotes a summary of approach across observations. Italicized text represents a representative quote.
Substantial research has documented the sociocog-
nitive processes that operate in dyadic interactions
when there is ambiguity in action or expected reaction.
Parties to such exchanges draw on prior experiences
and underlying expectations to inform current interac-
tions. Theory and research argue that individual social
actors are evaluated based on their salient characteris-
tics and others’ experience with those characteristics.
For example, employers extrapolate the potential of
prospective employees based on their specific gender
or racial characteristics (see, e.g., Becker 1959,Arrow
Finally, loan officers manage, on average, 250 clients. It is cogni-
tively taxing—some of them argue impossible—to follow different
styles with different clients.
1972,Bielby and Baron 1986,Fernandez and Green-
berg 2013).
A similar dynamic is evident in other social interac-
tions where actors have no prior relationships, which
leads them to extrapolate from typologies of prior
experience. Police officers, for example, use different
scripts depending on which type of citizen they per-
ceive they are dealing with, so they develop heuristics
to determine whether they are likely dealing with a
citizen, a criminal, or an “asshole” (Van Maanen 1978).
In microfinance, loan officers similarly try to estab-
lish role and relational expectations about their clients
when they evaluate them to create a profile. Clients
might be classified as high-risk or low-risk based
on observable factors such as industry, proposed
use of funds, and credit scores, as well as on soft
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 7
information. Once classified, borrowers’ subsequent
actions are often interpreted with reference to these
initial classifications.
For a borrower who most likely has little experience
with financial products, it is also important to under-
stand the expectations that her loan officer has of her
because compliance with their relational contract will
define her ability to succeed as a client and, therefore,
access future loans from the MFI. Loan officers must
therefore clarify task knowledge to clients on the techni-
calities of a loan and provide them with clear relational
knowledge (Gibbons and Henderson 2011) about how
those technicalities will be enacted. Will her loan offi-
cer establish and expect an arm’s-length exchange? Or
will the exchange rely on a closer social relationship
where the expectation is one of joint problem solv-
ing, transmission of soft information, and a contextual
interpretation of contractual terms?
By relational styles we refer to the specific manner in
which social actors in given roles interact and relate
to other social actors in given roles. Focus here is not
on the strength of the relationship (Granovetter 1973),
nor of the functional or other characteristics of the role
incumbent or successor (e.g., Burton and Beckman
2007). Rather, it is on the specific ways in which actors
interact, and how this interaction informs future inter-
actions. For example, a loan officer, by virtue of prior
experience, has a cognitive blueprint she enacts via
scripts when interacting and responding to different
client actions. This blueprint is based on her interpre-
tation and understanding of organizational policies,
incentives, and personal feelings about how to relate
to clients. Loan officers can signal these expectations
through a clear and consistent relational style, and
clients can adjust their behavior accordingly. One loan
officer explained,
They care about the loan and about the money, but
they worry more about whether things are going to
work out for longer, you know? They want the oppor-
tunity, not just the money. [000] So, you have to teach
them. You see them begin to manage the loan, and you
have to be clear with them, sometimes repeat the same
thing several times. Then they start becoming more
astute when they manage their money, and then you
see them loosen up; you see them trust you because
you do what you told them you would do. They do
what you told them to do, and then there are no tricks;
you increase the amount when they finish the first
loan and things happen as you described them, so they
trust you.
On the other hand, if a loan officer does not signal
clear expectations, or sometimes employs relational
scripts associated with a letter of the law style and
other times a spirit of the law style, borrowers will
have a difficult time understanding soft expectations
and respond accordingly (i.e., the if-then link becomes
unclear). A borrower accustomed to a spirit of the law
approach to contractual enforcement may thus come
to expect that if he confesses experiencing some famil-
ial challenges that undermined his ability to pay on
time his SL loan officer will then express understand-
ing while devising a plan to get the borrower back
on track. This expectation would, however, be under-
mined if the loan officer responds by indicating her
intent to strictly enforce contractual terms. Moreover,
this inconsistency should lead to ambiguity, misun-
derstanding, or even mistrust about what the loan
officer expects of the borrower in future interactions.
This leads us to expect the following.
Hypothesis 1 (H1). A borrower is less likely to miss
a payment contrary to contractual terms when her loan
officer has an individually consistent relational style.
1.4. Along Consistent (Between Individual)
Relational Styles
So far, we have specified how (within-officer) consis-
tency helps clarify expectations and thus provides a
solid basis for relational contracts. Consistency clari-
fies expectations because the elements that comprise
the actor and action are logically interconnected. The
relational scripts employed by a letter of the law loan
officer are mutually reinforcing manifestations of a
rational philosophy of action with certain premises
about behavior. For example, one LL officer described
the relational script he employs with clients:
I explained things to them carefully, I went over the
contract with them and they agreed. I told them of the
responsibilities and the implications and they agreed.
I went through different scenarios of good things and
bad things that could happen and what the contract
specified for good behavior and for bad behavior and
they agreed.
Consistency is concerned with the regularity of
style or action irrespective of its content. It clarifies
expectations by providing a within-actor baseline for
prediction. For example, prior actions by counterpar-
ties who follow a particular relational style lead to
predictions about their likely future relational styles,
as evidenced by models of relational embeddedness
(e.g., Uzzi 1997,Broschak 2004,Broschak and Block
2014). A broken tie is disruptive precisely because it
removes the dyadic history that sustains expectations.
There is nothing in this definition, however, to
restrict consistency to repeated interaction with the
same social actor. Sociocognitive understanding can
also arise from interaction with successive actors
who have similar relational styles. We label this
“along consistent relational styles” (i.e., consistency
in the individual styles employed by successive indi-
viduals), building on Max Weber’s (1962) concept
of uniformity concerning interaction with different
individuals.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
8Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
An implication of a focus on relational styles, there-
fore, is that trust and understanding can emerge
through dealings with different actors who exhibit a
similar way of interacting in specific roles and situ-
ations. This intuition underlies economic and socio-
logical models of employer screening that incorporate
consideration of categorical characteristics (e.g., race,
gender), as noted above. Another example is the com-
parative advantage that an organization gains from
screening for and then inculcating and rewarding sys-
tematic relational styles that reflect its identity in its
employees. Greetings by employees of Soup Kitchen
International (as demonstrated by the “Soup Nazi” in
the Seinfeld sitcom), for example, are of a definable
type that attracts customers in addition to the food.
In a different business context, Southwest and Sin-
gapore Airlines have different value propositions,
brand identities, and organizational cultures. The for-
mer stresses low-cost, no-frills air transportation that
is fun and requires customer involvement to achieve
cost advantages (e.g., Heskett and Hallowell 1993).
The latter positions itself as a premium product and
service. Although the functional objective of each of
these businesses is to transport people, how they do
so from a customer-experience perspective is drasti-
cally different. Consequently, so are their value propo-
sitions. Yet the sum of their internal processes and
external identity are tightly aligned in consistent yet
different ways, and both are praised for their excep-
tional yet distinct experiences.
Indeed, a flight attendant who previously worked
at Singapore Airlines and switched to Southwest
would have a confusing experience when first inter-
acting with Southwest customers and employees, and
vice versa. Moreover, in dealing with various employ-
ees of each company, a definable, consistent relational
style becomes evident that employees and customers
may have a preference or distaste for. Problems arise
when “what is said” deviates from “what is done.”
The relational styles evident in these organizations
are no accident. Organizations spend considerable
resources selecting and teaching employees how they
should interact with clients (Van Maanen 1973,1978,
1991). In our research context, trainees spend several
months shadowing experienced loan officers, observ-
ing and learning how they manage clients in the field.
With experience, loan officers become keenly aware of
the importance of providing a consistent client expe-
rience, as described by an officer:
Once clients become used to working in one way, if
you change things, many of them get confused and
some even go to another MFI. 000I know I am a good
loan officer, but my style is different, and I learned that
the hard way, losing clients in a previous rotation.
Consistency in the relational styles used by consec-
utive loan officers in our setting should thus facilitate
borrower understanding even in the face of a bro-
ken interpersonal tie because the schemata and scripts
employed by different loan officers are internally con-
sistent and may also be similar, and thus the client
has a sounder basis for understanding expectations
even without any prior experience with a specific loan
officer. Conversely, inconsistency in relational styles
should increase interpretive difficulty in soft expec-
tations or the enforcement of hard stipulations, thus
increasing ambiguity. One client who experienced a
loan officer change explained,
[Turning to his wife] What was the name of the other
woman? Yes, she was nice. I really liked how she
worked. She came in, it was all business: Do you want
to renew? How much? Any problems? Any referrals?
And she was gone. That worked for me. But this new
guy, man, he is so chatty. Always asking me about
other stuff, and then telling me how to run my busi-
ness. I just want my loan to run smoothly, as it did
with [the previous officer]. So yeah, the change was
not great for me. (Borrower)
Inconsistency across loan officers should increase
the likelihood of delinquency as it becomes more dif-
ficult to predict how a subsequent loan officer will
enforce contractual terms. This follows because not
only must the borrower become acquainted with a
new loan officer she does not know but she must
also learn how to interpret and thus respond to the
new loan officer’s requests and demands. The latter
is more difficult when the borrower’s previous officer
and new loan officer have distinct relational styles,
which leads to distinct expectations and responses to
contingencies. We should thus observe the following.
Hypothesis 2 (H2). A borrower is less likely to miss
a payment contrary to contractual terms when there is a
change in her loan officer and the subsequent loan officer
has a relational style consistent with the previous loan offi-
cer’s style.
From the discussion above, we can infer that the
disruption caused by a broken tie that brings inconsis-
tency to a borrower’s experience will be even larger
when this disruption also brings with it an internally
inconsistent new set of expectations. Such disruption
further compounds and increases the level of ambigu-
ity about expectations and likely reactions as a client
must contend with change on two margins: first, the
new loan officer does not engage interpersonally in
the way her predecessor did in response to similar sit-
uations; and second, the loan officer herself engages
with the client differently across situations that seem
similar. By contrast, this is less acute or moderated
when a change in loan officers and styles does not
also introduce internal inconsistency. We should thus
expect the following.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 9
Hypothesis 3 (H3). A borrower is less likely to miss
a payment contrary to contractual terms when there is a
change in her loan officer, the subsequent loan officer has
a relational style inconsistent with the previous loan offi-
cer’s style, but the subsequent loan officer’s style is also
individually consistent.
It is worth noting that relational styles, and social
action more generally, can be consistently inconsis-
tent,5which implies a set of scripts not applied in a
logically interconnected manner. We argue above that
individually (or intra-loan officer) consistent styles are
preferable, as is consistency across different loan offi-
cers (i.e., inter-loan officers). These two propositions
lead to a potential tension when there is a movement
from individually inconsistent to individually consis-
tent relational styles, which also implies along-actor
inconsistency. One can imagine two plausible predic-
tions concerning which basis of predictability is most
useful, with each favoring the two variants of consis-
tency discussed above. Absent theory, we pose this as
an empirical question to be explored with the data at
hand rather than as a formal hypothesis; to wit: Is a
borrower comparatively less (more) likely to miss a
payment contrary to contractual terms when there is
a change in her loan officer who has an inconsistent
style and the subsequent loan officer has an individ-
ually consistent relational style?
2. Setting and Analytical Strategy
2.1. Data
The quantitative data used in this study are drawn
from a proprietary loan-level database maintained by
one large MFI in Mexico for the period 2004–2008.
The MFI is a well-established and regarded market
leader that provides mostly individual loans in urban
areas, primarily Mexico City. The database includes
extensive, standardized measures for 450,000 loans
administered by more than 700 loan officers, which
reflects all the loans administered by the MFI in the
study time frame. On average, each loan officer han-
dles approximately 250 borrowers at a given time,
affording a sufficient number of transitions between
varying combinations of loan officer relational styles
for robust estimation. In terms of relevant informa-
tion, the measures include loan size, size of scheduled
payments, interest rate, term, client payment history,
client gender, whether the loan was administered as
part of a group, and previous delinquency. We focus
on loans as the level of analysis because each has spe-
cific features (e.g., interest rate, term, size) that vary
5On related intuition concerning predictably irrational behavior,
see Ariely (2008).
within borrowers and can have a bearing on delin-
quency.6Moreover, ultimately, loan officers must jus-
tify specific loans in branch credit meetings.
Two features of the study setting are worth high-
lighting: First, loan officers are randomly assigned
to branches upon entry to the MFI and, once there,
are assigned a geographic area of coverage. Second,
the company has a policy of randomly rotating loan
officers across branches. For example, the MFI pur-
posefully staffs new branches with existing, randomly
selected loan officers from the pool of hires and then
rotates additional officers around vacancies. The same
applies when a loan officer leaves the MFI, which
occurs quite frequently. This is a common policy in
MFIs employed to reduce the risk of corruption and
collusion between loan officers and clients, as well as
the “capture” of clients by loan officers who can take
them to a competitor if they leave the firm. When
rotations happen, the loan officer is assigned an exist-
ing portfolio at her new branch (see Hertzberg et al.
2010 and Fishman et al. 2011 on the logic of rotation
practices). Her original portfolio is then assigned to
a new loan officer or split between the officers who
remain in the branch.
Our basis of identification is thus the fact that re-
gardless of why a tie was broken between a client
and initial loan officer, the subsequent loan officer is
assigned at random. In turn, she may or may not have
a relational style that is consistent with the prior loan
officer, and it is this (in)consistency that is of inter-
est here. This provides random variation with respect
to the (in)consistency in the previous and subsequent
loan officers’ relational styles, which is orthogonal
to client and loan officer characteristics or the basis
for the (unobservable) cause of the originating loan
officer’s vacancy, that affords the analytical leverage
required to test Hypotheses 2and 3concerning incon-
sistency in inter-loan officer relational styles. This
exogeneity cannot, however, be substantiated with
respect to our first prediction about inconsistency in a
specific (i.e., intra) loan officer’s relational style, which
nonetheless relies on tests including careful inclusion
of theoretically informed covariates.
This paper is part of a larger mixed-data research
program considering processes and outcomes in mi-
crofinance. The qualitative component of the project
includes ethnographic evidence and interviews with
MFI managers and loan officers (N=76) at differ-
ent levels of experience and institutional authority,
as well as a random subset of their best and worst
clients (N=53). We conducted about 400 hours of
interviews and significant ethnographic observation
6Treating borrowers as the unit of analysis would therefore require
ignoring loan and time-varying contextual information or aggregat-
ing data in some fashion that would obscure important differences.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
10 Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
at three different MFIs in Mexico, generating approx-
imately 1,200 pages of notes that were transcribed by
one of the authors. These qualitative data are used
here to frame hypotheses and to inform the develop-
ment, understanding, and interpretation of key con-
structs, findings, and implications. The qualitative
data have been discussed in other studies (Canales
2011,2014). Therefore, we limit presentation and dis-
cussion of them here to conserve space and focus
attention on the novel contribution of this paper—the
implications of within-loan-officer and between-loan-
officer consistency on delinquency.
2.2. Measures
2.2.1. Outcome Measures. We calculate three
dummy-coded outcome measures that evidence
breach of contract: the first denotes that the bor-
rower missed one payment or more in breach of
contract during the life of the loan (mean =0.333,
SD =0.471). The second denotes that the bor-
rower missed two or more consecutive payments
(mean =0.168, SD =0.374). The third denotes that the
borrower missed three or more consecutive payments
(mean =0.115, SD =0.319). As evidenced by these
summary statistics, a third of the borrowers miss a
payment.7It is worth noting that of those who miss
a payment, nearly half miss a second payment. And
contingent on missing a second payment, two-thirds
miss a third payment or more. To conserve space,
we discuss the first measure in depth while making
reference to the other outcome measures in passing.
Complete results for these models are available in the
online appendix (available as supplemental material
at http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2167).
These measures are well suited to assess a breach
of contract and the theoretical predictions outlined
above because the timely repayment of a loan is the
most important responsibility of the borrower. In fact,
repayment rates are the first and most common met-
ric used by MFIs to evaluate loan officers, branches,
and the overall health of their lending portfolio. More
broadly, the timely repayment of a loan is the primary
measure of compliance in any credit relationship in
Mexico or the United States.
2.2.2. Predictors. We calculate two sets of vari-
ables to classify individual loan officer consistency
in relational styles. The first set includes spirit of
the law (SL), letter of the law (LL), and mixed (M)
7This number may seem high compared with microfinance best
practices, which usually document delinquencies below 5%. Publi-
cized numbers usually focus on 30-day or 60-day delinquency rates,
whereas we focus on the dynamics of enforcement by observing
trajectories of delinquency from the first missed payment. Overall
rates of delinquency and default mirror standard best practices.
relational style dummy variables to capture individ-
ual (within-actor) consistency of relational styles. SL
and LL styles are regarded as consistent and distinct
relational styles guided by principles that subsume
scripts that “hang together” in a logical fashion. By
contrast, loan officers exhibiting a mixed style engage
in practices that incorporate elements of both SL and
LL styles—practices that often do not hang together
in a logically complementary manner. For example,
a mixed loan officer might ask similar questions and
signal a similar personal relationship with a client as
an SL officer but may be unresponsive if the client
faces a problem that makes it difficult to pay, whereas
an SL officer would almost invariably engage in joint
problem solving. By contrast, an LL officer will typi-
cally use formal contractual mechanisms (asset confis-
cations, the presence of company collectors) to compel
repayment.
To code loan officers according to their relational
styles, three regional managers who supervise and
know all the loan officers were independently shown
Table 1and, using the full roster of loan officers, were
asked to code each loan officer as either SL, LL, or
mixed. We emphasized that the categories referred to
their relational styles and not to their performance.
It is worth mentioning that managers thought the
typology was descriptive, intuitive, and a fair repre-
sentation of loan officers. Managers also coded offi-
cers quickly, which both reinforces the validity of the
typology and reveals the depth with which managers
know their staff. Interrater reliability was just below
80%. At the same time, no manager had ever coded
loan officers this way, so managers did not have intu-
ition about which style would be “better.” In fact,
as documented in other work (Canales 2014), when
asked at the end of the process which style they
anticipated would perform best, every manager had
a different theory. There was no instance where one
manager coded an officer as SL while another coded
her as LL. The only discrepancies were between indi-
vidually consistent styles (LL or SL) and mixed. These
discrepancies were treated as mixed. The reason for
doing so is straightforward: the inability of managers
to agree on how to classify a loan officer provides
prima facia evidence that the loan officer’s style is
individually inconsistent.8
To ensure this classification captures real differ-
ences in loan officer relational styles rather than loan
officer experience, human capital, or other charac-
teristics that may be correlated with managers’ per-
ceptions of loan officers’ relational styles as well as
their loan portfolio delinquency rates, we performed
8See the online appendix for more information concerning con-
struct development and validity checks, as well as for ethnographic
information on typology development.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 11
a number of tests reflected in Table A1 of the online
appendix, in which we also discuss construct validity
in more depth. First, we calculated a direct measure
of loan officer experience (tenure) and then compared
it across styles reasoning that experience may be cor-
related with managers’ ability to accurately classify
loan officers. Second, we looked at the trajectory of
loan officers within the MFI, assessing whether loan
officers with different styles were rotated at different
rates (total branch rotations), deserted the firm in dif-
ferent proportions or rates (turnover in percentage)
and turnover in days), or had a different initial train-
ing experience (time in the first branch).
We also looked at other loan officer observable
characteristics, including educational attainment, age,
marital status, and gender. We calculated and com-
pared average loan values and interest rates across
styles. We reason that if managers differ in their
knowledge of loan officers’ experience and task-
specific human capital, thus leading to misclassifi-
cation, managers should be more restrictive in the
amount of the MFI’s resources they allocate to those
loan officers for the same reason. The results of
these tests confirm that managers classify loan officers
according to relational style and not based on a lack of
experience with, or knowledge of, the officers. Finally,
we directly compared loan officer performance by
relational styles to determine whether the mixed cat-
egory is a proxy for underperformance. Results are
inconsistent with such a supposition. On average,
mixed loan officers received average bonuses based
on their loan portfolio performance that did not differ
statistically from LL officers, for example. Moreover,
the loan officer with the single highest bonus was cat-
egorized as exhibiting a mixed style, and numerically
speaking, more mixed officers (126) performed in the
75%–25% interval than either SL (108) or LL (117)
officers.
The second set of measures assesses the impact
of broken ties on loan repayment. A variable codi-
fies cases when a client was transferred to a differ-
ent loan officer (changed officer). We then include
interactions capturing between-actor consistency in,
or the transition from, one loan officer relational
style at time tto the same or a different style at
time t+1. We create summary and fine-grained mea-
sures. The summary measures are dummy variables
denoting (1) between-actor consistency in individu-
ally consistent relational styles (SLtSLt+1or LLt
LLt+1), which means that although the client has a
new loan officer, she employs the same relational
style as her predecessor (“along consistent” relational
styles); (2) individually consistent, successively incon-
sistent styles (SLtLLt+1or LLtSLt+1) (across
consistent or “individually consistent to individually
consistent”); (3) along individually inconsistent styles
(MtMt+1) (“individually inconsistent to individu-
ally inconsistent”); and (4) moving from a within-
actor individually inconsistent style to an individually
consistent style (MtSLt+1or MtLLt+1) (“incon-
sistent to consistent”), which denotes that the original
loan officer employed an inconsistent relational style
whereas the subsequent one employed a consistent
one—either letter or spirit of the law.
The fine-grained transitions include spirit of the law
to spirit of the law (SLtSLt+15, letter of the law to
letter of the law (LLtLLt+15, mixed to spirit of the
law (MtSLt+15, mixed to letter of the law (Mt
LLt+15, letter of the law to mixed (LLtMt+15, letter
of the law to spirit of the law (LLtSLt+15, spirit of
the law to letter of the law (SLtLLt+15, and spirit of
the law to mixed (SLtMt+15, with the omitted cate-
gory in most specifications being changes from mixed
to mixed. These measures provide a means of assess-
ing how consistency in style across different loan offi-
cers over time has a bearing on the probability of
delinquency (see Baron et al. 2001 and Burton and
Beckman 2007 for similar coding strategies).
2.2.3. Controls. We include three classes of con-
trols, which are described and tabulated in Table 2,
to help rule out alternative explanations and some
endogeneity concerns. One class includes measures of
the characteristics of the loan that may have a bear-
ing on the recipient’s ability and willingness to repay
in a timely manner, which helps alleviate concerns
of reverse causality pertaining to client performance
and loan officer turnover. These include the size of
the loan in thousands of pesos (mean =ln4809255,
SD =8.561); gender (female =00624, SD =0.484); days
between scheduled loan payments (mean =15.545,
SD =14.423, range =7–86) (Field and Pande 2008);
whether the loan has been issued to a group, which
may increase social pressure to adhere to the pro-
visions of the loan (mean =0.15, SD =0.357) (e.g.,
Stiglitz 1990,Armendáriz de Aghion 1999,Sanyal
2009; but see Giné and Karlan 2012); interest rate
charged (mean =80.122, SD =6.476, range 58–96);
and a count of the total number of previous pay-
ments the borrower missed (mean =1.083, SD =1.525,
range =0–14). We also include controls that reflect
the history and interaction of the borrower and loan
officer to reflect their relationship and interpersonal
learning, and to account for other relationship-specific
effects. Measures include whether this is the client’s
first experience with a loan, which is important given
that for many clients microfinance is their first expo-
sure to financial products (mean =0.232, SD =0.422);
whether a loan was restructured, which might signal
that a client has experienced exogenous difficulties
(mean =0.006, SD =0.074); the number of loan cycles
the client has had with the MFI, as a proxy for experi-
ential learning (mean =5.701, SD =5.154, range 1–40);
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
12 Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
Table 2 Variables and Descriptive Statistics
Variable Description Mean SD Min Max
BusinessLoan Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 for incorporated firms and 0 for individual borrowers
with unregistered businesses.
00000 00016 0 1
ãLoanOfficer Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if the loan officer was rotated during the loan cycle. 00253 00435 0 1
ClientTenure Number of loan cycles the client has had with the firm. 50701 50154 1 40
Female Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 for female clients. 00624 00484 0 1
FirstLoan Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if this is the client’s first loan cycle with the firm. 00232 00422 0 1
GroupLoan Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 for group loans. 00150 00357 0 1
InterestRateaYearly interest rate charged. 800122 60475 58 96
LoanAmount aSize of the original loan, in thousand pesos. 80925 80561 0.50 50
PastDelinquency Total number of previous loan cycles where the client has missed a payment. 10083 10525 0 14
PaymentDueaSize of scheduled payments, in thousand pesos. 10114 10924 0 20
PaymentFrequency Days between scheduled loan payments. 150545 140423 7 86
PreviousRegime Length of relationship, in number of loan cycles, between the client and the previous loan
officer—conditional on a changed officer.
20370 20196 1 27
RestructuredLoan Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if the loan has been restructured. 00006 00074 0 1
ThreeMissedPayments Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if a third payment is missed. 00115 00319 0 1
TwoMissedPayments Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if a second payment is missed. 00168 00374 0 1
OneMissedPayment Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if there has been a missed payment in the loan cycle. 00333 00471 0 1
IndividuallyConsistenttDummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if loan officer has a spirit or letter of the law
relational style.
00665 00472 0 1
AlongConsistentt1 t +1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had a spirit or letter of the
law relational style, the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer
at time t+1 had a spirit of the law style if the prior loan officer had that style and a
letter of the law style if the prior loan officer had that style.
00021 00143 0 1
IndividuallyConsistentt
IndividuallyConsistentt+1
Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had a spirit or letter
relational style, the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at
time t+1 had either a spirit or letter style.
00019 00136 0 1
IndividuallyInconsistentt
IndividuallyConsistentt+1
Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had a mixed relational
enforcement style, the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer
at time t+1 had either a spirit or letter of the law style.
00062 00240 0 1
IndividuallyConsistentt
IndividuallyInconsistentt+1
Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had a spirit or letter of the
law relational style, the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer
at time t+1 had a mixed style.
00059 00235 0 1
SLtDummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if loan officer has a spirit of the law relational style. 00352 00478 0 1
LLtDummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if loan officer has a letter of the law relational style. 00313 00464 0 1
MtDummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if loan officer has a mixed relational style. 00336 00472 0 1
SLtLLt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had an SL relational style,
the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1 had an
LL style.
00028 00166 0 1
LLtSLt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had an LL relational style,
the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1 had an
SL style.
00019 00135 0 1
MtSLt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had a mixed relational
style, the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1
had an SL style.
00033 0018 0 1
MtLLt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had a mixed relational
style, the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1
had an LL style.
00024 00153 0 1
LLtLLt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had an LL relational style,
the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1 also
had an LL style.
0002 0014 0 1
SLtSLt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had an SL relational style,
the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1 also
had an SL style.
00032 00177 0 1
MtMt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had a mixed relational
style, the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1
had a mixed style.
00041 00198 0 1
SLtMt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had an SL relational style,
the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1 had a
mixed style.
00032 00175 0 1
LLtMt+1Dummy variable. Takes the value of 1 if at time tthe loan officer had an LL relational style,
the officer was reassigned, and the subsequent/different loan officer at time t+1 had a
mixed style.
00024 00154 0 1
aThe log of these variables is used in the analyses.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 13
as well as the number of loan cycles a client had
with a particular loan officer, to control for the per-
sonal bond that might have developed between them
(mean =2.370, SD =2.196, range 1–27). Branch and
year fixed effects are included to absorb institutional
and temporal variation. Loan officer fixed effects are
also included to ensure that the sequential consistency
effects we observe are not attributable to some unob-
served, time-invariant loan officer or borrower char-
acteristics. (Models without loan officer fixed effects
yield similar conclusions.)
2.3. Analytical Strategy and Identification
We model the probability of late payment with the
following summary model:
Pr8Y =19=G0+
P
X
p=1
14IndividuallyConsistentt5
+2LoanOfficert1 t+15
+34AlongConsistentt1 t+15
+44IndividuallyInconsistentt
IndividuallyInconsistentt+15
+54IndividuallyConsistentt
IndividuallyConsistentt+15
+64X5+äl+i+t+1
where Yis a binary variable denoting that, contrary
to contractual provisions, the borrower missed a
payment; ãLoanOfficert1 t+1denotes a change in loan
officer between time tand t+1; IndividuallyConsistentt
is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the loan officer orig-
inating the loan had either consistent relational styles
(SLtor LLt5;AlongConsistentt1 t+1is a dummy variable
equal to 1 if the former and subsequent loan officers
have the same relational style, e.g., LLtLLt+1or
SLtSLt+1(and is therefore contingent on a loan
officer change as are the measures that follow);
IndividuallyInconsistenttIndividuallyInconsistentt+1
is a dummy variable equal to 1 if both the orig-
inating and subsequent loan officers employ
mixed relational styles; IndividuallyConsistentt
IndividuallyConsistentt+1is a dummy variable equal
to 1 if both the originating and subsequent loan offi-
cers have individually consistent relational styles but
employ different ones (e.g., SLtLLt+1,LLtSLt+15
(the omitted category thus represents changes from
individually consistent to individually inconsistent;
e.g., SLtMt+1,LLtMt+15;Xis a vector of
controls; äldenotes loan officer fixed effects; i
denotes branch fixed effects, tdenotes year fixed
effects; and denotes the error term. We also specify
style-specific models that separate the LL and SL
effects in a similar fashion:9
Pr8Y =19=G0+
P
X
p=1
14LLt5+24SLt5
+3LoanOfficert1 t+15
+44SLtLLt+15+54LLtSLt+15
+64MtSLt+15+74MtLLt+15
+84SLtSLt+15+94LLtLLt+15
+104X5+äl+i+t+0
To ensure that clustering is adequately addressed, we
also estimated the model using a hierarchical nonlin-
ear framework and various standard error clustering
techniques. Results are consistent across models.10
3. Presentation of Findings
We begin by providing bivariate statistics in Figure 1
to build intuition and establish a baseline for the
multivariate analyses that follow. As is evident when
there is a change in loan officer, 38.8% of loans expe-
rience a missed payment as opposed to 31.3% when
there is no change, which reflects an increase of 24%
(contrast =0.074: t-test =13001, p < 00000); for two or
more missed payments, the difference is even greater
at 47.2% (contrast =0.071: t-test =13092, p < 00000),
and for three or more missed payments, the difference
is 61.3% (contrast =00061: t-test =13042, p < 00000).
Note that all these tests and those that follow are con-
ducted with robust standard errors clustered at the
loan officer level. It is thus evident that, as predicted
by relational embeddedness and the literature on
change in organizations, borrowers experience signifi-
cant disruption when the tie to their current loan offi-
cer is broken. These quantitative findings are echoed
in our qualitative work. An SL officer explained this
common concern: “Transfers are tricky. You can lose a
lot of clients, because the clients are used to working
with a different loan officer. So when you arrive they
can be like, ‘Who the f—k are you?’ ” The question is
whether the disruption arises solely from the loss of
a personal relationship or reveals a deeper pattern.
In Figure 2we introduce loan officer relational
styles. The bivariate results reveal significant varia-
tion by relational style. For loans administered by
officers with a mixed style, the percentage with a
9In loan officer fixed effects models, 1and 2cannot be identified.
Models without fixed effects and thus main relational style effects
yield similar results.
10 Given the size and complexity of our models, convergence took
a considerable amount of time, making it impractical for more than
a robustness check.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
14 Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
Figure 1 A Change in Loan Officer Results in a Higher Rate of Missed
Payments












.OCHANGE #HANGE
Source. Data obtained from a unique data set of 4501000 microfinance
loans made in Mexico, 2004–2008.
Notes. Black bars denote one missed payment; gray bars denote two or more
missed payments. Differences are statistically significant at p < 0001. Models
are unconditional.
missed loan payment is 35%, with 19.8% missing two
or more. By contrast, 30.3% of loans administered by
letter of the law officers are not paid on time (13.8%
two or more times). Spirit of the law officers exhibit
similar patterns as letter of the law officers with fig-
ures of 31.8% and 13.3%, respectively. For one missed
payment the contrasts between mixed and letter of
the law (contrast =0.047: t-test =3078, p < 00000) and
mixed and spirit of the law (contrast =0.033: t-test =
2048, p < 00013) are both statistically significant, while
the contrast between letter of the law and spirit of the
law is not statistically significant (contrast = −00014:
t-test = −0098, p < 00328). (The same statistical results
hold true for two or more or three or more delin-
quencies; available upon request.) These results sug-
gest that borrowers are less likely to miss a payment
if their loan officers have an individually consistent
style, irrespective of whether this style entails strict
interpretation and enforcement of the rules or a more
flexible style. Following this intuition, we present
Figure 2 Missed Payment Rates Vary by Loan Officer Relational
Enforcement Styles
32% 30%
35%
13% 14%
20%
10
15
20
%
25
30
35
40
Spirit Letter Mixed
One Two or more
Source. Data were obtained from a unique data set of 4501000 microfi-
nance loans made in Mexico between 2004 and 2008.
Notes. The black line denotes one missed payment; the gray line denotes
two or more missed payments. Differences are statistically significant at p <
0001. “Spirit” denotes spirit of the law loan officers, “Letter” denotes letter
of the law loan officers, and “Mixed” denotes loan officers who blend and
vacillate between styles. Models are unconditional.
findings integrating both consistent styles as well as
comparing each style separately.
To provide intuition concerning inter-loan officer
changes, Figure 3(a) illustrates unconditional loan
officer change and missed payment rates by sum-
mary categories of relational styles, and Figure 3(b)
breaks out results by specific transitions within or
between specific styles. The first two columns provide
baselines for one or two missed payments when there
is no change in loan officer. In such cases, 31.4% of
loans experience a missed payment, with 15% experi-
encing two or more. The proportions are considerably
Figure 3 Missed Payment Rates Vary by Transitions Between and
Within Loan Officer Relational Enforcement Styles
31% 33% 35%
37% 40%
44%
15% 15% 17% 18%
25%
28%
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
%
40
45
50
(a)
(b)
No change Inconsistent
Consistent
Along-
Consistent
Consistent
Consistent
Inconsistent
Inconsistent
Consistent
Inconsistent
33% 34% 35% 35% 37% 38% 40%
43% 46%
16% 15% 16% 18% 16%
20%
25% 27% 28%
0
5
10
15
20
%
25
30
35
40
45
50
MLL MSL SLSL LLLL LLSL SLLL MMSLMLLM
Source. Data were obtained from a unique data set of 4501000 micro-
finance loans made in Mexico between 2004 and 2008, by an urban-
focused MFI.
Notes. The black line denotes the sample average rate for one missed pay-
ment if there is a change in loan officer; the grey line, two missed payments.
Dark vertical bars represent one missed payment; variegated lines represent
two missed payments. Statistics presented are unconditional. AlongConsis-
tent denotes successive loan officers with the same individually consistent
styles (i.e., SL SL,LL LL), Consistent Consistent denotes mov-
ing between loan officers with individually consistent but different styles
(i.e., LL SL,SL LL), Inconsistent Inconsistent denotes successive
loan officers each with individually inconsistent styles, and Consistent
Inconsistent denotes moving from a loan officer with an individually consis-
tent style (spirit or letter) to one with a mixed style. SL denotes spirit of the
law loan officers, LL denotes letter of the law loan officers, and Mdenotes
loan officers who vacillate between styles. Arrows denote that, contingent
on a change in loan officer, the prior loan officer had the first enforcement
style and the subsequent one the style after the arrow. For example, MLL
denotes that the loan officer at time thad a mixed enforcement style and the
subsequent loan officer, at time t+1, had a letter of the law enforcement
style. Models are unconditional.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 15
higher when there is a change of any kind, as previ-
ously noted. However, there is significant variation in
these figures depending on the pattern of loan officer
relational style transitions. For example, when the for-
mer loan officer had a mixed style and the subsequent
one an individually consistent style (either spirit or
letter), the missed payment rate is approximately 33%
for one missed payment and 15% for two. These rates
are roughly 14% and 31% less than the overall aver-
age for an officer change (indicated by the horizontal
bars in the graphs). Moreover, for two missed pay-
ments, the figure is the same as that for the situation
in which there is no change. It is thus evident that the
style employed by subsequent loan officer matters.
The columns labeled “AlongConsistent” show that
when the prior and randomly assigned subsequent
loan officers employ the same relational style, there
is a 9% reduction in the percentage of loans missing
a payment and a 23% reduction in two missed pay-
ments. Reductions are also evident with transitions
across individually consistent styles (spirit to letter, or
vice versa). Increases are evident when there are tran-
sitions within mixed styles (+3% and +14% for one
or two missed payments, respectively), with the worst
outcome arising from a move from a loan officer with
an individually (internally) consistent style (spirit or
letter) to one who employs a mixed style (+14% and
+25% for one or two missed payments, respectively).
Figure 3(b) plots changes within and between spe-
cific relational styles. When there is a change in loan
officer, but the old and new loan officers both employ
a mixed style, 40% experience one missed payment
and 25.1% two or more. For letter of the law offi-
cers, the figures are 35.3% and 18.2%, and the cor-
responding figures for spirit of the law officers are
35% and 16.2%. Although a change in loan officer
appears to be detrimental in general,11 it is consid-
erably more detrimental when the loan officers have
mixed styles, as they result in 54.9% more multi-
ple delinquencies than changes in spirit of the law
officers (contrast =0005: t-test =2022, p < 00026) and
38.2% more than a comparable change in letter of the
law officers (contrast =00048: t-test =2046, p < 00014).
A movement from either a spirit of the law (43.2% for
one and 26.5% for two or more missed payments) or
letter of the law (46% for one and 28% for two or more
missed payments) relational style to one with a mixed
style results in a significantly greater percentage of
missed loan payments (contrasts are all statistically
significant). Moving from a mixed style to either an
LL (32.5% for one and 15.8% for two or more missed
payments) or SL (33.7% for one and 14.7% for two or
11 All contrasts are statistically significant when compared with no
change.
more missed payments) relational style decreases this
percentage appreciably.
Unpacking the results further, it appears that mov-
ing from a mixed to a letter of the law loan officer
reduces the probability of a missed payment by more
than 41% (contrast = −0013: t-test = −6074, p < 00000);
this compares with a 28% reduction for similar move-
ments from mixed to spirit of the law (contrast =
00095: t-test = −5039, p < 00000). The results for two
or more missed payments are even starker. But, inter-
estingly, here the largest comparative difference is
between moving from a mixed loan officer to one
with a spirit of the law style (85.7%) rather than vice
versa. An additional pattern is worth highlighting:
notice that changes to SL and LL styles perform sim-
ilarly for the first missed payment. At the same time,
clients who are assigned to SL officers after a rotation
are significantly less likely to miss their second and
third payments, practically eliminating the impact of
a broken tie. Thus, regardless of their preceding expe-
rience, clients who are assigned to SL officers consis-
tently “recover” from a change more promptly.
Bivariate analyses thus far reveal that borrow-
ers exhibit significantly different repayment patterns
based on the consistency of their loan officers’ rela-
tional styles. This implies that relational styles are
consequential, as borrowers are sensitive to them
regardless of their formal contractual responsibilities
or the power dynamics underlying their relationships
with loan officers. To ensure that these results are not
spurious, we present several multivariate models that
account for the characteristics of the borrower, the
loan itself, and the institutional and economic envi-
ronments within which loans are made below to test
our hypotheses.
Table 3presents logistic regression coefficients pre-
dicting the likelihood of breaching contractual provi-
sions concerning timely loan repayment. The models
control for the natural log of interest rate charged,
frequency of loan payments, natural log of the total
amount of loan, gender of the borrower, whether the
loan was received as part of a group, and whether
the borrower has a history of late payment. The con-
trols are all highly statistically significant and in the
anticipated directions, and they are included in all
models.
We build intuition by first presenting a summary
model to demonstrate aggregate consistency effects.
Model 1 reveals that loans administered by an offi-
cer employing an individually consistent style (either
letter or spirit) are less likely to experience a missed
payment than is the case with a mixed style, which is
the omitted category (eb4001255=0088, p < 00001 (two-
tailed test, as are all that follow)). Model 2 separates
the summary individually consistent effect into its
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
16 Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
Table 3 Logistic Regression Predicting a Missed Payment in a Loan Cycle
1234567
Variable b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE)
IndividuallyConsistentt(H1) 00125
4000075∗∗∗
SLt(H1) 0013 00079
4000095∗∗∗ 4000095∗∗∗
LLt(H1) 00118 00091
4000105∗∗∗ 4000105∗∗∗
Mt(H1) 00125
4000075∗∗∗
ãLoanOfficert1 t +100427 00419 00379 00187
4000095∗∗∗ 4000195∗∗∗ 4000155∗∗∗ 4000165∗∗∗
AlongConsistentt1 t +1(H2) 00206
4000305∗∗∗
IndividuallyConsistentt→ −00183
IndividuallyConsistentt+1(H2) 4000315∗∗∗
IndividuallyInconsistentt→ −00066 00165
IndividuallyInconsistentt+1(H2) 4000195∗∗∗ 4000195∗∗∗
IndividuallyInconsistentt→ −00251
IndividuallyConsistentt+1(H3) 4000235∗∗∗
SLtSLt+1(H2) 00178
4000345∗∗∗
LLtLLt+1(H2) 0015
4000435∗∗∗
SLtLLt+1(H2) 00145
4000365∗∗∗
LLtSLt+1(H2) 00141
4000435∗∗∗
MtSLt+1(H3) 00214
4000235∗∗∗
MtLLt+1(H3) 00206
4000285∗∗∗
SLtMt+1(H3) 0019
4000245∗∗∗
LLtMt+1(H3) 00284
4000275∗∗∗
Loan officer fixed effects NO NO NO NO YES YES YES
Branch fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Model fit/diagnostics
N438,252 438,252 438,252 438,252 438,346 438,346 438,346
248,031∗∗∗ 48,030∗∗∗ 48,031∗∗∗ 49,998∗∗∗ 46,402∗∗∗ 46,385∗∗∗ 46,395∗∗∗
Notes. Data were obtained from a proprietary, loan-level database of microfinance loans from one urban-market-focused MFI in Mexico between 2004 and
2008. The dependent variable is dichotomous and takes the value of 1 if, within a loan cycle, a client has missed a payment. In addition, all models include
the following controls, which were omitted from the table for presentation purposes and because the coefficients are remarkably stable across specifications
(coefficients significant at the 0.01 level in parentheses): PaymentFrequency 4000215, ln(LoanAmount)(0.817), ln(PaymentDue)4007775, ln(InterestRate)
(2.09), Female 4000255,GroupLoan (0.118), ClientTenure 4001375,BusinessLoan (0.462), PastDelinquency (0.417), RestructuredLoan (1.214), FirstLoan
(0.38), and PreviousRegime (0.025). The omitted category for models 1 and 2 is a Mixed style. For model 3, the omitted category is the individually consistent
category; for model 5, the omitted category is individually consistent to individually inconsistent; in model 6, it is spirit or letter to mixed; and in model 7, it
reflects any style-specific movement from mixed to something else, or between LL and SL.
∗∗∗p < 00001; ∗∗ p < 0001; p < 0005 (two-tailed tests).
constituent spirit (eb400135=00878, p < 00001) and let-
ter (eb4001185=00889, p < 00001) components, reveal-
ing that both tend to outperform the omitted baseline
mixed style. Model 3 includes a measure for a mixed
(intra-loan officer) style. The coefficient is positive,
suggesting that relative to either an LL or SL loan
officer (the omitted category), those loans adminis-
tered by an individually inconsistent loan officer are
more likely to experience a missed payment. These
tests individually and collectively provide support
for the first hypothesis that loans administered by
loan officers with individually (internally) consistent
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 17
relational styles are less likely to miss a payment con-
trary to contractual terms.
Model 4 demonstrates what happens when a loan
officer changes: there is a significant increase of more
than 50% in the odds of delinquency (eb4004275=1053,
p < 00001). The effect is even stronger for two or
more missed payments (model 3, Table A2: eb4008115=
2025, p < 00001) or three or more (model 3, Table A3:
eb400100255=2079, p < 00001). That these disruptive
effects increase with the length of the relationship a
client had with her previous loan officer is clear evi-
dence of relational considerations between clients and
their loan officers (eb4000255=1003 for every additional
loan cycle, up to a maximum of 27).
Model 5—including loan officer fixed effects (LO
FEs)—begins to provide a test of hypothesis two
concerning inter-loan officer consistency in relational
styles. Compared with a movement from an individ-
ually consistent to a mixed style, transitioning from
a loan officer employing an individually consistent
style (e.g., spirit, letter) to another officer employing a
different style that is nonetheless individually consis-
tent mitigates the impact of severing a tie, reducing
the negative shock from 52% to 26.6% (eb400419001835,
p < 00001), a result amplified in models of two or three
missed payments. Transitions along consistent styles
reduce the negative shock of a loan officer change
from 52% to 23.7% (eb400419002065,p < 00001), or a 54%
reduction as predicted in Hypothesis 2. Indeed, even
movements along mixed styles moderate the impact
of change (eb400419000665=10423 (versus 1.52), p < 00001),
a result that holds across models. Similar results are
evident for two (model 5, Table A2) or three (model 5,
Table A3) missed payments.12
Model 6 provides estimates for style-specific tran-
sitions (e.g., LLtLLt+15. The overall results are
consistent with the summary measures: relational
style-consistent moves—particularly those made
between spirit of the law officers—tend to mitigate
the impact of change (eb400379001785,p < 00001), as do
movements across different but internally consistent
forms (e.g., letter to spirit), albeit at somewhat
reduced rates (eb400379001415,p < 00001).13
Hypothesis 3 predicted that borrowers are less
likely to miss a payment when there is a change in
their loan officer and the subsequent loan officer has
a different style that is also individually consistent.
12 All contrasts are statistically significantly different in models
without LO FEs, and all are significant in those with LO FEs save
for the differences between mixed to individually consistent and
along consistent styles versus across consistent. All correspond-
ing contrasts are statistically significantly different for two or three
missed payments.
13 Differences are statistically significant in models without loan
officer fixed effects. All corresponding contrasts are statistically sig-
nificantly different for two or three missed payments.
Style-specific results in model 7 provide strong sup-
port for this argument. Compared with transitions
that are along consistent styles (e.g., LLtLLt+15
or across different but individually consistent forms
(LLtSLt+15, transitions from a consistent style to a
mixed style increase the odds of one, two, or more
missed payments appreciably. This is especially true
when moving from a letter of the law to mixed style,
which results in a 60% increase in the odds of missing
a payment (4eb400187+00284515100, p < 00001). These
results also hold across model specifications (see mod-
els 6 and 6(b) in Tables A2 and A3).
3.1. Robustness Checks
To ensure that the findings are not driven by client
or loan officer subpopulations, we performed a host
of robustness checks (some of these are presented in
Table 4, and all others are available upon request).
All robustness checks include loan officer, branch, and
year fixed effects. The first two models, 8 and 9, are
restricted to female and male borrowers, respectively,
to determine whether missed payments vary by bor-
rower gender. There is no evidence of this. More-
over, coefficient estimates tend to be similar for both.14
Models 10 and 11 are restricted to group and indi-
vidual borrowers, respectively. Results indicate that
our hypothesized mechanisms operate for both, con-
sistent with work by Giné and Karlan (2012). Mod-
els 12 and 13 are restricted to clients with less than
and more than average tenure with the firm, respec-
tively, to assess differences in possible learning effects.
Models 14 and 15 are contingent on loan sizes below
and above the median, respectively, to proxy for client
wealth, since loan sizes are correlated with it. Mod-
els 16 and 17 distinguish the gender of the loan officer
to determine whether style effects vary as a conse-
quence of whether a male or female employs each.
Finally, models 18–20 are conditional on a loan offi-
cer change (rather than based on interaction terms).
Furthermore, to ensure that the results are not driven
by unobservable loan officer skill, we restricted mod-
els to loan officers who, in the organization’s perfor-
mance assessment, performed above the median, in
the top quartile, or in the two mid-quartiles, between
the 25th and 75th percentiles (results omitted to con-
serve space but are available upon request). The
mechanisms we outline hold.
Contextualizing all the previous findings, it is
important to note that when a new loan officer is
assigned to administer a loan, the borrower does not
choose the loan officer’s identity or relational style.
14 Statistically comparing across models is a nontrivial challenge.
Because our hypotheses are agnostic to sample differences, and the
point of these checks is to establish robustness rather than theorize
differences, we refrain from such comparisons here.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
18 Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
Table 4 Robustness Checks: Logistic Regression Predicting a Missed Payment in a Loan Cycle
8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
Variable b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE) b(SE)
ãLoanOfficert1 t +100523 00516 00673 0048 00517 00435 00538 00481 00504 0055
4000225∗∗∗ 4000295∗∗∗ 4000445∗∗∗ 4000195∗∗∗ 4000315∗∗∗ 4000285∗∗∗ 4000265∗∗∗ 4000255∗∗∗ 4000295∗∗∗ 4000275∗∗∗
AlongConsistentt1 t +100275 00217 00266 00242 0026 00331 00314 00213 00187 00344 00663
4000365∗∗∗ 4000465∗∗∗ 4000755∗∗∗ 4000315∗∗∗ 4000375∗∗∗ 4000465∗∗∗ 4000425∗∗∗ 4000395∗∗∗ 4000425∗∗∗ 4000425∗∗∗ 4000375∗∗∗
IndividuallyInconsistentt→ −00332 00338 00363 00317 00289 00433 00359 0031 00374 00361 00714
IndividuallyConsistentt+14000275∗∗∗ 4000345∗∗∗ 4000525∗∗∗ 4000235∗∗∗ 4000285∗∗∗ 4000335∗∗∗ 4000305∗∗∗ 4000305∗∗∗ 4000345∗∗∗ 4000305∗∗∗ 4000315∗∗∗
IndividuallyConsistentt→ −00211 00228 0023 00212 00247 00233 00197 00243 00308 00219 00659
IndividuallyConsistentt+14000375∗∗∗ 4000475∗∗∗ 4000725∗∗∗ 4000325∗∗∗ 4000385∗∗∗ 4000475∗∗∗ 4000425∗∗∗ 4000415∗∗∗ 4000455∗∗∗ 4000415∗∗∗ 4000395∗∗∗
MtMt+100048 00084 00082 00054 00055 0007 00064 00053 0002 00044 00106 00589
4000225∗∗ 4000285∗∗∗ 4000415∗∗ 4000195∗∗∗ 4000245∗∗ 4000275∗∗∗ 4000255∗∗∗ 4000245∗∗ 00029 00027 4000215∗∗∗ 4000285∗∗∗
SLtSLt+100606
4000465∗∗∗
SLtLLt+100611
4000515∗∗∗
LLtLLt+100616
4000555∗∗∗
LLtSLt+100595
4000545∗∗∗
MtSLt+100649
4000375∗∗∗
MtLLt+100662
4000425∗∗∗
SLtMt+100645
4000325∗∗∗
LLtMt+100763
4000355∗∗∗
Loan officer fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Branch fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Sample/Restrictions Female Male Groups Individual Tenure <Tenure >Size of Size of LO LO Conditional on loan
borrowers borrowers borrowers Med. Med. payment <Med. payment >Med. female male officer change
Model fit
N273,268 164,877 63,624 374,548 232,751 205,484 213,662 224,590 174,290 218,454 112,188 112,188 112,188
231,123∗∗∗ 18,894∗∗∗ 5,763∗∗∗ 43,985∗∗∗ 19,087∗∗∗ 26,748∗∗∗ 23,284∗∗∗ 27,549∗∗∗ 21,187∗∗∗ 24,897∗∗∗ 12,058∗∗∗ 12,037∗∗∗ 12,063∗∗∗
Notes. Data were obtained from a proprietary, loan-level database of microfinance loans from one urban-market-focused MFI in Mexico between 2004 and 2008. The dependent variable is dichotomous and takes
the value of 1 if, within a loan cycle, a client has missed a payment. Where indicated, models also include loan officer (LO) fixed effects. In addition, all models include the controls outlined in the previous table.
∗∗∗p < 00001; ∗∗ p < 0001; p < 0005 (two-tailed tests).
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 19
This exogenous change in loan officer style contin-
gent on change enables us to identify to what extent
moving from an inconsistent relational style to a con-
sistent one impacts breach of contract in the form of
a missed payment. The results suggest that moving
from a mixed to a spirit of the law relational enforce-
ment style reduces the odds of delinquency apprecia-
bly. The same is true for a movement from a mixed to
a letter of the law relational style. The converse is also
true: moving from an individually consistent style
(either LL or SL) to an inconsistent style increases the
odds of a delinquency (see model 2). Moreover, the
results are amplified when we consider two or more
or three or more delinquencies.15
Finally, it becomes clear that clients who are trans-
ferred to an LL or SL officer have similar likelihoods
of missing a first payment, but across the board, we
find that clients who are transferred to an SL officer
have a significantly lower likelihood of missing their
second and third payments. The pattern may seem
puzzling, but together with our qualitative data, it
provides evidence of the mechanisms that we theo-
rized affect loan outcomes after a broken tie. In dis-
cussing why consistency should matter in exchange
relationships, we argued that loan officers “educate”
clients not only on the technical aspects of a loan but
also on the relational expectations of a lending rela-
tionship. When the patterns that clients expect in their
loan interactions change, clients experience a disrup-
tion in the relational contract with the MFI. But the
replacement loan officer can mitigate this by taking
the time to “reeducate” existing clients and establish
new relational expectations:
Before I move to my new branch I go out with the
loan officer and ask him to take me to his clients and
introduce me, and then I spend time explaining to the
clients how I like to work and letting them ask me all
their questions. Then when I am transferred I go out
again, and I say, “Remember me? I am your new loan
officer,” and I tell them again how my style is different
and why I think it is better. (SL officer)
From this perspective, it is less surprising that SL
officers eliminate the negative impact of a broken tie
by the second and third missed payment of a loan.
In loan officer interviews and observations, SL offi-
cers not only spoke more often and in more depth
about the importance of educating clients, but we also
observed them spend much more time in client edu-
cation activities, especially following a branch rota-
tion. In fact, it is an inherent characteristic of the SL
style that loan officers spend more time exchanging
15 We estimated the model using a two-level (Bernoulli) hierarchical
model. The results (available upon request) were substantively and
statistically similar.
soft information with their clients. This includes infor-
mation on why clients miss payments if their loan
officers are transferred and on the expectations they
created during their previous lending relationships
that no longer hold. This pattern provides additional
insights into the implications of our findings for orga-
nizations, which we discuss in the next section.
4. Discussion and Conclusion
Formal contracts constitute an important mechanism
to facilitate repeated exchange, which is essential in
social and economic life. Given inherent limitations in
contracts, it has long been shown that organizations
can derive significant value through relationships,
theorized as relational contracts or as the embed-
ded ties that enable them. However, an organization
cannot establish these relationships—only individuals
authorized to do so on its behalf can. It is thus unclear,
considering the inevitability of turnover and change,
when and how organizations can retain the value cre-
ated through relational mechanisms (Sorenson and
Rogan 2014). Put differently, we need more clarity on
how relational ties, which are established and main-
tained by individuals, can become an organizational
capability.
We propose theory that specifies how both within-
and between-employee consistency in relational styles,
net of relational embeddedness, allow an organization
to largely retain the value of its employees’ relational
ties. We define relational styles as discernible, reoc-
curring patterns of interaction within and between
social actors. Informed by rich qualitative and quan-
titative evidence, we demonstrate that loan officers
who employ consistent relational styles improve loan
outcomes. We also show that when a loan officer
leaves the firm, replacing him with another officer
who employs a consistent relational style mitigates
the negative effects of the broken tie.
We use this evidence to argue that organizations
can derive significant and sustainable advantage by
developing capabilities to establish consistent pat-
terns of interaction with their clients, which in turn
allow them to retain the value of the relational ties
otherwise anchored in their employees. By implica-
tion, specific people or positions become less impor-
tant, and consistent relational styles can constitute an
important link between formal organizational prac-
tices and actual client experiences. This finding may
be particularly valuable in settings or situations where
organizations assign client relationships to a sin-
gle employee, rendering the organization particularly
susceptible to employee turnover.
This implies that organizations should establish
routines that, in alignment with their identity, select
and socialize employees to develop consistent rela-
tional styles with clients. They should also train
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
20 Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
employees to “educate” clients on the relational
expectations of their interactions with the organiza-
tion. To the extent that an organization can maintain
consistent relational styles with clients across indi-
vidual employees, it will be able to establish clear
and predictable relational expectations, thus increas-
ing its ability to appropriate the value of relational ties
despite employee turnover and exogenous change.
The findings also have sociological implications.
Prior theory has considered the impact individuals (or
dyadic ties) and positions (e.g., roles) have on a wide
range of outcomes of interest. For example, it is well
documented that organizations gain value through
the social capital generated by interpersonal ties. At
the same time, relational value travels through differ-
ent mechanisms, with implications for the firm’s (ver-
sus the employee’s) ability to appropriate it (Sorenson
and Rogan 2014). In this research we provide addi-
tional specificity on the sources of relational value and
an organization’s ability to appropriate it. We demon-
strate that the “logic of affection” plays a critical role
but is retained by individual employees.
Yet we also uncover a different layer of social struc-
ture that plays a larger role and is easier for the
organization to appropriate: typologies of relational
styles within and between social actors that establish
clear and stable relational expectations, particularly
in the face of change. Whereas relational embedded-
ness and the network literature more generally focus
on what social ties look like and their implications,
relational styles concern how interpersonal ties are
enacted and their implications for repeated exchange.
Whereas individuals own relational ties, relational
styles can become an organizational routine and, as a
result, transfer ownership of the relational value to the
organization.
Relational styles may also inform other theoreti-
cal concerns. Norm enforcement, for example, is usu-
ally understood to improve with cohesion (structural
embeddedness). We show that compliance to norms
of behavior may also be determined by a shared
understanding of expectations and the social scripts
that underpin them. A change in script (through a
change in style) is problematic because it removes
shared expectations, weakening norm compliance.
This paper suggests the possibility that people who
are similar on several dimensions may also follow
similar relational scripts, making exchange smoother
and more efficient.
As this is an initial statement concerning rela-
tional styles, many questions follow. First, the data
used here are rich and extensive. However, they are
derived from one industry, in one country, during
a specific period of time. The extent to which these
findings apply in other settings should be investi-
gated. Second, additional theorization and investiga-
tion into the antecedents, forms, and consequences of
consistency in relational styles is necessary. Indeed,
we believe there is significant opportunity to broaden
and deepen our collective understanding of interac-
tion patterns and their consequences in a range of set-
tings by considering relational styles, which we view
as a theoretical concept that integrates and extends
insights from rich literatures concerning categories
and relational embeddedness. This includes the basic
question of how relational styles develop in the first
place. Our intuition on the matter, based on field
observations, is that the origin of relational styles rests
largely in social structures including one’s family,
early socialization, initial (i.e., imprinting) and subse-
quent (in timing, quality, and duration) employment
experiences and genealogy, as well as more general
cultural forces. In this case, anecdotal evidence sug-
gests that loan officers who were recruited because
they were particularly successful clients or commu-
nity leaders and were first trained by an SL loan
officer tend to become SL loan officers themselves.
By contrast, loan officers who were recruited out of
college (typically from an economics or finance major)
and were first trained by an LL loan officer tend to
develop LL relational styles.16 The relative magnitude
and interaction of each of these forces is ultimately an
empirical question.
One can imagine other social settings where similar
dynamics are at work. Labor and dating markets are
clear examples, as are alliance relationships between
firms. In each of these cases, learning about how to
interact and transact with another party occurs at one
point in time. But this learning is not necessarily part-
ner or corporate actor specific. There are types of rela-
tional styles that reoccur, and having experience with
a particular type helps shape future understanding
and action when facing individuals who exhibit simi-
lar relational styles. Moreover, because of path depen-
dencies and self-fulfilling dynamics, these relational
style types can remain stable across interactions and
settings (e.g., Schelling 1960). One can imagine, how-
ever, a wide range of types of styles that are concep-
tually nested within a set of principles that serve as
building blocks for variations. We view letter of the
law and spirit of the law types as general categories
of actors’ understandings of the nature of organiza-
tional rules and their enactment, which can be applied
in a host of settings including, for example, educa-
tion, law enforcement, as well as in childrearing or
the sociology of marriage and family. To lower vio-
lence levels in inner-city communities, for example,
police forces must establish trust-based, productive
relationships with the community while also retain-
ing authority and clear territorial control. The “broken
16 These two represent the most common recruitment strategies.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 21
windows” approach to violence reduction, for exam-
ple, is based on the premise that the police will react
with absolute consistency across all types of criminal
acts, regardless of their magnitude.
Community policing models, by contrast, are based
on the premise that no police force can be effec-
tive without the community’s trust, which is built
by police officers who consistently show personal
involvement and concern for community members.
Consistent with this point, Google’s internal research
finds that whereas managers’ personalities and styles
can vary widely, consistency and predictability with
subordinates emerged as the best predictor of man-
agerial performance (Bryant 2011).
As noted above, many organizations spend consid-
erable time training employees on how to interact with
customers with a specific focus on providing a con-
sistent customer experience across employees. When
they join “The Happiest Place on Earth,” Disneyland
employees are heavily socialized. But so are visitors
(Van Maanen 1991). These taught and learned rela-
tional styles can be a key element of the organization’s
value proposition. From a customer’s perspective, it
clarifies expectations for interactions with the orga-
nization. Expectations are similarly set for employ-
ees concerning appropriate ways of interacting with
clients. Relational styles thus buffer the organiza-
tion against changes in personnel that could dam-
age customer–client relationships because customers
are not tied to organizational employees but rather
to how employees of the organization generally inter-
act with them. Creating organizational capabilities to
establish consistent relational styles may be especially
important for organizations that, similar to MFIs,
have dual or hybrid identities (Battilana and Dorado
2010). In the case of MFIs, key constituencies may
have different expectations for whether the organi-
zation should be primarily committed to social out-
comes or to financial returns. A lack of consistency in
how employees relate to different constituencies may
create confusion that can even lead to social unrest.
General principles of interaction can vary across
cultures. A question is thus to what extent relational
styles vary in form and effect across social space. In
our setting, for example, we find that clients are reac-
tive to a change in relational style even though they
are relatively dependent on their loans and are in
a situation of clear power disadvantage. We would
expect sensitivity to relational styles to increase with
the relative power of the counterpart. In similar fash-
ion, we see an effect of relational styles even though
loan contracts in microfinance are of the simplest
type. We would expect the relevance of relational
styles to increase with the technical complexity of
the information transferred in an exchange as the
necessity for, and volume of, information required
for interpretation increases. The extent to which stan-
dardization is important in one context can be one
basis of variation. In some industries or businesses,
there may be an expectation for individually con-
sistent relational styles but not necessarily across-
actor consistency. A business context that prides itself
on individuality or quirkiness may favor such an
approach. Finally, although we were able to exploit
random assignment of subsequent loan officers to test
our predictions concerning inter-loan officer inconsis-
tency, the data used here cannot support such strong
inferences with respect to intra-loan officer consis-
tency, which would require a different research design
and data structure.
Supplemental Material
Supplemental material to this paper is available at http://dx
.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2167.
Acknowledgments
Authorship is alphabetical; both authors contributed
equally in the development of this paper. The authors thank
Gino Cattani, Joe Porac, Catherine Turco, Ezra Zuckerman,
and seminar participants at Chicago, Cornell, Duke, Har-
vard Business School, the Massachusetts Institute of Tech-
nology, New York University, and Yale for their feedback
on earlier drafts. The authors also thank three anonymous
reviewers and the Management Science associate and depart-
ment editors. All errors and omissions are the authors’
alone. Please address correspondence to the second author.
References
Anthony D (2005) Cooperation in microcredit borrowing groups:
Identity, sanctions, and reciprocity in the production of collec-
tive goods. Amer. Sociol. Rev. 70(3):496–515.
Ariely D (2008) Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape
Our Decisions (HarperCollins, New York).
Armendáriz de Aghion B (1999) On the design of a credit agree-
ment with peer monitoring. J. Development Econom. 60(1):
79–104.
Armendáriz de Aghion B, Morduch J (2000) Microfinance beyond
group lending. Econom. Trans. 8(2):401–420.
Armendáriz de Aghion B, Morduch J (2004) Microfinance: Where
do we stand? Goodhard CAE, ed. Financial Development and
Economic Growth: Explaining the Links (Palgrave Macmillan, Bas-
ingstoke, UK), 135–148.
Arrow K (1972) Models of job discrimination. Pascal A, ed. Racial
Discrimination in Economic Life (D.C. Heath, Lexington, MA),
83–102.
Baker G, Gibbons R, Murphy K (1994) Subjective performance
measures in optimal incentive contracts. Quart. J. Econom.
109(4):1125–1156.
Baker WE, Faulkner RR, Fisher GA (1998) Hazards of the market:
The continuity and dissolution of interorganizational market
relationships. Amer. Sociol. Rev. 63(2):147–177.
Baker G, Gibbons R, Murphy K (2002) Relational contracts and the
theory of the firm. Quart. J. Econom. 117(1):39–84.
Baldwin M (1992) Relational schemas and the processing of social
information. Psych. Bull. 112(3):461–484.
Baron J, Hannan M, Burton M (2001) Labor pains: Organizational
change and employee turnover in young, high-tech firms.
Amer. J. Sociol. 106(4):960–1012.
Battilana J, Dorado S (2010) Building sustainable hybrid organiza-
tions: The case of commercial microfinance organizations. Acad.
Management J. 53(6):1419–1440.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
22 Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS
Beatty S, Morris M, Coleman JE, Ellis K, Lee J (1996) Customer-sales
associate retail relationships. J. Retailing 72(3):223–247.
Becker G (1959) The Economics of Discrimination (University of
Chicago Press, Chicago).
Berger P, Luckmann T (1967) The Social Construction of Reality, A
Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge (Doubleday, New York).
Berger A, Udell G (1995) Relationship lending and lines of credit
in small firm finance. J. Bus. 67(3):351–381.
Berger A, Klapper L, Udell G (2001) The ability of banks to lend
to informationally opaque small businesses. J. Banking Finance
25:2127–2167.
Besley T, Coate S (1995) Group lending, repayment incentives and
social collateral. J. Development Econom. 46(1):1–18.
Bester H (1985) Screening vs. rationing in credit markets with
imperfect information. Amer. Econom. Rev. 75(4):850–855.
Bielby W, Baron J (1986) Men and women at work: Sex segregation,
and statistical discrimination. Amer. J. Sociol. 91(4):759–799.
Biong H, Ulvnes AM (2011) If the supplier’s human capital walks
away, where would the customer go? J. Bus.-to-Bus. Marketing
18(3):223–252.
Broschak J (2004) Managers’ mobility and market interface: The
effects of managers’ career mobility on the dissolution of mar-
ket ties. Admin. Sci. Quart. 49(4):608–640.
Broschak J, Block E (2014) With or without you: When does man-
agerial exit matter for the dissolution of dyadic market ties?-
Acad. Management J. 57(3):743–765.
Bryant A (2011) Google’s quest to build a better boss. New
York Times (March 12), http://www.nytimes.com/2011/03/13/
business/13hire.html.
Burt R (2000) Decay functions. Soc. Networks 22:1–28.
Burt R (2001) Attachment, decay and social network. J. Organ.
Behav. 22(6):619–643.
Burton M, Beckman C (2007) Leaving a legacy: Position imprints
and successor turnover in young firms. Amer. Sociol. Rev.
72(2):239–266.
Canales R (2011) Rule bending, sociological citizenship, and orga-
nizational contestation in microfinance. Regulation Governance
5(1):90–117.
Canales R (2014) Weaving straw into gold: Managing organi-
zational tensions between standardization and flexibility in
microfinance. Organ. Sci. 25(1):1–28.
Coslovsky S (2011) Relational regulation in the Brazilian Ministério
Publico: The organizational basis of regulatory responsiveness.
Regulation Governance 5(1):70–89.
Daley-Harris S (2009) State of the microcredit summit campaign
report 2009. Report, Microcredit Summit Campaign, Wash-
ington, DC. http://www.microcreditsummit.org/resource/48/
state-of-the-microcredit-summit.html.
Durkheim E (1997) The Division of Labor in Society (Free Press,
New York).
Emerson RM (1962) Power-dependence relations. Amer. Sociol. Rev.
27(1):31–41.
Fernandez RM, Greenberg J (2013) Race, network hiring, and sta-
tistical discrimination. McDonald S, ed. Networks, Work and
Inequality, Research in the Sociology of Work, Vol. 24 (Emerald
Group Publishing, Bingley, UK), 81–102.
Field E, Pande R (2008) Repayment frequency and default in
microfinance: Evidence from India. J. Eur. Econom. Assoc. 2(3):
501–509.
Fishman R, Paravasini D, Vig V (2011) Social proximity and loan
outcomes: Evidence from an Indian bank. Working paper,
Columbia University, New York.
Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1990) Moral hazard and renegotiation in
agency contracts. Econometrica 58(6):1279–1319.
Gibbons R, Henderson R (2011) Relational contracts and organiza-
tional capabilities. Organ. Sci. 23(5):1350–1364.
Giné X, Karlan D (2012) Group versus individual liability: Long
term evidence from Philippine microcredit lending groups.
Working paper, World Bank.
Giné X, Jakiela P, Karlan D, Morduch J (2010) Microfinance games.
Amer. Econom. J.: Appl. Econom. 2(3):60–95.
Granovetter M (1992) Problems of explanation in economic sociol-
ogy. Nohria N, Eccles R, eds. Networks and Organizations: Struc-
ture, Form and Action (Harvard Business School Press, Boston),
25–56.
Granovetter MS (1973) The strength of weak ties. Amer. J. Sociol.
78(6):1360–1380.
Gulati R (1998) Alliances and networks. Strategic Management J.
19(4):293–317.
Guseva A, Rona-Tas A (2001) Uncertainty, risk, and trust: Russian
and American credit card markets compared. Amer. Sociol. Rev.
66(5):623–646.
Hannan M, Burton M, Baron J (1996) Inertia and change in the early
years: Employment relations in young, high-technology firms.
Indust. Corporate Change 5(2):503–536.
Hart O, Moore J (1999) Foundations of incomplete contracts. Rev.
Econom. Stud. 66(1):115–138.
Heimer M (1992) Doing your job and helping your friends: Uni-
versalistic norms about obligations to particular others in net-
works. Nohria N, Eccles R, eds. Networks and Organizations:
Structure, Form and Action (Harvard Business School Press,
Boston), 143–164.
Hermalin B, Katz AW, Craswell R (2007) Contract law. Polinsky A,
Shavell S, eds. Handbook of Law and Economics, Vol. 1 (North-
Holland, Amsterdam), 3–138.
Hertzberg A, Liberti J, Paravisini D (2010) Information and incen-
tives inside the firm: Evidence from loan officer rotation.
J. Finance 65(3):795–828.
Heskett J, Hallowell R (1993) Southwest Airlines—1993 (A). HBS
Case 694-023, Harvard Business School, Boston.
Jain P, Moore M (2003) What makes microcredit programmes effec-
tive? Fashionable fallacies and workable realities. Working
paper, Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, UK.
Janik M (2012) How is high staff turnover impacting Mexico’s
market? Announcement (December 27), Microfinance Informa-
tion Exchange, Washington, DC. http://www.mixmarket.org/
announcements/How-is-high-staff-turnover-impacting-Mexico
%E2%80%99s-market%3F%20%20.
Lipsky M (1980) Street Level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the Individual
in Public Services (Russell Sage Foundation, New York).
Macaulay S (1963) Non-contractual relations in business: A prelim-
inary study. Amer. Sociol. Rev. 28(1):55–67.
Macneil I (1978) Contracts: Adjustment of long-term economic rela-
tions under classical, neoclassical, and relational contract law.
Northwestern Univ. Law Rev. 72(6):854–902.
Malhotra D, Murnighan J (2002) The effects of contracts on inter-
personal trust. Admin. Sci. Quart. 47(3):534–559.
May P, Winter S (2000) Reconsidering style of regulatory enforce-
ment: Patterns in Danish agro-environmental inspection. Law
Policy 22(2):143–173.
McMillan J, Woodruff C (1999) Interfirm relationships and informal
credit in Vietnam. Quart. J. Econom. 114(4):1285–1320.
Moran P (2005) Structural vs. relational embeddedness: Social
capital and managerial performance. Strategic Management J.
26(12):1129–1151.
Morduch J (1994) Poverty and vulnerability. Amer. Econom. Rev.
84(2):221–225.
Morduch J, Armendáriz de Aghion B (2005) The Economics of Micro-
finance (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA).
Nahapiet J, Ghoshal S (1998) Social capital, intellectual capital,
and the organizational advantage. Acad. Management Rev. 23(2):
242–266.
Petersen M, Rajan R (1994) The benefits of lending relationships:
Evidence from small business data. J. Finance 49(1):3–37.
Piore M (2011) Beyond markets: Sociology, street-level bureaucracy,
and the management of the public sector. Regulation Governance
5(1):145–164.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Canales and Greenberg: Loan Officer Consistency and Exchange Continuity
Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2015 INFORMS 23
Poppo L, Zenger T (2002) Do formal contracts and relational gover-
nance function as substitutes or complements? Strategic Man-
agement J. 23(8):707–725.
Reille X, Forster S (2008) Foreign capital investment in microfi-
nance: Balancing social and financial returns. Focus Note 44,
CGAP, Washington, DC.
Rousseau DM (1990) New hire perceptions of their own and their
employer’s obligations: A study of psychological contracts.
J. Organ. Behav. 11(5):389–400.
Sanchez-Burks J, Nisbett R, Ybarra O (2000) Cultural styles, rela-
tional schemas, and prejudice against out-groups. J. Personality
Soc. Psych. 79(2):174–189.
Sanyal P (2009) From credit to collective action: The role of micro-
finance in promoting women’s social capital and normative
influence. Amer. Sociol. Rev. 74(4):529–550.
Schelling T (1960) The Strategy of Conflict (Harvard University Press,
Cambridge, MA).
Seabright MA, Levinthal DA, Fichman M (1992) Role of individual
attachments in the dissolution of interorganizational relation-
ships. Acad. Management J. 35(1):122–160.
Sharpe S (1990) Asymmetric information, bank lending, and
implicit contracts: A stylized model of customer relationships.
J. Finance 45(4):1069–1087.
Smith ER (1984) Model of social inference processes. Psych. Rev.
91(3):392–413.
Sorenson O, Rogan M (2014) (When) do organizations have social
capital? Annual Rev. Sociol. 40:261–280.
Stiglitz J (1990) Peer monitoring and credit markets. World Bank
Econom. Rev. 4(3):351–366.
Stiglitz J, Weiss A (1986) Credit rationing and collateral. Edwards J,
Franks J, Mayer C, Schaefer S, eds. Recent Developments in Cor-
porate Finance (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK),
101–135.
Uzzi B (1997) Social structure and competition in interfirm net-
works: The paradox of embeddedness. Admin. Sci. Quart. 42(1):
35–67.
Uzzi B, Lancaster R (2003) Relational embeddedness and learning:
The case of bank loan managers and their clients. Management
Sci. 49(4):383–399.
Van Maanen J (1973) Observations on the making of policeman.
Human Organ. 32(4):407–418.
Van Maanen J (1978) The asshole. Manning PK, Van Maanen J, eds.
Policing: A View from the Streets (Goodyear, Santa Monica, CA),
231–238.
Van Maanen J (1991) The smile factory: Work at Disneyland. Frost
PJ, Moore LF, Louis MR, Lundberg CC, Martin J, eds. Reframing
Organizational Culture (Sage, Newbury Park, CA), 58–76.
Weber M (1962) Basic Concepts in Sociology (Citadel Press,
New York).
Weber M (1978) Economy and Society (University of California Press,
Berkeley).
Williamson O (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (Free
Press, New York).
Yunus M (2003) Banker to the Poor: Microlending and the Battle Against
World Poverty (Public Affairs, New York).
Zucker L (1986) Production of trust: Institutional sources of eco-
nomic structure, 1840–1920. Staw BW, Cummings LL, eds.
Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 9 (JAI Press, Greenwich,
CT), 53–111.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.122.183.209] on 09 September 2015, at 12:12 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
... Following prior research examining microfinance loan repayment (Canales & Greenberg, 2016;Doering, 2018), we set a binary variable Missed Payment to one if a borrower failed to make a scheduled payment in a given month, and to zero otherwise. As expected, the overall rate of missed payment increased dramatically in the month of demonetization and remained high in the following months: the monthly default rate of 1%-2% in the 4 months prior to demonetization (July to October 2016) increased to 39% in the month of demonetization (November 2016), and further to 44%-46% in the 3 months that followed (December 2016 to February 2017). ...
... Loan defaults may have been influenced by multiple factors that varied across geographies, such as the speed with which the Reserve Bank of India sent new currency notes to a region, the ease with which people from the region had access to banks or ATM machines where new notes were dispensed, and the extent to which the region's economy relied on cash in the first place. Borrowers also interacted with distinct loan officers with different relational styles, a factor shown by prior research to influence repayment (Canales & Greenberg, 2016). Because we are unable to observe all such factors directly, we utilize statistical approaches that account for, to the greatest degree possible, unobserved heterogeneity in factors that might vary by geography. ...
... The estimator β 1 represents the effect of Same-JLG Peers Missed Payment (Nov16)-the number of peers within the focal borrower's joint-liability group who missed payment in November 2016-on Missed Payment (Dec16-Feb17). An important feature of this specification is the inclusion of loan officer area fixed effects, γ loan officer area (i) , to control for unobserved heterogeneity across loan officer areas that might also drive default rates (Angst et al., 2010;Canales & Greenberg, 2016;Doering, 2018). Table 1 provides formal definitions and summary statistics for all of our variables. ...
Article
Research Summary The microfinance “group lending” approach has achieved widespread success in promoting high rates of repayment, and thus the viability of financial access, in very low‐income environments. Yet group lending, which relies on social connections between borrowers to reinforce repayment, may be vulnerable under crisis conditions in which defaults are commonplace. We explore this possibility in the context of the liquidity crisis that followed India's 2016 demonetization policy. Using proprietary data on the repayment behavior of about two million microfinance borrowers, we find evidence of disproportionate localization of defaults within lending communities. Further analysis reveals evidence consistent with borrower‐to‐borrower spread of defaults not only through formal joint‐liability connections but also through informal community‐level connections, the latter effect being especially pronounced for borrowers from the same religion. Managerial Summary Microfinance lenders have successfully employed a “group lending” approach that holds borrowers within a small group responsible for each other's loans, thus creating strong social pressures for repayment. The findings of this study underscore potential vulnerabilities in the group lending model during economic crises. We analyze the loan repayment behavior of two million microfinance borrowers during a liquidity crisis precipitated by India's 2016 demonetization policy, finding that the resulting defaults were clustered within particular lending communities. Further analysis suggests that social processes within communities played a role in spreading defaults, not only through formal ties between borrowers who were responsible for each other's repayments, but also through informal social ties. The estimated effect of informal social ties was particularly strong for borrowers who shared the same religion.
... Yet, how these actors perceive and integrate moral concerns in their seemingly mundane functions remains underexplored. 1 Embedded in both SEs and communities, FLWs face competing or even conflicting demands that reflect underlying incompatible moral systems (Collins & Whitaker, 2009;Reinecke & Ansari, 2015). While FLWs are morally inclined to help community members who are their clients, because of their strong relational embeddedness (Almandoz, 2012;Bacq et al., 2022;Canales & Greenberg, 2016;Jack & Anderson, 2002;Marquis & Battilana, 2009), they must also adhere to organizational requirements to professionally manage worker-client relations (Canales, 2014) and conform to hierarchical demands from managers, the credit committee, and directors. Most often, the strict requirements of the organization constraints their desire to help and as the moral orders intersect, FLWs may have a split allegiance between community needs and organizational requirements, creating a fertile ground for moral ambiguities (Demers & Gond, 2020). ...
... Subjectivity reflects the agency of individuals in drawing on their past experiences, history, and explicit and tacit knowledge in decision-making processes influencing outcomes (Orlikowski, 2002). For example, in the case of microfinance, loan officers rely on relational ties to escalate commitment to poor performers (Doering, 2018) or leverage such ties to justify granting loans to "unqualified" borrowers (Canales & Greenberg, 2016). Despite its positive potential, subjectivity can also have a dark side resulting in biased decision-making which disfavours some marginalized groups. ...
... However, this community moral system also constrains the social mission (Jack & Anderson, 2002) as social ties and repeated interactions can create malfeasance (Granovetter, 1985). Relational embeddedness places FLWs in a position where they are obliged to be courteous and stretch the rules to help community members (Canales & Greenberg, 2016;Doering, 2018) or where they can exploit their vulnerabilities to discriminate against them (Agier & Szafarz, 2013a, 2013b. ...
Article
Full-text available
Building on the emerging literature on the ethics of social enterprises (SEs), this paper advances the underexplored role of frontline workers (FLWs) as embedded agents at the interface between communities and SEs. Specifically, we uncover the subjectivity of FLWs as they navigate moral ambiguities while performing their professional roles, dealing with rules and regulations within the organizational hierarchy and living as members of local communities. Based on an inductive case study of a microfinance organization in Cameroon, we find that FLWs engage in three rationalization strategies: cautious disengaging, safeguarding self-interest, and justifying relevance. Our findings offer a better understanding of the ethics of SEs by unpacking the subjectivity of FLWs. We highlight a bottom-up account of caring SEs, identify a boundary condition to subjectivity, and present a nuanced view of FLWs in embedded organizations. We also discuss the practical implications for SEs to improve their compassion and cater for the mental wellbeing of FLWs.
... In large part, endogeneity concerns stem from the fact that social relationships are the product of both opportunities for social interaction and the choices of multiple actors (Sewell 1992;Emirbayer and Goodwin 1994;Burt 2010Burt , 2012. How actors choose to shape their networks is likely a function of their own social characteristics, personality, prior networking experience, and networking style, preferences, and abilities (Mehra, Kilduff, and Brass 2001;Burt 2012;Smith, Menon, and Thompson 2012;Canales and Greenberg 2016), as well as the characteristics of those the focal actor seeks to interact with. Hence, it is often exceedingly difficult to clarify mechanisms in network studies because social networks are the outcomes of complex decisions enacted by many individuals (see, e.g., Jackson 2003). ...
... Third, participants will require temporary new agreements that address basic questions of organizing before they can coherently deploy the behaviors that collaboration requires. Without a formal, pre-existing structure, such agreements must run on (interorganizational) trust (Sorenson and Rogan, 2014;Canales and Greenberg, 2015). Jointly, these challenges call for processes that provide accountability and clarity of direction while allowing for trusting relationships, flexibility, and dynamic adaptation of goals (Lingo and O'Mahony, 2010;Davis and Eisenhardt, 2011;Davis, 2016). ...
Article
Full-text available
This inductive study of eight international development interventions analyzes mechanisms that enable integration of evidence in practice, a perennial challenge of learning and collaboration across occupational and organizational boundaries. We demonstrate how structural and programmatic scaffolding practices enabled actors from an array of organizations and communities of practice to collaborate and learn despite the uncertainty and complexity inherent in the international development context. These modular scaffolding practices offered temporary stabilization and support that fostered the counter-normative behaviors and mindsets required for continuous learning and adaptive coordination. Through 226 in-depth interviews with international development experts, including practitioners in eight matched interventions in India, Mexico, South Africa, and Ghana, we identified and analyzed mechanisms that explain the varying effectiveness with which evidence was integrated in each case. Our findings have implications for interorganizational innovation and collaboration under conditions of complexity and uncertainty and for dynamic interactions among individuals, their organizations, and their communities of practice when they are attempting to bring about systemic change.
Article
Purpose This study assesses the impact of microfinance experience on rural households’ subsequent bank credit access, defined as the stepping-stone effect. We evaluate the average impact, heterogeneity and mechanisms of this effect and draw policy implications. Design/methodology/approach Based on 2018 survey data from 2,347 rural households in six Chinese provinces, this study uses the IV-Probit model to evaluate the stepping-stone effect. Findings The microfinance experience increases rural households’ probability of obtaining subsequent bank credit by six percentage points. Whether distinguished by social capital or economic wealth, this effect is at least as significant among households previously excluded from bank credit as it is among those originally favored by bank credit. Two mechanisms behind this effect are identified: (1) the microfinance experience provides financial education, transforming hidden demand for bank credit into effective demand and (2) the microfinance experience creates a credit record in the National Credit Information System, increasing the ability to obtain bank credit by providing banks with credible credit information. Originality/value This study provides evidence of a progressive relationship in which microfinance acts as a stepping stone to deliver “credit graduate” clients to bank credit. And we also provide a different perspective for understanding MFIs’ relatively high interest rates. We may treat a part of the interest payment as a tuition for financial education and a price for credit information. Highlights (1) We study whether microfinance in China had the stepping-stone effect of improving a rural household’s subsequent access to bank credit and investigate the likely mechanisms behind it. (2) Microfinance served as a stepping stone to bank credit: the microfinance experience increases rural households’ probability of obtaining subsequent bank credit by six percentage points. (3) Whether distinguished by social capital or economic wealth, this effect is at least as significant among households previously excluded from bank credit as it is among those originally favored by bank credit. (4) On the credit demand side, the microfinance experience provides financial education, transforming hidden demand for bank credit into effective demand. (5) On the credit supply side, the microfinance experience creates a credit record in the National Credit Information System, increasing the ability to obtain bank credit by providing banks with credible credit information.
Article
Third parties who refer clients to expert service providers help clients navigate market uncertainty by curating well-tailored matches between clients and experts and by facilitating post-match trust. We argue that these two functions often entail trade-offs because they require referrers to activate network relationships with different experts. While strong ties between referrers and experts promote trust between clients and experts, the presence of such ties reduces the likelihood that intermediaries refer clients to socially distal experts who may be better suited to serve clients’ needs. We examine this central and unexplored tension by using full population medical claims data for the state of Massachusetts. We find that when primary care physicians (PCPs) refer patients to specialists with whom the PCPs have strong ties, patients demonstrate more confidence in the specialists’ recommendations. However, a strong tie between the PCP and specialist also reduces the expertise match between a patient’s health condition and a specialist’s clinical experience. These findings suggest that the two central means by which referrers add value may be at odds with one another because they are maximized by the activation of different network ties.
Article
In internal Bank Shinhan, My Car Loan is one of their top consumer products. However, when compared to other car financing competitors, Bank Shinhan was far behind in terms of sales performance. Hyundai Motors Indonesia has four official financial partners to support its car purchasing, namely: Maybank Finance, Mandiri Tunas Finance, Sunindo KB Finance, and Bank Shinhan. The company is the only bank-based financial partner, while the three others were multi-finance companies that specialized in car financing. Moreover, two of them, Mandiri Tunas Finance and Maybank were already well-known players in the car financing industry. Meanwhile, Bank Shinhan is a new player with low brand awareness among the public. In this research, the data collection methods were interviews and questionnaires. As for the research method, for the questionnaire data, the author used the NPS (Net Promoter Score) method and reliability test. As for the interview data, the author used the TA (thematic analysis) method. With this research, the author aimed to get insights to propose new strategies.
Chapter
This article investigates the factors to access to credit of the largest public bank in Ecuador. The methodology includes a logistic regression model to a database corresponding to loan applications from associations of the Popular and Solidarity Economy of Ecuador during the period 2016–2019. The estimates show that the unsecured guarantee, belonging to the tertiary sector, being located in a rural environment and the sex of the loan officer influence the access to financing. In the first place, it was found that the businesses that belong to the tertiary sector show a higher statistically significant probability for the granting of credit, this is in accordance with the business structure of Ecuador where most of the companies are part of this sector.
Chapter
This book was originally published in 1986. During the decade preceding publication there were a number of significant developments in financial economics and major contributions made both by individuals who could be classified as conventional financial economists and by others who do not fit easily into this category - theoretical microeconomists, public and industrial economists. This volume contains a selection from the papers presented at a conference in Oxford in September 1985 which aimed to bring together a number of the leading participants in this field. The papers in the volume cover a wide range of topics - the efficiency of financial markets, new equity issues, asymmetric corporate taxation and investment, credit rationing, international investment, the foundations of banking theory - but they clearly reflect the main themes in financial economics at the time: the importance of informational asymmetries and of taxation.
Article
This paper introduces a social network perspective to the study of strategic alliances. It extends prior research, which has primarily considered alliances as dyadic exchanges and paid less attention to the fact that key precursors, processes, and outcomes associated with alliances can be defined and shaped in important ways by the social networks within which most firms are embedded. It identifies five key issues for the study of alliances: (1) the formation of alliances, (2) the choice of governance structure, (3) the dynamic evolution of alliances, (4) the performance of alliances, and (5) the performance consequences for firms entering alliances. For each of these issues, this paper outlines some of the current research and debates at the firm and dyad level and then discusses some of the new and important insights that result from introducing a network perspective. It highlights current network research on alliances and suggests an agenda for future research.© 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Chapter
Economies are built upon people buying and selling, lending and borrowing. The beauty of the market is that, when it works well, sellers are matched to buyers and lenders are matched to worthy borrowers. But when the market does not work well, goods go unsold and promising investment projects go unfunded. We understand why markets fail - the economics of information provides rigorous underpinnings for why credit markets, in particular, are so problematic.1 The challenge has been to move from diagnosis to prescription. The challenge is particularly great in poorer regions, where individuals may have workable ideas and relevant experience but lack collateral. Even a £100 loan can make a difference to a small-scale shopkeeper or craftsperson in countries like Nepal or Uganda, but formal sector banks have steered clear, focusing instead on larger loans to better-established, wealthier clients.
Article
Scholars of the theory of the firm have begun to emphasize the sources and conditions of what has been described as “the organizational advantage,” rather than focus on the causes and consequences of market failure. Typically, researchers see such organizational advantage as accruing from the particular capabilities organizations have for creating and sharing knowledge. In this article we seek to contribute to this body of work by developing the following arguments: (1) social capital facilitates the creation of new intellectual capital; (2) organizations, as institutional settings, are conducive to the development of high levels of social capital; and (3) it is because of their more dense social capital that firms, within certain limits, have an advantage over markets in creating and sharing intellectual capital. We present a model that incorporates this overall argument in the form of a series of hypothesized relationships between different dimensions of social capital and the main mechanisms and processes necessary for the creation of intellectual capital.
Chapter
Abstract: Purpose – Research has shown that employers often disfavor racial minorities - particularly African Americans - even when whites and minorities present comparable resumes when applying for jobs. Extant studies have been hard pressed to distinguish between taste-based discrimination where employers' racial animus is the key motivation for their poor treatment of minorities and variants of statistical discrimination where there is no assumption at all of racial animus on the part of the employer. This chapter proposes a test of these theories by observing whether employers use employee referrals as a “cheap” source of information to help assess applicant quality. Methodology/approach – Unique quantitative data encompassing the entire pool of 987 candidates interviewed by one company in the western United States during a 13-month period are used to test our arguments. Findings – We find that employers in this setting are making use of the cheap information available to them: Consistent with statistical discrimination theory, minority referrals are more likely to receive a job offer than non-referred minority applicants, and are not disfavored relative to referred whites. Originality/value of the chapter – Both statistical and taste-based theories of discrimination propose similar observable outcomes (lower rates of disfavored minority hiring). While different mental processes are being invoked by taste-based and statistical discrimination theories, the theories are extremely difficult to distinguish in terms of observable behaviors. Especially for the purpose of designing legal remedies and labor market policies to ameliorate the disparate treatment of minority groups, differentiating between these theories is a high priority.
Article
A definition of stochastic poverty is set out in an attempt to formalise the difference between it and risk per se. Three additional factors contribute to poverty in poor countries: weather and price variability which are responsible for a large part of income fluctuations; financial institutions are poorly developed; and social insurance institutions are often weak. The problem of transitory poverty in rural India, much of which is due to stochastic poverty, is then addressed largely by increasing the extent and effectiveness of insurance mechanisms. -from Author